A Race of Cuckoos :
Cninese Migration, Anti-Chinese

Logialation and the
Canadian Pacific Railway.

Ronald Faust ino-Santos

Chinese labour migration to Canada in the nineteenth century is
explained in terms of the respective positions of China and
Canada within the World System. The role of the state in
determining this position is discussed . With respect to the
several states occupying China, this took the form of attempts to
officially regulate the migrant labour trade. The Canadian state
provided for the general interests of capital by reinforcing the
use of Chinese as cheap labour for work on railway construction

.

Race as an ideology is used to explain the concrete actions of
class fractions as they appropriated racism to promote their
material interests . In China this took the form of European
merchants and plantation owners aligned against exploited Chinese
labour. Within Canada, the merchant class, which favoured
political marginal ization of the Chinese but not necessarily
exclusion , was aligned against the white working class which
favoured the outright exclusion of Chinese from Canada.

42



At the economic level, it is clear that race must be
given its distinctive and 'relatively autonomous'
effectivity, as a distinctive feature. This does not
mean that the economic is sufficient to found an
explanation of how these relations concretely function.
One needs to know how different racial and ethnic groups
were inserted historically, and the relations which
tended to erode and transform, preserve these
distinctions through time not simply as residues
and traces of previous modes, but as active structuring
principles of the present organization of society.
Racial categories will not provide or explain these.
What are the different forms and relations in which
these racial fractions were combined under capital? Do
they stand in significantly different relations to
capital Do they stand within an articulation of
different modes of production? .... Nevertheless, such
an analysis would need to be complemented by an analysis
of the specific forms which racism assumes in its
ideological functioning. Here, we would have to
begin by investigating the different ways in which
racist ideologies have been constructed and made
operative under different historical conditions: the
racisms of mercantilist theory and of chattel slavery;
of conquest and colonialism; of trade and 'high
imperialism'; of 'popular imperialism' and of so-called
'post-imperialism'. In each case, in specific social
formations, racism as an ideological configuration has
been reconstituted by the dominant class relations and
thoroughly reworked (see Hall , 1980 : 338 ) .

Introduction

The above quotation establishes the salience of race and

ethnicity within capitalism. Hall suggests that one must

examine the historically specific 'articulation' of race and the

economic base, while attributing 'relative autonomy' to race as

a 'distinctive feature' of capitalist social relations. This

suggests an examination of the material base for racism as well

as how racism at the political and ideological level reproduces

the existing capital relations structured along racial lines.

43



The purpose of this paper is to examine how class struggle at the

political level came to be defined along racial lines within two

contexts: the British imperial state in China and the Canadian

state. This paper will deal specifically with Chinese migration

to Canada in the late nineteenth century.

The analysis will tawe place at two levels. The first level

will involve an examination of the particular economic conditions

within the world capitalist system which led to Chinese

migration. The role of the British imperial state in promoting

this migration will be discussed. In an indirect way the

material conditions* within the world system and the role of the

British state in creating these conditions contributed to the

structuring of class struggle along racial lines in the Canadian

context. The role of the Canadian state in reproducing class

relations along racial lines will be examined. Moreover, the

play of class forces which determined the expression of racism in

the Canadian state will also be investigated. The focus will be

on how racism is appropriated by class fractions to promote their

own material interests.

True to the method suggested above, the material conditions

for the salience of race within capitalist social relations must

be established. The salience of race within this particular

historical period can be related to the imperialist stage of

competitive capitalism. The root of imperialism lies in the

tendency of the capitalist system towards cyclical crises, due to

the Tendency of the Rate of Profit to Fall (TRPF), and the

44



resulting barriers in the valorization of capital I Bonac ich , 1 984

and Hirsch, 1 978 ) . The developed capitalist countries in Europe

attempted to deal with these crises by exporting capital to its

colonies

.

The export of labour from the colonies as a means to counter

the TRPF is one of the chief attractions of imperialist expansion

( Bonachich , 1 984 : 1 7 ) . Employers in the metropole can deal with

the TRPF by increasing the extraction of absolute surplus value

through the lowering of workers' wages (5). Workers from the

colonies can be paid a lower wage rate than their metropole

counterparts because the cost of reproducing migrant labor power

is borne by the colony (Burawoy, 1976). The state also plays a

part in the exploitation of migrant labor power.

From the perspective of the colony, the exportation of its

labor force is characterized by a relationship of dependency and

domination in the form of an International Division of Labor

( Baratt-Brown, 1974 ) . In the late nineteenth century, imperialism

made Britain the 'workshop of the world' to be supplied with raw

aterials (including labor) by its colonies. An International

Division of Labor emerged, with advanced European countries being

supplied with resources and markets by its colonies. Goods

manufactured with foreign capital from the colony were then

exported back to the metropole. Thus, there was an unequal

exchange of value between the metropole and the colony with the

profit from manufactured goods flowing to the metropole

(Bonachich, 1984:12-16). The relationship between the colony

45



and the metropole was one of dominance and exploitation on the

part of the metropole, and led to the underdevelopment of the

colony (16-20). Therefore, at the economic level, race is a

salient characteristic of capitalist social relations because of

the domination of non-European countries by European imperial

powers

.

This is not to reduce race to the needs of capital

accumulation. Hall (1980) notes that the structures through

which black labor is reproduced are not simply 'colored' by race,

they work through race. Therefore, a problem in Marxist

conceptualizations of racism is to define racism in such a way as

to affirm its material base without reducing it to the economic.

Miles' (1982) conceptualization of racism as an ideology is the

most profitable. He does not attribute the emergence of racism

to the capitalist mode of production. Miles claims that the

relative autonomy of racism as an ideology can be explained in

two ways. First, racism in the nineteenth century was the

product of a number of relatively 'independent' ideologies such

as Christianity and 'scientific' racism as well as the 'lived

experience' of early explorers to Africa.

Racism was relatively autonomous as well in that it was not

reducible to a single class. The most significant aspect of

Miles' argument is the process by which racism in the nineteenth

century was appropriated by the Bourgeoisie to legitimate

imperialism, "racism was used by those advancing the policy of

expansionism as justification for intervention in Africa"

( Mi les , 1 982 : 1 1 6 ) . The working class can also appropriate racism

46



to further its own material self-interests, as was the case with

the anti-Oriental policy adopted by organized labor in British

Columbia.

China and the World System

Non-capitalist social relations can exist within a larger

capitalist system. Lever-Tracy (1983), at a global level,

conceptualizes a World System, the general form of which can be

characterized as capitalist. Subsumed within this capitalist

form are non-capitalist social relations which contribute to the

World System. Bonacich (1984) also attributes the existence of

cheap migrant labor to subsistence economies in the periphery.

The articulation of China as a non-capitalist social formation

within the world capitalist system set the conditions for labour

migration from China. This describes accurately the relationship

of China to the British state within the World System.

The Chinese social system in the early seventeenth century

can be characterized as feudal, the power resting, on the one

hand, with the absentee landlord and the impotence of the

landless peasant on the other ( Li , 1979 : 326 ) . Imperialism laid

the ground work for labour emigration to Canada because of the

considerable displacement which occurred as a result of

imperialism in China. Local craft workers were driven out of

their trades by competition from cheap manufactured imports.

Peasants were forced off their lands (Bonacich, 1984:27).

In the competitive stage of capitalism, transitory or

propertyless labour was needed in the colonies because settlers

47



became small landowners and were not predisposed to participate

in wage labour. (Marx in Barrat-Brown , 1 974 : 50 ) The migrant, with

kinship ties elsewhere, was suited to the needs of capital.

According to Bonachich (1984:27):

The temporary nature of colonial labor (sic)
was completely rational from the point of
view of the emigrant and his family. His
supplementary remittances meant a great deal
to the well-being of his family in the
subsistence sector, while he could only
support the most degraded style of life
within the capitalist economy.

China's integration into the world market was detrimental

to its internal development. Those who benefited from the

Chinese migrant labour trade were the imperial states which could

expropriate Chinese labour for use in the colonies. China, being

debt-burdened, was dependent on remittances from its workers

abroad for foreign currency ( Friedman , 1980 : 1 18 ) . At the

political level, the British imperial state played an important

role in determining China's mode of articulation within the world

system.

PART I: THE IMPERIAL STATE AND MIGRANT LABOUR

The state plays a crucial role in capitalist expansion,

providing the general and external conditions for the

accumulation of capital (Hirsch 1978:67). The form of the

capitalist state can therefore be derived from the laws of motion

of capital. The form of the state is bounded and structured by

the precondition of its own existence, i.e. the need to attempt

to ensure the general conditions for the continued accumulation

of capital which individual capitalists cannot create for

themselves (67). Deri vat ioni sts , like Hirsch, are mainly

48



concerned with the modern capitalist state, but the above

observation may also be applied to the imperial state.

If imperialism is a strategy to counter the TRPF, then the

imperial state mediates the crisis by providing the political

conditions advantageous to imperialist expansionism. Thus, the

Opium Wars of 1839 to 1842 marked the coming of western

imperialism to China by securing the military domination of China

for western imperial powers.

During the early part of the seventeenth century, China was

a source of raw materials for export to Britain. By 1839, China

began to be viewed as a potential market for British goods.

Opium exports to China were a major source of profit for Britain.

Needless to say, China's efforts to stem the flow of opium (due

to the growing addiction of the Chinese population to the drug)

was met with hostility on the part of the British. The sinking

of three Chinese gunboats on November 3, 1839 marked the

beginning of the Opium Wars. The imperial navy blockaded the

Yangtze river thereby cutting off the northern part of China from

its food source, securing a victory for the British

(Chan, 1983:23-29).

The British state, as a member of the alliance of foreign

capital in China, played a role in opening the country to the

world market by legitimating the presence of foreign capital in

China. Before 1842, the trading rights of the western powers

were severely curtailed. Only one port, Canton, was open to

foreign traders. The import and export trade was regulated by a

49



group of firms (collectively known as the Cohong ) to which the

Qing government had awarded a monopoly. In return, the Cohong

closely monitored the activities of all foreigners in Canton. All

of this changed with the signing of the treaty at Nanking which

ended the Opium Wars. This treaty, signed in 1842, provided for

the establishment of five treaty ports where foreigners could

trade freely. It also ceded Hong Kong to Great Britain. More

importantly, the treaty abolished the Cohong ( Chan , 1 983 : 23-29 )

.

On the political and diplomatic level, western imperialism

laid the groundwork for Chinese migration. One third of the

foreign treasury of China went to pay reparations for the Opium

War ( Bonacich , 1984 : 30 ) . In 1859, the provincial government of

Quandong was forced to officially sanction the contract labour

trade (230). This could have been due to the fact that allied

troops had control of the provincial capital, Canton, because of

the popular unrest directed at foreigners and specifically, at

their involvement in the coolie trade ( Campbell , 1 923 : 1 1 9 )

.

Another important treaty that benefited Canada directly was

the Burlingame treaty of 1868, signed between China and the

United States. The treaty affirmed the right "of free migration

of aliens and subjects from one country to another." The most

favoured nation clause, where rights gained by one imperial

nation would apply to all other nations occupying China,

automatically granted the same privilege to Britain and all its

former colonies ( Chan , 1983 : 43 )

.

The treaties imposed by the imperial powers is an example of

50



how the imperial state provided the general and external

conditions for the accumulation of capital by securing the

political domination of China by the European powers. The

treaties assured the smooth accumulation of capital by-

integrating China into the world system. Free labour was allowed

to circulate from China, essentially removing barriers for its

expropriation and facilitating its movement into Canada. The

military power of the imperialist nations also created an unequal

political relationship which meant that the foreign powers were

able to regulate the flow of Chinese labour.

The commerce of migration: the contract labour trade

The 'coolie' trade was debt-bondage based on the

'credit-ticket' system by which a Chinese worker would be

advanced passage money and would therefore be bound to a foreign

employer for a certain amount of free labour while having to work

off the commission of the coolie-broker. 'Coolies' very often

could not pay back this debt and were not guaranteed passage

back. Foreign merchant houses in the treaty ports were connected

to a vast network of 'eating houses' in the countryside. These

'eating houses' were run as labour depots by crimps (coolie

brokers) who were continually kept informed of the labour market

needs in the treaty ports. Crimps frequently bought persons

outright as debt-payment, reselling them to foreign immigration

merchant houses. Kidnapping was a common form of recruitment

(Campbell, 1923:2-120) .

The abuses of the 'coolie' system led to an alternative form

51



of labour recruitment which came to be regulated by the foreign

powers in China: the contract labour system. The formal

distinction between the contract and the credit-ticket systems

was that the contract between labourer and employer specified the

period of employment and other obligations of the employer and

thus protected the labourer ( Campbell , 1923 : 91 ) . The Chinese

labourer was, therefore, selling his labour freely by signing the

contract. In practice, there was no distinction between the

credit-ticket system and the contract labour system. Prospective

migrant Chinese workers were often coerced into signing contracts

by the crimps of the white trading houses. Torture was not an

uncommon practice for extracting consent (118).

The link between the international capitalist labour market

and the Chinese feudal economy was the comprador. Compradors

were the traditional merchant brokers ( ya-hang ) who now worked

for specific foreign merchant houses. They acted as

intermediaries between Chinese officials and merchant houses.

The Hong Kong compradors were the principal administrators of the

contract labour system and used their kinship and regional ties

to promote the trade ( Hao , 1970 : 99 )

.

The compradors processed migrant workers when they were in

Hong Kong. The agent's task included collecting regular fees

from the North American contract labourers for the purposes of

registration fees and arranging contracts with foreign companies.

He would also be responsible for seeing that remittances from the

workers were sent to the workers' family in China, or guaranteed

52



workers' return (dead or alive) to China after the contracts

expired. At the North American end there was another network of

Chinese businessmen known in the U.S. as the Six Companies and in

Canada, after 1884, as the Chinese Benevolent Association. 1

(Chan, 1983:44 ) .

The imperial state and the 'coolie' trade

The content of state activities develops through a process

of mediated reaction to the crisis in accumulation

( Carnoy , 1984 : 142 ) . The evolution of the coolie trade from an

unregulated 'industry' to a regulated and state-sponsored trade,

is a response by the imperial nation states to the crisis in

accumulation brought about by the abolition of slavery and the

animosity of the Chinese to the 'coolie' trade. Race informed

this class conflict with white European merchants and plantation

owners aligned against exploited Chinese labour.

The Emancipation Act of 1833 which abolished slavery in

Britain and its colonies threatened the dominant mode of

production (the plantation economy) in the West Indies

(Campbell , 1923 :86 ) . In 1842, by the terms of the Webster-

Ashburton Treaty, Great Britain and the United States agreed to

enforce the international abolition of the slave trade by

patrolling the coast of Africa; thus effectively eliminating the

trade ( Ching-Hwang , 1 985 : 32 ) .

With the abolition of the slave trade a new source of labour

for the West Indies and other slave/plantation economies had to

be found. The competition for Chinese labour became fierce with

53



all the major foreign powers competing for labourers. The high

demand led to deceitful practices on the part of the foreign

Merchant houses. For example, Syme-Muir Inc., the leading

foreign coolie broker, confined Chinese workers to compounds at

the front of the merchant house.' Some were held there against

their will < Campbell , 1 923 : 1 28 )

.

Given the fierce competition among the foreign powers and

the agitation against the trade by the Chinese, it was in the

interest of the British state to rationalize the trade where it

had jurisdiction, and to induce other foreign powers to do

likewise. The British state did this in a way which assured the

West Indian plantation owners that their interests were taken

into account. 3 The contract system, which legally bound the

worker to the employer for a specified period of time, was

favoured by the West Indian plantation owners. This was because

of the militancy of the Chinese who, according to one planter,

would not accept wages "lower than the amount at the time"

implying that migrant workers were traditionally paid below the

average wage rate ( Campbell , 1 923 : 89 ) . The contract system was,

therefore, a form of labour control.

The 'coolie' trade was further disrupted by the fact that

the increase in Chinese labour recruitment was accompanied by a

corresponding increase in the sentiment against it. In Canton, a

mob killed a group of crimps who had been accused of kidnapping

( Campbell , 1923 : 1 19 ) . The opposition to the trade culminated in

the 1852 Amoy and 1859 Shanghai Ant i-kidnapping riots. 4 (Ching-

Hwang, 1985: 74-81 ) .

54



It was probably the animosity of the Chinese and the fierce

competition that led the British state to attempt to eliminate

the abuses of the 'coolie' trade by negotiating, with the other

foreign powers, a contract system universally applicable to all

countries participating in the trade. The British state

introduced the Canton System in 1859 which regulated the trade by

appointing a government official to act as agent between West

Indian plantation owners and Chinese labourers. The British

Emigration House would insure that the labourer entered freely

into the contract and that travel accommodations were humane

(Campbell, 1923:124). The Emigration House was to be supported

with public funds as well as by a tax on employers of Chinese

labourers (108). Canada, as a colony of Britain, benefited from

this regulation in that it ensured that 'coolies' were in good

health on coming to Canada, "if for no other reason than that the

investment outlay was greater.'' ( Chan , 1983 : 45 ). 5

The material basis for the antagonism between the white

working class and Chinese labour can be related, in part, to the

historically lower subsistence level of Asians compared to

Europeans (Creese, 1984:10) and to the fact that the costs of

reproducing migrant labour are confined to China. 6 This, in

turn, can be attributed to conditions at the level of the

Capitalist world system; conditions that were created and

reproduced by the British imperial state in China. These

conditions at the level of the world system contributed in turn

to the 'making' of a labour market split along racial lines in

British Columbia. 7

55



PART II: CHINESE MIGRATION AND THE CANADIAN STATE

At the national level, the Canadian state contributed to

the reproduction of the split labour market as well. Just as

class conflict over the 'coolie' trade was structured by race

(i.e. the exploitation of Chinese labour by European merchants

and plantation owners), race informed class conflict in the

Canadian context. All of these issues must be discussed within

the context of the changing economic structure of Canada as well

as Canada's own 'articulation' within the world system.

Canada in the World System

Canada's economy in the early 1800s, like that of any other

British colony, was geared to the interests of the British

Empire. For example, Canada was required to take all its imports

from Britain ( Pentland , 1981 : 101 ) . Furthermore, Canada's economy

was geared to the export of staples to Britain (131). Therefore,

Canada possessed two basic characteristics of a colonial economy:

it was a source of raw materials for the metropole as well a

market for its manufactured goods. As Naylor has noted, "the

metropole defines the character and extent of economic

development in the hinterland area" ( Naylor , 1 972 : 2 ) . Therefore,

the general need for Chinese labour in the Canadian economy can

be linked to the interests of the Empire.

Given that Canada's economy was geared towards the

circulation of staples, the dominant class fraction (the merchant

class) had built a considerable trade in timber and grain with

56



Britain ( Nayior , 1972 : 90 ) . Mercantile capital works within the

sphere of circulation and accumulates wealth through intermediary

activities between producers and consumers (90). Therefore, it

was in the interest of Canadian merchant capital, as well as

British capital, to expedite the circulation of raw materials

from Canada to Britain. Infrastructure construction (i.e.

railways, canals, and roads) which expedites the circulation

process, was, therefore, important for mercantile capital and the

general needs of the Empire. The construction of the CPR can be

seen as a state-sponsored attempt to provide the needed

infrastructure for merchant capital. 8

It is not surprising, then, that the greatest influx of

Chinese to British Columbia occurred during the construction of

the railroad. Fifteen thousand Chinese labourers worked for

Andrew Onderdonk, the largest railroad contractor, between May

1880 and July 1885 ( Chan, 1983 : 63 ) . In 1882 alone, Onderdonk

contracted with Lian Chan Inc. for two thousand workers from Hong

Kong (Wickberg et al, 1982: 21). Several authors have commented on

the fact that the presence of Chinese labour dampened wages

because of their lower subsistence level compared to whites

( Berton, 1971 ; Chan, 1983 and Fang, 1931). Thus, Chinese migrant

labour helped to promote the interests of the Empire by being a

source of cheap labour, acting as a damper on the wages of white

workers, especially with respect to keeping the cost of railway

construction down.

The low cost of Chinese labour relative to white labour

57



resulted in antagonisms between these class fractions. The

practices of white employers and that of the Canadian state

contributed to conditions in the labour market which formed the

material foundation for racial antagonisms. The labour market,

split along racial lines, was the structure in which this

antagonism took place. 9

At the political level, one way in which the state

reproduced this labour market was by politically marginalizing

the Chinese. First, Chinese and Asians in general were accorded

the official status of 'non-settler' by the Canadian government

( Creese , 1 984 : 15 ) . Second, in a series of amendments to the

Voter's Act, the British Columbian legislature disenfranchised

the Chinese at the provincial and municipal level (Wickberg et

al., 1982:83). By 1920, the Chinese were formally

disenfranchised at all levels of government (119). The stage was

set for labour to make anti-Orientalism an issue in their

political conflict with capital.

Organized Labour and Racism

By the middle of the nineteenth century, the economic

structure of Canada began to shift gradually from a staple

economy to a nascent industrial economy: "mercantile capital and

an unmistakable agrarian dominance gave way to a more pervasive

industrial capitalism" ( Palmer , 1983 : 60 ) . One particular

consequence of the gradual shift from a staple to an industrial

economy was the rise of organized labour and an increase in

class conflict. "The 1880s was a decade of unprecedented working

58



class militancy and cultural cohesion" (99). One of the largest

and most influential labour organizations was the Knights of

Labor. In the west, workers' associations made ant l-Or lental ism

a vital plank in their policy platforms. For example, R.D. Pitt,

Master Workman for the Vancouver chapter of the Knights of Labor,

ran on an anti-Chinese platform and later formed the Anti-Chinese

League. (Wickberg et al . , 1982 : 62 ) . Another anti-Chinese

organization, the Working Man's Protective Association ( WPA ) , was

formed in Victoria under Noah Shakespeare, an avowed racist (48).

The explicitly racist ideology of the WPA can be seen in its

declarations of purpose, which were:

the mutual protection of the working class in B.C.
against the great influx of Chinese; to use all
legitimate means for the suppression of their
immigration; to assist each other in the obtaining of
employment; and to devise means for the amelioration of
the condition of the working class of this province in
general ( 48 ) .

At the national level, much of the success of the Trades and

Labor Congress of Canada between 1880-1900 can be attributed to

its anti-Oriental policy which tended to unify otherwise

dissenting groups. Ireland (1960) suggests that the Trades and

Labor Congress incorporated the Chinese exclusionary policy in

their Platform of Principles largely as an expedient measure to

secure continued support from British Columbian representatives.

It would be a mistake to reduce labour's racist attitudes to

differences in wages. Implicit in a racist ideology is that one

race possesses a moral and cultural superiority over all otner

races. This 'moral imperative' is used as a rationale for the

59



domination of one racial group over another. Therefore, labour

representatives expressed negative attitudes towards Chinese in

moral and cultural terms when calling for their exclusion. This

can be seen in the submission of the Nanaimo Trades Association

to the Royal Commission on Chinese Immigration,

Vice, including prostitution and gambling, is abundant
in those (Chinese) quarters .... They are a
non-assimilat ing race. Their vices are most disgusting.
They turn their sick out to die in the streets and their
lepers to fill our prisons .... Our children oust seek
employment in other countries to make room for a race of
cuckoos ... In fact, the results of our investigation
brings us to the conclusion that the Chinese are a
disgrace to a civilised community, and we beg that steps
may be taken to stop the influx of Chinese to our shores
( 54 ) .

The WPa ' s declaration of purpose clearly shows that the 'working

class' was defined along racial terms, marked by the exclusion of

Chinese labour. Chinese labourers were in effect seen as

'non-workers', and possibly sub-human, if we consider seriously

the submission of the Nanaimo Trades Association. Racist

attitudes, therefore, informed the political strategies of the

labour movement. Instead of seeking to include the Chinese in

the organized labour structures, the Canadian labour movement

sought to exclude them from Canada. This, of course, reinforced

the position of the Chinese in the labour market. In the long

run this strategy was detrimental to the working class as a

whole .

Racism was appropriated by certain class fractions to

further their own self-interests. The specific issue was

anti-Chinese legislation. The political power of labour was

60



growing and the calls for exclusionary legislation could not go

unheeded. Cheap migrant labour was needed for the completion of

the railway, but the availability of a cheap labour supply was

not in the interests of the white working class. The positions

of capitalists and the working class with respect to anti-Chinese

legislation varied according to their class interests.

Capitalists could be seen as favouring forms of anti-Chinese

legislation which created the political conditions that favoured

the continued exploitation of Chinese labour. Capitalists then

would favour legislation politically marginalizing the Chinese,

but not necessarily excluding them from Canada. The working

class, on the other hand, would favour legislation that would

terminate the use of the Chinese as a source of cheap labour.

Given the racist attitudes of the working class, this meant calls

for the exclusion of Chinese workers from Canada. These issues

will be dealt with in the next section.

A short review of anti-chinese legislation in Canada

The evolution of anti-Chinese legislation from political

marg inalizat ion to de facto exclusion can be explained in terms

of class conflict at the political level. More specifically, the

change in anti-Chinese legislation can be attributed to the

growing political power of organized labour. A review of

anti-Chinese legislation will show, however, that the political

pressure from labour for exclusionary Chinese legislation was

resisted until the completion of the CPR.

The string of exclusionary anti-Chinese legislation since

61



1885 was the culmination of anti-Chinese sentiment evident since

the 1860s. 10 The Gold Rush Period marked a sudden surge of

economic prosperity for Victoria which was transformed fron 'a

quiet English village' into a busy commercial centre 'with

several thousand residents'" (13). While racism did not find

expression in legislation at the provincial or federal level,

racist sentiments against the Chinese were already evident in

1858. Amor De Cosmos, editor of the COLONIST and prominent

Vancouver Island businessman, wrote that the Chinese were:

inferior to Europeans and Americans in ability, hostile
to us in race language and habits and may remain among
us a pariah race . . . when the time arrives that we can
dispose of them, we will heartily second a check to
their immigration (43).

The first attempt at monitoring Chinese immigration to the

West coast came as early as 1860 when the House of Assembly

Colony of Vancouver Island proposed a poll tax of $10 to be

levied on each Chinese (42). The tax was opposed by Amor De

Cosmos who, despite his racism, believed that Chinese labour was

profitable for the colony (43). This is a prime example of

'situational' racism since he would later be at the fore of

anti -Oriental agitation.

By 1864, the Gold Boom began to level off and antagonisms

between white and Chinese labour in the Cariboo began to grow

(44). It was not surprising that the most strident voices for

anti-Chinese legislation came from labour representatives. For

example, Noah Shakespeare, leader of the racist Working Man's

Protective Association and a Victoria City Councillor, was

responsible for legislation banning the Chinese from city works

U8) -



The first attempt at banning the Chinese from railway

construction came five years before the Government of Canada

called tenders for railway construction. John Robson (a

pro-labour member from Nanaimo ) presented a resolution in the

Provincial legislature prohibiting the hiring of any Chinese on

any public works in the province, effectively banning the Chinese

from the proposed railway construction (46). This motion was

defeated on the grounds that it interfered with free enterprise

(46). When the Government of Canada called tenders for railway

construction in 1877, the Governor of British Columbia

petitioned J. A. MacDonald to insert in all contracts a clause

prohibiting the employment of Chinese workers (20). This appeal

was rejected by the MacDonald Government (20). Amor De Cosmos

presented a petition to the Government of Canada calling for the

exclusion of Chinese from railway construction as well as other

proposals designed to exclude Chinese immigration to Canada ( -18 ) .

These proposals were rejected although the petition did prod the

MacDonald government to create a Select Committee, chaired by

Amor the Cosmos, to examine the 'Oriental question' (49). Up to

the time of the Select Committee it seems that the form of

racist legislation was meant to politically marginalize the

Chinese. All attempts at outright exclusion were rebuffed by the

Canadian Government.

Further evidence of this can be seen in the response of the

MacDonald government to the Select Committee report. While the

63



recommendat ions of the Committee are not known, the fact that it

was chaired by one of British Columbia's leading racists and

that oniy two witnesses spoke favourably of the Chinese, (49) is

a good indication of what the recommendations must have been.

It would appear that no official policies came from the

Committee's recommendations.

The government of the day seems to have subordinated calls

for Chinese exclusion to the completion of the railway. As

MacDonald bluntly told Members of Parliament from British

Columbia, if they wanted the railway built they would have to

accept Chinese labour (49). The MacDonald Government's actions

in 1884 are also significant. In 1884, the Provincial Parliament

of British Columbia proposed an act which would levy a head tax

on all Chinese in British Columbia and forbid them from owning

crown lands (56). The government of Canada disallowed the

bill. 11 However, MacDonald was forced to commit himself to an

investigation of Chinese immigration restrictions and measures to

regulate Chinese migration. The result was the Royal Commission

of 1884 (55). In February of 1885, the Provincial Act of 1884

was reenacted as a protest to the perceived ineffectual

solutions to Chinese immigration proposed by the Commission of

1884 (56). This was a direct threat to the completion of the

railway. As Onderdonk wrote to George Stephen, president of the

CPR:

a large number of Chinamen will necessarily have to come
from Oregon and California in the Spring to work on your
road above Kamloops. It would be well for you to see
that this act is disallowed immediately (see
Ward, 1978:39)

.

64



MacDonald disallowed the act for the second time (39j. The

Royal Commission that MacDonald had been forced to create to

investigate Chinese immigration gave full expression to racism in

British Columbia. Unfair competition between Chinese and white

workers was a major issue. Other issues were raised concerning

the shortcomings of Chinese culture, including: the hazard they

posed to the health of the white community (Chinese were unclean

and spread disease); and their morality (gamblers and opium

smokers (39). The recommendations of the commissioners are

especially enlightening because they represent the

class-selective nature of official racism against the Chinese.

Mr. Justice Gray readily admitted that the Chinese were a 'boon

to the economy'. The principle which should govern future

legislation was a policy of "judicious selection" to make sure

that "the great interests and enterprises not be harmed" (40).

It is more than apparent that Justice Gray had the interests of

the large capitalists at heart. Unlike in 1879, when the

government of Canada ignored the findings of the Select

Committee, the government acted swiftly on the Commission's

recommendations. This may have been due, in part, to the fact

that the railway was nearing completion. According to Chan (1984)

the railway was completed in July 29,1885. The new Chinese

Immigration Act gained royal assent on July 20, 1885 (see

Wickberg et al

.

. 1982).

It is true that part of the explanation for the emergence of

exclusionary legislation can be a attributed to the growing

65



political power of labour. This can be seen in the evolution of

anti-Chinese legislation in the late nineteenth century from

those measures to politically marginalize the Chinese, to those

which exclude them from immigrating to Canada. Creese (1984) has

noted that the denial of political franchise and the

progressively more stringent restrictions and taxes on Asian

immigration occurred through pressure by the working class and

small business rather than at the 'behest' of the capitalists in

British Columbia (although it may have been in their long term

sel f- interests )

.

Calls for the exclusion and di senf ranchisement of the

Chinese were made by labour. One can make the argument that the

actual point at which the demands of labour were expressed in the

state occurred at the behest of capital. Witness how MacDonald

studiously ignored petitions for measures to exclude Chinese

labour from railway construction, or for measures to exclude

Chinese immigration before the end of railway construction was

in sight, or in his twice-ordered disallowance of British

Columbia's attempts at exclusionist legislation -- given, it

seems, at the bidding of the president of the CPR.

Thus, it seems that the particular expression of racism in

the Canadian state, here in the form of anti-Chinese legislation

-- from political marginal ization to de facto exclusion -- was

subordinated to the needs of capital accumulation and reflected

the power of the working class in relation to capital within the

state at that particular historical moment.

66



Conclusions

We have seen in the above discussion that race played an

important part in the structuring of class relations along

racial lines in British Columbia. At the level of the world

system, race was made salient as a structuring element of class

relations in British Columbia through the imperial expansionism

of the European powers. The British state played a crucial role

in creating the conditions which indirectly contributed to the

significance of race in British Columbia by creating conditions

at the level of the world system which favoured labour migration

from China. The concrete actions of the British state in

creating these conditions was determined by the play of class

forces in China. Class conflict in China proper was structured

along racial lines with exploited Chinese labour aligned against

the white plantation owners and the foreign trading house

merchants

.

Within the Canadian context, race was made a salient feature

of class relations in three ways: first, through the practices of

white employers who used Chinese as a source of cheap labour and

as strike-breakers; secondly, through the appropriation of a

racist ideology by the Canadian white working class and the

Canadian merchant capitalist class to further their own material

self-interests; and thirdly, through the practices of the

Canadian state which, firstly, politically marginalized the

Chinese and then proceeded to exclude them from Canada.

As in the British imperial state, the concrete activities of

67



the state were conditioned by class conflict. Specifically,

expressions of racism in the state, in the form of anti-Chinese

legislation, were conditioned by the play of class forces at the

political le\el. One could further speculate that the relatively

weak position of the white working class vis a vis the capitalist

class could have been improved if Chinese labour were

incorporated into existing labour organizations. Again, however,

we see the influence of a racist ideology on the balance of class

forces

.

NOTES

1. Chinese contract labour in Canada seems to have been
principally organized through the affiliates of the larger
Chinese merchant houses operating in the United States. The
recruitment of Chinese from the United States for the railway was
undertaken by a Chinese company, the Lian Chang Company,
organized by a Chinese businessman from San Francisco, (see
Wickberg et al

.

. 1982 : 21 ) Other affiliates of Chinese merchant
houses in the United States supplying Chinese labour to British
Columbia include the Hop Kee and Co. of San Francisco which
arranged with the shipping company Allan Lowe and Co. for passage
to Victoria on the Caribbean for 300 Chinese (13). Evidence
seems to indicate, however, that the dominant company dealing in
Chinese labour recruitment to the railway was non-Chinese,
Stahlschmidt & Ward. This company received five thousand of the
eight thousand Chinese who landed in Victoria during 1882 (21).

2. The common designation for the recruitment of migrant Chinese
was the 'buying and selling of pigs'. The compounds in front of
the foreign trading houses where migrant Chinese waited to be
shipped out were called 'pig-pens' ( Campbell , 1 923 : 97 ) . This
term accurately reflects the living conditions within these
compounds

.

3. For example while calling for the end to the abuses of the
coolie trade, the British State introduced legislation narrowing
the permissible minimum space allowed for Asian and Black workers
on ships. Minimum allowable space on ships was reduced from 15
to 12 feet for 'natives of Asia or Africa' ( Campbell , 1 923 : 1 08 )

.

68



4. In both instances the riots centered around the kidnapping of
Chinese by crimps for the foreign merchant houses (hongs) which
dealt in the 'coolie' trade.

The Amoy riot was sparked by the actions of Mr. Syrae of Syme,
Muir 4 Co., a foreign 'hong' with a notorious reputation for
abusive 'coolie' recruitment practices. Mr. Muir attempted to
forcibly 'liberate' one of his 'crimps' (who was charged with
kidnapping) from the Chinese authorities (Ching-Hwa, 1985:75).
The ensuing riot left twelve killed and sixteen wounded
(Campbell, 1923: 101 ) .

The Shanghai riots were precipitated by the friends and relatives
of kidnapped Chinese who attacked foreign sailors of 'coolie '-

bearing ships. The mob attacked several people including the
Inspector General of the Chinese Maritime Customs and a British
doctor (Ching-Hwa, 1923 : 81 ) .

5. Other foreign powers were quick to follow the British lead.
All foreign consuls gave their support to the Canton system. In
December 1859, the French emigration agent formally applied and
received permission from the Governor-General of Quandong to
establish an Emigration House under the Canton System. The
Spanish also established Emigration Houses in Canton. The
American consul required all American ships to conform to the
regulations governing emigration under contract, pending receipt
of further instructions from the Secretary of State
(Campbell ,1923:12 6- 127).

Enforcement of a contract labour system applicable to all foreign
powers proved to be a problem in the years following the Canton
System. Under the Canton system no labour recruitment was
allowed outside of licensed Emigration Houses in the Treaty-
Ports. In reality, a substantial amount of the trade was still
conducted outside of the Emigration Houses. Subsequent attempts
at the replacement of the coolie trade with a contract labour
system, such as the Peking Regulations of 1866, proved to have
limited success. The abuses of the coolie trade persisted until
1874 when Portugal, the last of the foreign powers which still
sanctioned the trade, abolished it in Macao (Ching-
Hwang, 1985 : 103)

.

6.Burawoy (1976) has made a similar argument in his analysis of
South African and Mexican migrant workers. The relative low cost
of migrant labour is due to the fact that the reproduction costs
of the worker are borne by the migrant's family at the periphery.

7. Creese (1984) applies the split labou market model to describe
the labour market structure in British Columbia during the late
nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. The essence of the
split labour according to Bonachich is that the dynamic of
capitalism attempts to drive down the price of labour, and an

69



ethnically split labour market results from the differential
resources available to dearer and cheaper workers in tneir
attempt to improve wages and working conditions (see in
Creese, 1984 : 6 )

.

8.Naylor (1972) has pointed to the fact that the National Policy
of the MacDonald government i of which the construction of the
CPR was only an aspect; was a construct of the merchant class to
benefit its material interests by suppressing the growth of
other class fractions of the Bourgeoisie i.e. the petite
Bourgeoisie and the 'nascent' industrial class.

9. The relative cheapness of Chinese labour, aside from the
existence of a split labour market, can also be attributed to the
form of labour recruitment used by the railroad contractors.
Chinese labour was not contracted individually, but in work
gangs. Probably*, an agent of the contracting company was
resident in the camp. Each gang had a non-Chinese foreman or
'herder' who was responsible to the construction company
(Wickberg et al. . 1983 : 22 ) According to Muszynski, (1986) the
Chinese labourers were forced into a continuing dependence on
the contractor. The cycle of continuing indebtedness prevented
the workers from going back to China. Thus the Chinese custom of
indebtedness was used as an instrument to provide for a pool of
cheap labour,

This is an instance of a precapitalist relation of
production being used within a capitalist mode of
production . ( 93 )

10. The first piece of anti-Chinese legislation meant to exclude
Chinese immigrants to Canada was passed in 1885 in the form of a
$50 head tax levied on every Chinese entering Canada. The
special tax was raised to S10Q in 1900 and $500 in 1903.
Anti-Chinese sentiment reached a climax in 1923 when the
Parliament of Canada passed the Chinese immigration Act which
basically excluded all Chinese from entering Canada. Between
1925 and 1947, the year that the Chinese Immigration Act was
repealed, Chinese immigration to Canada was virtually stopped
(Li, 1979:323).

11. The Chinese in British Columbia did not depend on the charity
of the federal government to ensure that their rights were
protected. In 1878, the government of British Columbia attempted
to pass what amounted to a head tax on all Chinese (Wickberg et
al . 1982:48). Opposition was immediate and culminated in a
general strike by the Chinese community (lasting five days) where
stores closed, domestic servants stayed away from homes, Chinese
workers refused to report to hotels and boot factories. The
Governor General of Canada disallowed the law on October 28,
1879 (49)

.

70



REFERENCES

Barat -Brown

,

1974 The Economics of Imperialism . Middlesex, England:
Penguin Book Ltd.

Berton, Pierre
1971 The Last Spike . Montreal: McClelland and Stewart Ltd.

Bonacich, Edna and Lucie Cheng
1 984 Labour Immigration Under Capitalism: Asian Workers in

the United States . Berkeley: University of California
Press

.

Burawoy, Micheal
1981 "The Functions and Reproduction of Migrant Labor:

Comparative Material From Southern Africa and the
United States", American Journal of Sociology :
1050-1087.

Cambell, Persia
1923 Chinese Coolie Emigration . New York: Negro

Universities Press.

Carnoy , Martin
1984 The State and Political Theory . Princeton: Princeton

University Press

Chan, Anthony
1983 Gold Mountain . Vancouver: New Star Books

Creese, Gillian
1984 "Immigration Policies and the Creation of an

Ethnically Segmented Work Force in British Columbia
1880-1923", Alternate Routes . Vol 7, pp. 1-34.

Friedeman, Edward
1980 "Maoist Conceptulaizat ions of the Capitalist World

System" in The Process of the World System . Terence K.
Hopkins and Immanuel Wallerstein (eds. ) Pol itical
Economy of the World System Annuals . Vol 3, London:
Sage Publications

Hall , Stuart
1980 "Race Articulations and Societies Structured

Dominance", UNESCO Sociological Theories Race
Colonisation . Paris: UNESCO

Hao , Yen-P ' Ing
1970 The Comprador in Nineteenth Century China . Cambridge

Mass: Harvard University Press

71



riirscr., Joachim
1978 'The State Apparatus and Social Reproduction: Elements

of a Theory of the Bourgeoisie State" in J. Holloway
and S. Picciotio (eds. ) State and Capital: A Marxist
Debate . USA: London Publishers Co.

Ireland, Ralph R.
1960 "Some Effects of Oriental Immigration on Canadian

Trade Lnion Ideology", American Journal of Economics
and Sociology , Vol.19, pp. 217-220.

Lenin, V.I.
1939 Imperialism Highest Stage of Capitalism .

ISA: International Publishers Co.

Lever-Tracy, Constance
1983 "Immigrant Workers and Postwar Capitalism: In Reserve

or Core Troops in the Front Line ", Pol itics and
Society , Vol.12, No . 2 , pp. 125-57.

Li , Peter
1979 "A Historical Approach to Ethnic Stratification: The

Case of the Chinese in Canada" The Canadian Review
of Sociology and Anthropology . Vol.16, No. 3, pp. 3 20-
332.

and B. Sing Bolaria
1979 "Canadian Immigration Policv and Assimilation Theory'

in John Allen ed. Economy Class and Social Reality .
Toronto: Buttersworth

McEnvoy , F.J.
1982 "A Symbol of Racial Discrimination: The Chinese

Immigration Act and Canada's Relations with China,
1942-1947", Canadian Ethnic Studies . Vol. XIV No.

3

Muszynski , Alicja
1986 "Class Formation and Class Consciousness: The Making

of Shoreworkers in the BC Fishing Industry", Studies
in Political Economy 20 Summer.

Nay lor, R.T.
1972 "The Rise and Fall of the Third Commercial Empire of

the St. Lawrence", in G.Teeple, Capitalism and the
National Question in Canada , pp. 2-36.

72



Palmer, Bryan
198 3 Working Class Experience: The Rise and Reconst 1 tut ion

of Canadian Labour: 1800-1980 . Toronto: Butterworth
and Co. Ltd.

Pentland, H.C.
1981 Labour and Capital in Canada 1650-1860 . Toronto:

James Lorimer and Co.

Shaw, P.
19 7 5 Migration Theory and Fact: A Review and Bibliography

of Current Literature . Philadelphia: Regional Research
I nst l tute

Yen, Ching-Wang
1985 Coolies and Mandarins . Singapore: University of

Singapore Press.

73