ZHANG ARTICOLO FORMATTED 2


3 

 

 
DYNAMIC INTERACTIONS AMONG 

GROWTH, ENVIRONMENTAL CHANGE, 
HABIT FORMATION, AND PREFERENCE 

CHANGE 
 

WEI-BIN ZHANG 
Ritsumeikan Asia Pacific University, Japan 

 
 
Received: March 27, 2013 Accepted: July 30, 2013      Online Published: October 10, 2013 
 
 

Abstract 
 

The purpose of this study is to construct an economic growth model with environmental 
change and preference formation. The paper is focused on dynamic interactions among 
capital accumulation, environmental change, habit formation, preference change, and 
division of labor in perfectly competitive markets with environmental taxes on production, 
wealth income, wage income and consumption. The model integrated the dynamic economic 
mechanisms in the neoclassical growth theory, the environmental dynamics in traditional 
models of environmental economics, and the literature of economic growth with habit 
formation and within a comprehensive framework. It is showed that the motion of the 
economic system is given by three nonlinear autonomous differential equations. We simulate 
the time-invariant system. The simulation demonstrates some dynamic interactions among the 
economic variables which can be predicted neither by the neoclassical growth theory nor by 
the traditional economic models of environmental change. For instance, if the past 
consumption has weaker impact on the current consumption, although the long-term 
equilibrium of the dynamic system will not be affected, the transitional paths are shifted as 
follows: initially the transitional path of the stock habit becomes lower than its original path; 
the consumption level falls initially in association with falling in the propensity to consume; 
the exogenous disturbance causes the propensity to consume to fall and the propensity to save 
to rise; the national wealth and capital inputs of the two sectors are augmented; the labor 
force is shifted initially from the industrial sector to the environmental sector, but 
subsequently the direction is opposite before the labor distribution comes to its original 
equilibrium point; the wage rate is enhanced in association with falling in the rate of interest; 
the level of pollution falls initially, but rise subsequently; the output levels of the two sectors 
and the total tax income are enhanced before they come back to their original paths.   

 
Keywords: Habit formation; preference change; environmental tax; pollution; economic 
growth. 

 
Acknowledgements: The author is grateful for the financial support from the Grants-in-Aid 
for Scientific Research (C), Project No. 25380246, Japan Society for the Promotion of 
Science. 



4 

 

 
1. Introduction 
Economic growth has close relationships with environmental changes. As far as neoclassical 
growth theory is concerned, early formal modeling on tradeoffs between consumption and 
pollution were found in the seminal papers by Plourde (1972) and Forster (1973). Interactions 
between environmental change and economic growth have received increasingly attention in the 
literature of economic growth and development (see, for instance, Pearson, 1994; Grossman, 
1995; Copeland and Taylor, 2004; Stern 2004; Brock and Taylor, 2006; Dasgupta, et al. 
2006). In the literature of economic development and environmental change many researches are 
conducted to confirm or question the environmental Kuznets curve. The environmental Kuznets 
curve refers to the phenomenon that per capita income and environmental quality follow an 
inverted U-curve. A recent survey on the literature of the curve is given by Kijima et al. 
(2010). In fact, in the increasing literature of empirical studies on relations between growth and 
environmental quality rather than the suggested environmental Kuznets curve one finds different 
relations such as inverted U-shaped relationship, a U-shaped relationship, a monotonically 
increasing or monotonically decreasing relationship (Dinda, 2004; Managi, 2007; Tsurumi and 
Managi, 2010). The various relations between economic development and environmental quality 
the inability of economic theories for properly explaining these observed phenomena implies the 
necessity that more comprehensive theories are needed. The purpose of this study is to introduce 
habit formation and preference change into the literature of economic growth and environmental 
change. As far as I am aware, there is no formal neoclassical growth model based on micro 
economic foundation which deals with economic growth, environmental change, habit 
formation, and preference change in an integrated framework.  

 People behave under influences of their habits. These habits are formed over years. People 
may change their habits with different speeds. Habits are parts of preferences. Different people 
have different preferences. The preference is also changeable over time for the same person. This 
study tries to integrate habit formation, preference change and economic growth within a 
comprehensive framework. Preferences are changeable and many factors may attribute to these 
changes. For instance, Becker and Mulligan (1997) found that expenditures in health and 
education have positive impacts saving (see also, Fuchs, 1982; Shoda et al., 1990; Olsen, 1993; 
Kirby et al. 2002; Chao et al., 2009). Many empirical studies identify relations between 
preference changes and other changes in social and economic conditions (e.g., Horioka, 1990; 
Sheldon, 1997, 1998). In the literature of economic growth with preference change, economists 
analyze preference change mainly by introducing time preference change in the Ramsey growth 
model. A main approach to modeling relations between growth and preference change is the so-
called endogenous time preference. The formal modeling in continuous time formation was 
initiated with Uzawa’s seminal paper (Uzawa, 1968). Following Uzawa, Lucas and Stokey 
(1984) and Epstein (1987) establish relations between time preference and consumptions. Becker 
and Barro (1988) build a time preference change model in which the parent’s generational 
discount rate is connected to their fertility. There are other studies on the implications of 
endogenous time preference for the macroeconomy (see, e.g., Epstein and Hynes, 1983; 
Obstfeld, 1990; Shin and Epstein, 1993; Palivos et al., 1997; Drugeon, 1996, 2000; Stern, 2006; 
Meng, 2006; Dioikitopoulos and Kalyvitis, 2010). The idea of analyzing change in impatience in 
this study is influenced by the literature of time preference. We introduce changes in impatience 
in an alternative utility proposed by Zhang (1993). Except the literature on time preference 
change, this study is also influenced by the so-called habit formation or habit persistence model. 
The model was initially proposed in formal economic analysis by Duesenberry (1949). Becker 
(1992) explains the role of habit in affecting human behavior as follows: “the habit acquired as a 
child or young adult generally continue to influence behavior even when the environment 



5 

 

changes radically. For instance, Indian adults who migrate to the United States often eat the same 
type of cuisine they had in India, and continue to wear the same type clothing.” Habit formation 
is also applied to different fields of economic analysis (for instance, Pollak, 1970; Mehra and 
Prescott, 1985; Sundaresan, 1989; Constantinides, 1990; Campbell and Cochrane, 1999; de la 
Croix, 1996; Boldrin et al., 2001; Christiano et al. 2005; Ravn et al., 2006; Huang, 2012). It 
should be noted that since the research by Abel (1990), ‘catching up with the Joneses’ is often 
used exchangeable with external habit formation. 

 The purpose of this paper is to study economic growth with environmental change and 
preference change on the basis of the Solow one-sector growth model, Zhang’s approach to 
household behavior, the neoclassical growth models with environmental change, the literature of 
time preference and the literature of habit formation. The model in this paper is an extension of 
Zhang’s two models on environmental change and habit formation. The interdependence 
between savings and dynamics of environment is mainly based on Zhang (2011), while the habit 
formation and preference change are based on Zhang (2012). Section 2 introduces the basic 
model with wealth accumulation, environmental dynamics, habit formation and preference 
change. Section 3 studies dynamic properties of the model and simulates the model, identifying 
the existence of a unique equilibrium and checking the stability conditions. Section 4 conducts 
comparative dynamic analysis with regard to some parameters. Section 5 concludes the study. 
The appendix proves the analytical results in Section 3.  

 
2. The Basic Model 
The production side of the economy consists of one industrial sector and one environmental 
sector. The industrial sector is similar to the standard one-sector growth model (see Burmeister 
and Dobell 1970; Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1995). The economy has only one (durable) good and 
one pollutant in the economy under consideration. In the literature of environmental economics, 
there are different kinds of environmental variables (e.g., Moslener and Requate, 2007; Repetto, 
1987; Leighter, 1999; and Nordhaus, 2000). Capital of the economy is owned by the 
households who distribute their incomes to consume the commodity and to save. Exchanges take 
place in perfectly competitive markets. The population N  is fixed and homogenous. The labor 
force is fully employed by the two sectors. The commodity is selected to serve as numeraire 
(whose price is normalized to 1), with all the other prices being measured relative to its price.  

 
The industrial sector 
Economic productivities are affected by pollution through different channels. For instance, 
pollution may directly affect production technology or the productivity of any input (Grimaud, 
1999; Chao and Peck, 2000; Gradus and Smulders, 1996; Ono, 2002) for the impact on the 
productivity of any input. We assume that production is to combine labor force, ( ),tN i  and 
physical capital, ( ).tK i  We add environmental impact to the conventional production function. 
The production function is specified as follows 

 
( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( ) ,1,0,,, =+>Γ= iiiiiiiiii AtNtKtEAtF ii βαβαβα                                        (1) 

 
where ( )tFi  is the output level of the industrial sector at time ,t ( )EiΓ  is a function of the 
environmental quality measured by the level of pollution, ( ),tE  iA  is the total productivity, and 

iα and iβ  are respectively the output elasticities of capital and labor. The environmental impact 
on the productivity ( )EiΓ  is specified as follows 

 



6 

 

( )( ) ( ) .0, ≤=Γ ibi btEtE i  
 
In perfectly competitive markets are competitive, labor and capital earn their marginal 

products. The environmental quality is not decided by any individuals firm. Let ( )tr  and ( )tw  
represent respectively the rate of interest and wage rate as follows 

 

( ) ( ) ( )
( )

( ) ( ) ( )
( )

,
1

,
1

tN

tF
tw

tK

tF
tr

i

iii

i

iii
k

τβτα
δ

−
=

−
=+                                                     (2) 

 
where kδ  is the fixed depreciation rate of physical capital and iτ  is the fixed tax rate, 

.10 <<< iτ   
 

Consumer behaviors 
The representative household decides how much to consume and how much to save. This applies 
the approach to behavior of the household proposed by Zhang (1993). Per capita wealth is 
denoted by ( ).tk  We have ( ) ( ) ,/ NtKtk =  where is the total capital stock. The per capita 
disposable current income which is the sum of the interest payment ( ) ( )tktr  and the wage 
payment ( )tw  after taxation is given by 

 
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ),11 twtktrty wk ττ −+−=                                                                 

 
where kτ  and wτ  are respectively the tax rates on the interest payment and wage income. The 
per capita disposable income is 

 
( ) ( ) ( ).ˆ tktyty +=                                                                                                               (3) 

 
The disposable income is distributed between saving and consumption. The representative 

household spends the total available budget on saving, ( ),ts  and the commodity, ( ).tc  The 
budget constraint is  

 
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ),ˆ1 tytstcc =++ τ                                                                                                  (4) 
 

where cτ  is the tax rate on the consumption. In this study we neglect the possibility that 
consumers explicitly take care of environment. For modern economies, consumers tend to make 
efforts in improving environment, for instance, by preferring to environment-friendly goods. As 
observed by Selden and Song (1995), when society has a lower level of pollution, the 
representative agent may not care much about environment and spends his resource on 
consumption; however, as the environmental quality lowers and the agent earns more, the agent 
may spend more resources on environmental improvement.  

The household decides the two variables, ( )ts  and ( ).tc  This study specifies the utility 
function as follows 

 
( ) ( )( ) ( )( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( ) ,0,,, 000000 >= − χλξχλξ tttEtstctU ttt                                              

 



7 

 

where ( )t0ξ  is the utility elasticity of the commodity, called the propensity to consume, ( )t0λ  is 
the utility elasticity of saving, called the propensity to own wealth, and 0χ  is the elasticity of 
environmental quality. This type of utility function was initially proposed by Zhang (1993). As 
Balcao (2001) and Nakada (2004), we assume that utility is negatively to pollution, which is a 
side product of the production process.  According to Munro (2009: 43), “environmental 
economics has been slow to incorporate the full nature of the household into its analytical 
structures. … [A]n accurate understanding household behavior is vital for environmental 
economics.” In our approach,  

For the representative household, )(tw  and )(tr  are given in markets. Maximizing )(tU  
subject to (4) yields 

 
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ),ˆ,ˆ tyttstyttc λξ ==                                                                                         (5) 

 
where  

 

( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) .
1

,,
1 00

0
0

tt
ttt

tt
t

c λξ
ρλρλ

τ
ξρ

ξ
+

≡≡
+

≡  

 
We call ( )tξ  and ( )tλ  respectively the relative propensities to consume and to save. It is the 

values of the relative propensities, not the propensities, which matter in determining the 
expenditure allocation.  

 
 

Dynamics of wealth accumulation 
According to the definition of ( ),ts the change in the household’s wealth is given by 
 

( ) ( ) ( ).tktstk −=&                                                                                                             (6) 
 
 The equation simply states that the change in wealth is equal to saving minus dissaving.  
 

The demand and supply balance 
The output of the industrial sector equals the sum of the level of consumption, the 

depreciation of capital stock and the net savings. Hence we have 
 
      ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ),tFtKtKtStC ik =+−+ δ                                                                (7) 
 

where ( ) ( ) NtctC =  is the total consumption, and ( ) ( ) ( )tKtKtS kδ+−  is the sum of the net 
saving and depreciation, where ( ) ( ) .NtstS ≡  

 
Full employment of production factors 
We use N te ( )  and K te ( ) to respectively stand for the labor force and capital stocks employed by 
the environmental sector. As full employment of labor and capital is assumed, we have 

 
( ) ( ) ( ),tKtKtK ei =+   ( ) ( ) .NtNtN ei =+                                                                       (8) 

 



8 

 

Environmental change 
We now describe dynamics of the stock of pollutants ( ).tE  Both production and consumption 
pollute environment. The dynamics of the stock of pollutants is specified as follows 

 
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ),0 tEtQtCtFtE ecif θθθ −−+=&                                                                          (9) 

 
where q qf c, , and q0  are positive parameters and 

 
( ) ( ) ( ) ,0,,,)( >Γ= eeeeeeee AtNtKEAtQ ee βαβα                                                             (10) 

 
where ,eA ,eα and eβ  are positive parameters, and )0()( ≥Γ Ee  is a function of .E  As in 

Gutiérrez (2008), the emission of pollutants during production processes is linearly positively 
proportional to the output level. This is reflected by Ffθ  in (10). As in John and Pecchenino 
(1994), John et al. (1995), and Prieur (2009), in consuming one unit of the good the quantity cθ  
is left as waste. We consider cθ  is related to the technology and environmental sense of 
consumers. The term E0θ  is the rate that the nature purifies environment, where 0θ  is called the 
rate of natural purification. We use the term, ,ee ee NK

βα  in Qe  to reflect that that the purification 

rate of environment is positively related to capital and labor inputs. The function )(EeΓ  means 
that the purification efficiency is related to the stock of pollutants. For simplicity, we specify eΓ  
as follows ( ) ,ebee EE θ=Γ  where eθ  and eb  are parameters.  

 
The behavior of the environmental sector 
In this study we consider that the environmental sector is financially supported by the 
government. The sector decides the number of labor force and the level of capital employed. The 
government’s tax revenue consists of the tax incomes on the industrial sector, consumption, 
wage income and wealth income. Hence, the government’s income is given by  

 
( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ).tKtrtwNtCtFtY kwciie ττττ +++=                                                        (11) 

 
As in Ono (2003), we assume that all the tax incomes are spent on environment. For 

simplicity, we assume that all the revenue of the government is spent on protecting environment. 
The environmental sector’s budget is 

 
( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ).tYtNtwtKtr eeek =++ δ                                                                                 (12) 

 
According to Zhang (2011), the environmental sector employs labor and uses capital in such 

a way that the purification rate achieves its maximum under the given budget constraint. The 
sector’s optimal problem is given by 

 
( )tQeMax     s.t.: ( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ).tYtNtwtKtr eeek =++ δ   

 
The optimal solution is 
 

( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ),, tYtNtwtYtKtr eeeek βαδ ==+                                                             (13) 



9 

 

 
where  

 

.,
ee

e

ee

e

βα
β

β
βα

α
α

+
≡

+
≡  

 
The time preference and the propensity to hold wealth 
Following Zhang (2012), we introduce preference change through making the propensity to own 
wealth and propensity to consume endogenous variables. Zhang’s approach is influenced by the 
traditional approach to preference change in economic theory. To illustrate the approach in this 
study, we consider a traditional modeling framework by Chang et al. (2011) in which the 
representative household maximizes the following discounted lifetime utility with perfect 
foresight  

 

( ) ( ) ,,
0∫
∞ − tdemcu tρ  

 
in which u  is the utility function, c  is consumption, and m  is holdings of real money 

balances. The time preference ( )tρ  is endogenously determined (see also, Uzawa, 1968; 
Epstein, 1987; Obstfeld, 1990; and Shi and Epstein, 1993). The variable changes as follows 

 

( ) ( )( ) ,
0∫ ∆=
t

sdsutρ  
 

where 0>∆  is an instantaneous subjective discount rate at time ,s  which satisfies ,0' >∆  
,0" >∆  and .0' >∆−∆ u We have  

 
     ( ) ( )( ).tut ∆=ρ&  
 
 There are many other studies with endogenous time preference (for instance, Dornbusch and 

Frenkel, 1973; Persson and Svensson, 1985; Blanchard and Fischer, 1989; Orphanides and 
Solow, 1990; Das, 2003; Hirose and Ikeda, 2008). Although this study does not follow the 
Ramsey approach in modeling behavior of household, we will adapt the ideas about time 
preference within the Ramsey framework. The time preference in the traditional approach is 
related to real wealth or/and current consumption. This study treats the propensity to save as a 
function of the wage rate and wealth. Following Zhang (2012), the dynamics of the propensity to 
save is 

 
( ) ( ) ( ),0 tktwt kw λλλλ ++=                                                                                                (14) 

 
where ,0>λ  ,wλ  and kλ  are parameters. When ,0== kw λλ  ( )t0λ  is constant. If we follow 
Uzawa’s idea, then it is reasonable to assume 0>wλ  and .0=kλ   If we follow the assumption 
that the rate of time preference is positively related to wealth, for instance, accepted by Smithin 
(2004) and Kam and Mohsin (2006), then 0=wλ  and .0>kλ   

 



10 

 

The habit formation and the propensity to consume 
The modeling of the propensity to save is influenced by the literature of time preference change. 
In order to model how the propensity to consume, we will adapt the basic ideas in the habit 
formation approach to our framework. To illustrate the ideas in the traditional approach, we 
introduce the following habit formation (e.g., Alvarez-Cuadrado et al., 2004; and Gómez, 
2008) 

  

( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ,10,0,10 ≤≤>= −
∞−

−
∫ φρρ

φφ sdsCsCet
t

tsh
h  

 
where ( )tC  is the consumer’s consumption and ( )tC  is the economy-wide average 
consumption. A larger value for 0h  implies that the household puts lower weights to more 

distant values of the levels of consumption. Taking the derivatives the equation with respect to 
time yields 

 
( ) ( ) ( ) ( )[ ].10 tsCsCt hhh& −= −φφ  

 
If ,0=φ  the habit formation corresponds to the model with external habits. If ,1=φ  the 

habit formation corresponds to the model with internal habits. If ,10 << φ  habits arise from 
both the consumer’s and average past consumption. There are other models with habit formation 
(Deaton and Muellbauer, 1980; Carroll, 2000; Fuhrer, 2000; Kozicki and Tinsley, 2002; 
Amano and Laubach, 2004; Carroll et al., 1997; Corrado and Holly, 2011). Following Zhang 
(2012), this study also applies the concept of habit stock to analyze how the past consumption 
affects the current preference. The habit formation is specified as  

 
( ) ( ) ( )[ ].0 ttct hhh& −=                                                                                                       (15) 

 
Equation (15) corresponds to the model with internal habits. If the current consumption is 

higher than the level of the habit stock, then the level of habit stock will rise, and vice versa. The 
propensity to consume is relate to the habit stock as follows 

 
( ) ( ) ( ),0 ttwt hw hξξξξ ++=                                                                                            (16) 

 
where ,0>ξ  wξ  and 0≥hξ  are parameters. If 0=wξ  and ,0=hξ  ( )t0ξ  is constant. The term 

( )tywξ  implies that the propensity to consume is affected by the wage rate. If ,0)(<>wξ  then a 
rise in the wage rate enhances (lowers) ( ).0 tξ  It is reasonable to assume .0≥wξ  The term 

( )th hξ  shows that if ( )th  rises, the propensity to consume will rise, and vice versa.  
 We have thus built the dynamic model. We now examine dynamics of the model. 
 

3. The Motion of the Economic System 
The appendix confirms that the motion of the economic system is given by three autonomous 
differential equations with ( ) ( )ttz h,  and ( ).tE  as the variables, where ( )tz  is a new variable 
defined by 

 



11 

 

( ) ( )( ) .ktr
tw

tz
δ+

≡  

 
The following lemma shows that once we solve the time-invariant system, we know the 

values of all the other variables in the economy at any point of time.  
 
Lemma 1 
The motion of the three variables, ( ) ( )ttz h,  and ( ),tE  is obtained by solving the following 

three autonomous differential equations with 
 
     ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( ),,, tEttztz z h& Λ=  
     ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( ),,, tEttzt c hh& Λ=   
     ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( ),,, tEttztE E h& Λ=                                                                                         (17) 
 

in which ,zΛ  ,cΛ  and EΛ  are functions of ( ) ( )ttz h,  and ( )tE  defined in the appendix. All the 
other variables are solved as functions of ( ) ( )ttz h,  and ( )tE  as follows: ( )tr  and ( )tw  by (A2) 
→ ( )t0ξ  by (A16) → ( )t0λ  by (A15) → ( )tλ  and ( )tξ  by (5) → ( )tKi  and ( )tKe  by (A7) → 

( ) ( ) ( )tKtKtK ei +=  → ( ) ( ) NtKtk /=  → ( )tNi  and ( )tN x  by (A1) → ( )tFi  by (1) → ( )tQe  
by (10) → ( )tŷ  by (3) → ( )tc  and ( )ts  by (10). 

 
From the procedure in Lemma 1 we can get the value of any variable at any point of time as 

functions of ( ) ( )ttz h,  and ( ).tE  The three dimensional autonomous differential equations are 
nonlinear. It is almost impossible to get analytical solution of the time-invariant system. 
Nevertheless, we can use a common computer to follow the motion of the three-dimensional 
time-invariant system. To simulate the model, we choose the following parameter values  

 

.03.0,05.0,1.0,1.0,05.0,05.0

,05.0,05.0,40.0,10.0,2.0,1.0,02.0,01.0

,6.0,05.0,05.0,4.0,4.0,3.0,5.0,1,5

0

0

======
=======−=

=−=−=======

kcfwk

cihwkw

eieeisi bbAAN

δθθθττ
ττξξξλλ

λβαα
h      (18) 

 
In the remainder of this study, the depreciation rate is fixed as .03.0=kδ  The population 

is chosen 10  and the total available time is unity. In our neoclassical model the population 
size has no impact on the per-capita variables, even though it affects the aggregate variable 
levels. The chosen values of the available time and the population will not affect our main 
conclusions. The total productivity and the output elasticity of capital of the capital goods 
sector are respectively ,1.1  ,35.0  and the total productivity and the output elasticity of capital 
of the capital goods sector are respectively 9.0  and .30.0  It should be noted that both in 
theoretical simulations and empirical studies the output elasticity of capital in the Cobb-Douglas 
production is often valued approximately equal to 3.0  and the value of the total productivity is 
chosen to be close to unity (e.g., Miles and Scott, 2005; Abel, Bernanke, Croushore, 2007). 
Although the chosen values of the preference parameters are not empirically based, we choose 
the coefficients associated with the wage and wealth very small so that we may effectively 
analyze the effects of changes in these coefficients on the economic structure. We now specify 
the initial conditions to see how the variables change over time. To follow the motion of the 
system, we choose the following initial conditions: 



12 

 

 
( ) ( ) ( ) .3.10,120,5.60 === hEz  

 
Figure 1 plots the simulation result. We first observe that the habit stock of leisure time 

falls while the habit stock of consumer goods rise till they respectively approach the leisure 
time and the consumption level of consumer goods. This happens as the two stocks are 
initially different from their corresponding variables. The work time, total labor supply and 
labor inputs of the two sectors are increased over time. The total capital and capital input of 
the consumer goods sector fall, while the capital input of the capital goods sector rises. The 
price and wage rate fall slightly, while the rate of interest rises. The propensity to consume 
rises, while the propensities to use leisure time and to save are affected only slightly. The 
GDP and the output level of the consumer goods sector fall while that of the capital goods 
sector rises. It should be noted that it takes much less time for the leisure time to converge to 
its habit stock level than the consumption level of consumer goods to its habit stock.  

 Figure 1 shows that the variables tend to move towards stationary states. This implies the 
existence of an equilibrium point. Our simulation identifies the equilibrium values of these 
variables as follows 

 

.09.1,72.0,27.0

,65.0,25.0,83.0,11.0,05.3,69.11

,50.0,50.4,83.0,53.0,31.5,96.10,75.14

00

====
======

=======

c

ei

eieei

c

wrKK

NNYQFEK

hλξ
λξ  

 
It is straightforward to get the following three eigenvalues 
 

.05.0,03.0137.0 −±− i  
 
As the three eigenvalues have real negative parts, the equilibrium point is locally stable. 

Hence, the system always approaches its equilibrium if it is not far from the equilibrium point. 
This is important as it guarantees the validity of comparative dynamic analysis for transitional 
paths.  

 
4. Comparative Dynamic Analysis 
From the analysis in the previous section we know that that the economic system has a unique 
locally stable equilibrium. This guarantees that we can make comparative dynamic analysis. This 
section conducts comparative dynamic analysis with regard to some parameters. It should be 
remarked that because the system contains many variables which nonlinearly interact with each 
other in a very complicated manner over time, it is not easy to accurately interpret how all these 
variables interact over time.  

 



13 

 

Figure 1 – The Motion of the Economic System 

 
 
 

Lower weights being put to more distant values of the levels of consumption  
We first study the case where the household puts lower weights to more distant values of the 
levels of consumption in the following way: .3.01.0:0 ⇒h  The rise in the parameter also 

means that the habit stock and the current level of consumption mutually converge faster. Figure 
2 diagrams the simulation results. In this study we use the variable ( )tx∆  to stand for the change 
rate of the variable, ( ),tx  in percentage due to changes in some parameter value. Indeed, the 
disturbance in the speed of adjustment will not affect the equilibrium of the dynamic system. 
Nevertheless, the transitional paths towards the equilibrium points of the variables are strongly 
perturbed. As the household puts lower weights to more distant values of the levels of 
consumption, initially the transitional path of the habit stock is deviated from the original path. 
As the speed is sped up, the path of the stock habit becomes lower than its original path. As the 
habit stock becomes lower, the consumption level also falls initially in association with falling in 
the propensity to consume. The disturbance causes the propensity to consume to fall and the 
propensity to save to rise. As the relative propensity to save is λ  increased, the national wealth is 
augmented. The disturbance in the national wealth enables the two sectors to employ more 
capital. The labor distribution path is also shifted. The labor force is shifted initially from the 
industrial sector to the environmental sector, but subsequently the direction is opposite before the 
labor distribution comes to its original equilibrium point. The wage rate is enhanced in 
association with falling in the rate of interest. The level of pollution falls initially, but rise 
subsequently. The output levels of the two sectors and the total tax income are enhanced before 
they come back to their original equilibrium levels.  

 
The environmental tax rate on consumption being enhanced 
We now enhance the environmental tax rate on consumption as follows: .07.005.0: ⇒cτ  The 
impacts are plotted in Figure 4. As the tax rate on consumption is increased, the consumption 

25 50 75 100
12
13
14
15

25 50 75 100
11

11.3
11.6
11.9

0 25 50 75 100
0.82

0.83

0.84

0 25 50 75 100
3

4

5

0 25 50 75 100
0.72

0.78
0.82
0.86

0 25 50 75 100
0.5

0.55
0.6

0.65

25 50 75 100
1.1

1.2

1.3

25 50 75 100
0.255
0.26

0.265
0.27

25 50 75 100
0.1

0.104

0.108

h  

K  

0ξ  

λ  

r  

t  t  

 

c  

t  

t  

t  t  

t  
t  t  

E  

iN  

eK  

iF  
eY  

w  

eQ  
eN  

0λ  

ξ  



14 

 

Figure 2 – The Household Puts Lower Weights on More Distant Values of Consumption 
 

  
 
 

level and the habit stock of consumption are lessened. The lowered habit stock diminishes the 
propensity to consumption, which implies augmenting in the propensity to save. The national 
wealth is increased as the propensity to save is increased. More capital and labor resources are 
located to the environmental sector. The environment is improved. Both the rate of interest 
and wage rate are increased. It should be noted that in the Solow-type neoclassical growth 
theory without endogenous environment, the rate of interest and wage rate are changed in the 
opposite directions. In our model the two variables are changed in the same direction because 
the environmental change affects the productivity. In our simulation case the improved 
environment augments the productivity of the industrial sector. This leads to the same change 
direction in the wage rate and the rate of interest.  The net consequence of the rising national 
wealth and capital input of the environmental sector leads to lowering in the capital input of 
the industrial sector. As the capital and labor resources located to the industrial sector are 
lowered, the output level of the industrial sector is reduced.   

 
Wealth more strongly affecting the propensity to save 
How the propensity to save may influence economic growth and development is a main question 
in economics. It is well known that Adam Smith and Keynes have the opposite opinions about 
the effects of a change in the saving propensity. Adam Smith holds that a rise in the propensity to 
save will encourage long-run economic growth as to save more means more capital in the 
economy, while Keynes argues that to save less means to create more job opportunities and 
economic growth will be encouraged. In modern economics there is no convergence in empirical 
studies about the impact of the propensity to save. Moreover, there are only few formal models 
of economic growth with endogenous preference for saving. Our model explicitly introduces 
endogenous propensity to save.  

 
 

30 60 90
0

0.15
0.3

0.45

30 60 90�0.04
0.02
0.08
0.14

0 30 60 90
0

0.2
0.4

0 30 60 90
0

0.4
0.8
1.2

30 60 90
�0.15
�0.1
�0.05

0

0 30 60 90
0

0.1
0.2
0.3

30 60 90

�1.2
�0.8
�0.4

0
30 60 90

�6
�4
�2

0
30 60 90

�1.2
�0.8
�0.4

0

 

  

 
 

t  

K∆  

h∆  
0ξ∆  

eY∆  

c∆  

eK∆  

iK∆  

t  t  

t  t  

t  

t  

t  t  

0λ∆  

iN∆  

E∆  

r∆  

w∆  i
F∆  

eQ∆  

eN∆  

λ∆  

ξ∆  



15 

 

Figure 3 – A Rise in the Tax Rate on Consumption 
 

  
 
 
We now examine how the economic system responds to the following exogenous 

disturbances: .03.002.0: ⇒kλ  The change augments the propensity to save. The relative 
propensity is increased, while the relative propensity to consume is lessened. The change in 
the preference results in the increase of national wealth. The two sectors’ capital inputs are 
thus increased. More capital supply leads to lower rate of interest and rising wage rate. Labor 
force is shifted from the environmental sector to the industrial sector. The net result of 
lessened labor input and augmented capital input of the environmental sector is the rising 
output level of the sector. As the increased production and consumption pollute the 
environment more severely than before, the more efforts in cleaning environment do not 
improve the environment. 

 
The environmental sector improving its productivity 
We now deal with the impact of the following productivity enhancement in the environmental 
sector: .6.05.0: ⇒eA  An immediate result of the productivity improvement is augments 

of the environmental sector’s output level. The environment is provided as the economy is 
more effectively in cleaning the environment. The labor distribution is slightly changed. The 
improved environment enhances the productivities of the industrial sector. Although the 
relative propensity to save is lowered, the national wealth is augmented. The two sectors employ 
more capital inputs irrespective of rising in the cost of capital. The wage rate, habit stock of 
consumption and the consumption level are raised.  
 
 

30 60 90
0
4
8

12
30 60 90

�9
�6
�3

0

30 60 90
0

0.16
0.32
0.48

30 60 90
�1.5

3
7.5
12

30 60 90
0
4
8

12

0 30 60 90
0.04
0.07
0.1

0.13

30 60 90

�1.8
�1.2
�0.6

0
30 60 90

�1.2
�0.8
�0.4

0

0 30 60 90
0

0.3
0.6
0.9

 

  

 
 

t  

K∆  

h∆  

0ξ∆  

eY∆  

c∆  

eK∆  

iK∆  

t  

t  

t  t  

t  

t  

t  

t  

0λ∆  

iN∆  

E∆  

r∆  

w∆  

iF∆  

eQ∆  

eN∆  

λ∆  

ξ∆  



16 

 

Figure 4 – The Propensity to Save Being More Strongly Affected by Wealth 
 

   
 
 

Figure 5. The Environmental Sector Improving Its Productivity 
 

  
 

 
Raising the tax rate on the industrial sector 
Let us now change the tax rate on the output level of the industrial sector as follows: 

.07.005.0: ⇒iτ  The raised tax rate lowers the output level of the industrial sector. As the 
tax revenue is increased, the environmental sector has more resources to employ more capital 

30 60 90�0.9
0.2
1.3
2.4

30 60 90
�0.2

0.2
0.6

1

0 30 60 90
0
1
2

30 60 90
0
2
4
6

30 60 90
�0.9
�0.6
�0.3

0

30 60 90

3
4
5

30 60 90

�3
�2
�1

0

30 60 90
�3
�2
�1

0
1

30 60 90

�5
�3
�1

0

0 30 60 90
0

6.5
13

19.5
30 60 90

�15
�10
�5

0

0 30 60 90
0

0.45
0.9

1.35

0 30 60 90
0

0.4
0.8
1.2

30 60 90
�0.025
�0.015
�0.005

0.005

30 60 90�0.04
0

0.04
0.08

0 30 60 90
0

0.08
0.16
0.24

0 30 60 90
0

0.45
0.9

1.35

0 30 60 90
0

0.065
0.13

0.195

 

  

 
 

t  

K∆  

h∆  
0ξ∆  

eY∆  

c∆  

eK∆  
iK∆  

t  t  

t  
t  

t  

t  

t  
t  

0λ∆  iN∆  

E∆  

r∆  

w∆  
iF∆  

∆

 

eN∆  λ∆  

ξ∆  

 

  

 
 

t  

K∆  

h∆  

0ξ∆  

eY∆  

c∆  

eK∆  

iK∆  

t  

t  

t  
t  

t  

t  

t  t  

0λ∆  
iN∆  

E∆  

r∆  

w∆  

iF∆  

∆

 

eN∆  λ∆  

ξ∆  



17 

 

and labor inputs. The resources are shifted from the industrial sector to the environmental 
sector. The environment is improved. The industrial sector’s productivity is enhanced. As the 
productivity is enhanced only slightly in initial stage, the wage rate is reduced. As the 
productivity is further increased, the wage rate is increased. The reduced national wealth is 
associated with rising cost of capital. The relative propensity to save rises initially, but 
subsequently falls. The consumption level and habit stock of goods are increased. 

 
 

Figure 6 – Raising the Tax Rate on the Industrial Sector 
 

  
 
 

5. Concluding Remarks 
The paper constructed an economic growth model with environmental change and preference 
formation. The paper is focused on dynamic interactions among capital accumulation, 
environmental change, habit formation, preference change, and division of labor in perfectly 
competitive markets with environmental taxes on production, wealth income, wage income and 
consumption. The model integrated the dynamic economic mechanisms in the neoclassical 
growth theory, the environmental dynamics in traditional models of environmental economics, 
and the literature of economic growth with habit formation and within a comprehensive 
framework. We could have synthesized the different ideas in a few main streams of economic 
theory as we applied an alternative approach to household behavior initially proposed by Zhang 
(1993). We showed that the motion of the economic system is given by three nonlinear 
autonomous differential equations. We simulated the time-invariant system. 

The simulation demonstrates some dynamic interactions among the economic variables 
which can be predicted neither by the neoclassical growth theory nor by the traditional 
economic models of environmental change. For instance, we examined the effects that the 
household puts lower weights to more distant values of the levels of consumption. If the past 
consumption has weaker impact on the current consumption, although the long-term equilibrium 
of the dynamic system will not be affected, the transitional paths are shifted as follows: initially 
the transitional path of the stock habit becomes lower than its original path; the consumption 

30 60 90
0
5

10
30 60 90

�9
�6
�3

0

30 60 90�0.1
0

0.1
0.2
0.3

30 60 90
0
3
6
9

30 60 90
0
3
6
9

30 60 90
0

0.05
0.1

0.15

30 60 90�0.1
�0.02

0.06
0.14

0 30 60 90
0

0.4
0.8
1.2

0 30 60 90
0

0.5
1

1.5

 

  

 
 

t  

K∆  

h∆  
0ξ∆  

eY∆  

c∆  

eK∆  

iK∆  

t  

t  

t  t  

t  

t  

t  t  

0λ∆  

iN∆  

E∆  

r∆  

w∆  

iF∆  

∆

 

eN∆  

λ∆  

ξ∆  



18 

 

level falls initially in association with falling in the propensity to consume; the exogenous 
disturbance causes the propensity to consume to fall and the propensity to save to rise; the 
national wealth and capital inputs of the two sectors are augmented; the labor force is shifted 
initially from the industrial sector to the environmental sector, but subsequently the direction is 
opposite before the labor distribution comes to its original equilibrium point; the wage rate is 
enhanced in association with falling in the rate of interest; the level of pollution falls initially, but 
rise subsequently; the output levels of the two sectors and the total tax income are enhanced 
before they come back to their original paths.  

As the model is based on the basic ideas in some economic theories, it is straightforward to 
extend the model in some directions. For instance, we may introduce leisure time as an 
endogenous variable. Munro (2009: 3) observes: “In the unitary model, the household acts as 
if it is a single individual maximizing a single utility function in the face of one budget 
constraint. It is a simplifying modeling assumption that is widely used in most branches of 
economics, but it is wrong. The fact that the unitary model is inaccurate is well-known and 
has been known for many years now.” It is necessary to model family structure and economic 
structure for understanding relations among growth, environmental change and preference 
change (see, for instance, Dinda, 2004; Hamilton and Zilberman, 2006).  

 
Appendix: Identifying the Three Autonomous Differential Equations 
We now find the three autonomous differential equations and confirm the procedure in the 
lemma. First, from (2) and (15), we solve  

 

,
e

ee

i

ii

N

K

N

K
z

ββ
=≡                                                                                                        (A1) 

 
where ,/ jjj αββ ≡ ., eij =  Substituting (1) into (2) yields  

 

  ( ) ( ) ,,,,
i

i

i

i

i

iii
k

iiii
zA

Ezw
z

A
Ezr α

α

β

β

β
β

δ
βα Γ

=−
Γ

=                                                     (A2) 

 
where we use (A1). From (8) and (A1), we solve 

 
.NzKK eeii =+ ββ                                                                                                      (A3) 

 
Insert (5) in (7) 

 
( ) .ˆ ik FKKyN =+−+ δλξ                                                                                         (A4) 
 

Put (3) in (A4) 
 
( )( )[ ] ( ) ,1 iwk FwNKr =++−++ τλξδτλξ                                                             (A5) 

 
where kk ττ −≡ 1  and .1 ww ττ −≡  Replacing iF  in (A5) with ( ) iiiki KrF ταδ /+=  from (2), 
we acquire 

 



19 

 

( )( )[ ] ( ) ( ) .1
ii

i
kwk

K
rwNKr

τα
δτλξδτλξ +=++−++                                           (A6) 

 
From ,KKK ei =+  (A6) and (A3), we solve 

 

,,, ei
e

ii
ei KKK

KNz
KNK +=

−
==

β
β

φ                                                             (A7) 

 
where 

 

( ) ( )
( )

( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( )[ ] ./,~

,11,,1,

,~,,,

ieiik

keikwek

rEz

rrEzwzrEz

z
Ez

βδβταδδφ

τββτφτβτφ
φφλξ
δφλξ

λξφ

ξ

ξξ

ξξ

ξ

−++≡

+−+≡++≡

++
−+

≡

 

 
From the definition of ξ  and ,λ  we have 

 

,
~

00

00

λξ
λξτ

λξ
+
+

=+                                                                                                     (A8) 

 
where ( ).1/1~ cττ +≡  Insert (A8) in the definition of φ  

 

( ) ( ) ( )
( ) ( )

.~~

~
,,,

0000

0000
00 λξφφλξτ

λξδφλξτ
λξφ

ξξ

ξ

+++
+−+

=
z

Ez                                                             (A9) 

 
From (14), we acquire 

 

.0 KN
wN

k

w

k

+






 +
=

λ
λλ

λ
λ

                                                                                       (A10) 

 
Put (A7) in (A8) 

 

,
~

00 φβφλ +=                                                                                                         (A11) 
 

where  
 

( ) ( ) .~,,0
e

kie

e

k
w

z
wEz

β
λββ

β
β
λ

λλφ
−

≡++=                                                             (A12) 

 
Put (A9) in (A11) 

 



20 

 

( ) ( )
( ) ( )

,~~

~~~

0000

0000
00 λξφφλξτ

λξδβφβλξτ
φλ

ξξ

ξ

+++
+−+

+=
z

                                                               (A13) 

 
We rewrite (A13) as follows 

 
,0201

2
0 =−+ ωλωλ                                                                                                     (A14) 

 
where 

 

( )

( ) .~
~~~~~

,,

,~

~~~~~
,,

000000
02

0000
01

ξξ

ξξξ

ξξ

ξξξξξ

φφ
ξφβτξδβξφφφφξτ

ξω

φφ
φβδβφφφφξφφξτ

ξω

+

+−+
≡

+

−+−−+
≡

z
Ez

z
Ez

 

 
We solve (A14) with 0λ  as the variable 

 

( ) .
2

4
,, 2

2
11

00

ωωω
ξλ

+±−
=Ez                                                                                (A15) 

 
We have two solutions from the above equation. In our simulation case the solution  

 

( )
2

4
,, 2

2
11

000

ωωω
χξλ

++−
=z  

 
is meaningful. From (16), we have 

 
( ) .,,0 hh hw wEz ξξξξ ++=                                                                                        (A16) 

 
We solve all the variables as functions of ,z  ,E  and h  as follows: r  and w  by (A2) → 0ξ  by 
(A16) → 0λ  by (A15) → λ  and ξ  by (5) → iK  and eK  by (A7) → ei KKK +=  → 

NKk /=  → iN  and xN  by (A1) → iF  by (1) → eQ  by (10) → ŷ  by (3) → c  and s  by 
(10). Here, we express the function for wealth obtained by this procedure as ( ).,, hEzk Φ=  
From (11), (3), (15) and (17) and the procedure to determine the variables as functions of ,z  

,E  and ,h  we have the following three differential equations 
 

( ) ,ˆ,, kyEzk −≡Λ= λh&                                                                                         (A17) 
( ) ,,, 0 EQCFEzE ecifE θθθ −−+≡Λ= h&  

( ) ( ) ( )[ ].,, 0 ttcEzc hhhh& −≡Λ=                                                                                    (A18) 
 

We do not provide the expressions because they are tedious. Taking derivatives of 
( )h,, Ezk Φ=  with respect to time yields 

 



21 

 

,
h

&&

∂
Φ∂

Λ+
∂

Φ∂
Λ+

∂
Φ∂

= cE
E

z
z

k                                                                                        (A19) 

 
where we also apply (A18). Injecting (A17) in (A19) yields 

 

( ) .,,
1−










∂
Φ∂










∂
Φ∂

Λ−
∂

Φ∂
Λ−Λ≡Λ=

zE
Ezz

c
cEz

h
h&                                                         (A20) 

 
We thus proved Lemma 1. 

 
 

References 
Abel, A. (1990). Asset Prices under Habit Formation and Catching up with the Joneses. 

American Economic Review, 80(2), 38-42.  
Abel, A., Bernanke, B.S., & Croushore, D. (2007). Macroeconomics. New Jersey: Prentice Hall.  
Alvarez-Cuadrado, F., Monteriro, G., and Turnovsky, S.J. (2004). Habit Formation, Catching-

Up with the Joneses, and Economic Growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 9(1), 47-80. 
Amato, J.D., & Laubach, T. (2004). Implication of Habit Formation for Optimal Monetary 

Policy. Journal of Monetay Economics, 51(2), 305-25. 
Balcao, A. (2001). Endogenous Growth and the Possibility of Eliminating Pollution. Journal of 

Environmental Economics and Management, 42(3), 360-73. 
Barro, R.J., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1995). Economic Growth. New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc. 
Becker, G. (1992). Habits, Addictions and Traditions. Kyklos, 45(3), 327-45. 
Becker, G.S., & Barro, R.J. (1988). A Reformation of the Economic Theory of Fertility. 

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 103(1), 139-71.  
Becker, G.S., & Mulligan, C.B. (1997). The Endogenous Determination of Time Preference. The 

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(3), 729-58.  
Blanchard, O.J., & Fischer, S. (1989). Lectures on Macroeconomics. Cambridge, MA: MIT 

Press.  
Brock, W., & Taylor, M.S. (2006). Economic Growth and the Environment: A Review of 

Theory and Empirics, in S. Durlauf, & P. Aghion (Eds.), The Handbook of Economic 
Growth. Amsterdam: Elsevier.  

Boldrin, M., Christiano, L., and Fisher, J. (2001). Habit Persistence, Asset Returns, and the 
Business Cycle. American Economic Review, 91(1), 149-66. 

Burmeister, E., & Dobell, A.R. (1970). Mathematical Theories of Economic Growth. London: 
Collier Macmillan Publishers. 

Campbell, J., & Cochrane, J. (1999). By Force of Habit: A Consumption-Based Explanation of 
Aggregate Stock Market Behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 107(2), 205-51. 

Carroll, C.D. (2000). Solving Consumption Models with Multiplicative Habits. Economics 
Letters, 68(1), 67-77. 

Carroll, C.D., Overland, J., & Weil, D.N. (1997). Consumption Utility in a Growth Model. 
Journal of Economic Growth, 2(4), 339-67. 

Chang, W.Y., Tsai, H.F., & Chang, J.J. (2011). Endogenous Time Preference, Interest-Rate 
Rules, and Indeterminacy. The Japanese Economic Review, 62(3), 348-64.  

Chao, H. and Peck, S. (2000). Greenhouse Gas Abatement: How Much? And Who Pays? 
Resource and Energy, 67(1), 1-24. 

Chao, L.W., Szrek, H., Pereira, N.S., & Paul, M. (2009). Time Preference and Its Relationship 
with Age, Health, and Survival Probability. Judgment and Decision Making, 4(1), 1-19.  



22 

 

Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M., & Evans, C. (2005). Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic 
Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy. Journal of Political Economy, 113(1), 1-45. 

Constantinides, G. (1990). Habit Formation: A Resolution of the Equity Premium Puzzle. 
Journal of Political Economy, 98(3), 519-43. 

Copeland, B., & Taylor, S. (2004). Trade, Growth and the Environment. Journal of Economic 
Literature, 42(1), 7-71. 

Corrado, L., & Holly, S. (2011). Multiplicative Habit Formation and Consumption: A Note. 
Economics Letters, 113(2), 116-19. 

Das, M. (2003). Optimal Growth with Decreasing Marginal Impatience. Journal of Economic 
Dynamics and Control, 27(10), 1881-98.  

Dasgupta, S., Hamilton, K., Pandey, K.D., & Wheeler, D. (2006). Environment During Growth: 
Accounting for Governance and Vulnerability. World Development, 34(9), 1597-611. 

De la Croix, D. (1996). The Dynamics of Bequeathed Tastes. Economics Letters, 51(1), 89-96. 
Deaton, A., & Muellbauer, J. (1980). Economics and Consumer Behavior. Cambridge: 

Cambridge University  Press.  
Dinda, S. (2004). Environmental Kuznets Curve Hypothesis: A Survey. Ecological Economics, 

49(4), 431-55. 
Dioikitopoulos, E.V., & Kalyvitis, S. (2010). Endogenous Time Preference and Public Policy: 

Growth and Fiscal Implications. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 14(2), 243-57. 
Duesenberry, J. (1949). Income, Saving, and the Theory of Consumer Behavior. Cambridge, 

MA.: Harvard University Press. 
Dornbusch, R., & Frenkel, J. (1973). Inflation and Growth: Alternative Approaches. Journal of 

Money, Credit and Banking, 50(1), 141-56.  
Drugeon, J.P. (1996). Impatience and Long-run Growth. Journal of Economic Dynamics and 

Control, 20(1), 281-313.   
Drugeon, J.P. (2000). On the Roles of Impatience in Homothetic Growth Paths. Economic 

Theory, 15(1), 139-61. 
Epstein, L.G. (1987). A Simple Dynaic General Equilibrium Model. Journal of Economic 

Theory, 41(1), 68-95. 
Epstein, L.G., & Hynes, J.A. (1983). The Rate of Time Preference and Dynamic Economic 

Analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 91(4), 611-35. 
Forster, B.A. (1973). Optimal Consumption Planning in a Polluted Environment. Economic 

Record, 49(4), 534-545. 
Fuhrer, J. (2000). Habit Formation in Consumption and Its Implications for Monetary Policy 

Models. American Economic Review, 90(3), 367-90.  
Fuchs, V.R. (1982). Time Preference and Health: An Exploratory Study. In V.R. Fuchs (Ed.) 

Economic Aspects of Health. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. 
Gómez M.A. (2008). Convergence Speed in the AK Endogenous Growth Model with Habit 

Formation. Economics Letter, 100(1), 16-21.  
Gradus, R. and Smulders, S. (1996). The Trade-Off Between Environmental Care and Long-

Term Growth-Pollution in Three Prototype Growth Models. Journal of Economics, 58(1), 
25-51. 

Grimaud, A. (1999). Pollution Permits and Sustainable Growth in a Schumpeterian Model. 
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 38(3), 249-66. 

Grossman, G.M. (1995). Pollution and Growth: What Do We Know?. In I. Goldin, & L.A. 
Winters (Eds.) The Economics of Sustainable Development. Cambridge: Cambridge 
University Press. 

Gutiérrez, M. (2008). Dynamic Inefficiency in an Overlapping Generation Economy with Pollution 
and Health Costs. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 10(4), 563-94.  



23 

 

Hamilton, S.F., & Zilberman, D. (2006). Green Markets, Eco-certification, and Equilibrium Fraud. 
Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 52(3), 627-44. 

Hirose, K.I., & Ikeda, S. (2008). On Decreasing Marginal Impatience. The Japanese Economic 
Review, 59(3), 259-74.  

Horioka, C. (1990). Why Is Japan’s Households Saving So High? A Literature Survey. Journal 
of the Japanese and International Economics, 4(1), 49-92.  

Huang, M.M. (2012). Housing Deep-Habit Model: Mutual Implications of Macroeconomics and 
Asset Pricing. Economics Letters, 116(3), 526-30. 

John, A., & Pecchenino, R. (1994). An Overlapping Generation Model of Growth and the 
Environment. The Economic Journal, 104(427), 1393-410. 

John, A., Pecchenino, R., Schimmelpfenning, & Schreft, S. (1995). Short-Lived Agents and the 
Long-Lived Environment. Journal of Public Economics, 58(1), 127-41. 

Kam, E., & Mohsin, M. (2006). Monetary Policy and Endogenous Time Preference. Journal of 
Economic Studies, 33(1), 52-67. 

Kijima, M., Nishide, K., & Ohyama, A. (2010). Economic Models for the Environmental 
Kuznets Curve: A Survey. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 34(7), 1187-201. 

Kirby, K.N., Godoy, R., Reyes-Garcia, V., Byron, B., Apaza, L., Leonard, W., Perez, B., Vadez, 
V., & Wilkie, D. (2002). Correlates of Delay-Discount Rates: Evidence from Tsimane 
Amerindians of the Bolivia Rain Forest. Journal of Economic Psychology, 23(3), 291-316. 

Kozicki, C., & Tinsley, P. (2002). Dynamic Specifications in Optimizing Trend-Deviation Macro 
Models. Journal of Economic Dynamics Control, 26(9), 1586-611. 

Leighter, J.E. (1999). Weather-induced Changes in the Trade-of Between SO2 and NOx at Large Power 
Plants. Energy Economics, 21(1), 239-59. 

Lucas, R.E. Jr., & Stokey, N.L. (1984). Optimal Growth with Many Consumers. Journal of 
Economic Theory, 32(1), 139-71.  

Mehra, R., & Prescott, E. (1985). The Equity Premium: A Puzzle. Journal of Monetary 
Economics, 15(2), 145-61. 

Managi, S. (2007). Technological Change and Environmental Policy: A Study of Depletion in 
the Oil and Gas Industry. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.  

Meng, Q. (2006). Impatience and Equilibrium Indeterminacy. Journal of Economic Dynamics 
and Control, 30(12), 2671-92.   

Miles, D. and Scott, A. (2005). Macroeconomics – Understanding the Wealth o Nations. Chichester: 
John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 

Moslener, U., & Requate, T. (2007). Optimal Abatement in Dynamic Multi-Pollutant Problems 
when Pollutants Can Be Complements or Substitutes. Journal of Economic Dynamics & 
Control, 31(7), 2293-316.  

Munro, A. (2009). Introduction to the Special Issue: Things We Do and Don’t Understand About the 
Household and the Environment. Environmental and Resources Economics, 43(1), 1-10. 

Nakada, M. (2004). Does Environmental Policy Necessarily Discourage Growth? Journal of 
Economics, 81(3), 249-68. 

Nordhaus, W.D. (2000). Warming the World, Economic Models of Global Warming. MA., Cambridge: 
MIT Press.  

Obstfeld, M. (1990). Intertemporal Dependence, Impatience, and Dynamics. Journal of 
Monetary Economics, 26(1), 45-75.  

Olsen, J.A. (1993). Time Preference for Health Gains: An Empirical Investigation. Health 
Economics, 2(3), 257-65.  

Ono, T. (2002). The Effects of Emission Permits on Growth and the Environment. Environmental and 
Resources Economics, 21(1), 75-87. 



24 

 

Ono, T. (2003). Environmental Tax Policy and Long-Run Economic Growth. Japanese Economic 
Review, 54(4), 202-17. 

Orphanides, A., & Solow, R. (1990). Money, Inflation and Growth. In B. Friedman, & F. Hahn 
(Eds.) Handbook of Monetary Economics. North-Holland: Amsterdam.  

Palivos, T., Wang, P., & Zhang, J. (1997). On the Existence of Balanced Equilibrium. 
International Economic Review, 38(1), 205-24.  

Pearson, P.J. (1994). Energy, Externalities and Environmental Quality: Will Development Cure the Ills 
It Creates? Energy Studies Review, 6(3), 199-216. 

Persson, T., & Svensson, L. (1985). Current Account Dynamics and the Terms of Trade: 
Harberger-Laursen-Metzler Two Generations Later. Journal of Political Economy, 93(1), 
43-65. 

Plourde, G.C. (1972). A Model of Waste Accumulation and Disposal. Canadian Journal of Economics, 
5(1), 119-125. 

Pollak, R. (1970). Habit Formation and Dynamic Demand Functions. Journal of Political 
Economy, 78(4), 745-63. 

Prieur, F. (2009). The Environmental Kuznets Curve in a World of Irreversibility. Economic Theory, 
40(1), 57-90. 

Ravn, M., Schmitt-Grohe, S., & Uribe, M. (2006). Deep Habits. Review of Economic Studies, 
73(1), 195-218. 

Repetto, R. (1987). The Policy Implications of Non-Convex Environmental Damages: A Smog Control 
Case. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 14(1), 13-29 

Selden, T.M., & Song, D. (1995). Neoclassical Growth, the J Curve for Abatement and the 
Inverted U Curve for Pollution. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 
29(2), 162-68.  

Sheldon, G. (1997). Molding Japanese Minds: The State in Everyday Life. Princeton NJ: 
Princeton University Press. 

Sheldon, G. (1998). Fashioning a Culture of Diligence and Thrift: Savings and Frugality 
Campaigns in Japan, 1990-1931. Honolulu: University of Hawaii Press.  

Shi, S., & Epstein, L.G. (1993). Habits and Time Preference. International Economic Review, 
34(1), 61-84. 

Shoda, Y., Mischel, W., & Peake, P.K. (1990). Predicting Adolescent Cognitive and Self-
Regulatory Competencies from Preschool Delays of Gratification: Identifying Diagnostic 
Conditions. Developmental Psychology, 26(6), 978-86.   

Smithin, J. (2004). Controversies in Monetary Economies. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.  
Stern, D.I. (2004). The Rise and Fall of the Environmental Kuznets Curve. World Development, 

32(8), 1419-39.  
Stern, M.L. (2006). Endogeneous Time Preference and Optimal Growth. Economic Theory, 

29(1), 49-70. 
Sundaresan, S.M. (1989). Intertemporally Dependent Preferences and the Volatility of 

Consumption and Wealth. Review of Financial Studies, 2(1), 73-89. 
Tsurumi, T., & Managi, S. (2010). Decomposition of the Environmental Kuznets Curve: Scale, 

Technique, and Composition Effects. Environmental Economics and Policy Studies, 11(1), 
19-36. 

Uzawa, H. (1968). Time Preference, the Consumption Function, and Optimum Asset Holdings. 
In J.N. Wolfe (Ed.) Value, Capital and Growth: Papers in Honor of Sir John Hicks. 
Chicago: Aldine.  

Zhang, W.B. (1993). A Woman’s Labor Participation and Economic Growth: Creativity, 
Knowledge Utilization and Family Preference. Economics Letters, 42(4), 105-10. 



25 

 

Zhang, W.B. (2011). Environmental Policy and Pollution Dynamics in an Economic Growth 
Model. Modern Economy, 2(2), 233-41. 

Zhang, W.B. (2012). Habits, Saving Propensity, and Economic Growth. Scientific Bulletin - 
Economic Sciences, 11(2), 3-15.