Baltic Journal of Economic Studies  

244

Vol. 4, No. 3, 2018

Corresponding author:
1 Department of Economics, Tavria State Agrotechnological University.
E-mail: rechkanegerey@gmail.com

DOI: https://doi.org/10.30525/2256-0742/2018-4-3-244-253

INVESTIGATING MARKET PRICES FOR AGRICULTURAL 
PRODUCTION MEANS AND AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTS

Kateryna Rechka1
Tavria State Agrotechnological University, Ukraine

Abstract. At the present stage of development of Ukrainian agribusinesses, pricing for agricultural products is one 
of the major tasks to be solved. It is well known that the price significantly impacts business performance since it 
determines both production cost recovery and business profit. In a market economy, the success of agribusinesses 
largely depends on how reasonable prices for their products are. However, the current sluggish pricing process at 
agribusinesses argues the lack of effective methodological and theoretical support for decision-making in the field 
of pricing policy, which often leads to material miscalculations when pricing, and consequently to significant losses. 
Thus, it is necessary to study pricing principles, methods, and features in the sector and their impact on the efficiency 
of agribusinesses. The purpose and objectives of the study: the study aims at determining the factors, methodological 
approaches and peculiarities of pricing for agricultural products and agricultural production means in the present-day 
conditions. Background: the peculiarities of pricing in the agrarian sector and the influence of the price mechanism 
on the Ukrainian agrarian sector are examined by many domestic scientists. Among the works published in recent 
years, the fundamental studies by M.M. Artus, R.F. Brukhanskyi, V.B. Vavryk, V.V. Hudak, Ye.M. Kyryliuk, M.Z. Matviichuk, 
M.K. Parkhomets, B.Y. Paskhaver, Ye.A. Firsov, O.M. Shpychak, and others deserve a special consideration. Although, it 
should be noted that there are significant changes in how certain factors impact pricing for agricultural and agrarian 
products. For the reasons given, it is necessary to continue investigating the corresponding processes. The research 
methodology is based on the dialectical method of cognition of the current market situation, in which agribusinesses 
function, the method of theoretical generalization, analysis and synthesis to determine theoretical framework for 
studying pricing for agricultural products, determining pricing methods and rationalizing their application, a systematic 
approach to determining pricing factors and interrelations between them. Having examined, synthesized and critically 
evaluated studies on pricing in the agricultural sector at the stage of its reform and the market-oriented agricultural 
model, the following theses have been formulated. A broad methodological and theoretical base for pricing is laid in 
classical works on economic theory. Although, there have been different trends, concepts, and schools within the issue. 
They can be classified according to two main and even alternative price theories: 1) labour theory of value and price; 
and 2) marginal utility theory. Their content is well-known and developed in many studies in economics. For the said 
reason we only note that currently, domestic scientists suggest various points of view on base and basis of pricing. Many 
of them argue that in the market system of economic management, regardless of its model and national characteristics, 
the law of value functions in all spheres and branches of the economy. Results. The author focuses on the peculiarities 
of pricing for agricultural products, considers the causes and consequences of a significant fluctuation in prices for 
certain types of products and shows an increasing influence on the pricing of foreign economic transactions and the 
concentration of agricultural production. It is concluded that agribusinesses strengthen their positions in pricing their 
products, which is proved by improving selling price variation in the context of individual producers and their groups. 
The practical implication of the results of the study is as follows applying in practice the suggested recommendations 
that allow providing a comprehensive definition of the factors affecting the price of agricultural products. Value/
originality. Knowledge of theoretical foundations of pricing is one of the most important success factors in the practical 
application of experience. Very relevant is the analysis of numerous price strategies of foreign companies related to 
differences in the positioning of companies and goods, the speed of penetration of the national and the world markets, 
the formation of brands, relationships with competitors and consumers, systems of stimulation of demand and sale, 
movement of goods products, the ratio of wholesale and retail components of the sales complex.

Key words: selling price, agricultural products, agribusiness, price variation, price disparity.

JEL Classification: E30, D40, D46, Q10, Q13



Baltic Journal of Economic Studies  

245

Vol. 4, No. 3, 2018

1. Introduction
In today’s conditions, one of the most important social 

problems is the problem of economic growth of the 
country, which focuses on the attention of politicians 
and leading scholars of economic science.

The problem of ensuring high-quality economic 
development in Ukraine and in the world is gaining 
momentum due to the global exacerbation of socio-
economic and financial problems. Indeed, the dynamics of 
economic growth gives us a description of the development 
of the national economy, its place on the international scene. 
On the basis of its data, there is an opportunity to draw 
conclusions: on the standard of living of the population, 
about how the problem related to the resource constraints 
are being solved. Support for economic development, its 
rates at an optimal and stable level, is among the main long-
term goals of the government of any country in the world, 
as a part of its economic policy, which has been observed 
over the past decades.

In this regard, the emergence of functional studies 
that reflect the theoretical and practical aspects 
of ensuring sustainable economic growth and the 
development of agrarian production in Ukraine under 
present conditions are very timely and important in the 
scientific world.

Strengthening globalization processes, Ukraine’s 
European integration in the direction of the EU, in 
particular, will contribute to the growth of exports 
of agricultural products. At the same time, the most 
pressing problem for the latter is the formation of a more 
efficient structure of export of agricultural products. 
First of all, it is about increasing the share of ready-to-
eat products.

Economic growth and development in the 
agricultural sector as a sphere of the national economy 
and its primary production chains are determined by 
numerous conditions and factors. The driving forces 
of this process, mainly at the micro level, i.e. economic 
entities, are generally investigated. There is a system of 
internal (endogenous) factors affecting their economic 
development. The thesis that the latter is significantly 
influenced by a number of external (exogenous) 
factors, in particular, climatic and natural conditions in 
agriculture, is theoretically substantiated and practically 
proven. Apart from the above factors, the rest can 
be divided into political (political stability), legal 
(economic law), social, and economic. A system of these 
factors creates a macro environment, in which each 
production agristructure functions and correspondently 
its economic growth and development or its decline and 
even destruction (economic bankruptcy).

2. Pricing as an external influence on economic 
growth

An individual, an economic entity, is the dominant 
driving force of economic growth and development.  

If he/she is an entrepreneur-business manager, his/her 
main goal is to obtain and maximize profits. “Economic 
interest in managing the agrarian sector,” as notes 
P.T.  Sabluk, “largely depends on external factors, which 
under market conditions radically changed the order of 
income generation in agribusinesses. The times demand to 
produce what can be sold and gain profits” (Sabluk, 2008).

The profit is ultimately determined by the difference 
between the product/service price and its cost price. 
As to the goods produced and offered for sale, for the 
seller of such goods, the “production costs” (cost price) 
component is fixed in a purchase and sale transaction.  
It is beyond the influence of both market counterparties. 
To achieve the desired profit, its increase at given market 
prices is possible only with a reduction in production 
costs and an increase in profit caused by such a reduction. 
In other words, with respect to the goods marketed, the 
market price is an external influence on the profitability 
of agribusinesses. An increase in profit, its maximization 
can be realized provided the highest possible price of 
the goods under the given market conditions and a 
specific act of selling the goods. But the market price 
may be reduced to a minimum level.

The minimum price for a particular product is the 
marginal price that covers production and selling costs 
(cost price). In this case, the return is zero. There are 
no profits at all. At lower prices, the production ceases 
to have its meaning, i.e. becomes unprofitable and the 
commodity producer is unable to carry out even simple 
reproduction.

Meanwhile, in terms of incentives for economic growth 
and development, the minimum price may ensure 
survival and further reduction in costs, profit-earning 
and an increase in profits as well. As to market prices, 
on the surface level, a number of concepts are used that 
somehow characterize them as: “reasonable”, “low”, 
“factory”, “moderate”, “acceptable” and so forth. It is quite 
obvious that prices should be theoretically substantiated 
and satisfies the “selfish” interests of the commodity 
producer and society, that is, promote economic growth 
and development of both the enterprises and the national 
economy. Considering the fact that in the market 
conditions production is aimed at gaining the profit, then 
any prices should ensure it for the producer.

For the reasons above, scientists and political 
economists have always had an undying interest in 
pricing. In this regard, however, “quantity has not 
transformed into quality.” Neither in the past nor in 
the present has a single “theory of value and prices” 
been developed. Instead, there are different and even 
alternative points of view on this issue. It is a complex 
multi-vector and requires special fundamental, 
methodological, and theoretical research. It should be 
also taken into account that during the transformation 
from a centrally planned economy to a market economy, 
a number of works by Ukrainian scientists were devoted 
to the theory and practice of pricing.



Baltic Journal of Economic Studies  

246

Vol. 4, No. 3, 2018
That is why, in the context of the research area, the 

price is analysed only as an external influence on the 
profitability of agroproducers, and accordingly on 
the economic growth and development of individual 
agribusinesses and their aggregate (agriculture).

3. Analysing the pricing theories
In Soviet times, it was generally accepted that only the 

“labour” theory of value is scientifically substantiated. 
All the others are contrary to the market economy. 
Since the 90s of the last century, domestic scientists 
began introducing other approaches to determining the 
intrinsic substance of market prices. Let us distinguish 
the most typical of them.

The labour theory of value. Its supporters believe 
that no one has refuted the Marx’s formula c + v + m.  
The cost of goods is determined by the costs of socially 
necessary labour (c + v), and the price must recover 
costs and ensure the surplus value (m). This is the 
requirement of an objective law of value, the violation 
of which leads to significant losses, up to halt to a 
business. The price should cover production costs, 
circulation costs, and provide every properly operating 
enterprise with required profit – the fundamental rule of 
a market economy that determines the feasibility of an 
enterprise in the market and in the industry. “Currently, 
the main issue that must be resolved is the compliance 
with the objective law of value.” (Mesel-Veseliak, 2012) 
The intersectoral exchange, like any exchange process, 
is regulated by the law of value. However, a relation 
between the non-equivalence of the intersectoral 
exchange and the law of value is quite specific. The law 
of value stipulates that the sum of the prices of all goods 
to be exchanged must equal their social value. This 
equality cannot be realized at the level of an individual 
commodity, but when the goods are considered in the 
entirety of the exchange process, it becomes contingent 
and necessary in accordance with the law of large 
numbers (Valentynov, 2002). “The labour theory of 
value can be refuted by a theory that offers the substance 
of the prices common to all goods, which are weightier 
for abstract work and more closely related to the price. 
This, however, is not given” (Hosh, 2001).

The concept of market base and market prices: “The 
basis for pricing under market conditions is the ratio 
of product supply and demand” (Melnyk, 2009). The 
pricing is significantly influenced by “...the ratio of supply 
and demand for a certain type of goods” (Demediuk, 
2013).

The multi-factor market pricing: “Under market 
conditions, prices for manufactured products are 
determined by supply and demand, quality, production 
and selling costs, and taxes and market charges. Finally, 
the price is a monetary reflection of the commodity 
value and its value for buyers.” (Cherven, 2007) 
“The price of goods contains a conflict: it is almost 

always low for the seller, and high for the buyer. Price 
harmonization takes place in the market and is based on 
the law of supply and demand, where the supply is based 
on the theory of labour value, and the demand – on the 
theory of marginal utility. The theory of labour value 
examines the problem from the producer’s standpoint, 
and the theory of marginal utility – from the consumer’s 
standpoint”. (Stratehiia rozvytku ahrarnoho sektoru 
ekonomiky na period do 2020 roku, 2013).

The above gives grounds to conclude that there is 
no single theory of value and prices. The thesis that 
the labour theory of value is the only one scientifically 
substantiated theory, which was popular in the Soviet 
times, was proven to be wrong. Any of the theories 
are valid to some extent, and different pricing theories 
focus on different aspects of this complex process. 
Thus, the labour theory of value and prices emphasizes 
production costs (c + v). Scientists argue that the 
market compensates commodity producers for the 
public, not individual expenses, and non-equivalent 
exchange occurs only when the price of goods does not 
cover them and does not bring profit. Since individual 
expenses (cost price) in this sector are significantly 
differentiated in accordance with businesses, it is 
normal for the market economy when some businesses 
receive an excess profit (due to low cost compared 
to the public one), and some make no profit at all.  
The differentiated individual expenses encourage 
businesses to achieve social production costs and 
reduce them in order to obtain excess profit as a result 
of innovative development. And in this context, the 
market constantly encourages commodity producers 
to introduce scientific and technological advances in 
production and contributes to the development of the 
industry. Such pricing is typical for a competitive market, 
which provides an equivalent exchange based on the 
law of value, i.e. prices are formed at average costs. But 
with limited natural resources, e.g. agricultural land and 
its fertility, climatic conditions, more adverse business 
conditions in relation to the factors may be acceptable.

In other words, agricultural prices theoretically should 
be based on costs incurred in the worst lands. This is 
due to the fact that the land is a unique, space-limited 
resource, and there is land rent. That is, all parcels of 
land, except for the worst ones, bring excess profit. 
However, due to the difficulty in determining prices for 
agricultural products from the worst land, this idea has 
not been put into practice, and the prices are formed at 
average costs. The latter makes it difficult to solve the 
problem of disparity of price for agricultural products 
and material and technical resources entering the 
agriculture sector and requires to solve the disparity in 
its own way (Melnyk, 2016; Semenova, 2013, Stratehiia 
rozvytku ahrarnoho sektoru ekonomiky na period do 
2020 roku, 2013).

But the said refers to highly competitive markets, where 
all its subjects gain profits on the difference between 



Baltic Journal of Economic Studies  

247

Vol. 4, No. 3, 2018
the price of production and the average industry costs.  
If any subject of the agrarian market takes a monopoly or 
oligopolistic position, then he/she will take advantage 
of that position to dictate his/her terms to partners.  
The economic realization of the market monopoly is 
earning monopoly excess profit by using price factor. 
There are monopoly (oligopoly) high prices in the market 
of agricultural production means, and there are monopoly 
low purchasing prices in the agricultural market. In both 
cases, the agrarians incur the loss appropriated by their 
counterparts in those markets (Melnyk, 2016).

Summarizing numerous scientific approaches to the 
price base, we believe that each of them is worthy of 
attention, and all of them are mutually complementary. 
The study is not aimed at developing another approach 
to pricing. There is probably no need for it. We are rather 
interested in the practical aspect of pricing, namely: 
the market price at a given cost price determines the 
producer’s profit, which is the main goal, the motivator 
of all economic entities involved. In terms of the law of 
value, each commodity producer with socially necessary 
expenses gains profit according to his/her average rate. 
Those whose expenses are lower gain excess profit, 
while those whose expenses are higher lose a share 
of the average profit. Such pricing and profitability 
correspond to market management principles and 
objective economic laws.

The above provision is implemented in the conditions 
of the free competition market, the so-called perfect 
market. Almost all domestic scientists have to admit that 
agrarians generally have the least market power in all 
markets and accordingly experience economic pressure in 
both markets: in the input market – from the enterprises 
of the first sphere of the agro-industrial complex, in 
the output market – from the third sphere, primarily 
mediators. In other words, agrarians, compared with 
other agrarian market participants, have less opportunity 
to defend their interests. As a consequence, the long-term 
non-equivalence of intersectoral relations within the 
agro-industrial complex often called “disparity or price 
discrepancy” is not in favour of the agricultural sector.

All domestic scientists agree that price disparity has 
an adverse influence on agriculture: poor material and 
technical base; reduced remuneration of labour; and 
suspended social development of rural areas. Prices 
for agricultural products do not reimburse their cost of 
production.

The specific losses in the industry referred to in 
works on economics are as follows. The agribusinesses 
lose 8.37 billion UAH of their average annual income 
because of price disparity, and the agricultural workers 
are underpaid 3.34 billion UAH because of disparity in 
remuneration of labour. The total lost profit accounts 
for 128 billion UAH, which also includes a reduction in 
budget financing (Sabluk, 2008; Semenova, 2013).

The price disparity in the agricultural sector can be 
caused by different reasons. They are generally caused 

by special characteristics of the industry. An increase in 
non-equivalent intersectoral exchange can be explained 
by increasing dependence of agriculture on industries 
that buy its products and sell the means of production 
to it, as a result of a deeper social division of labour. 
Ultimately, inelastic demand for agricultural products is 
typical for the agricultural market. All of the above lead 
to price diktat from the enterprises of the first and third 
spheres of the agro-industrial complex.

Thus, the market mechanism, in the agrarian market 
where oligopolistic mediators dominate, leads to the 
fact that the agrarian producer loses profits or even 
suffers losses, and the mediators gain excess profit. That 
explains why for many years agriculture is actually on 
the verge of simple reproduction. The adverse influence 
of “price disparity” on the profitability of agribusinesses 
today is probably the most significant among the 
factors that hinder the agrarian sector from developing 
and contribute to its destruction. This applies to both 
economic and social components.

The accuracy of the data given can be disputed. 
After all, the case in hand is about a potential loss, and 
even according to their minimal estimate, annually the 
agrarians receive 40-50 billion UAH less, which is twice 
the amount of net profit earned by agribusinesses in 
2014 (20.3 billion UAH). At best, prices for agricultural 
products provide a simple reproduction for most 
agribusinesses, which conflicts with the laws of the 
market economy. As a result, the money, which has 
not been received by peasants, is appropriated by other 
agrarian market participants (Melnyk, 2016).

In the final analysis, agriculture is one of the least 
profitable since the surplus value is to some extent 
appropriated by those who buy their products. Provided 
that there were equivalent exchange conditions, this 
could be avoided. Hence, the conclusion to be drawn is 
that the price factor of agribusiness profitability hinders 
its economic growth and development.

In a perfect market, the price of goods is close to 
its value. The more perfect the market, the more the 
commodity price is close to its value, and the profit to 
the surplus value.

Monopoly low prices or monopoly high prices 
are a means to calculate the latter, its free transfer by 
agricultural producers to the buyer, or to the seller 
who sells products to agricultural producers, that is, 
agricultural production means.

It should be noted that almost all agrarian economists 
argue that the agrarian market is imperfect. It is first of 
all about the non-equivalent intersectoral exchange and 
price disparity in agriculture from the first and third 
spheres of the agro-industrial complex.

Based on this, most scientists conclude that the 
experience of the developed countries and domestic 
practice show that the market economy does not provide 
such pricing in the agrarian market that would promote 
economic growth and development of agriculture.



Baltic Journal of Economic Studies  

248

Vol. 4, No. 3, 2018
Concerning the set of causes that explain the 

increasing discrepancy between prices for agricultural 
products and production resources for agriculture, 
scientists emphasize the relative disadvantage of 
agriculture, primarily due to high monopolization of 
allied industries. This forces agricultural commodity 
producers to accept prices that are formed in uneven 
distribution of market power. Other causes include: 
inelastic supply of agricultural products and demand for 
them; inequality between scientific and technological 
progress and increasing demand for agricultural 
products; high immobility of agricultural resources; 
inequality of the speed of capital circulation in various 
sectors (Valentynov, 2002).

“In market conditions, the profit regulates the 
production. It is the factors of long-term return of 
advanced capital and the profitability of current costs 
that measure the investment attractiveness of the 
specific industry. Agriculture belongs to the industries 
that are unable to accumulate capital and create excess 
profit. Due to slow capital turnover and dependence 
on climatic and weather conditions, agriculture 
is considered to be one of the riskiest industries.  
It is difficult to predict prices for products, amount 
of products and marginal costs for agribusinesses.  
The monopsonic structure of the market makes the 
situation more complicated. Having market power, 
processing and procurement enterprises exert a significant 
pressure on agricultural prices. Thus, the agrarian sector 
becomes non-competitive and unattractive for investment 
due to the lack of government regulatory measures aimed 
at agricultural price support” (Kozak, 2009).

Foreign and domestic practices clearly show that the 
agrarian market is far from the perfect. It is characterized 
by inelastic demand for agricultural products and, 
to a certain extent, their surplus (both absolute for 
developed countries and relative for prohibitive market 
prices due to low incomes of the population).

However, at least in theory, market conditions in any 
economic field and industry should ensure exchange 
equivalence. Otherwise, what was the reason to 
create an entrepreneurial and market environment for 
Ukrainian agriculture is to denationalize the latter. After 
all, in recent years, the vast majority of scientists suggest 
that government should intervene in market pricing 
mechanisms.

Thus, it is of significant practical importance to 
scientifically substantiate the objective necessity for the 
government to interfere in market pricing mechanisms 
in the agrarian market. It is evident that over the years 
since independence the agrarian market has been 
imperfect since it lacks for equivalent intersectoral 
relations. “The current agrarian market model formed 
over the last two decades makes it possible to provide 
tangible financial performance only to large producers – 
agrarian holdings. At the same time, small and medium-
sized farms are not developed properly.” (Stratehiia 

rozvytku ahrarnoho sektoru ekonomiky na period 
do 2020 roku, 2013) Due to imperfect intersectoral 
economic relations, the price mechanism in particular, 
over the last 15 years the industry has lost more than 
600 billion UAH, which caused a significant decrease in 
funds channelled for its material and technical facilities 
and remuneration of labour, which are twice lower in 
the agriculture sector when compared to the industry.

The low profitability of most agribusinesses does not 
facilitate the key driving force of economic growth and 
development of agriculture – the satisfaction of the 
economic needs and interests of its subjects. It should 
be noted that most scientists, investigating the nature of 
the non-equivalent interchange exchange, consider it is 
a perennial problem of agriculture in market conditions 
and it is impossible to avoid it completely.

Now let us consider theoretically the market capacity 
to settle, provide equivalent intersectoral relations in 
agribusiness, and give an answer whether the state 
intervention in this process is objective.

4. Regulating the market for intersectoral 
relations in the agro-industrial complex

As we have already noted, most domestic scientists 
agree that objective economic law of value operates in 
agriculture as well, and, accordingly, its self-regulation. 
And this means that the price is based on the social cost 
of production and sale of goods. That is, market prices 
are formed on the basis of the law of value, which is the 
law of prices. And here, as the scientists rightly believe, it 
is important to determine what costs are involved since 
in practice individual expenses, especially in agriculture, 
differ significantly in the industry. They can be divided 
into three groups for convenience: high; average; and 
low. According to the labour theory of value (and it is 
logical), the market price should compensate for the 
costs incurred in socially normal production conditions, 
with an average level of technical and technological 
equipment, professional skills, and the average intensity 
of labour. Such costs are more or less in line with the 
economic units that currently produce most of the 
products. But even common sense and logic give 
grounds to assert that for the seller the commodity price, 
with all price manipulation, has a lower limit – the costs 
of production. Moreover, the commodity producer has 
not only to reimburse the costs incurred. His/her activity 
is aimed at gaining a profit. The buyer, who creates the 
demand, is primarily interested in the “marginal utility” 
of the product and, of course, he/she considers his/her 
ability to pay. Any commodity producer, therefore, will 
fail to reproduce even simple production, if the market 
price does not constantly compensate for it. In this case, 
the following are possible: 1) incomplete reproduction; 
2) production specialization change; 3) economic 
bankruptcy. That is, the case in hand is the decline and 
destruction of a certain type or branch of production 
(Melnyk, 2016).



Baltic Journal of Economic Studies  

249

Vol. 4, No. 3, 2018
The development of the productive forces is 

accompanied by significant shifts in the production 
structure. Certain types of production are reduced 
and even completely replaced by others (for example, 
ironmaking and steelmaking are largely replaced by 
plastic and ceramics). However, it is impossible to 
imagine the suspension of production in the agriculture 
sector, where products of vital importance and raw 
materials for many processing enterprises are produced. 
Theoretically, the world division of labour makes it 
possible for small countries, for example, Iceland. For 
most countries of the world, mass imports are issues of 
food and economic security, a demand for considerable 
funds.

If agriculture is considered within the national 
economy of those countries, in which it is the main 
agricultural producer, the massive bankruptcy of 
agribusinesses without government intervention 
would inevitably lead to an increase in prices to a level 
of sufficient profitability (subject to socially necessary 
costs). Market conditions would naturally increase 
the concentration, centralization, and integration of 
production and reduce the public spending. The whole 
society would benefit from this, but there would be a 
significant decrease in the number of economic entities. 
Therefore, now most of the Western countries support 
small- and medium-sized farms, as discussed above.

A rather different situation is observed in Ukraine. 
The government support is insufficient. The rural 
households survive due to their mostly subsistence 
consumption character. In the sector of agricultural 
enterprises, expenses are compensated for about 
9/10  agribusinesses. Others are satisfied with 
relatively low profitability, and every tenth enterprise is 
unprofitable. In the end, all this significantly hinders the 
economic growth and development of agriculture.

Thereby, settling parity intersectoral relations in the 
agro-industrial complex is a pressing issue. It requires 
to develop ways to activate the main factor that affects 
the profitability of agribusinesses, and thereby their 
main economic goal achievement. Science and practice 
have proved that in current conditions one of the most 
accessible is free competition market relations, and 
accordingly spontaneous self-organization. However, 
as it has been already noted, this option is not used in 
almost all countries with developed market economies. 
Agriculture is regulated both by the market and by the 
state. How exactly it is sufficiently covered in many 
economic works. In particular, back in the late 90s of 
the last century, S. Demianenko noted that now more 
and more economists abandon themselves to the idea 
that it is quite difficult to reach price parity, and in 
general, its expediency is questionable. And with it, 
significant shortcomings of the concept of price parity 
are emphasized.

Therefore, now most Western economists incline 
to two other concepts of equalization of production 

opportunities in agriculture and other industries. These 
are the concepts of income parity and resource parity, 
which currently are the most popular in agrarian policy.

The concept of income parity provides that in 
agriculture, net profit and profitability (the share of 
profit in the price of agricultural products) should be 
the same as in other economic sectors.

The concept of resource parity lies in the fact that 
agriculture should ensure the same resource efficiency 
as non-agricultural sectors. First of all, it is meant the 
resource productivity and production optimization, 
at which resources would be optimally (in terms of 
resource allocation between different sectors of the 
national economy) involved in the production.

The national agrarian policy should be based on 
the parity of incomes between agricultural producers 
and workers in other sectors, as well as the resource 
productivity parity. This means a retreat from the 
concept of agricultural and industrial price parity.

The concept of income parity is much broader than 
the concept of price parity. It consists in equalizing 
the incomes of agricultural workers with the incomes 
of workers in other sectors and provides for a set of 
measures aimed at achieving that, including maintaining 
prices for industrial resources for agriculture, subsidizing 
certain types of agricultural products (in particular 
livestock), creating a favourable tax climate for agrarian 
enterprises, and improving social living conditions 
in rural areas. The implementation of the concept of 
income parity will increase the incomes of agricultural 
producers (which are now half as low as the national 
average) and balance the development of the agrarian 
sector as well (Demianenko, 1998).

The issues of state regulation of prices and incomes 
in Ukraine should neither be underestimated nor 
overestimated. At least since independence, it has been 
very problematic. Let us consider what agribusinesses 
themselves can do in the current marketing environment 
in Ukraine.

To answer the question posed, the agricultural market 
has been analysed (Table 1).

As can be seen from the table, in 2015, “other 
channels” account for the lion’s share of agricultural 
products, – 86.0%. And it has significantly increased 
over the last 20 years. Only 2.0% was sold in the market.

This raises the question about what the most 
economically significant agricultural product sale, – 
“other channels” include. It should be noted that in 1990, 
there were no “other channels” for any of the products 
except for grain and leguminous crops (3.2%) and eggs 
(0.2%). Who personifies this “encoded” agricultural 
sale channel, that is, who buys the agricultural products? 
The scientists give an unambiguous answer to this 
question – various mediatory structures, grain traders 
in particular. Concerning the latter, economists believe 
that the largest grain traders in the Ukrainian and foreign 
markets occupied their niche long ago, and still hold 



Baltic Journal of Economic Studies  

250

Vol. 4, No. 3, 2018

their positions. According to the Ukrainian Agrarian 
Confederation, the top three grain traders provided 
about 38% of exports, and the top seven – about 3/4 of 
Ukraine’s total grain exports.

International trader representatives remain the largest 
exporters of Ukraine’s grains (Serna PE, Louis Dreyfus 
Commodities Ukraine Ltd, Suntrade AC, Kernel 
Trade LLC, Alfred C. Toepfer Ukraine LLC, etc.), and 
among the companies with domestic capital, the largest 
are Agroexport and Adora. Of the 600 companies 
exporting grain, the largest accounts for about 60-70% 
of the shipped grain. The total number of exporters is 
practically unchanged over the years. Most of them are 
in Kyiv, Odesa, Mykolaiv, and Kherson regions.

Domestic grain traders made a significant impact on 
the production and sale of grain, focusing on exports, 
they actively developed their trade infrastructure by 
creating regional grain elevator networks and investing 
in domestic port facilities. Due to private investment, 
grain exports from 2003 to 2010 grew from 6 million 
tons to 36 million tons (Vlasenko, 2015).

The vast majority of scientists criticize the dominance 
of mediators in the agricultural product market (Table 2).

Some researchers rightly believe that one should 
not absolutize mediator malpractice in the agricultural 
products market. That is, in a more general approach to 
the problem, mediation should not be perceived only 
as a negative phenomenon. After all, the presence of 
mediators is typical for a market economy as a whole, 
at all stages of its development. As is generally known, 
almost all trade performs such a role, once separated 
from the industry. And this is beneficial to both sectors 
and their primary structures. The agrarians also will 
benefit from specializing in direct production and 
transferring such functions as transportation, storage, 
processing, and sale of products that require funds, time, 
and professional skills to mediatory structures. The 
latter have the opportunity to obtain “economy of scale” 
in selling products since they serve many agricultural 
producers, they have the opportunity to thoroughly 
study the market situation, use marketing structures, 
and minimize transaction costs.

Table 1
The structure of the main agricultural products sold by Ukrainian agribusinesses according to sale channels  
(as a percentage of total sales)

Types of products
To processing 

enterprises
To shareholders

To population  
as remuneration  

of labour
In the market Other channels

1990 2014 1990 2014 1990 2014 1990 2014 1990 2014
Grain and leguminous crops 80.4 3.3 - 4.7 13.2 0.2 3.2 3.1 3.2 88.7
Oil crops 98.9 6.1 - 0.3 0.8 - 0.3 2.0 - 91.6
Sugar beet 100.0 93.6 - - - - - - - 6.4
Livestock and poultry  
(live weight)

94.8 23.5 - 0.1 3.3 0.3 1.8 16.6 0.1 68.8

Milk and dairy products 99.1 94.9 - - 0.8 0.1 0.1 1.3 - 3.7
Eggs 98.1 3.5 - - 0.4 0.2 1.3 14.5 0.2 81.8

Source: (Statystychnyj zbirnyk “Silske hospodarstvo Ukrainy” za 2015 rik, 2016)

Table 2
The assessment of mediatory structures in the agricultural product market by domestic scientists

Author Interpretation

M.V. Zubets

“Currently, the domestic market is mainly controlled by mediatory structures, whose main purpose is to pay as cheap as 
possible for the grown produce to the agricultural producer when buying and sell as expensive as possible to the consumer. 
This leads to the impoverishment of agricultural producers, buyers are unable to buy products at high prices. This results in 
artificial overproduction and creates an opportunity for a mediator to export the products. Such actions nullify almost all 
the government efforts to support the agricultural sector, and most importantly, the absence of market self-regulation since 
the results of the supply and demand interaction, in this case, are reaped by mediators” (Zubets, 2007)

V.Ya. Mesel-Veseliak
“... various trader formations, which undertook to sell agricultural products. They set purchase prices which are not 
for benefit of agrarians, trade in the world market and appropriate all the earnings” (Mesel-Veseliak, 2009)

M.O. Pohoretskyi

“... the domestic agricultural commodity producer leaves it to mediators to deliver products to the ultimate consumer. 
The mediators often take advantage of that, setting a very high margin between the purchase price and the selling 
price. Ultimately, the consumer receives products at excessively high prices, and the mediator becomes the most 
profitable participant in the market, producing nothing and spending very little. The government must solve this 
problem by constantly influencing the mediatory structures and issuing relevant laws” (Pohoretskyi, 2013)

P.T. Sabluk
“An analysis of export selling prices shows that at the export stage up to 70% of the total revenues from the sale of 
agricultural products in the world market are formed, and expenditures at this stage in most types of products do not 
exceed 20%” (Sabluk, 2011)

Source: summarized by the author



Baltic Journal of Economic Studies  

251

Vol. 4, No. 3, 2018
The most important thing for direct agricultural 

producers is to get a fair price for their products. But in 
Ukraine, mediators dictate prices to them, i.e. establish 
a monopoly low level (Melnyk, 2016).

5. Conclusions
Thus, a branched commercial mediator system has 

been created in Ukraine’s agricultural market. They 
wedged themselves in between agricultural producers 
and ultimate consumers. Such mediators are not 
superfluous since they are engaged in moving products 
from the producer to the ultimate consumer. Under 
certain conditions, the mediator is beneficial for the 
producer, the ultimate consumer and society provided 
they conduct a proper price policy in respect of both 
their counterparties. To date, “...a rather branched 
and practically uncontrolled commercial mediator 
system has wedged in the market turnover mechanism. 
Thus, agrarian products move as follows: the agrarian 
enterprise – the mediator – the ultimate consumer 
...Therefore, the price formed in this way is virtually 
unprofitable for agrarians and production becomes 
unprofitable. But the mediator buys the product for 
a song (the cost price is higher than the offered price) 
and sells it to the ultimate consumer at the price, 
which provides the mediator with high profit. So, the 
market mechanism can be represented as follows: the 
agribusiness – losses; the mediator – excess profits; 
the processing enterprise – profits; the ultimate 
consumer. Thus, losses incurred by the agribusiness are 
transformed into excess profits gained by the mediator 
and profits made by the processing enterprise ... Their 
participation in the agrarian market is determined by 
the algorithm: to buy as cheap as possible to sell as 
expensive as possible” (Khorunzhyj, 2011).

It should be noted that there is no official data on 
the excess profits gained by agrarian market mediators. 
Accordingly, it is impossible to accurately determine 
losses born by agribusinesses as a result of not selling 
their products to the ultimate consumer by themselves. 
Losses from price disparity can only be hypothesized.

The above refers to all agrarians: “Agricultural 
producers do not have direct access to the market since 
the market is shared primarily by mediatory structures 
that operate according to non-transparent schemes for 
selling food products” (Kotkalova, 2010).

Under such conditions, it is urgent to use all possible 
directions, mechanisms, and levers to ensure that 
agricultural producers directly participate in the entire 
food chain to move their products to the ultimate 
consumer. How exactly? It is well-known that this 
requires handling costs, from transportation, storage, 
reprocessing, and processing of agricultural products 
to the formation of trade and logistics infrastructure, 
the construction of grain elevators and port facilities, 
commodity exchanges, auctions, and formal markets.  

It is clear that producers take risks and bear possible 
losses when storing products. The agrarian market 
eventually becomes more transparent and predictable 
for all its participants.

The above gives grounds to conclude that in the 
current economic conditions, most agricultural 
enterprises do not sell their products directly to 
domestic ultimate consumers, not to mention foreign 
consumers. This is due to many reasons. The main of 
them are: lack of common facilities for agribusinesses 
to use when moving their products from the producer 
to the ultimate consumer. It is primarily about different 
types of cooperatives, common grain elevators, 
processing enterprises, wholesale markets, firms, and 
so on. In selling products to processing enterprises, 
it is important to establish long-lasting and mutually 
beneficial relationships between agrarians and 
processors. It is important to compensate socially 
necessary expenses to agricultural enterprises and a 
normal profit gained by them, in other words, to obtain 
mutual maximum benefits by each of the participants.

Creating these conditions does not exclude the 
presence of mediators in the agrarian market. But they 
will have to act in a competitive environment. This will 
significantly decrease the government regulation and 
support of market prices. Is it possible for individual 
agricultural producers to sell products to the ultimate 
consumer? It is probably possible only for those who 
have reached production overconcentration, agro-
holdings in particular. The others need to join their 
efforts to implement those functions that are currently 
performed by mediators.

The experience of economically developed countries 
gives grounds to assert that one of the effective ways to 
reach the ultimate consumer is to create “own mediators”, 
as a rule, non-profit ones. Such mediators also act in 
the agrarian market according to the algorithm: “to buy 
as cheap as possible to sell as expensive as possible”, for 
example, supply and marketing cooperatives. But such 
savings are distributed among the cooperative members. 
Other ways for the producer to directly access the ultimate 
consumer or processing enterprise are also important.

In Ukraine, the cooperative movement has not 
developed properly due to the negative impact of 
objective and subjective reasons. Currently, the 
following directions are deemed as the most actual 
(for more or less large-scale agribusinesses). First, to 
create joint ventures to develop an extensive network 
to perform certain functions in the supply chain from 
the producer to the ultimate consumer. For example, 
the construction of joint warehouses, elevators for 
storage of products. Domestic scientists have repeatedly 
pointed to the fact that, for example, the effectiveness 
of grain production is affected by a term of realization. 
Agribusinesses that do not have warehouses (elevators) 
for storing grain are forced to sell their products in July-
August when grain prices are sharply reduced due to an 



Baltic Journal of Economic Studies  

252

Vol. 4, No. 3, 2018
increase in supply. Agribusinesses that have their own 
elevators and enough working capital can sell grain, 
soya beans, and sunflower seeds in January-June when 
prices are high. Therefore, for lack of elevator capacities 
in Ukraine, it is advisable to have own granary in order 
to increase profitability in the production of grain, soya 
beans, rapeseed, sunflower seeds.

An agribusiness project provides for the construction 
of an elevator with a capacity of 40 thousand tons.  
In addition to drying and storing own grain, the business 
may provide such services to other agribusinesses, 
which will provide extra earning and improve return on 
investment in the elevator (Ilchuk, 2015).

Secondly, an important direction in diminishing 
agricultural price disparity is to build an effective 
contractual system, conclude long-term contracts  
(on a long-term basis) as to the amount, quality, terms 
and, most importantly, the price. It is clear that the 
latter is the principal and most controversial item of the 
contract as both counterparts have opposite interests.

The practice of relations between agricultural 
producers and buyers of agricultural products indicate 
the lack of an effective contractual system that would 
guarantee reduction of risks for buyers and sellers, timely 
payment and would be a medium to avoid bankruptcy 
and sale of non-profitable companies. The problem 
can be solved by developing an appropriate legislative 
framework for concluding, maintaining, and executing 
contracts, bearing responsibility for non-fulfilment of 
contractual obligations and protecting the party whose 
rights have been violated.

Overseas experience confirms the importance of a 
contractual system for marketing agricultural products. 
For example, in the USA 90% of broilers, up to 30% 
of veal, and a quarter of all wholesale trade are sold in 
accordance with contractual relations between the 
producer and the supplier, with clearly defined volume 
and cost of production. Such measures make product 
quality control more effective and the market situation 
more predictable for all its operators (Hura, 2013).

References:
Valentynov V.L. (2002). Teoretychni osoblyvosti neekvivalentnosti mizhhaluzevykh vidnosyn v APK [Theoretical 
peculiarities of nonequivalence of intersectoral relations in agrarian and industrial complex]. Ekonomika APK 
[Economy of agroindustrial complex]. No. 11, pp. 34-37.
Vlasenko Yu.H. (2015). Rol zernotreideriv v eksporti vitchyznianoi pshenytsi [The role of grain traders in the 
export of domestic wheat]. Ahrosvit [Scientific and practical magazine Agrosvit]. No. 5, pp. 41-45.
Hosh O. (2001). Obiektyvni zasady tsinoutvorennia v postsotsialistychnii Ukraini [Objectives of pricing in post-
socialist Ukraine]. Ekonomika Ukrainy [ Journal of Economics of Ukraine]. No. 1, pp. 52-57.
Hura A.M. (2013). Orhanizatsijno-ekonomichni zasady formuvannia systemy zbutu v silskohospodarskykh 
pidpryiemstvakh [Organizational and economic principles of the formation of a system of sales in agricultural 
enterprises]. Ahrosvit [Scientific and practical magazine Agrosvit]. No. 21, pp. 21-24.
Demediuk L.V. (2013). Tsinove seredovyshche protsesu vidtvorennia v osobystykh selianskykh hospodarstvakh 
[Price environment of the reproduction process in private peasant farms]. Ahrosvit [Scientific and practical 
magazine Agrosvit]. No. 3, pp. 15-18.
Demianenko S. (1998). Do kontseptsii natsionalnoi ahrarnoi polityky. [To the Concept of National Agrarian 
Policy]. Ekonomika Ukrainy [ Journal of Economics of Ukraine]. No. 1, pp. 22-30.
Zubets M.V. (2007). Rozvyvaty vnutrishnii ahrarnyi rynok [Develop an internal agrarian market]. Ekonomika 
APK [Economy of agroindustrial complex]. No. 1, pp. 50-51.
Ilchuk M.M. (2015). Efektyvnist investytsiinoho proektu stvorennia ta funktsionuvannia 
vysokotekhnolohichnoho silskohospodarskoho pidpryiemstva [Efficiency of an investment project for the 
creation and operation of a high-tech agricultural enterprise]. Ekonomika APK [Economy of agroindustrial 
complex]. No. 5, pp. 55-61.
Kozak L.V. (2009). Rehulyatyvni zakhody pidtrymky vitchyznianykh silskohospodarskykh vyrobnykiv [Regulatory 
measures to support domestic agricultural producers]. Ekonomika APK [Economy of agroindustrial complex].  
No. 10, pp. 14-17.
Kotkalova I.V. (2010). Upravlinnia kapitalom ahrokholdynhiv: avtoref. dys. na zdobuttia nauk. stupenia kand. 
ekonom. nauk: spets. 08.07.02 Ekonomika ta upravlinnia pidpryiemstvamy (mashynobuduvannia, ahropromyslovyi 
kompleks, turystychni pidpryiemstva ta pidpryiemstva rekreatsiinoho kompleksu) [Economy and management 
of enterprises (machine building, agro-industrial complex, tourist enterprises and enterprises of the recreational 
complex]. Yevropeiskyi universytet [European University]. Kyiv, 2010, 20 p.
Melnyk L.L. (2016). Ekonomichna zasady prybutkovosti silskoho hospodarstva: Monohrafiia. [Economic 
principles of profitability of agriculture: Monograph] Svidler A.L. Publishing House.
Melnyk Yu.F. (2009). Ahropromyslove vyrobnytstvo Ukrainy: uroky 2008 roku i shliakhy zabezpechennia 
innovatsiinoho rozvytku [Agro-industrial production of Ukraine: lessons of 2008 and ways of providing innovative 
development]. Ekonomika APK [Economy of agroindustrial complex]. No. 1, pp. 3-15.
Mesel-Veseliak V.Ya. (2009). Napriamy zabezpechennia konkurentospromozhnosti ahrarnoho vyrobnytstva [Areas 
of ensuring the competitiveness of agrarian production]. Ekonomika APK [Economy of agroindustrial complex]. 
No. 10, pp. 7-14.



Baltic Journal of Economic Studies  

253

Vol. 4, No. 3, 2018
Mesel-Veseliak V.Ya. (2012). Tsinovyi faktor i rozvytok ahrarnoho vyrobnytstva Ukrainy [Pricing factor and 
development of agrarian production in Ukraine]. Ekonomika APK [Economy of agroindustrial complex]. No. 1, 
pp. 179-180.
Pohoretskyi M.O. (2013). Teoretychni osnovy realizatsii ahrarnoi produktsii [Theoretical basis for the 
implementation of agrarian products]. Ahrosvit [Scientific and practical magazine Agrosvit]. No. 14, pp. 39-42.
Sabluk P.T. (2008). Problemy zabezpechennia dokhidnosti ahropromyslovoho vyrobnytstva v Ukraini v 
postindustrialnyi period [Problems of ensuring the profitability of agro-industrial production in Ukraine in the 
post-industrial period]. Ekonomika APK [Economy of agroindustrial complex]. No. 4, pp. 19-37.
Sabluk P.T. (2011). Realizatsiia mekhanizmu reform v ahrarnii sferi [Realization of the mechanism of reforms in 
the agrarian sector]. Ekonomika APK [Economy of agroindustrial complex]. No. 10, pp. 3-6.
Semenova L.Yu. (2013). Osoblyvosti dii tsinovoho mekhanizmu na rynku silskohospodarskoi produktsii [Features 
of the price mechanism on the market of agricultural products]. Ahrosvit [Scientific and practical magazine 
Agrosvit]. No. 18, pp. 40-46.
Statystychnyj zbirnyk «Silske hospodarstvo Ukrainy» za 2015 rik. (2016). Statistical collection "Agriculture of 
Ukraine" for 2015 / State Statistics Committee of Ukraine.
Stratehiia rozvytku ahrarnoho sektoru ekonomiky na period do 2020 roku: zbirnyk materialiv Chotyrnadtsiatykh 
richnykh zboriv Vseukrainskoho konhr. vchen. ekonomistiv-ahrarnykiv. (2013). [Strategy for the development of 
the agrarian sector of the economy for the period up to 2020: a collection of materials of the Fourteenth Annual 
Meeting of the All-Ukrainian Cong. scientist economists-agrarians] (Kyiv, October 16-17, 2012).
Khorunzhyj M.J. (2011). Problemy tsinoutvorennia na silskohospodarsku produktsiiu [Problems of Pricing on 
Agricultural Products]. Ekonomika APK [Economy of agroindustrial complex]. No. 1, pp. 57-67.
Cherven I.I. (2007). Ahrarnyi rynok vymahaie vyvazhenoi tsinovoi polityky [The agrarian market requires a well-
balanced pricing policy]. Ekonomika APK [Economy of agroindustrial complex]. No. 3, pp. 99-104.