Agricultural and Food Science, Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.


A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

193

© Agricultural and Food Science 
Manuscript received June 2007

Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies 
in Finland

Markku Ollikainen1*, Jussi Lankoski2 and Sami Nuutinen1
1Department of Economics and Management, PO Box 27, FI-00014 University of Helsinki, Finland, 

2OECD, Directorate for Trade and Agriculture, Paris, France
*e-mail: markku.ollikainen@helsinki.fi

This paper assesses policy-related transaction costs (PRTC) associated with the main agricultural and 
agri-environmental policy instruments in Finland. We find that area-based income support measures entail 
low transaction costs as expressed in percent of payments, not only in Finland but also in other European 
countries. Moreover, transaction costs in the Finnish agri-environmental programme are surprisingly low. 
Within the agri-environmental programme, transaction costs increase with more targeted and differenti-
ated agri-environmental measures. For the basic mandatory measures, these costs are even lower than the 
transaction costs for the area-based income support measures. What regards the most differentiated policy 
measures such as conservation of special biotopes or establishment of riparian buffer zones, transaction 
costs increase considerably. Combining these findings with the actual targets of the Finnish agricultural 
policies provides indirect evidence about the impacts of policy instruments and the efficiency of administra-
tion in implementing the instruments. For area-based income support measures, the Finnish administration 
seems to work very efficiently. For water protection targets, enforcement and division of labour within the 
administration seem to be insufficient.

Key-words: transaction costs, agricultural policies, targeting, efficiency of administration 

Introduction

Agricultural policy measures have traditionally 
required administration and monitoring. Recent 
policy shifts from commodity production coupled 

support payments towards decoupled payments that 
are targeted to specific environmental or farm income 
objectives will further increase administration and 
monitoring of policies (OECD 2007). Decoupled and 
targeted policies imply increased administration and 
monitoring, and therefore also higher implementa-



A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Ollikainen, M. et al. Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies in Finland 

194

A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

195

tion costs for the government. Administrative costs 
of agricultural policies accrue at national, regional 
and local levels of administration. It has become 
commonplace to name these costs as policy-related 
transaction costs, PRTCs (see OECD 2007). 

PRTCs belong to the more general class of 
transaction costs, introduced by Ronald Coase 
(1937) when explaining the nature of firms. The 
concept has been further developed especially in 
the work of Williamson (1985). OECD has given 
the following broad definition of transaction costs: 
“Broadly defined, transaction costs could include 
all costs associated with any allocative decision re-
gardless of whether the decision is made in a mar-
ket or by government” (OECD 2007, 21). Furubotn 
and Richter (1998) suggest that the broadly defined 
transaction costs can be divided into institutional 
transaction costs, managerial transaction costs 
and market transaction costs. The policy related 
transaction costs belong to the class of institutional 
transaction costs (OECD 2007). They cover the 
costs associated with the transaction between the 
government and farmers, that is, costs that are as-
sociated with a given policy or policy reform. 

PRTCs are important for any policy or policy 
reform for two reasons.  First, tracking and meas-
uring PRTCs helps to assess the costs of public 
administration and to improve administrational ef-
ficiency, thereby making better use of public funds. 
For instance, a comparison of PRTCs between the 
EU countries may reveal important differences in 
the efficiency of national administration. Second, 
accounting for PRTCs is important for designing 
policy alternatives and choosing optimal policies. 
Recent policy reforms imply increased targeting, 
that is, improved precision of policies. However, 
increasing precision increases policy-related trans-
action costs in a percent of payments (see Vatn et 
al. 2002). Therefore, a good grasp of PRTCs is 
required to find a policy that has a good balance 
between improved precision and increased transac-
tion costs. 

Indeed, there has been a lot of policy debate 
concerning whether the potentially higher PRTCs 
of more decoupled and targeted policies can be 
large enough to offset the economic benefits of 
such policies (for a comprehensive treatment of 

PRTCs of agricultural policies, see OECD 2007). 
As shown by Vatn (2002) and others, the trade-
off between the precision of agri-environmental 
policies and the associated PRTCs is obvious. For 
instance, reducing nitrogen runoff can be shown to 
require a combination of a fertilizer tax (restriction) 
and buffer strip payment that are differentiated ac-
cording to the land productivity and environmental 
sensitiveness of field parcels. However, accounting 
for the transaction costs may reveal that adhering 
to uniform instruments instead of differentiated in-
struments is cheaper for the society (see Lankos-
ki and Ollikainen 2003). Hence, when designing 
policies, the key question is how great the PRTCs 
are.

It is somewhat surprising that, despite the fact 
that the importance of PRTCs for policy choice 
is widely recognized, PRTCs have seldom been 
included in formal models for agricultural and 
agri-environmental policy making (OECD 2007). 
Moreover, there are only a few studies that provide 
empirical estimates of PRTCs of agricultural and 
agri-environmental policies. These include notably 
Falconer and Whitby 1999, Falconer et al. 2001, 
Falconer and Saunders 2002, Mann 2000, McCann 
and Easter 1999, McCann and Easter 2000, Vatn 
et al. 2002, and Rørstad et al. 2007. The common 
way to define PRTCs in this literature has been to 
express them as a percentage of transfers. 

Overall, this empirical literature shows that 
there is huge variation in PRTCs between differ-
ent agricultural and agri-environmental policy in-
struments. As a percent of transfers or payments, 
PRTCs range from less than 1% up to over 110% 
(see e.g. OECD 2007 and Rørstad et al. 2007). 
Studies demonstrate that payments through com-
modities, arable area payments and payments based 
on livestock numbers have the lowest PRTCs (see 
e.g. Vatn et al. 2002, McCann and Easter 1999, Fal-
coner et al. 2001). Not so surprisingly, individually 
tailored agri-environmental management agree-
ments have the highest PRTCs (McCann and Easter 
1999 and Vatn 2002). Quite clearly, the number 
of transactions decreases PRTCs (Falconer et al. 
2001). Moreover, some studies suggest that there 
is a significant learning effect, which exerts down-
ward pressure on PRTCs in the longer run (Falcon-



A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Ollikainen, M. et al. Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies in Finland 

194

A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

195

er and Whitby 1999) as an indication of improved 
efficiency of administration. Finally, evidence from 
expenditure data from U.S. conservation programs 
shows that there are substantial transaction costs in 
developing and rolling out conservation programs 
in their initial years, relative to ongoing costs once 
programs are established (OECD 2007). 

In this paper we assess the PRTCs of the main 
agricultural and agri-environmental policy instru-
ments in Finland. Like Vatn et al. (2002) and Rør-
stad et al. (2007), we focus on the costs of imple-
mentation of these policies and omit the set-up 
costs (initial and closing costs of a program). The 
farmers’ transaction costs are also omitted here 
as they are subject to another study. We collected 
the data from all levels of administration by us-
ing personal interviews that covered all ministries 
involved with agricultural policy implementation. 
We interviewed the representative regional and mu-
nicipal authorities in Southern Finland and general-
ized these results to the rest of Finland. Given that 
our focus is on the implementation of agricultural 
and agri-environmental policies, the data contain 
working time, average salaries, and computer costs 
and other operational costs.

The main contribution of this paper is to pro-
vide, for the first time, information on the PRTCs 
in Finland. We contribute to the international lit-
erature in two ways. First, we contrast the Finnish 
PRTCs to those of Norway, which has similar agri-
cultural conditions. Also, we make comparisons of 
PRTCs between selected EU countries; this brings 
indirect information about how the administrative 
efficiency, that is the effectiveness and capability 
of the administration to implement policy meas-
ures, differs between these countries. Second, we 
link transaction costs to the success of policies in 
achieving their targets and assess how well the di-
vision of PRTCs across administrations and their 
efforts in designing, implementing and monitoring 
helps in achieving those targets.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In 
the next section, a conceptual framework of PRTCs 
is presented and policy instruments included in this 
study are reviewed. This is followed by a descrip-
tion of data collection, the estimation results and 
a comparison of those results with estimates from 

other EU countries. A concluding section ends the 
paper.

Framework and overview of 
policy measures

In this section, we describe the conceptual frame-
work for identifying relevant elements of PRTCs and 
present some typical hypotheses that affect the size 
of the costs. We then discuss the agricultural policy 
measures for which the data are collected. 

Policy-related transaction costs:  
a framework

The key concept of this study is that of policy-related 
transaction costs of agricultural and agri-environ-
mental policies. To discuss PRTCs of agricultural 
policies with a sharp focus, we distinguish between 
the set-up costs and running costs of PRTCs. The 
set-up costs of PRTCs refer to initial and closing 
costs (i.e., the costs related to initiating or closing a 
program) of any policy, including required agricul-
tural census systems. Typically, the implementation 
and monitoring system, such as the EU’s IACS 
(Integrated Administration and Control System) 
takes the main share of set-up costs. The running 
costs in turn refer to all ongoing variable and fixed 
costs of policy implementation in practice. 

Set-up and running costs have an interesting 
mutual relationship. Set-up costs, typically lump-
sum costs, may originally be high, but after the 
establishment of the system these costs are sunk, 
so that it is the running costs of a policy that really 
matter. Modifying Vatn (2001), we illustrate this 
relationship in Figure 1, where the vertical axis de-
scribes PRTC and the horizontal axis the precision 
of the policy in question. Precision is defined as the 
degree to which the desired target is achieved and 
described graphically as the distance between the 
desired and realized situation. 



A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Ollikainen, M. et al. Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies in Finland 

196

A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

197

Figure 1 illustrates two alternative policies: 
Policy 1 with associated transaction costs (P1) en-
tailing high set-up costs, F, but low running costs 
ts(p), and Policy 2 with associated transaction costs 
(P2) with zero set-up costs but high running costs 
TS(p). As Figure 1 demonstrates, despite the fixed 
costs, the total PRTCs under Policy 1 are lower 
than those of Policy 2 when the policy precision 
level is higher than p’. The important lesson of 
Figure 1 is, thus, that existing implementation and 
monitoring systems, such as the EU’s IACS, entail 
sunk set-up costs but can benefit many alternative 
policy designs. For this reason, the focus of the 
study is on running costs of policy instruments, 
because most likely the running costs differ signifi-
cantly from one policy measure to another.

The link of PRTC to actual policy and the im-
portance of understanding transaction costs are 

illustrated in Figure 2, which describes the mar-
ginal social costs (MSC) and marginal social ben-
efits (MSB) of a given policy i as a function of its 
precision. The MSB curve is decreasing in preci-
sion and varies in the type of the good in question. 
The vertical axis of Figure 2 measures marginal 
social benefits and marginal social costs of a policy 
whereas the horizontal axis measures the precision 
of this policy.

In Figure 2, if transaction costs are neglected, 
the optimal policy in terms of its precision would 
be p*. However, at that point the marginal social 
benefits are lower than the overall marginal social 
costs comprising transaction costs. Hence, the op-
timal policy would be to choose p**, which implies 
less precision in the policy.

OECD (2007) distinguishes between three 
main sub-categories of PRTCs for budgetary pay-
ments for agricultural policies: initial and closing 
costs (set-up costs), implementation costs (running 
costs) and farmers’ participation costs.1  Specific 
items under each category are represented in Fig-
ure 3. 

PRTCs occur first at the governmental level, 
where the policy is explored and designed. The de-
signed policies need to be enacted and the required 
consensus between government and civil society 
has to be built. Policy implementation comprises 
the distribution of support and monitoring and con-
trol. Distribution of payment comprises the identi-
fication of beneficiaries, processing of applications 
and the provision of payment.  The processing of 
applications may sometimes need further fine-tun-
ing and special conditions, individual or collective 
projects and technical assistance. Eligibility and 
compliance need to be monitored. Enforcement 
and litigation might follow, if required compliance 
is not achieved. Participation costs refer to all costs 
that farmers have to bear to participate in the policy 
(OECD 2007).

In this study the focus is on the middle sub-
category, the costs of implementing agri-environ-

1  This is by no means the only way of defining the 
relevant transaction costs.  For instance, Dahlman (1979) 
breaks up the transaction costs in three components: the cost 
of information gathering, the cost of contracting and the cost 
of control.

P1 = F + ts (p) 

PRTC 

P2 = TS (p)

F 

Precision, p
p’ 

Fig. 1. Set-up costs, unit costs and the precision of 
policies

MS Bi

mci (p)  

Precision, p

MSB i , M S C i

p*  p**  

M S Ci = mc i (p)  +  Pi (p)  

Fig. 2. The impact of PRTCs on optimal policies



A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Ollikainen, M. et al. Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies in Finland 

196

A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

197

mental policies. As we analyze administration, the 
participation aspect is omitted, as well as set-up 
costs. However, given that agri-environmental 
policies are revised every five to seven years, we 
include the costs of design (which has in practice 
been fine-tuning in Finland) in our analysis. The 
costs identified in Figure 3 for this study can be 
assessed using either direct interviews, top-down 
or bottom-up approaches (for these methods, see 
OECD 2007). 

As for the expected size of the identified cost 
items, we follow Williamson (1985). He identifies 
three main factors affecting the transaction costs 
for different goods: asset specificity, frequency 
and uncertainty (for a discussion, see Milgrom 
and Roberts, 1992, 303-313). Rørstad et al. (2007) 
applied these concepts to agri-environmental poli-
cies as follows. If asset specificity (variation in 
the quality of the good in question) is high, poli-
cies targeted to it may entail high PRTC, and vice 
versa. Hence, environmental goods, such as local 
landscape features and semi-natural habitats, imply 
that agri-environmental policies targeted directly to 
their provision may have high PRTCs. By contrast, 
targeting market goods with low asset specificity, 
such as commodities, fertilizers and pesticides en-

tails potentially low PRTCs. The higher the trans-
action frequency (how often the transaction is un-
dertaken, or how many operations or contracts can 
be treated equally) and the number of agents, the 
lower the PRTCs per program participant or per 
contract will be. Uncertainty relates to behavior 
under asymmetric information; the higher the in-
formation gap the higher the PRTCs. Uncertainty 
and PRTCs are negatively linked to the frequency 
of transactions, as frequent transactions create 
trust (Rørstad et al. 2007). Note that through these 
features PRTCs occur at all stages of the policy 
process: design, implementation, monitoring and 
evaluation of policy. 

Agricultural and agri-environmental  
policies in Finland

Before the implementation of the Single Farm Pay-
ment Scheme as part of the Mid-Term Review of 
the EU Common Agricultural Policy, the Finnish 
agricultural policy consisted of the following main 
agricultural support measures: CAP compensation 
payments, Compensatory allowances (support 

Transaction costs 

Implementation costs 

Farmers’ costs 

 
Distribution Monitoring/control 

Identification of 
beneficiaries 

- filling forms 

- transport 

- etc. 

Actual payment 

Compliance and 
enforcement  

Eligibility 

Participation costs Set-Up Costs 

Processing of 
applications, 
including 
contracting 

Research, 
information 

Design 

Enactment/ 
consensus 
building 

Evaluation 
Monitoring of 
implementation  

Fig. 3. Sub-categories of poli-
cy-related transaction costs for 
the provision of budgetary pay-
ments – modified from OECD 
(2007) and Mann (2000).



A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Ollikainen, M. et al. Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies in Finland 

198

A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

199

for Less Favoured Areas, LFA), National support 
and Agri-environmental support. We assess the 
PRTCs for all these support forms. In terms of 
our framework, we can expect that the PRTCs for 
area-based CAP support (CAP and LFA payments) 
and National support differ from those of the agri-
environmental support. While the other support 
measures are frequent, simple and subject to easy 
monitoring, agri-environmental support measures 
are less frequent, differentiated and more subject to 
opportunistic behaviour due to asymmetric informa-
tion. Hence, the natural hypothesis is that the other 
examined support payments entail lower PRTCs 
than agri-environmental support payments. 

CAP compensation payment is paid on the ba-
sis of the arable area and the number of animals 
and it constitutes a central policy instrument in the 
common agricultural policy of the EU. These area 
payments are based on regional reference yields 
on the basis of historical production. Area-based 
CAP support also includes the so-called drying 
aid (24 €/ton) in Finland and in Northern Sweden. 
The amount of support is 295 €/hectare in support 
area A, € 243/ha in areas B and C1 and € 200/ha 
in areas C2-C4 (Niemi and Ahlstedt 2005). The 
location of different agricultural support areas in 
Finland is shown in Figure A1 in Appendix and the 
level of payments in Table A1 in Appendix. CAP 
support is fully financed by the EU. Compensatory 
allowances (LFA support) are intended to equalise 
differences between different agricultural regions, 
guarantee farming and maintain the rural popula-
tion. LFA support is paid in all areas of Finland 
and the average EU contribution is 32%. The LFA 
support is € 150/ha in support area A, € 200/ha in 
support areas B and C1 and in support areas C2-C4 
it is €210/ha. (Niemi and Ahlstedt 2005).

Acreage-based national support is divided into 
four main policy measures: Northern aid, National 
aid for Southern Finland, National supplement to 
the agri-environmental support, and National sup-
plement to the LFA support. These payments are 
intended to secure the preconditions for Finnish 
agriculture in different support regions and produc-
tion lines. The support is based on cultivated area 
and crop, livestock units, and support area (Niemi 
and Ahlstedt 2005).

The agri-environmental support compensates 
the farmers for extra costs incurred and income 
losses due to the undertaking of environmental 
measures. The contribution of the EU is on the av-
erage 55 percent (Niemi and Ahlstedt 2005). The 
agri-environmental support consists of basic meas-
ures, additional measures and contracts for special 
environmental measures. There are five basic man-
datory measures. A farmer that participates in the 
agri-environmental support scheme gives a com-
mitment to the basic measures for five years. The 
amount of support is €93/ha. In addition to these 
five basic measures, livestock farmers have a sixth 
measure concerning the handling of animal manure 
and for that they receive an extra payment so that 
the support for livestock farmers is €117/ha. 

Mandatory basic measures are as follows. Envi-
ronmental planning and monitoring in farming: the 
objective of this measure is to establish an active 
planning and monitoring system. Basic fertilisa-
tion levels of arable crops: here the objective is to 
reduce the nutrient load to surface waters, ground 
waters and emissions to air by a more precise use of 
fertiliser and manure. The objective of plant protec-
tion is to reduce pesticide emissions by means of 
training and testing of the equipment used in the 
spreading of plant protection products. Headlands 
and filter strips prevent and reduce the runoff of 
nutrients and soil particles to watercourses. Main-
taining biodiversity and landscape aim at preserv-
ing the traditional biotopes and open arable areas 
shaped by agriculture. Basic measures on livestock 
farm aim at reducing nutrient runoff and emis-
sions related to the storing and handling of manure 
(Kröger et al. 2004). 

Besides the mandatory basic measures, each 
farmer has to select one additional measure. For 
this study, the following three measures were se-
lected. More precise fertilisation aims to reduce nu-
trient loads by increasing precision in the combined 
use of manure and chemical fertilisers. Plant cover 
in winter and reduced tillage aims to reduce erosion 
and prevent runoff of particulate phosphorus and 
nitrogen into surface and ground water. Additional 
measures on livestock farms aim to reduce nutrient 
loading, promote the welfare of production animals 



A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Ollikainen, M. et al. Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies in Finland 

198

A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

199

and reduce ammonia emissions from manure stor-
ages. (Kröger et al. 2004)

Special environmental measures consist of en-
vironmentally more effective measures and they 
are targeted to a limited number of farmers. Con-
tracts are made for five or ten years. In order to be 
eligible for these measures, the farmer must imple-
ment the basic and additional measures as well. 
The following special measures were selected for 
this study. Buffer zones aim to reduce erosion and 
nutrient runoff through the establishment of at least 
15 meters wide buffer zones to those field parcels 
that have a steep slope towards a watercourse. 
Traditional biotopes aim to preserve and enhance 
the biodiversity of flora and fauna in traditional 
biotopes (such as meadows and pastures). Their 
purpose is also to maintain rural cultural heritage 
and landscape values. (Kröger et al. 2004)

Levels of administrations and 
generation of data 

The data for this study was gathered in 2005. Fol-
lowing the logic of Figure 3, we identified the levels 
of public authorities participating in the public 
implementation of the Finnish agricultural policies. 
The levels of administration follow the Integrated 
Administration and Control System (IACS) of the 
EU and comprise the national, regional and munici-
pal authorities. Three ministries are participating 
in the administration of the programmes at the 
national level. These ministries are: the Ministry of 
Agriculture and Forestry, the Ministry in Industry 
and the Trade and Ministry of the Environment. The 
Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry is responsible 
for the design of policies. 

Administration at the regional level is conduct-
ed by the Rural Departments of the Ministry in 
Industry and Trade and the Regional Environment 
Centres of the Ministry of the Environment. Final-
ly, at the local level there are municipal agricultural 
authorities. All levels of administration participate 
in the implementation of agricultural policies. 

Municipal agricultural authorities, governed by 
the Rural Departments, handle, for instance, farm-
ers’ support payment applications and other related 
issues. Regional Environment Centres and Rural 
Departments also directly contact farmers when 
promoting alternative policy measures, designing 
prescriptions and monitoring the implementation of 
the measures. The monitoring and enforcement of 
policy is accomplished by the IACS.  Monitoring 
of policy consists of measurement with satellites 
image and farm and field inspections. It is carried 
out by the Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, 
Rural Departments, Regional Environment Centres 
and municipal authorities.

Our interviews covered two ministries, the 
Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry and the Min-
istry of the Environment. We chose the representa-
tive Rural Department and Regional Environment 
Centres from Southern Finland, because it is the 
most important area for crop production. The in-
terviews began from the Ministry of Agriculture 
and Forestry.  Here, the data gathering method was, 
exceptionally, a top-down approach. Information 
of total person-years was collected from electronic 
telephone directory that includes task descriptions. 
Based on that, person-years were divided between 
policy measures. The overhead costs were derived 
from the ministry’s report of administration pro-
ductivity program. 

Data from the Ministry of the Environment are 
based on direct interview in the department of En-
vironmental Protection. The duties of the Ministry 
of the Environment (in year 2004) relate to agri-
environmental support design, implementation 
and follow-up. In the interview, the share of basic 
measures was about 10%, and the additional and 
special measures took up 20% and 70% of labour 
input, respectively. The share is the same for all du-
ties. On the basis of this information and allocated 
time the person-years within the measures and du-
ties were divided. 

The Rural Departments of Employment and 
Economic Development Centres are supervised by 
the Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry and the 
Ministry in Industry and Trade. There are a total of 
15 Rural Departments. The Varsinais-Suomi Rural 
Department was chosen as the representative office 



A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Ollikainen, M. et al. Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies in Finland 

200

A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

201

because of its location in the main crop production 
area. Within the Rural Department, the Support and 
Environmental Service unit was the main focus of 
this study.

In the interview, annual task calendar was used 
to get overall picture of activities related to our 
study. Monitoring is the most important duty of the 
Rural Departments. That includes the monitoring 
farmers in co-operation with municipal authorities 
and the Regional Environment Centres, monitoring 
municipal authorities, and different cross-examina-
tions. Monitoring information is registered at very 
high accuracy. This proved helpful in the division 
of the labour input for different policy measures 
and administrative duties. Consequently, these data 
can be considered to be very reliable.

There are a total of 13 Environment Centres. 
The Centre of Southwest Finland was selected as 
a representative office. Agricultural duties in the 
Regional Environment Centre are supervised by 
the Rural Group of Environmental Techniques and 
Management Department. The duties of the Re-
gional Environment Centre concern only special 
agri-environmental measures. Labour years were 
allocated to the policy measures by similar time 
usage estimates as in the case of the Ministry of En-
vironment. This entails some uncertainty when it 
comes to allocation of person-years, yet it is based 
on the assessment of a specialist. 

In 2004, there were altogether 444 municipali-
ties in Finland, out of which we chose Loimaa and 
Somero as the representative municipalities. Data 
are based on interviews of persons responsible for 
municipal rural services. The division between the 
duties and measures is based on evaluated shares 
of person-years. Labour and overhead costs were 
derived from settlement of accounts. 

We generalized the data from the interviews to 
the whole Finland as follows. We assumed that the 
unit implementation costs do not differ between 
areas; they differ only across the measures. Under 
this assumption we can define a coefficient for each 
measure as the share of support payments paid in 
each region to the overall support payments in the 
whole country for this measure. Thus, the regional 
total transaction costs of the Rural Departments, 
Environment Centres and Municipal are calculated 

as a sum of constant unit transaction costs from the 
acreage-based support payments and from the agri-
environmental support payments multiplied by the 
share of payments by the regional authorities in the 
payment of the whole country. 

Policy-related transaction costs 
for the Finnish agricultural 

policy

We follow the convention and express the transac-
tion costs as a percentage of the payment transfers. 
This is generally regarded as the most convenient 
way to compare different policy measures. Using 
percentage expressions leans to an assumption that 
transfers are a proxy for the size of the policy or the 
value of social outcomes. The results are generalized 
to the national level and reported in Table 1. 

In Table 1, we aggregated the area-based CAP, 
LFA and national support into one figure, as the 
PRTCs associated with each support measure were 
quite similar. This only reflects the fact that the 
measures by themselves are quite similar. The 
PRTCs of the basic, additional and special meas-
ures are from the interviews. While it was impos-
sible to impute costs separately for the specific sub-
measures among the basic measures, we were able 
to define the costs for some selected additional and 
special measures that represent a set of fairly differ-
entiated and targeted measures. This was done by 
assuming that the costs of the agri-environmental 
policy measures vary with the number of hectares 
they are applied to.

From Table 1, the basic lesson is quite evident. 
PRTCs for CAP, LFA and national supports are rel-
atively low. These measures are very frequent and 
simple, and given the IACS system, they are easy 
to monitor. Thus, PRTCs should be low. As we will 
shortly see, these figures are perfectly in line with 
findings in Norway and many other countries. 

Interestingly, the PRTCs in percent of the total 
agri-environmental support are quite low, too. They 



A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Ollikainen, M. et al. Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies in Finland 

200

A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

201

are only slightly higher than the PRTCs associated 
with the area-based support. The explanation for 
this feature is two-fold. First, the share of basic 
measures in the agri-environmental support pay-
ments is large, and the farmers’ participation rate 
in basic measures is high (more than 92% of farm-
ers), making thereby the magnitude of payments 
large, since 90% of agri-environmental funding 
is allocated to basic and additional measures and 
only 10% to special measures. The high participa-
tion rate and large payments decrease the percent 
PRTCS. Second, the enforcement costs of basic 
measures are fairly low: All basic measures ad-
dressing land use and crop choices are quite easy 
and inexpensive to monitor due to establishment of 
the IACS system. However, a sub-measure that is 
difficult to monitor and enforce is the application 
limits for fertilizer use. 

We next focus in detail on the basic, selected and 
additional measures within the agri-environmental 
support programme. The basic measures have low 
PRTCs – even lower than those associated with the 
CAP, LFA, and national support payments. In line 
with our hypothesis, PRTCs increase when mov-
ing from basic measures to selected additional and 
special measures. The selected special measures 
entail the highest PRTCs 33.1%. 

Within the selected additional measures, the 
measure on livestock farms has fairly low PRTC; 
it is only about half of the average PRTCs for addi-
tional measures. Interestingly, payments to a more 
precise fertilisation have higher PRTCs than other 
additional measures. The special measures entail 
high transaction costs. These arise from a large la-
bour input for design and monitoring. The differ-
ence between percent PRTCs of traditional biotopes 
and riparian zones was larger than expected, since 
traditional biotopes are a very site-specific meas-
ure. As design and monitoring of riparian zones 
require significant labour input and total payments 
are quite low, the percent PRTCs were highest of 
the analysed policy measures.

Table 2 indicates how the PRTCs are associ-
ated with the area support payments and agri-envi-
ronmental support at each level of administration. 
Also, it shows how the transaction costs emerge 
from the three basic operations, policy design, im-
plementation, and monitoring. 

From Table 2, the share of the Ministry of Ag-
riculture and Forestry is almost 25 million euros, 
which makes 61% of the total PRTCs. The Ru-
ral Departments have PRTCs of 7.6 million euros 
(18.6%); the share of municipal authorities is 13% 
and Regional Environment Centres 10%. While 
implementation entails the highest PRTC item in 

Measure
PRTC, 
€ 1000

Subsidy,  
€ 1000

PRTC/subsidy,  
%

CAP-, LFA- and national support 32 077 1 519 000 2.11
Agri-environmental support 8 664 312 000 2.78
Total 40 741 1 831 000 2.23
Forms of the agri-environmental support
Basic measures (total) 3 079 211 000 1.46
Additional measures (total) 2 719 40 620 6.69
    More accurate fertilization 471 4 800 9.81
    Plant cover in winter and reduced tillage 1 710 21 270 8.04
    Additional measures on livestock farms 538 14 550 3.70
Special measures (total) 2 866 8 670 33.06
    Buffer zones 1 131 2 640 42.83
    Traditional biotopes 1 735 6 030 28.77

Table 1. PRTC of the Finnish agricultural and agri-environmental policy measures in the year 2004.



A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Ollikainen, M. et al. Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies in Finland 

202

A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

203

the CAP, LFA and national support, PRTCs in mon-
itoring are the biggest item in agri-environmental 
policy. The share of monitoring costs of the total 
PRTCs in agri-environmental scheme is about 42% 
which is almost twice as high as monitoring costs 
in the area payment support. However, the abso-
lute cost is about € 3.64 million, which cannot be 
regarded high.

Table 3 provides a more detailed look at the 
PRTCs associated with the mandatory, additional, 
and selected measures of the agri-environmental 
support. 

Table 3 contains many interesting features. 
Most of PRTCs for the Rural Departments emerge 
from the monitoring of the basic and additional 
measures. In contrast, the respective figure of the 
local administration, the municipal agricultural 
authorities is just 1%, although they should have 
in principle the best possibilities to monitor the 
farmers. The task of monitoring is mostly a duty 
of Rural Departments. Environmental centers have 
the role only in the case of special measures. An 
interesting observation is that the share of PRTCs 
in design is very high, 52% of total PRTC of the 
Environmental Centers. This is due to the fact that 

buffer zones and traditional biotopes require a lot of 
labor input to make both regional and farm specific 
plans for these measures. As pointed out by the 
referee, the design by the Environmental Centers 
can equally well be interpreted as the implementa-
tion of the agri-environmental policy. This would 
imply that the more than 90% of their PRTCs are 
due to implementation.

In Figure 4 we omit the allocation of PRTCs 
between the administrations and demonstrate how 
the total policy-related transaction costs are divided 
in aggregate between policy design, policy imple-
mentation, and monitoring. 

From Figure 4, in comparison to area-based 
income support measures, the basic and additional 
agri-environmental measures imply a higher share 
of monitoring costs. In fact, monitoring costs rep-
resent approximately 60% of transaction costs in 
the case of basic and additional agri-environmental 
measures. In the case of specialised agri-environ-
mental measures, the share of policy design is rela-
tively highest, which is explained by the heteroge-
neous and site-specific nature of these two policy 
measures. Indeed, both of these special measures 
require a detailed site-specific planning, which in-

Measure and authority
Total PRTCs,  

€ 1000
PRTCs in 
design, %

PRTCs in  
implementation, %

PRTCs in  
monitoring, %

CAP, LFA and national support 32 077 24 55 21
Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry 23 340 29 58 13
Ministry of the Environment 0 0 0 0
Rural Departments 3 678 0 0 100
Environment Centers 0 0 0 0
Municipal Authorities 5 059 21 78 1

Agri-environmental support 8 664 23 35 42
Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry 1 641 39 39 22
Ministry of the Environment 7 29 14 57
Rural Departments 3 899 0 19 81
Environment Centers 1 973 51 42 7
Municipal Authorities 1 144 23 76 1

Total PRTCs 40 741 - - -

Table 2. PRTCs in total (€ 1000), design (%), implementation (%) and monitoring (%) by administrations.



A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Ollikainen, M. et al. Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies in Finland 

202

A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

203

creases the labour input of environmental authori-
ties, especially in Regional Environment Centres.

We would finally like to emphasize that when 
comparing the different policy measures with each 
other, the percent PRTCs as an indicator does not 

give the whole picture of the nature of policies and 
specific measures. The shares are strongly influ-
enced by the level of payments and they may not 
entail all costs and benefits of a policy (see e.g. 
Vatn et al. 2002 and OECD 2007). 

Agri-Environmental support
Total PRTCs,  

€ 1000
PRTCs in  
design, %

PRTCs in  
implementation, %

PRTCs in  
monitoring, %

Basic measures 3 079 16 25 59 
Ministry of  Agriculture and Forestry 851 39 39 22 
Ministry of the Environment 2 29 14 57 
Rural Departments   1 624 1 0 99 
Environment Centers 0 0 0 0 
Municipal agricultural authorities 602 24 75 1 

Additional measures 2 719 16 26 58 
Ministry of  Agriculture and Forestry 778 39 39 22 
Ministry of the Environment 4 29 14 57 
Rural Departments   1 403 1 0 99 
Environment Centers 0 0 0 0 
Municipal agricultural authorities 534 22 77 1 

Special measures 2 866 36 55 10 
Ministry of  Agriculture and Forestry 12 39 39 22 
Ministry of the Environment 1 50 14 57 
Rural Departments   872 0 84 16 
Environment Centers 1 973 52 42 7 
Municipal agricultural authorities 8 22 77 1 

Total 8 664 23 35 42 

Table 3. PRTCs in agri-environmental support.

0 %

10 %

20 %

30 %

40 %

50 %

60 %

70 %

80 %

90 %

100 %

CAP, LFA and 
national support

Basic measures 
(total)

Selected 
additional 

measures (total)

Riparian zones Traditional 
biotopes

Share of cost components

Design Implementation Monitoring

Fig. 4. Share of transaction cost 
components in selected policy 
measures.



A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Ollikainen, M. et al. Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies in Finland 

204

A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

205

But even more importantly, the mere size of 
PRTCs does not indicate much about the perform-
ance of policies. The fact that transaction costs are 
either high or low does not guarantee that the cho-
sen policy measures and the administrative effort 
achieve the objectives and targets set for the policy. 
Hence, one should distinguish between the admin-
istrative efficiency of implementing a given set of 
policy measures and the performance of the cho-
sen instruments in producing the desired outcomes. 
The level and allocation of PRTCs provide indi-
rect evidence about the administrative efficiency in 
implementing the given policy measures. An effi-
cient administration implements policies with least 
transaction costs. This does not, however, imply 
that the selected measures always have the desired 
impact; this depends on how well the measures are 
chosen and designed.

These aspects are especially important for the 
discussion on the Finnish agri-environmental sup-
port policy, which was originally launched in 1995 
and has remained roughly the same over the years. 
Its goal is predominantly to reduce nutrient runoff 

from the fields. Additionally, it aims at maintaining 
agricultural landscape and safeguarding biodiversi-
ty. Empirical studies show, however, that achieve-
ments in reducing nutrient runoff have been very 
modest. In fact, there has not been reduction in the 
nutrient runoff from agriculture (Turtola and Lem-
ola 2004). Our analysis shows one factor that may 
have affected the slow progress in nutrient con-
trol. PRTCs in monitoring the basic measures were 
relatively low indicating that monitoring effort is 
not expanded to a level needed for full compliance 
with the basic measures. This conclusion is con-
firmed by Turtola and Lemola (2004), who notify 
failures in the enforcement of agri-environmental 
measures. This indicates inefficient allocation of 
administrative efforts, but is by no means the only 
reason for the failure of agri-environmental sup-
port program to reduce runoff. We will return to 
this issue at length in the concluding section. We 
next turn to comparing our findings with the results 
obtained in other studies.

Acreage 
support

Traditional biotopes 
and landscape ventures

Government agencies
PRTCs,  
€ 1000

PRTCs,  
 %

PRTCs,  
€ 1000

PRTCs,  
 %

FINLAND

Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry 2 204 0.37 10 0.16
Ministry of the Environment 0 0.00 1 0.02
Rural Departments   1 094 0.18 393 6.52
Environment Centers 0 0.00 1 325 21.97
Municipal agricultural authorities 2 357 0.40 7 0.11
Total 5 655 0.95 1 735 28.77
NORWAY
Ministry of Agriculture 0 0.00 3 0.02
Norwegian Agricultural authority 675 0.17 455 3.31
County authority 357 0.09 421 3.06
Local agricultural authority 2 143 0.54 6 313 45.90
Total 3 175 0.80 7 192 52.29

Table 4. PRTCs in the Finnish acreage-based national and traditional biotopes support, and in the Norwegian acreage 
and special landscape ventures support



A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Ollikainen, M. et al. Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies in Finland 

204

A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

205

Comparison of policy-related 
transaction costs in some  

countries
We first compare our findings with those obtained 
for Norway by Vatn et al (2002). Vatn et al. (2002) 
estimated PRTCs of various Norwegian agricultural 
and agri-environmental policy measures. Their data 
is based on interviews of farmers, policymakers, 
and wholesalers and they determined labor cost, 
computer, information material, postage and general 
overhead costs. They focus on the running costs of 
policy measures because the lack of data related to 
set-up costs. Given that agriculture is practised in 
northern conditions and both countries have large 
rural areas with low population density, the com-
parison is meaningful. We restrict the comparison 
to the measures that are similar in Finland and 
Norway. Also, the total PRTCs are compared. The 
Norwegian currency, NOK was converted to euros 
using exchange rate of year 2000.

Starting from the total figures, we find that in 
Finland the total subsidy payment amount to € 1 
831 000 000 and the total PRTCs is € 40 741 035, 
which gives the share of PRTCs 2.23%. Accord-
ing to Vatn et al. (2002), the respective figures in 
Norway were € 772 626 646, € 905 239, and 2.19 
% PRTC share. Hence, the PRTCs are very low 
and close to each others despite the differences in 
policy measures. This indicates that the adminis-
tration is efficient in implementing the policies in 
both countries.

We next compare the PRTCs associated with 
two measures, the acreage-based national pay-
ments and landscape conservation in both coun-
tries. The acreage-based national support payments 
in Finland are 594 million euros and in Norway 
they are slightly below 397 million euros. While 
these support payments promote conservation of 
traditional biotopes, they slightly differ from each 
others. The Norwegian special landscape venture 
consists of five different measures that, in addi-
tion to traditional biotopes, include promotion of 
biodiversity and preservation of cultural sites. The 
overall payments for this purpose are 6.03 mil-

Subsidy PRTC
PRTC/Subsidy, 

%

England (1998) 1 582 300 17 900 1.1

Finland (2005) 594 000 5 430 0.9

Netherlands (1997) 128 000 8 745 6.8

Norway (2000) 396 836 3 175 0.8

Sweden (1996) 418 310 11 939 2.9

Table 5. PRTCs of acreage-based national supports and arable area payments for selected countries.

Payment, 

€ 1000

PRTCs, 

€ 1000

PRTCs/Payment, %

Belgium 1 604 1 065 66

Finland 6 030 1 737 29

Norway 13 755 7 192 52

Sweden 17 073 4 828 28

Uk 40 430 9 959 25

Table 6. Transaction costs in biodiversity and landscape conservation programs in selected countries.



A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Ollikainen, M. et al. Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies in Finland 

206

A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

207

lion euros in Finland and 13.75 million euros in 
Norway. Table 4 facilitates the comparison of the 
PRTCs; the Norwegian data produce using Vatn et 
al. 2002, Appendix 3. 

As for the acreage support, the percentage cost 
shares are of the same size, though slightly higher 
in Finland. The Finnish acreage-based national sup-
port consists of four different measures, which may 
explain the higher estimate. The Finnish national 
support payment system benefits from the monitor-
ing of the CAP support system (including CAP in-
come support and LFA), which may underestimate 
the PRTCs of national acreage support in Finland. 
The total transfers in Finland are about 200 mil-
lion euros larger than in Norway. There are also 
differences in the shares of different governmental 
agencies. The Finnish Ministry of Agriculture and 
Forestry bears about 37% and local authorities 40% 
of the costs, while the Norwegian Ministry does not 
have any PRTCs and local authorities bear 54% of 
costs. Thus, the Norwegian support system seems 
to be more decentralized than the Finnish system, 
which follows the requirements of the EU’s Com-
mon Agricultural Policy. In sum, however, the 
transaction costs of the Finnish and Norwegian 
acreage payments are very similar.

From Table 4, the PRTCs of the traditional 
Finnish biotopes are clearly much smaller but the 
explanation for this may be due to above-men-
tioned differences in policy measures. Still, tradi-
tional biotopes may be an efficiently administered 
policy measure, especially when the required level 
of precision is taken into account. An interesting 
difference between Finland and Norway is in the 
fact that in Norway PRTC burden lies in local ag-
ricultural authorities, whereas in Finland it is in the 
regional Environmental Centres; in both countries 
duties are decentralized but more so in Norway.

We, finally, extend our comparison to England, 
the Netherlands, Norway and Sweden. Again, our 
comparison is restricted to measures that can be ex-
pected to be quite close to each other. However, the 
amount of uncertainty is now much higher than in 
the previous comparison between Finland and Nor-
way. We first focus on the crop area payments and 
then discuss conservation of traditional biotopes 
and other semi-natural habitats.

Table 5 condenses PRTCs of acreage-based 
supports and arable area payments for some se-
lected countries (data is taken from SAI 2000). 
Unfortunately, the data for each country comes 
from different years, which makes the comparison 
less reliable. The general picture seems to be quite 
clear, though. Finland, England and Norway have 
low PRTCs for their area-based support measures. 
Sweden and Netherlands have much higher esti-
mates for PRTCs. 

Conservation measures for special semi-natural 
habitats and landscape ventures differ but aim at a 
similar type of goals. The Finnish and Norwegian 
systems have been presented above. Sweden has 
a conservation system similar to the Finnish case: 
cultural heritage and traditional biotopes are con-
served. We do not have data from the Netherlands 
but from Belgium, which has roughly similar ag-
ricultural conditions as in the Netherlands. In Bel-
gium the conservation aims at promoting pollard-
willows and small landscape elements. Finally, in 
the UK, the aim is to conserve environmentally 
sensitive areas. Table 6 facilitates the comparison 
(the data is from Falconer and Whitby 1999b, ap-
pendix 1 summary tables and Vatn et al. 2002, ap-
pendix 3). 

Irrespective of differences in measures, all coun-
tries exhibit the common feature that semi-natural 
habitat conservation entails much higher PRTCs 
than area payments. The observed range is from 
25% (UK) up to 66% (Belgium). Finland, Swe-
den and UK have roughly similar PRTCs, between 
20% - 30%, while Norway and Belgium have much 
higher figures. Belgium and Norway have higher 
figures, because their conservation measures are 
more comprehensive and differentiated than those 
in Finland, Sweden and UK. This demonstrates that 
increased targeting of agri-environmental measures 
leads to higher transaction costs.

Conclusions 

Policy-related transaction costs are important for 
two reasons. Tracking and measuring PRTCs helps 



A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Ollikainen, M. et al. Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies in Finland 

206

A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

207

us to assess the costs of public administration and 
to improve its efficiency. This leads to a better use 
of public funds. Equally importantly, accounting 
for PRTCs helps in the design and implementation 
of agricultural policy instruments and choosing the 
optimal policies. Optimal policies increase target-
ing (precision) up to the point where the marginal 
benefits from targeting equal the marginal policy-
related transaction costs.

We assessed the PRTCs of agricultural and 
agri-environmental policies in Finland for the main 
policy instruments. Our focus was on the costs of 
implementation of policies. To get some indirect 
information on the efficiency of the Finnish ad-
ministration, we also compared Finnish PRTCs 
with Norway and some selected EU countries. Our 
method was to interview all levels of administra-
tion to produce estimates on working time, aver-
age salaries, and operational costs. The interviews 
covered all ministries involved with agricultural 
policy implementation. At the regional and mu-
nicipality level we chose Southern-Finland as the 
study area. 

The findings of this paper can be condensed 
as follows. First, all area-based income support 
measures entail low PRTCs. This holds not only for 
Finland but also for all Nordic countries, the Neth-
erlands and the UK. Thus, we can conclude that the 
administration in Finland seems to work efficiently 
in implementing these income support measures. 
This conclusion is also conformed by the facts that 
there are no reported problems in transferring pay-
ments to farmers. Moreover, reported cases where 
farmers falsely claim for certain crop area-based 
supports are extremely rare, which indicates that 
the monitoring effort and PRTCs associated with 
it are at an efficient level.

Second and quite surprisingly, PRTCs in the 
Finnish agri-environmental programme turned out 
to be low, too. Within the agri-environmental pro-
gramme, the share of PRTCs increases with tar-
geted and differentiated agri-environmental meas-
ures. For the basic measures that are common to 
all farmers who participate in the Finnish Agri-En-
vironmental Programme PRTCs are even slightly 
lower than PRTCs for the area-based income sup-
port measures. As regards the most differentiated 

policy measures, such as conservation of special 
biotopes or establishment of riparian buffer zones, 
PRTCs increase considerably. The same pattern can 
be observed for other countries, too.

Thus, the administrative efficiency in im-
plementing the agri-environmental protection 
measures seems to be good. However, this is not 
necessarily true. Recall, the main goal of the agri-
environmental program is to reduce nutrient run-
off. Thus, the low PRTCs must be contrasted with 
the fact that nutrient runoff reduction targets have 
not been achieved. Our figures showed that the ad-
ministrative efforts in monitoring and enforcement 
were fairly low. Moreover, PRTCs revealed that 
in the division of labour inside administration, the 
local authorities do not have a key role in monitor-
ing farms despite the fact that their possibilities for 
this function are the best. While the latter feature 
may be an integral part of the agri-environmental 
programme that the administration cannot change, 
the former aspect shows weakness in allocating the 
administrative efforts.

The low monitoring rate can also be linked to 
the high participation rate of farmers to the vol-
untary agri-environmental program. The high par-
ticipation rate can be regarded as an indication of a 
generous compensation for environmental protec-
tion (compensating just for the average compliance 
costs would reduce the number of participants, as 
evidence from other EU countries shows). Gener-
ous compensations associated with low enforce-
ment may indicate that the Finnish agri-environ-
mental support has a flavour of an income support 
that is given in a “green package”. In any case, our 
analysis demonstrates that the further development 
of the Finnish agri-environmental programme re-
quires improving enforcement and the division of 
labour inside administration. Moreover, the exami-
nation of the transaction costs accruing to farmers 
and the ability of current agri-environmental meas-
ures to promote the desired environmental goals is 
needed to complement the analysis presented in 
this paper.
 
Acknowledgements. This paper was part of the project 
“Multifunctional Agriculture and Policies” funded by 
the Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry. This funding 



A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Ollikainen, M. et al. Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies in Finland 

208

A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

209

is gratefully acknowledged. We are grateful to Jarmo 
Salonen for helping to frame the research idea. We thank 
Catherine Moreddu for insightful advice and comments. 
The comments by two anonymous referees are gratefully 
acknowledged.
Disclaimer. The views are those of the authors and do 
not reflect the official view of the OECD or its member 
governments.

References
Coase, R. 1937. The nature of the firm. Economica 

4:386–405.
Dahlman, C.J. 1979. Problem of externality. Journal of Law 

and Economics 22:141–162. 
Falconer, K. and Whitby, M. 1999. The invisible costs of 

scheme implementation and administration, in G. Van 
Huylenbroeck and M. Whitby, Countryside Steward-
ship: Farmers and Markets, Chapter 4, Elsevier Sci-
ence Ltd. 

Falconer, K. Dupraz, P. & Whitby M. 2001. An investiga-
tion of policy administrative costs using panel data for 
the English Environmentally Sensitive Areas. Journal of 
Agricultural Economics, 52:83–103.

Falconer, K. and Saunders, C. 2002. Transaction costs for 
SSSIs and policy design. Land use policy 19:157–166.

Furubotn, E.G. & Richter, R. 1998. Institutions and Econom-
ic Theory. The University of Michigan Press, USA.

Kröger, L. Lankoski, J. & Huhtala, A. 2004. Agri-environ-
mental policy in Finland 1995 - 2006. Unpublished ITAES 
Workpackage report. 

Lankoski, J. & Ollikainen, M. 2003. Agri-environmental ex-
ternalities: a framework for designing targeted policies. 
European Review of Agricultural Economics 30:51–75.

Mann, S. 2000. Transaktionskosten der landwirtschaftli-

chen Investitionsförderung  – ein komparativer Ansatz. 
Agrarwirtschaft 49:259–269.

McCann, L. & Easter K. W. 1999. Transaction costs of pol-
icies to reduce agricultural phosphorous pollution in the 
Minnesota River. Land Economics 75:402–414. 

McCann, L. & Easter K. W. 2000. Public sector transaction 
costs in NRCS programmes. Journal of Agricultural and 
Applied Economics 32:555–563. 

Milgrom P. and J. Roberts1992. Economics, Organiza-
tion and Management. Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliff, 
USA.

Niemi, J. & Ahlstedt, J. (2005). Finnish Agriculture and Ru-
ral Industries 2005 - Ten Years in the European Union. 
Agri-Food Finland. Publications 105.

OECD 2007. The implementation costs of agricultural poli-
cies. OECD, Paris. 195 p. 

Rørstad, P. K., Vatn, A. & Kvakkestad, V. 2007. Why do 
transaction costs of agricultural policies vary? Agricul-
tural Economics 36:1–11.

SAI 2000. Administration of arable payments in the Neth-
erlands, Sweden, and England. A report by the Neth-
erlands Court of Audit, the Swedish National Audit Of-
fice and the United Kingdom National Audit Office, 
April 2000.

Turtola, E. & Lemola, R. 2004. Maatalouden ympäristötu-
en seuranta MYTVAS 2. Osahankkeiden 2–7 väliraportit 
2000–2003. Maa- ja elintarviketalous 59. Jokioinen.

Vatn, A. 2001. Transaction costs and multifunctionality. Pa-
per presented at the OECD workshop on “Multifunction-
ality: Applying the OECD Analytical Framework – Guid-
ing Policy Design”, Paris, 2–3 July. 

Vatn, A. 2002. Multifunctional agriculture: some conse-
quences for international trade regimes. European Re-
view of Agricultural Economics 29:309–327.

Vatn, A. Kvakkestad, V. and Rørstad P. K. 2002. Policies 
for multifunctional agriculture: The trade-off between 
transaction costs and precision. Agricultural University 
of Norway. Department of Economics and Social Sci-
ences. Report No. 23. 

Williamson, O.E. 1985. The economic institutions of cap-
italism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. Free 
Press, New York. 



A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Ollikainen, M. et al. Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policies in Finland 

208

A G R I C U L T U R A L  A N D  F O O D  S C I E N C E

Vol. 17 (2008): 193–209.

209

Appendix

Policy measures
Support area  

A
Support area  

B
Support area  

C1
Support areas 

C2-C4

CAP 295 €/ha 243 €/ha 243 €/ha 200 €/ha

LFA 150 €/ha 200 €/ha 200 €/ha 210 €/ha

National support
74–215 €/lu 
73–392 €/ha

74–215 €/lu 
73–392 €/ha

251–410 €/lu 
69–185 €/ha

251–1042 €/lu 
30–185 €/ha

Agri-environmental support Same level of payments in all support areas

Basic measures 93–117 €/ha

Additional measures 13–24 €/ha

Special measures 65–450 €/ha, 168–360 €/lu
lu=livestock unit

Table A1. Agricultural support payments in different support areas in Finland (Niemi and Ahlstedt 2005, the Finnish 
Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry).

 

C1 

C2 

C3 

C4 

B

A

C2 north 

Fig. A1. Agricultural support areas in Finland 
(Niemi and Ahlstedt 2005).


	Policy-related transaction costs of agricultural policiesin Finland
	Introduction
	Framework and overview of policy measures
	Levels of administrations and generation of data
	Policy-related transaction costs for the Finnish agricultural policy
	Comparison of policy-related transaction costs in some countries
	Conclusions
	References
	Appendix