This is an Open Access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (https://creativecommons. org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited. Copyright © 2021 The Author(s). Published by Vilnius Gediminas Technical University *Corresponding author. E-mail: journaltm@ukr.net Business, Management and Economics Engineering ISSN: 2669-2481 / eISSN: 2669-249X 2021 Volume 19 Issue 2: 244–271 https://doi.org/10.3846/bmee.2021.14472 INFLUENCE OF INTERNAL AND EXTERNAL FACTORS ON THE STRUCTURAL CHANGES OF NATIONAL ECONOMY: AN EXAMPLE OF UKRAINE Uliana NIKONENKO 1, Olena KHALINA 2, Tanina KAZYUK 3, Viktor PALIUKH 4, Serhiy SHEVCHENKO 5 1,2Faculty of Media Communications and Entrepreneurship, Ukrainian Academy of Printing, Lviv, Ukraine 3National Academy for Public Administration under the President of Ukraine, Lviv, Ukraine 4National University of Civil Protection of Ukraine, Kharkiv, Ukraine 5Lviv Regional Institute for Public Administration, National Academy for Public Administration under the President of Ukraine, Lviv, Ukraine Received 24 February 2021; accepted 01 May 2021 Abstract. Purpose – the purpose of our article is to study structural changes in the national economy using a portfolio model of sectors with different returns and, on this basis, processing the methodology for identifying the current state and instrumental factors of economic policy. Research methodology – the methodology of empirical research includes methods of grouping, abstraction, comparison, systems analysis, synthesis and generalization, graphical methods and regression analysis. To analyze the nature of the relationship between the index of structural changes and the dynamics of GDP, which determines the comparative profitability of the resource and non-resource sectors and the current position of the current structure relative to the equilib- rium value, we used error-corrected models (ECMs). Findings – using regression models with error correction, a favourable long- and short-term rela- tionship between structural changes in favour of non-resource exports and Ukraine’s GDP has been empirically confirmed. Using the index of structural changes, considering the ratio of raw materials and non-raw materials exports, the necessity of applying administrative measures is substantiated. Research limitations – the study concerned mainly the national economy of Ukraine, but in the future, attention should be paid to the application of the results of our study in other countries of Eastern Eu- rope. In the future, the results obtained can be adapted for other countries of the world. The research was based on the use of specific mathematical methods, and not all mathematical possibilities were used. Practical implications – the model can be used in the practical activities of state economic structures In the future, it is possible to change key indicators and further expand the field of use of the model. Originality/Value – the novelty of the study lies in the development of a methodology for identifying the current state and instrumental factors of economic policy that can speed up economic growth based on favourable structural shifts (in favour of the non-resource export sector). Keywords: raw materials sector, exports, structural changes, terms of trade, exchange rate. JEL Classification: D51, F63, E60. mailto:journaltm@ukr.net https://doi.org/10.3846/bmee.2021.14472 https://orcid.org/0000-0002-6015-6248 https://orcid.org/0000-0002-4086-6314 https://orcid.org/0000-0002-5003-4896 https://orcid.org/0000-0001-9429-2013 https://orcid.org/0000-0002-5522-3258 Business, Management and Economics Engineering, 2021, 19(2): 244–271 245 Introduction The aim of this work is to study the structural changes in the Ukrainian economy using a portfolio model of sectors (raw and non-raw materials) and, on this basis, processing the methodology for identifying the current state and instrumental factors of economic policy, which provides for three stages: 1) the choice of the structural equilibrium index, since certain industries combine raw materials and non-raw materials; 2) identification of the structural state of the economy; 3) an assessment of the factors of economic policy, capable of accelerating economic growth based on favorable structural changes. The research task is to explain the structural changes in the Ukrainian economy using a sectoral model with two sectors – raw materials and non-raw materials. For this we use the index of structural equilibrium (structural change). This is important, because certain industries combine raw materials and non-raw materials. For example, this applies to metal- lurgy. A practical substitute for the “real” structural equilibrium index can be an index based on the structure of exports. In fact, there is no reason to believe that the “real” and export structures of the economy are significantly different. Our next step is to identify the structural state of the economy. We are talking about the nature of the relationship between the selected structural index and the dynamics of GDP, which determines the comparative profitability of the raw materials and non-resource sectors and the current position of the current structure relative to the equilibrium value. In such a context, error correction models (ECMs) provide a convenient toolkit. The final stage is the assessment of economic policy factors that can accelerate economic growth based on favorable structural shifts. First, we are talking about a standard set of tools for fiscal and monetary policy, as well as the problem of choosing the exchange rate. In a broader sense, the set of independent variables should contain variables that characterize the quality of economic policy and the scale of institutional change (error correction models – ECMs). In this article, we investigate the structural changes of the national economy, which mean qualitative changes in the structure of domestic exports, taking into account the above fac- tors, which will increase the level of GDP. It is advisable to stimulate structural changes in favor of the non-resource sector (non-resource exports) by strengthening the monetary unit, attracting foreign direct investment and limited government intervention, primarily to prevent the transfer of resources to the raw materials sector (infrastructure modernization, human capital development). It is interesting that the feasibility of the policy of administra- tive incentives for the transfer of production resources to the non-resource sector only in- creases in the event of structural shocks. In particular, this can be expected from a sustained deterioration in the terms of trade in world commodity markets. A powerful obstacle to such a development of events can be the inflow of foreign investment, because in this case, the incentives for internal redistribution of resources in favor of the raw materials sector are offset by the increased profitability of foreign investment in the country-raw materials exporter compared to the host country. The instrumental factor is the possibility of using the “underestimated” labour force and other advantages, which, possibly, are associated with the availability of raw materials. 246 U. Nikonenko et al. Influence of internal and external factors on the structural changes of national... 1. Literature review It is necessary to assess the export orientation of the Ukrainian economy at the present stage from the standpoint of the well-known hypothesis of the “life cycle of industry” proposed by the American economist J. Cornwell (1977). According to this theory, economic growth begins with the export of raw materials. Subsequently, income growth and technological changes in traditional industries modifiesthe structure of the economy in favor of technology sectors. The main macroeconomic indicators of such changes are growth in: 1) final domes- tic consumption in GDP and 2) the share of high-tech products in total exports (Wei et al., 2019). The key element of the industrial cycle hypothesis is the formation of net savings with added value created in export industries as a source of financing for economic restructuring (Ertz & Leblanc-Proulx, 2018). Such scientists as Danylchuk et  al. (2019) and Kazunobu (2017), based in their works on the existing model of three sectors, investigated the main structural changes that occur in the national economy of Ukraine, while highlighting and focusing on the importance of separating external and internal factors of influence on the main indicators of the national economy. The increase in employment can be taken as a criterion of optimal economic policy, does not contradict the widespread perception of the Ukrainian economy which is char- acterized by an excess oflabour in comparison with capital. In particular, Korablin (2017), Kiselakova et al. (2018), Koziuk (2018a, 2018b), Braun and Toth (2020), Antoniuk (2017) and Sijabat (2019) argue that the share of Ukraine in the global labor force (0.65%) is 5–8 times higher than the share in the gross accumulation of global capital (0.08%) and the production of world GDP (0.12%) testifies in favor of the dominance of labor-intensive, not too technological and capital-intensive industries. Experts Shynkaruk et  al. (2015) and Ginevicius et  al. (2020) also believe that the structure of employment in the Ukrainian economy is not optimal, does not meet the requirements of a post-industrial society and characterizes the processes of labour de- industrialization. The domestic service sector is primarily trade, hotel and restaurant busi- ness, although recent employment in the information and communication sector has been growing (Holian, 2016). In general, the position of Vashkiv (2017) and Cui et al. (2019) is logical, which believes that the analysis of sectoral structural shifts significantly benefits, if not limited to the share of each of the sectors in GDP, but also to study the share of employed workers in each of them. Based on this assumption, we formalized the main relationships between the raw materials and non-resource sectors. At the same time, despite a large number of publications indicating the feasibility of structural shifts in favor of the non-resource sector for a specific Ukrainian case, there is a lack of empirical estimates of 1) the impact of the structural change index on the dynam- ics of Ukraine’s GDP as a country-exporter of raw materials, 2) economic policies that can accelerate economic growth based on favorable structural changes. Business, Management and Economics Engineering, 2021, 19(2): 244–271 247 2. Theoretical model To explain the structural changes in the national economy, it is appropriate to use a sectoral model with two sectors – raw materials and non-raw materials (Nikonenko, 2018). Both sec- tors compete for labour and investment, are characterized by free movement of resources, and can export their products without hindrance. The main functional dependencies are as follows Equations (1)–(6): 1 1 2 1 (1 ) (1 ) (1 ) (1 ) ; T T T t t t t t t T T T T t t t t t t t Q L K g F CA b E L L a E K K+ + = α + −α + − g + −h + −ρ −    − − − + ξ    (1) 1 1 2 1 (1 ) ; S S S t t t t t t S S S S t t t t t t t Q L K g F CA a E L L a E K K+ + = β + −β + g + h +ρ −    − − − + ε    (2) *(1 )( ) ;S Tt t t t t t tP Y E P Q P Q= −ϕ + ϕ (3) *(1 )( ) ;S Tt t t t tE P Q P Q−ϕ = ϕ (4) * (1 ) ( )t t t t t tg E P P P Y g + − g = t  ; (5) * *, , ,tt t t t E P F CA Y Y P   =      (6) where StQ and T tQ , S tL and tOPD , S tK and T tK – production volumes, employment and means of capital in the raw and non-raw (technological) sectors, respectively, 1 S t tE L + and 1 S t tE K + , 1 T t tE L + and 1 T t tE K + – employment expectations and investment vol- umes in the raw materials and non-resource (technological) sectors, S tL and S tK , T tL and T tK – equilibrium values of labour and capital in the raw materials and non-resource (technological) sectors, respectively, gt – budget balance, Ft – volumes of foreign investments, * tP and tP – the level of prices for raw materials and technological goods, respectively, Et – nominal exchange rate (value of foreign currency in the national currency), Yt – income (gross domestic product), t – share of tax revenues in GDP. Equations (1) and (2) describe the production function in the commodity and non- commodity sectors, respectively. Production volumes depend on labour and capital inputs, government spending, foreign investment, and overseas demand. Correction mechanisms in the labour and financial resources markets provide that in case of expectations of excess sectoral employment and reinvestment in physical capital, there will be a corrective decrease in employment and investment. It can be conditionally assumed that the share of labour force prevails in the non-resource sector ( 1 )α > −α , while the opposite relationship is observed in the commodity sector ( 1 )β < −β . Government spending and foreign investment are divided between both sectors – raw materials and non-resource, and the corresponding ratio is determined by the coefficients g and h. For simplicity, the current account balance is assumed to be symmetric in both sec- 248 U. Nikonenko et al. Influence of internal and external factors on the structural changes of national... tors – QT and QS, although in a more general case, the balance of exports-imports may be individual for each of the sectors. Equation (3) provides an expression for income (GDP) in the prices of goods in the non- resource sector. The value of commodity products is determined by world market prices and the exchange rate. The devaluation of the monetary unit creates incentives in favour of the commodity sector. The coefficient f characterises the non-price component of structural changes and may reflect the characteristics of the institutional environment. Preferences in favour of the non-resource sector (this implies an increase in values f) can neutralise the impact of both the rise in prices for raw materials on world markets and the devaluation of the monetary unit. The strengthening of the monetary unit in response to the rise in prices for raw materials will have a similar impact. Equation (4) defines the sectoral equilibrium condition when price and non-price factors do not create advantages in favour of one sector. This is logical in the absence of institutional barriers to employment and investment in both sectors. Equation (5) defines the budget constraint. It is assumed that tax revenues ( )t tP Yt suffice to finance government spending in the primary and non-primary sectors. Equation (6) defines the balance of payments with equilibrium. In a somewhat simplified way, the current account balance is balanced by the inflow of foreign capital. The functional dependencies of the current account are defined in a standard way, namely: this indicator improves in the event of a decrease in the exchange rate and an increase in the income of trading partner countries; the opposite effect is an increase in own GDP. Taking into account the equilibrium condition (Equation (5)), from Equations (1) and (2) for the equilibrium state, we obtain that Equation (7): { } * * * * * * * 1 (1 )(1 ) (1 ) (1 ) (1 ) (1 ) (1 ) (1 ) (1 ) (1 ) , t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t t L E P P K P E P E P P g E P P F E P P CA  = −f −β −f −α + fα − −f β    −f g −f − g + −f h −f −h +     −f ρ −f −ρ + ε −ξ  (7) where L* and K* – are the equilibrium values of the means of labour and capital. It is not difficult to find a condition for the implementation of structural changes in favor of the non-resource sector, providing for an increase in the exchange rate Equation (8): { } * * * * 1 (1 )(1 ) (1 ) (1 ) (1 ) (1 ) (1 ) (1 ) (1 ) (1 ) . t t t t t t t t t L K P P E P E P g F CA ∂ = −f −β −f −α +       ∂ fα − −f β             −f g −f − g + −f h−f −h +       −f ρ−f −ρ + ε −ξ   (8) A fairly high value 1−β , combined with a low value 1−α and low share of non-primary goods in GDP, provides investment in physical favourable capital when the share of non- primary goods increases. Low value f enhances the corresponding stimulus for government spending, foreign investment and net exports. Business, Management and Economics Engineering, 2021, 19(2): 244–271 249 The main ideas for econometric modeling: to investigate the nature of the relationship between the index of structural changes and the dynamics of gross domestic product; explore the impact of terms of trade and policy instruments on structural shifts in favor of the non- resource export sector. 3. Methods and data Methodologically, identification of the current state and instrumental factors of economic policy involves three stages: 1. Choice of the index of structural equilibrium. 2. Identification of the structural state of the economy. 3. Assessment of economic polic y factors capable of accelerating economic growth based on favorable structural shifts. Based on the Engle and Granger (1991) methodology, the presence of cointegration of two indicators containing the so-called unit root I (1) allows us to estimate the long-term relationship between them (in levels) Equation (9): ,t t tY X= α +β + ε (9) and then use the resulting residuals to assess the short-term dynamics of the dependent variable (in the first differences) Equation (10): 0 1 ,t t t tY X −D = d + gD −dε + ξ (10) where Yt – dependent variable, tX – vector of independent variables, tε and tξ – stochastic factors. In Equation (10), the lags value of the residuals from Equation (9) is added to the list of independent variables. The coefficient d characterises the rate of return of the dependent variable to the equilibrium value based on deviations from long-term equilibrium. It should be noted that if there is over one cointegration equation between several variables, it is nec- essary to use the alternative VAR/VEC procedure (Alogoskoufis & Smith, 1991; Tang et al., 2015). It is also important that predictions for short-term rates may differ in principle from estimates for long-term relationships. The list of independent variables may also differ. To assess the peculiarities of the relationship between GDP and the structural character- istics of the domestic economy, the index of structural changes based on export commodity groups was used (Figure 1). To assess the peculiarities of the relationship between GDP and the structural character- istics of the domestic economy, the index of structural changes based on export commodity groups was used (Figure 1). Raw material exports include: agricultural products, mineral products, products of the chemical and related industries, timber and wood products, pulp made of wood or other fibrous cellulose materials, products made of stone, gypsum, cement, ceramics, glass. According to non-commodity exports, the rest of the exports are credited: finished food products, polymeric materials, plastics and rubber, leather and fur raw materi- als and products from them, textiles and textile products, footwear, hats, umbrellas, products from ferrous and non-ferrous metals, machines and mechanisms materials and their parts, 250 U. Nikonenko et al. Influence of internal and external factors on the structural changes of national... devices for recording and reproducing images and sound, vehicles and road equipment, op- tical instruments and apparatus, medical or surgical apparatus; clock; musical instruments, various goods and products. Metallurgy classification issues may seem controversial, because quite often metallurgy is considered a raw materials and medium- or low-tech industry. In any case, references to the hypertrophied development of the mining and metallurgical complex as one of the reasons for the structural problems of the domestic economy are quite common. Regardless of the classification of the metallurgical industry, a constant decrease in the share of mechanical engineering can be considered a sign of an increase in the raw materials orientation of pro- duction and exports to Ukraine and an increased dependence on the situation in external raw materials markets, although some researchers believe that official statistics underestimate the export volumes of technological exports (Bitsyura, 2016). To assess the peculiarities of the relationship between GDP and the structural character- istics of the domestic economy, the index of structural changes based on export commodity groups was used. Raw materials exports include: agricultural products, mineral products, products of the chemical and related industries, timber and wood products, wood pulp or other fibrous cellulosic materials, products made of stone, plaster, cement, ceramic, glass. Ac- cording to non-commodity exports, the remaining exports are included: finished food prod- ucts, polymeric materials, plastics and rubber, leather and fur raw materials and products from them, textiles and textile products, footwear , hats, umbrellas, products made of ferrous and non-ferrous metals, machines and mechanisms, electrical equipment and their parts, devices for recording and reproducing images and sound, vehicles and road equipment, op- tical instruments and apparatus, medical or surgical apparatus; clock; musical instruments, various goods and products (Korablin, 2017). Metallurgy classification issues may seem controversial, because quite often metallurgy is considered a raw material and medium- or low-tech industry. References to the hypertro- phied development of the mining and metallurgical complex as one reason for the structural problems of the domestic economy are quite common. Regardless of the classification of the metallurgical industry, a constant decrease in the share of mechanical engineering can be 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 1 9 9 8 1 9 9 9 2 0 0 0 2 0 0 1 2 0 0 2 2 0 0 3 2 0 0 4 2 0 0 5 2 0 0 6 2 0 0 7 2 0 0 8 2 0 0 9 2 0 1 0 2 0 1 1 2 0 1 2 2 0 1 3 2 0 1 4 2 0 1 5 2 0 1 6 2 0 1 7 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 1 9 9 8 1 9 9 9 2 0 0 0 2 0 0 1 2 0 0 2 2 0 0 3 2 0 0 4 2 0 0 5 2 0 0 6 2 0 0 7 2 0 0 8 2 0 0 9 2 0 1 0 2 0 1 1 2 0 1 2 2 0 1 3 2 0 1 4 2 0 1 5 2 0 1 6 2 0 1 7 a) volume of commodity and non-commodity exports b) index of structural changes Figure 1. Ukraine export structural characteristics, 1998–2017 (source: developed by authors) Business, Management and Economics Engineering, 2021, 19(2): 244–271 251 considered a sign of an increase in the raw materials orientation of production and exports to Ukraine and an increased dependence on the situation in external raw materials markets, although some researchers believe that official statistics underestimate the volumes of non- resource (technological) exports. The index of structural changes (structural equilibrium index, structural index) is the ratio between non-primary and primary exports. Considering causality t tSTR Y⇒ there are grounds for such a system of two Equations (11), (12): 0 1 1 1 , n m t i t i i t j t t i j Y a Y b STR CRISIS− − = = = α + + + α + ε∑ ∑ ; (11) 0 1 1 1 1 , n m t i t i i t j t t t i j Y c Y d STR CRISIS− − − = = D = β + D + D +β + dε + ξ∑ ∑ (12) where Yt – GDP, STRt – index of structural changes, CRISISt – crisis-related dummy (1 for 2000Q1, 2004Q3:2004Q4, 2008Q3:2009Q4, 2013Q1:2015Q4, 0 – for the rest of the quarters). Thus, it is assumed that the situation at the beginning of 2000 had its own influence. It is as- sociated with the inertia of the deep currency crisis of 2008–2009. A short period of financial destabilisation at the end of 2004, caused by the Orange Revolution, the events of the global financial crisis in 2008–2009 and the most recent acute crisis in 2014–2015. It is assumed that the crisis phenomena appeared in early 2013 and ended by the end of 2015, although the restoration of the pre-crisis economic dynamics continues to this day. Since we are talking about Ukraine as a country with a raw material orientation of ex- ports, the sample of the years 2000–2010 and 2000–2018 was made considering the volatility of prices for raw materials (in the early 2000s – a sharp increase in prices for raw materials, 2009 – a slight decrease and in 2010 – prompt resumption of growth). By crises it is assumed that the situation at the beginning of 2000 had its own influence; a short period of financial instability at the end of 2004, caused by the Orange Revolution; events of the world financial crisis of 2008–2009, and the most recent acute crisis in 2014– 2015. (it is assumed that the crisis phenomena appeared at the beginning of 2013 and ended by the end of 2015, although the restoration of the pre-crisis economic dynamics continues to this day). The chosen division of the time sample is primarily due to considerations of checking the stability of the obtained estimates to a change in the time period. At the same time, the choice of a short sample of 2000–2010 provides for the inclusion of one of the major crisis periods (2008–2009), but in such a way that the so-called marginal effects do not occur, when the data of the last few years, estimates obtained (this explains the inclusion of 2010 data). The time sample of 2000–2013 does not differ much from the sample of 2000–2018, which does not allow us to check the stability of the estimates obtained. The choice of a dummy variable to take into account the possible impact of crisis phenomena or, more precisely, periods with a significant decrease in GDP below the equi- librium trend is a standard procedure and does not provide for an in-depth study of the reasons for such a decline (internal or external, monetary or non-monetary, assumed or unpredictable, etc.) 252 U. Nikonenko et al. Influence of internal and external factors on the structural changes of national... In our case, the inclusion of the CRISIS variable was intended to “cleanse” the impact of the STR variable on GDP from crisis phenomena, regardless of the main reasons (for ex- ample, the crisis events of the second half of 2004 were not as economic as political in origin) and could affect the long-term trajectory of GDP or short-term changes this indicator. Since the periodization of crisis phenomena or periods with a significant decline in production was made, it turned out to be an important factor in the long-term trajectory of income (in lev- els) - the corresponding coefficient is statistically significant at the level of 5%, which means that regardless of the nature, events in these periods had an intuitively expected negative impact on the trajectory domestic GDP. At the same time, no such influence was found for short-term dynamics; it is easier to explain by the effectiveness of mechanisms for correcting deviations from the long-term trend (coefficient d). The results obtained can be interpreted in such a way that, regardless of origin, any significant production downturns in Ukraine negatively affect the long-term growth trajectory. The mechanisms of such influence will be clarified by us in future studies. In particular, the prime candidates are investments, which recover very slowly after significant production downturns, whereas during unproblematic economic growth there is no proportional increase in investments that should compensate for the losses of the investment process during even short downward “episodes”. CRISIS is a dummy variable that takes into account only the exogenous impact of crisis phenomena. The basic statistical model assumes that structural shifts in favour of the non-resource sector depend on the terms of trade and economic policy instruments (Nikonenko, 2018): , , 0 1 1 2 1 2 1 3 4 5 ln ln 2 , n A B C t i t t t t t i t t t STR a STR b TOT b FDI c G c RER c M c DEBT c CRISIS − = = α + + + + + + + + + ε ∑ (13) where , ,A B CtTOT – calculated intersectoral terms of trade, FDIt – direct foreign investments (% GDP), RERt – real exchange rate (іndex, 2010 = 100), Gt – government spending (% GDP), M2t – monetary aggregate М2 (million UAH), DEBTt – external public debt (% GDP). Data on world prices for raw materials of foreign direct investment, RER and M2 money supply are obtained from the IMF database (International Monetary Fund, n.d.). Data on the volume of external public debt was obtained from the relevant statistics of the NBU (National Bank of Ukraine, 2021). Under the logic of the model (1)–(6), the intersectoral terms of trade are calculated as the ratio of prices for raw materials and non-primary exports. Three separate indexes are used (Nikonenko, 2018): / , A t t tTOT PRAW METAL= ; (14a) 1 2/( ), B t t t tTOT PRAW w METAL w PFOOD= + ; (14b) 1 2 3/( ), Ñ USPPI t t t t tTOT PRAW w METAL w PFOOD w P= + + (14c) where USPPItP – US Wholesale Price Index (index 2005 = 100), w1, w2, w3 – weighting factors. The first of the indices is determined by the ratio of world prices for agricultural raw ma- terials and metal products. In a simplified way, it is assumed that the price index for agricul- tural products characterises raw materials, and the metal price index characterises non-raw materials. The second of the indices considers the share of metal products and food products Business, Management and Economics Engineering, 2021, 19(2): 244–271 253 in export volumes. Finally, the third of the indices considers the inflation of wholesale prices in the United States – this indicator can be considered an approximate characteristic of other non-primary exports, except for metal products and food products. 4. Results and discussion 4.1. Using tests for stationarity and to identify the fact of cointegration to characterize endogenous variables To determine the characteristics of endogenous variables, the Augmented Dickey-Fuller test or the Phillips-Perron test are used, and the Johansen cointegration test is used to identify the fact of cointegration. Both Dickey-Fuller (ADF) and Phillips-Perron (PP) tests show the non-stationary of the Yt and STRt levels, while the first differences of both indicators are stationary (Table  1). This means that both indicators have a unit root I (1), and, the basis for studying their cointegration. Table 1. Stationarity tests for GDP and structural change index (source: own calculations based on data of the National Bank of Ukraine, 2021) Variable Sample ADF PP Levels The first differences Levels The first differences Yt 2000–2010 –1,64 (0,75) –4,31 (0.0***) 1,03 (0,92) –4,31 (0,0***) 2000–2018 –1,90 (0,64) –5,71 (0.0***) –1,61 (0,77) –5,69 (0,0***) STRt 2000–2010 –2,57 (0,29) –8,07 (0.0***) –2,68 (0,24) –8,09 (0,0***) 2000–2018 –3,09 (0,11) –4,08 (0.0***) –3,21 (0,08*) –10,55 (0,0***) Johansen’s test confirms the presence of one cointegration equation at a statistical signifi- cance level of at least 5% according to four out of five test assumptions (Table 2). An error-cor- rected model (Alogoskoufis & Smith, 1991) can apply to the GDP and structural change index. Table 2. Johansen test for cointegration of GDP and structural change index (source: own calculations) Model М1 М2 М3 М4 М5 Trend No No Linear Linear Quadratic Test Type Without a constant With constant With constant With constant With constant Without trend Without trend Without trend With trend With trend Trace r = 0 16.34** 27.16*** 28.15*** 32.18*** 29.41*** r = 1 0.05 4.94 4.43** 5.45 2.29 Max Eigen r = 0 16.28** 22.21*** 21.71*** 27.34*** 27.11*** r = 1 0.05 4.94 4.43** 5.45 3.34 Note: *** means rejection of the hypothesis of no causality at the 1% statistical significance level (** at the 5% level, * at the 10% level). 254 U. Nikonenko et al. Influence of internal and external factors on the structural changes of national... Visual analysis of these indices reveals the differences are relatively insignificant (Figure 2). 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 1 9 9 8 1 9 9 9 2 0 0 0 2 0 0 1 2 0 0 2 2 0 0 3 2 0 0 4 2 0 0 5 2 0 0 6 2 0 0 7 2 0 0 8 2 0 0 9 2 0 1 0 2 0 1 1 2 0 1 2 2 0 1 3 2 0 1 4 2 0 1 5 2 0 1 6 2 0 1 7 TOT-A TOT-B TOT-C Figure 2. Ukraine: sectoral terms of trade, 1998–2017 (calculated according to the State Statistics Service of Ukraine, n.d.) 4.3. Empirical estimates for long- and short-term coefficients of the influence of the index of structural changes on GDP The statistical model (11) assumes that GDP depends on the index of structural chang- es, which, for its part, reflects the ratio between the primary and non-primary sectors. If 1 0, m i j b = >∑ the economy is in line with the assumption of higher profitability in the non-com- modity sector QT; otherwise, the commodity sector has a higher return on investment QS. Empirical estimates for long- and short-term coefficients of the influence of the index of structural changes on GDP are given in Table 3. Quite predictably, the coefficient of determi- nation R2 is much higher for estimates of long-term coefficients, but its value for estimates of short-term coefficients is also quite high as for the first differences. For a brief sample of 2000–2010. The included variables explain 48% of changes in GDP dynamics, and for the 2000–2018 sample This figure drops to 41%. In all cases, the ADF test detects the stationarity of the residues and allows an adequate interpretation of the results obtained Long-term coefficients provide estimates for data in levels and concerning long-term dependencies, they turn out only over time, but short-term coefficients are estimated for data in the first differences, they are dynamic in nature and technically consider the effect of residuals for long-term equations (coefficient d), which allows us to establish the nature of the influence of long-term factors on short-term dependencies, as well as the rate of convergence to an equilibrium state. Estimates for long-term ratios show a direct favourable relationship between structural changes in favour of non-primary exports. The corresponding coefficient for STRt becomes smaller for the 2000–2018 samples, which may mean approaching a certain equilibrium value of QT/QS over the past few years. However, there is no reason to deny the assumption of the highest return on non-resource sector products. Business, Management and Economics Engineering, 2021, 19(2): 244–271 255 Ukrainian GDP exaggeratedly reacts to changes in the previous period, because the coef- ficients at Yt–1 exceed 1. The correction occurs with a lag of two quarters, despite that, based on the sum of two quarters, domestic GDP looks very inertial. As might have been expected, the crisis phenomena were reflected in a decrease in GDP. Estimates for short-term coefficients confirm the favourable nature of structural shifts in favour of non-primary goods (with a lag per quarter), and the corresponding coefficient at DSTRt–1 becomes larger for the 2000–2018 sample. The nature of the autoregressive depen- dence is also confirmed, when the increase in the dynamics of GDP growth with a lag of one quarter is further corrected with a lag of two quarters. Since no confirmation has been found for the destructive impact of crisis phenomena in the short term, this leads to the assumption of their long-term nature. Finally, the correction factor d exhibits a very prompt correction of long-term dependen- cies with some “overshoot”. This structural feature corresponds to a situation where higher profitability of activities in the commodity sector leads to the opposite reaction. The obtained functional dependencies can be considered quite stable, because the esti- mates of the regression coefficients for the periods 2000–2010 and 2000–2018 practically do not differ. 4.3. Estimates of the factors of structural changes in Ukrainian exports As provided by the theoretical model (1)–(6), an increase in profitability in the commod- ity sector should be expected from an improvement in the sectoral terms of trade, should reduce the index of structural changes, but at the same time the equilibrium value of QT/QS rises, which objectively strengthens long-term incentives for investment in non-commodity Table 3. Estimates of the dependence of GDP on structural changes in Ukrainian exports (source: own calculations) Independent variable Long-term coefficients Independent variable Short-term coefficients Dependent variable Yt Dependent variable DYt 2000–2010 2000–2018 2000–2010 2000–2018 Yt–1 1.203 (7.93***) 1.220 (10.37***) DYt–1 1.394 (5.16***) 1.311 (5.08***) Yt–2 –0.226 (–1.50) –0.230 (–1.95*) DYt–1 –0.487 (–2.86***) –0.359 (–2.49**) STRt 0.415 (2.26**) 0.263 (2.20**) DSTRt–1 1.112 (2.90***) 1.348 (3.74***) CRISISt –0.625 (–1.95**) –0.457 (–2.21**) – – – – – – d –1.110 (–3.64***) –1.045 (–3.72***) R2 0.97 0.97 R2 0.48 0.41 ADF –4.10*** –8.30*** ADF –6.34*** –8.42*** 256 U. Nikonenko et al. Influence of internal and external factors on the structural changes of national... sector. However, the weakness of this trend in the context of significant foreign investment, motivated by the logic of “pushing out” and targeted policy of government stimulation of the non-resource sector, gives reason to hope for a standard dependence, when the rise in prices for raw materials is accompanied by a deterioration in the QT/QS ( 1( 0)b < . Since in Ukraine foreign investors do not have wide access to the raw material sector, in- cluding agriculture, and assembly plants and the service sector have received increased atten- tion, it can be expected that the structural proportions in the economy will improve 2( 0)b > . If government spending is concentrated primarily in the primary sector which can be explained by both profitability considerations and lobbying activities, this will lead to a de- terioration in structural ratios, but it is possible that targeted support for the non-primary sector will have the exact opposite effect 1( 0)c <> . At first glance, the impact of RER does not differ from the effects of changing trading conditions, but at least three features need to be considered. First, the RER considers changes in domestic prices and the exchange rate, which do not always correlate with changes in world market prices. Secondly, it should be borne in mind that the price level P for non- commodities is only conditionally correlated with the level of domestic prices, because non- commodities can also be exported or serve as substitutes for imports. Perhaps EP * commod- ity prices correlate much more closely with world market prices than non-commodity prices. Third, the exchange rate policy creates its own influence, which may be aimed at inflation targeting or the exchange rate itself. Combined with the above arguments for the terms of trade, this significantly weakens the intuitive argument that lowering the RER should stimu- late the expansion of the commodities sector. In general, the impact of RER on the structural proportions between the raw and non-raw sectors is not unambiguous 2( 0)c <> . In conditions of a fixed exchange rate, an increase in the money supply should be ac- companied by an increase in the price level P, which should contribute to the expansion of the non-resource sector, but in an economy with strong devaluation expectations, it is more realistic to hope for an imminent devaluation of the monetary unit. There are incentives to expand the commodity sector. For a floating exchange rate, the consequences of an increase in the price level P are potentially offset by the devaluation of the monetary unit, so one can hope for the neutrality of the money supply regarding the price ratios between the commod- ity and non-commodity sectors. More precisely, in price inertia in the non-resource sector, a short-term “flight” of the exchange rate downward should be accompanied by a temporary decrease in RER, which is likely to contribute to an increase in the share of the commod- ity sector. Arguments for worsening structural relationships look more convincing (c3 < 0). The accumulation of public external debt is likely to contributing to the raw material specialisation of the economy, as obtained in many studies, but this possibility is not uncon- tested. If the accumulation of public debt creates a “gap” between domestic consumption i production (Agénor, 2016) or reflects overly optimistic expectations about the terms of trade (Senhadji, 1997), it is more likely to hope for increased demand for non-primary goods more complementary to domestic demand. However, this does not apply to agricultural products, it is predominantly of a raw material nature and can not only be exported but also consumed in the domestic market. In this case, it is rather difficult to determine the direction of the resulting structural changes. The situation becomes more transparent if external borrowing Business, Management and Economics Engineering, 2021, 19(2): 244–271 257 of the public sector is carried out for reasons of reducing the cost of excessive public debt and/or insufficient domestic savings. The devaluation of the monetary unit usually creates a negative balance effect, and this requires a prompt restoration of the balance of payments equilibrium, it is easier to implement by increasing the volume of exports of raw materials. According to the accumulation of external public debt, it becomes a factor of structural changes in favour of the raw materials sector (c4 < 0). Similarly, crisis phenomena require an immediate improvement in the balance of export-import of goods and services, objectively strengthens the position of the raw materials sector (c5 < 0). Since there is one cointegration equation between the studied indicators, the estimates of the 2SLS statistical model with error correction were used. The use of three indices of sectoral terms of trade yielded similar results, primarily for assessing long-term coefficients, but from the point of view of the statistical significance of the obtained short-term coefficients, the specification with the index BtTOT (Table 4). Table  4. Estimates of factors of structural changes in Ukrainian exports, taking into account govern- ment spending Independent variable Long-term coefficients Independent variable Short-term coefficients Dependent variable STRt Dependent variable DSTRt 2000–2010 2000–2018 2000–2010 2000–2018 STRt–1 0.433 (3.08***) 0.502 (4.62***) DSTRt–1 0.380 (2.26**) 0.408 (2.61***) STRt–2 0.216 (1.57) 0.206 (2.02**) – – – 1 B tTOT − –0.505 (–2.22**) –0.360 (–2.33**) 1 B tTOT −D –0.318 (–1.12) –0.258 (–1.11) FDIt–1 0.033 (1.88*) 0.019 (1.95*) DFDIt–1 0.025 (2.01**) 0.014 (1.88*) Gt 0.008 (0.43) 0.020 (2.32**) DGt 0.014 (0.92) 0.014 (1.64*) RERt 1.234 (4.13***) 0.936 (4.77***) DRERt 0.080 (0.33) 0.724 (1.82*) M2t –0.373 (–3.48***) –0.314 (–4.93***) – – – DEBTt –0.012 (–1.56) –0.011 (–3.13***) – – – CRISISt –0.211 (–2.94***) –0.160 (–3.55***) – –0.081 (–1.45) –0.158 (–1.78*) – – – d –1.149(–4.61***) –1.017 (–4.88***) R2 0.74 0.92 R2 0.43 0.34 ADF –7.37*** –8.41*** ADF –6.34*** –7.11*** Note: ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. Calculated by the authors. 258 U. Nikonenko et al. Influence of internal and external factors on the structural changes of national... The results obtained show the inertial nature of the calculated index of structural changes, which has increased somewhat over the past few years. Besides recognising the quite natural inertia of processes in the real sector, this may mean significant institutional factors that are not considered by the specification of the assessed statistical model. According to the results of two quarters, over 2/3 of long-term structural changes are determined by their own dy- namics. For short-term dynamics, the inertia remains at a sufficiently high level. It is quite predictable that an improvement in the terms of trade in favour of the com- modity sector worsens the structural proportions of QT/QS in Ukrainian exports, although the corresponding influence has been weakening over the past few years, as provided by the comparison of long-term coefficients 1 B tTOT − for the 2000–2010 and 2000–2018 sample. (Both ratios are statistically significant at the 5% level.) No short-term impact of cross-sec- toral terms of trade on structural change has been identified (the corresponding coefficient at 1 B tTOT −D is negative, but lacks statistical significance). Foreign-invested enterprises are stimulating action on both dimensions: long- and short- term. This means that the attraction of foreign capital takes place mainly in the non-resource sector. A certain discomfort is created because the coefficients for FDIt–1 і DFDIt–1 become smaller for the 2000–2018 sample, because this implies a weakening of the favourable func- tional dependence in recent years. The decline in RER is accompanied by an increase in the share of non-primary exports, which is mainly of a long-term nature. In the short term, the decrease in RER affects the structural proportions much weaker, and this effect is of relatively recent origin. The benefi- cial effect of a decrease in RER can be explained by the insignificant dependence of produc- tion in the non-primary sector on imported components, but this may be a sign of its low innovativeness. Corrective factor d shows a prompt correction of long-term dependencies. This means that structural changes in favour of non-resource exports, which are driven by long-term dependencies, take little time to translate into practice. Thus, in order to improve the structural proportions in the Ukrainian economy (for example, the export sector), it is necessary to more actively attract FDI, maintain a decrease in RER, prevent an excessive increase in the money supply, refrain from increasing public external debt (the relationship with domestic public debt has not been studied) and crisis phenomena. The resulting relationship suggests that government spending stimulates an improvement in the QT/QS ratio in Ukrainian exports, but this should occur without increasing external public debt. Government spending should be funded from tax and other budget revenues. The direct relationship between budget revenues and structural shifts in favour of the non- resource sector has empirical confirmation (Table 5). Estimates of the statistical model (13) with the variable of budget revenues Tt (% of GDP) instead of government expenditures show that an increase in budget revenues im- proves structural relationships in favour of the non-resource sector in the long run, without having an adverse short-term impact. This result can be explained by the observance of the intertemporal budgetary constraint, as provided by Equation (5), but other causal mecha- nisms are sufficient. Business, Management and Economics Engineering, 2021, 19(2): 244–271 259 Changes to the specification of the regression model did not affect changes in other functional dependencies. Almost the only difference concerns the appearance of the influ- ence of the current account balance CAt (% of GDP) on the short-term dynamics of struc- tural changes (with a lag of two quarters). The corresponding positive coefficient at DCAt–2 provides for an improvement in structural proportions because of an improvement in the current account balance. The effect of the current account balance is not seen for long-term ratios. Similarly, including this variable has no statistically significant effect in the previous specification with government spending. This feature can be explained because budget rev- enues largely depend on customs payments. Since changes in the structure of production (exports) can be endogenous, not only depend on internal and external factors but also influence them, functional dependencies were studied using two VAR models, considering the influence of: price ratios between non-commodity Table 5. Estimates of the factors of structural changes in Ukrainian exports, taking into account budget revenues (source: calculated by authors) Independent variable Long-term coefficients Independent variable Short-term coefficients Dependent variable STRt Dependent variable DSTRt 2000–2010 2000–2018 2000–2010 2000–2018 STRt–1 0.418 (3.44***) 0.462 (4.48***) DSTRt–1 0.342 (2.30**) 0.401 (2.85***) STRt–2 0.203 (1.74*) 0.204 (2.12**) – – – 1 B tTOT − –0.521 (–2.61**) –0.382 (–2.18**) 1 B tTOT −D –0.297 (–1.17) –0.248 (–1.18) FDIt–1 0.033 (2.14**) 0.016 (1.67*) DFDIt–1 0.026 (2.30**) 0.012 (1.71*) Tt–1 0.005 (0.34) 0.017 (2.11**) DTt–1 0.004 (0.18) 0.010 (1.10) RERt 1.218 (4.51***) 0.929 (5.04***) DRERt –0.145 (–0.19) 0.553 (1.43) M2t –0.356 (–4.21***) –0.282 (–5.07***) – – – DEBTt –0.011 (–1.53) –0.011 (–3.41***) – – – CRISISt –0.206 (–3.10***) –0.149 (–3.56***) – –0.080 (–1.63) –0.061 (–2.05**) – – – DCAt-2 0.015 (1.87*) 0.010 (1.76*) – – – d –1.113(–5.01***) –1.038 (–5.50***) R2 0.73 0.92 R2 0.44 0.37 ADF –7.24*** –8.48*** ADF –6.36*** –7.32*** Note: ***, ** and * denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels, respectively. 260 U. Nikonenko et al. Influence of internal and external factors on the structural changes of national... and commodity exports, FDI, RER, money supply (monetary aggregate M2), income (GDP), and one of the fiscal variables – government spending or budget revenues. Assuming the presence of cointegration between dependent (endogenous) variables, the following causality is used: “TOT ⇒ FDI ⇒ G (T) ⇒ M2 ⇒ RER ⇒ STR ⇒ Y”. The price ratios between commodity and non-commodity exports are considered to be an independent (exogenous) variable in the current period that determines the volume of FDI. In the future, this affects the level of government spending or budget revenues. Fiscal indicators determine the supply of money supply, which should affect the RER. In the cur- rent period, the structural proportions in exports and GDP are considered because of the remaining endogenous variables. 4.4. Graphic visualization of the factors of influence of individual endogenous variables on the structure of domestic exports The results obtained confirm the powerful influence of structural changes in favour of non- resource exports as a factor in increasing GDP (Figure 3). –0.5 –0.3 –0.1 0.1 0.3 0.5 0.7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 TOT G M2 RER STR Y –1.5 –1 –0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 TOT FDI M2 RER STR Y –0.04 –0.03 –0.02 –0.01 0 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 –0.03 –0.02 –0.01 0 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 а) foreign direct investment b) government spending c) money supply d) RER Figure 3. To be continue Business, Management and Economics Engineering, 2021, 19(2): 244–271 261 Decomposition of the residuals shows that changes in TOT determine up to 13% of changes in GDP, while changes in FDI account for up to 10%, and structural changes deter- mine from 21 to 17% of changes in GDP, and the significance of this factor comes with time. Considering the structural and investment factors, the dependence of GDP on the instru- ments of economic policy becomes marginal (Figure 4, Table 6). –0.08 –0.06 –0.04 –0.02 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 0.12 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 TOT FDI G M2 RER Y –0.5 –0.3 –0.1 0.1 0.3 0.5 0.7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 e) STR f ) GDP Note: The effects of shocks on the endogenous variable are shown with a confidence level of ±2 standard deviations. Figure 3. Graphic visualisation of the factors of influence of individual endogenous variables on the structure of domestic exports (built by the authors) –0.04 –0.02 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 TOT FDI G M2 RER STR Y –0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 TOT FDI G M2 RER STR Y а) intersectoral b) foreign direct investment Figure 4. To be continue 262 U. Nikonenko et al. Influence of internal and external factors on the structural changes of national... –1.5 –1 –0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 TOT FDI G M2 RER STR Y –0.04 –0.03 –0.02 –0.01 0 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 –0.04 –0.03 –0.02 –0.01 0 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 TOT FDI G M2 RER STR Y –0.1 –0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 TOT FDI G M2 RER STR Y –0.5 –0.3 –0.1 0.1 0.3 0.5 0.7 0.9 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 c) government spending terms of trade (TOTCOM2) d) money supply e) RER f ) STR g) GDP Note: Consequences of shocks on the endogenous variable shown in confidence ± 2 standard deviations. Figure 4. Graphic visualisation of the factors of influence of individual endogenous variables on the structure of domestic exports (VECM-1) Business, Management and Economics Engineering, 2021, 19(2): 244–271 263 Table 6. Decomposition of VECM residuals of mutual influence of export structure and terms of trade, foreign direct investments, government spending, money supply, RER and GDP, 2000–2019 (source: calculated by the authors) Impulse Response to changes Forecast horizon (quarters) Impulse Response to changes Forecast horizon (quarters) 4 8 12 16 4 8 12 16 Sectoral terms of trade (TOT) TOT 83 81 79 78 Real exchange rate (RER) TOT 3 15 23 27 FDI 2 3 4 4 FDI 12 20 24 26 G 4 3 3 3 G 0 0 0 0 M2 2 1 1 1 M2 1 1 1 1 RER 7 8 9 10 RER 75 51 37 25 STR 0 0 0 0 STR 2 2 2 2 Y 1 2 3 3 Y 8 11 13 14 foreign direct investment (FDI) TOT 4 4 3 3 Structural Change Index (STR) TOT 12 18 18 18 FDI 80 72 69 66 FDI 4 6 6 6 G 1 3 4 5 G 0 0 0 0 M2 5 4 3 3 M2 2 3 4 5 RER 6 14 17 19 RER 42 48 50 51 STR 2 2 3 3 STR 37 24 20 18 Y 1 1 1 1 Y 2 2 1 1 Budget receipts (T) TOT 8 10 10 10 GDP (Y) TOT 7 11 12 13 FDI 18 23 24 25 FDI 7 9 10 10 G 44 30 26 23 G 0 1 1 1 M2 5 3 2 1 M2 3 2 1 1 RER 6 8 8 8 RER 1 1 2 2 STR 15 21 24 25 STR 21 18 18 17 Y 4 5 6 7 Y 61 57 56 55 Monetary aggregate М2 (М2) TOT 0 2 4 5 FDI 1 2 3 3 G 15 15 14 14 M2 61 49 42 39 RER 2 5 7 8 STR 8 9 9 9 Y 12 18 20 21 Similar to the 2SLS estimates, there is no objection to improved structural proportions resulting from FDI inflows and lower RERs. Similarly, the 2SLS and VAR / VEC estimates agree that the deterioration in STR is because of the improved terms of trade in favour of commodity exports and an increase in money supply. The RER factor determines about half of the STR changes, while the share of TOT gradually grows from 12 to 18%. The weight of FDI and money supply is relatively insignificant – only 6%. 264 U. Nikonenko et al. Influence of internal and external factors on the structural changes of national... The growth in the share of non-commodity exports helps to attract foreign direct invest- ment (however, the weight of STRt in the decomposition of FDIt balances is not high), a decrease in government spending (the weight in the decomposition of Gt balances gradually increases to 25%), and an increase in the money supply (the weight in the decomposition of М2t balances is 8–9%). This functional influence only strengthens the argument in favour of improving the quality structure of domestic exports. Among other functional dependencies, a decrease in RER is a significant factor in en- couraging FDI (the weight in the FDI decomposition gradually increases from 6 to 19%), does not contradict the logic of attracting foreign investment to improve the structure of domestic exports. The rest of the factors are less important (the weight of each of them does not exceed 5%), although based on the analysis of the impulse function, one can expect an increase in FDI in the event of a restriction in the supply of money supply, an increase in government spending and a deterioration in TOT. There are signs of direct dependence of FDI on economic growth and do not create grounds for assumptions about the “attraction” of foreign investment by economic dynamics within Ukraine. It is noted that FDI inflows are accompanied by an increase in government spending (the weight of the factor in the Gt decomposition reaches 25%). This may mean that FDI inflows are accompanied by an increase in government spending on projects of oligarchic structures that have a significant influence on political decision-making. In this case, there is a mutual reinforcement between FDI and government spending, but note that the decomposition of the residuals reveals the primacy of the inflow of foreign investment. It is logical to assume that FDI comes in first, and only then government spending grows. Another, more optimis- tic scenario assumes that FDI inflows (not related to the activities of oligarchic structures) are accompanied by an increase in government spending on infrastructure development or excessive optimism, which inclines to an increase in consumer spending. Government spending increases with an increase in the money supply, but the influence of this factor in the decomposition of Gt balances is insignificant (only 5%). Besides struc- tural shifts in favour of non-resource exports, lower government spending is also supported by improved TOT, lower RERs and higher income. Although the weight of each of these factors in the decomposition of the residual Gt is relatively low, in total they account for 56 to 77% of changes in government spending. In contrast to the standard “textbook” designs, government spending is quite endogenous in the system of major macroeconomic indicators. The improvement in price ratios in favour of raw material exports is reflected in the sup- ply’s restriction of money supply. However, the weight of TOT in changes in the monetary aggregate M2 is insignificant, which does not allow overestimating the importance of the causality of “ТОТ⇒М2”. All other endogenous factors result in an increase in the supply of money supply. If an increase in the money supply in response to an increase in income is quite natural from the point of view of meeting the higher demand for money, then such de- pendence on government spending means supporting fiscal policy through monetary policy. There was no reaction to the decrease in RER during the first two quarters, but in the future, an increase in the supply of money supply is observed. True, the RER weight in the decom- position of M2 residues is 8%. An improvement in price ratios in favour of non-commodity exports leads to a signifi- cant decrease in RER, and the weight of TOT in the decomposition of the residuals of this Business, Management and Economics Engineering, 2021, 19(2): 244–271 265 indicator gradually increases to 27%. Equally important is the dependence on FDI inflows, which increases the RER (the weight of FDI in the decomposition of residuals gradually increases from 12 to 26%). It is most likely that the growing demand for money becomes a factor in the increase in RER, because the consequences of an increase in GDP are similar (the weight of the factor in the decomposition of residuals is 14%). At the same time, RER does not depend on government spending and money supply. If instead of indicator government spending we use the indicator of budget revenues, the important result practically does not change, an increase in the share of non-primary exports is reflected in GDP growth, and the main drivers of favourable structural changes are the rise in prices for non-primary exports and a decrease in RER. The optimising effect of FDI on STR and income remains, but the weight of this factor in the decomposition of the residu- als of both variables remains low. With the change in the VECM specification, the negative impact of the money supply on STR is weakening. The increase in budget revenues reduces the share of non-primary goods in total exports (Figure 5, Table 7). –0.04 –0.02 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 0.1 0.12 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 TOT FDI T M2 RER STR Y –1 –0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 TOT FDI T M2 RER STR Y –1 –0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 TOT FDI T M2 RER STR Y –0.04 –0.02 0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 а) intersectoral b) foreign direct investment c) government spending terms of trade (TOT- COM2) d) money supply Figure 5. To be continue 266 U. Nikonenko et al. Influence of internal and external factors on the structural changes of national... –0.04 –0.03 –0.02 –0.01 0 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 TOT FDI T M2 RER STR Y –0.1 –0.05 0 0.05 0.1 0.15 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 TOT FDI T M2 RER STR Y –0.5 –0.3 –0.1 0.1 0.3 0.5 0.7 0.9 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 e) RER f ) STR g) GDP Note: The effects of shocks on the endogenous variable are shown with a confidence level of ±2 standard deviations. Figure 5. Graphic visualization of the factors of influence of individual endogenous variables on the structure of domestic exports (VECM-2) Table 7. Decomposition of VECM balances of the interaction of the structure of exports and trade condi- tions, FDI, budget revenues, money supply, RER and GDP, 2000–2019 (source: calculated by the authors) Impulse Response to changes Forecast horizon (quarters) Impulse Response to changes Forecast horizon (quarters) 4 8 12 16 4 8 12 16 Sectoral terms of trade (TOT) TOT 84 79 77 75 Real exchange rate (RER) TOT 1 11 17 20 FDI 1 2 2 2 FDI 10 18 22 24 T 2 3 3 3 T 20 15 12 11 M2 4 8 5 5 M2 1 1 1 1 RER 8 10 11 12 RER 63 46 37 31 STR 0 1 1 1 STR 1 2 4 5 Y 1 1 2 2 Y 5 7 8 8 Business, Management and Economics Engineering, 2021, 19(2): 244–271 267 The revision of the VECM specification does not change the conclusion on the increase in RER from FDI inflows and the increase in income. Similarly, the money supply decreases after commodity prices rise, while the opposite occurs with higher incomes, lower RERs, and improved export patterns. Certain differences lie because FDI does not respond to RER, and the negative feedback of M2 on the increase in FDI also disappears. The inflow of FDI increases budget revenues, does not differ from the nature of the im- pact on government spending, but the weight of FDI in the decomposition of T balances is three times lower – 4–8%. A similar symmetry is characteristic of the dependence of govern- ment spending and budget revenues on STR, but in the second case, the weight in the de- composition of residuals T is also approximately half as much – 10–13%. Growing revenues to the budget are reflected in an increase in RER (the weight of T in the decomposition of residuals is initially 20% and eventually decreases to 11%), which differs from the neutrality of government spending on RER. Also, with an increase in budget revenues, the resulting decrease in STR becomes more expressive. Impulse Response to changes Forecast horizon (quarters) Impulse Response to changes Forecast horizon (quarters) 4 8 12 16 4 8 12 16 Direct foreign investments (FDI) TOT 0 1 1 1 Structural Change Index (STR) TOT 11 20 23 24 FDI 82 78 77 77 FDI 2 4 4 5 T 13 16 17 17 T 4 5 6 6 M2 0 0 0 0 M2 1 1 1 1 RER 1 2 2 2 RER 41 50 53 54 STR 3 2 2 2 STR 36 17 11 8 Y 1 1 1 2 Y 4 3 2 2 Budget receipts (T) TOT 1 2 4 4 GDP (Y) TOT 4 9 12 14 FDI 4 6 7 8 FDI 4 7 9 9 T 78 74 72 70 T 4 3 2 2 M2 0 0 0 0 M2 1 1 1 1 RER 4 4 3 3 RER 1 2 3 4 STR 10 11 12 13 STR 23 17 14 12 Y 4 3 3 2 Y 63 61 59 58 Monetary aggregate М2 (М2) TOT 1 3 5 6 FDI 4 5 6 7 T 0 0 0 0 M2 82 75 71 69 RER 0 2 3 3 STR 4 4 3 3 Y 8 11 11 12 End of Table 7 268 U. Nikonenko et al. Influence of internal and external factors on the structural changes of national... Structural changes (in favour of the non-resource export sector of the domestic economy) will give us the opportunity to attract foreign investment, preferably the capital of the largest industrial companies with a worldwide reputation (in Ukraine, foreign investors do not have wide access to the raw materials sector, including agriculture, and assembly plants received increased attention and service industry). To improve the structural proportions in the Ukrainian economy, it is worth: maintaining a depreciation of the exchange rate, but this does not mean the devaluation of the monetary unit is advisable, but rather the need to maintain low inflation (the beneficial effect of the depreciation of the exchange rate can be explained by the insignificant dependence of production in the non-resource sector on imported components) to limit the supply of monetary mass and accumulation of external public debt and avoid crises. Government spending should occur without increasing the external public debt, that is, they should be financed from tax and other budget revenues. Budget revenues, which largely depend on customs duties, improve the structural balance in favour of the non-resource sector in the long run, without having an adverse short-term impact. This result can be explained by the observance of the intertemporal budgetary constraint, but other causal mechanisms are sufficient. Thus, we have empirically proved that an increase in the share of non-primary exports is reflected in GDP growth, and the main drivers of favourable structural changes are the rise in prices for non-primary exports and a depreciation of the exchange rate. Summing up, we find that for structural changes in favour of more technological (non- resource) exports, it is necessary to attract more FDI, preferably the capital of the largest industrial companies with a worldwide reputation, to limit the supply of money supply and the accumulation of external public debt, and also to avoid crisis phenomena. A decrease in RER is desirable, but this does not mean the advisability of devaluing the currency, but the need to maintain low inflation. Conclusions The novelty of the study lies in the development of a methodology of identifying the cur- rent state and instrumental factors of economic policy that can speed up economic growth based on favorable structural shifts (in favor of the non-resource export sector). It has been empirically proven that the structural proportions in favor of non-resource (technological) exports are improving due to: a) the rise in prices for metal products and food products compared to agricultural products, b) foreign direct investment receipts, c) a decrease in the exchange rate, d) an increase in the share of government spending in GDP, e) reduction of external public debt, f ) reduction of excess money supply During crises, structural propor- tions deteriorate. The increase in government spending stimulates non-resource exports, but should occur without accumulating external public debt. An increase in tax and other budget revenues also improves the structural ratios in favour of the non-resource sector in the long run, without having an adverse short-term impact. Additional verification of the obtained results for sustainability using the alternative VAR/ VEC methoddoes not refute: an improvement in structural proportions because of inflows of foreign direct investment, deterioration of the terms of trade in favour of commodity exports Business, Management and Economics Engineering, 2021, 19(2): 244–271 269 and a decrease in the money supply. A depreciation of the exchange rate is desirable, but this does not mean the devaluation of the monetary unit is advisable, but rather shows the need to maintain low inflation. An increase in income (GDP) does not provide an evolutionary improvement in the structure of exports. VAR/VEC estimates confirm the powerful impact of structural changes in favour of non- resource exports as a factor in increasing GDP. Foreign direct investment has a similar ben- eficial effect. An increase in the money supply has a short-term positive impact, such as a monetary “surprise” that gradually diminishes. A depreciation of the exchange rate initially leads to a decrease in income, but later it becomes expansionary. Government spending and an increase in budget revenues have some adverse effects, but the most negative factor is the improvement in the terms of trade in favor of agricultural raw materials. The growth in the share of non-resource exports helps to attract foreign direct investment, reduce government spending and increase the money supply. This functional influence only strengthens the arguments in favor of improving the quality structure of domestic exports. Based on the analysis of the decomposition of VECM balances, it was found that: a) at- tracting foreign direct investment contributes to a decrease in the exchange rate, b) inflows of foreign direct investment are accompanied by an increase in government spending, c) a decrease in government spending contributes to an improvement in the terms of trade, a depreciation of the exchange rate and an increase in income (although the weight of each of these factors in the decomposition of the residuals Gt is relatively low, but in total they account for 56 to 77% of changes in government spending), d) an increase in government spending leads to an increase in the of money supply, e) the dynamics of the exchange rate depends significantly on world prices for raw materials and foreign direct investment. At the time of this writing, the authors did not have official statistics for the end of 2019 and 2020. For this, the authors plan to receive data for the above periods from state institu- tions of Ukraine in the future and conduct a similar study. Also, in the future, it is planned to conduct a similar study in countries with a analogous economic situation as in Ukraine, such as Poland or Hungary. References Agénor, P.-R. (2016). Optimal fiscal management of commodity price shocks. Journal of Development Economics, 122, 183–196. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2016.05.005 Alogoskoufis, G., & Smith, R. (1991). On error correction models: Specification, interpretation, estimation. Journal of Economic Surveys, 1(5), 97–128. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6419.1991.tb00128.x Antoniuk, V. (2017). Structural shifts in the national economy as a threat to Ukraine’s sustainable de- velopment. Visnyk ekonomichnoi nauky Ukrainy, 2(33), 7–12. Bitsyura, Y. (2016). Structural shifts in the economy of European countries. Foreign trade: Economics, Finance, Law, (3), 59–72. Braun, A., & Toth, R. (2020). Circular economy: national and global policy – overview. Clean Technolo- gies and Environmental Policy, 23, 301–304. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10098-020-01988-8 Cornwell, J. (1977). Explanations: Styles of explanation in science. Oxford University Press. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2016.05.005 https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6419.1991.tb00128.x https://doi.org/10.1007/s10098-020-01988-8 270 U. Nikonenko et al. Influence of internal and external factors on the structural changes of national... Cui, L., Hou, Y., Gao, M., & Yang, Y. (2019). Exploring the influencing factors of sharing economy sustainability based on a two-mode social network analysis. In 2019 16th International Conference on Service Systems and Service Management (ICSSSM) (pp. 1–5). IEEE. https://doi.org/10.1109/ICSSSM.2019.8887647 Danylchuk, H., Kovtun, O., & Opalenko, A. (2019). Assessment of the structural changes under transi- tion of Ukraine towards postindustrial economy. Cherkasy University Bulletin: Economic Sciences, (4), 101–112. https://doi.org/10.31651/2076-5843-2019-4-101-112 Engle, R., & Granger, C. (1991). Long-run economic relationships: Readings in cointegration. Advanced Texts in Econometrics. Oxford University Press. Ertz, M., & Leblanc-Proulx, S. (2018). Sustainability in the collaborative economy: A bibliometric analy- sis reveals emerging interest. Journal of Cleaner Production, 196, 1073–1085. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.06.095 Ginevicius, R., Kliestik, T., Stasiukynas, A., & Suhajda, K. (2020). The impact of national economic development on the shadow economy. Journal of Competitiveness, 12, 39–55. https://doi.org/10.7441/joc.2020.04.03 Holian,  V.  A. (2016). Socio-economic determinants of nature management: amber fever syndrome. Economika ta derzhava, 6, 5–15. International Monetary Fund. (n.d.). IMF International Financial Statistics. https://data.imf.org Kazunobu, M. (2017). Structural change and a constant growth path in a three-sector growth model with three factors. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 21(2), 406–438. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1365100515000565 Kiselakova, D., Sofrankova B., Cabinova V., & Onuferova, E. (2018). Competitiveness and sustainable growth analysis of the EU countries with the use of global indexes’ methodology. Entrepreneurship and Sustainability Issues, 5(3), 581–599. https://doi.org/10.9770/jesi.2018.5.3(13) Korablin, S. (2017). Macroeconomic dynamics of Ukraine: the trap of commodity markets. Instytut eko- nomiky i prohnozuvannia NAN Ukrainy. Koziuk, V. (2018a, August 16). The oligarchic hydra of foreign direct investment. Dzerkalo tyzhnia. https://dt.ua/finances/oligarhichna-gidra-pryamih-inozemnih-investiciy-vid-makrofinansovoyi- nestabilnosti-do-tehnologichnogo-vidstavannya-285294_.html Koziuk, V. (2018b, September 10). The hologram of expectations, or zombie ghost figures 40. Dzerkalo tyzhnia. https://dt.ua/finances/golograma-ochikuvan-abo-zombi-privid-cifri-40-287790_.html National Bank of Ukraine. (2021). NBU Data. https://bank.gov.ua/ Nikonenko, U. М. (2018). Structural processes of the economy of Ukraine as an exporter of raw mate- rial resources. Naukovyi Visnyk Uzhhorodskoho Universytetu. Seriia “Ekonomika”, 2(52), 75–83. https://doi.org/10.24144/2409-6857.2018.2(52).75-83 Senhadji, A. (1997). Sources of debt accumulation in a small open economy (IMF Working Paper 97/146). https://doi.org/10.5089/9781451856606.001 Sijabat, R. (2019). Sharing economy: A study on the factors influencing users’ motivation to use ride sharing platforms. DeReMa Jurnal Manajemen, 14(1), 65–87. https://doi.org/10.19166/derema.v14i1.1367 Shynkaruk, L., Bevz, I., Baranovska, I., Vdovichen, A. A., & Herasimova, O. A. (2015). Structural trans- formations in the Ukrainian economy: Dynamics, contradictions and impact on economic develop- ment. Instytut ekonomiky i prohnozuvannia NAN Ukrainy. State Statistics Service of Ukraine. (n.d.). http://www.ukrstat.gov.ua Tang, C. F., Lai, Y. W., & Ozturk, I. (2015). How stable is the export-led growth hypothesis? Evidence from Asia’s Four Little Dragons. Economic Modelling, 44, 229–235. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2014.09.022 https://doi.org/10.1109/ICSSSM.2019.8887647 https://doi.org/10.31651/2076-5843-2019-4-101-112 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2018.06.095 https://doi.org/10.7441/joc.2020.04.03 https://data.imf.org https://doi.org/10.1017/S1365100515000565 https://doi.org/10.9770/jesi.2018.5.3(13) https://dt.ua/finances/oligarhichna-gidra-pryamih-inozemnih-investiciy-vid-makrofinansovoyi-nestabilnosti-do-tehnologichnogo-vidstavannya-285294_.html https://dt.ua/finances/oligarhichna-gidra-pryamih-inozemnih-investiciy-vid-makrofinansovoyi-nestabilnosti-do-tehnologichnogo-vidstavannya-285294_.html https://dt.ua/finances/golograma-ochikuvan-abo-zombi-privid-cifri-40-287790_.html https://bank.gov.ua/ https://doi.org/10.24144/2409-6857.2018.2(52).75-83 https://doi.org/10.5089/9781451856606.001 https://doi.org/10.19166/derema.v14i1.1367 http://www.ukrstat.gov.ua https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0264999314003927#! https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2014.09.022 Business, Management and Economics Engineering, 2021, 19(2): 244–271 271 Vashkiv, O. (2017). Sectoral structural transformations in Ukraine in the context of post-industrial economic development. Globalni ta Natsionalni Problemu Economiky, 16, 127–132. http://global-national.in.ua/archive/16-2017/27.pdf Wei, C.-L., Chang, Y.-C., Wang, W.-X., Chou, H.-M., & Chen, K.-J. (2019). Factors that influence shar- ing behaviors in sharing economy based on the theory of social capital and social exchange: Ex- ample of Taiwan-Based USPACE. In 2019 IEEE International Conference on Industrial Engineering and Engineering Management (IEEM) (pp. 659–663). IEEE. https://doi.org/10.1109/IEEM44572.2019.8978908 http://global-national.in.ua/archive/16-2017/27.pdf https://doi.org/10.1109/IEEM44572.2019.8978908