TX_1~AT/TX_2~AT International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues ISSN: 2146-4138 available at http: www.econjournals.com International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues, 2021, 11(6), 1-8. International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues | Vol 11 • Issue 6 • 2021 1 The Impact of the Outward and Inward FDI on Global Value Chains Hang Su, Yao Fu* College of International Economics and Trade, Dongbei University of Finance and Economics, Dalian, China. *Email: fylinda9441@163.com Received: 16 August 2021 Accepted: 17 October 2021 DOI: https://doi.org/10.32479/ijefi.11950 ABSTRACT What kind of trade agreements should a country choose? Regional trade agreements, multilateral trade agreements, or both? What’s the role of a country’s outward foreign direct investment (OFDI) and foreign direct investment (FDI) in its participation and position in global value chains (GVCs)? Is a country’s research and development spending conducive to breaking the “low-end locking” of FDI? Based on the World Input-Output Tables (WIOTs) released in 2016, this paper computes the indicators of GVC participation and position and identifies the feature of the production division, providing a reference for promoting regional and multilateral trade agreements. This paper uses feasible generalized least squares (FGLS) and system generalized method of moments (SYS-GMM) to examine the impact of a country’s outward and inward FDI on its GVC participation and position. The empirical results imply that a country’s OFDI promotes its GVC participation and fosters its upgrading within industries in GVCs, while FDI inhibits the upgrading of GVCs, though it promotes a country’s GVC participation. In addition, a country’s research and development spending can be conducive to breaking the “low-end locking” effect of FDI. Keywords: Outward Foreign Direct Investment, Inward Foreign Direct Investment, Global Value Chains, World Input-Output Tables, Feasible Generalized Least Squares JEL Classifications: C33, F21 1. INTRODUCTION Global value chains (GVCs) are a powerful driver of productivity growth, job creation, and increased living standards. GVCs give an impetus to development and growth (Humphrey and Schmitz, 2002). How countries engage with GVCs determines how much they benefit from them. With GVC-driven development, countries generate growth by moving to higher-value-added tasks and by embedding more technology and know-how in all their agriculture, manufacturing, and services production. In order to benefit from value chain participation, countries are also supposed to put in place the right kind of trade and investment policies and seize the opportunity to leap-frog their development process. The GVC position and participation of countries are increasingly linked to the ability to conduct more and better outward foreign direct investment (OFDI) and attract higher quality foreign direct investment (FDI) (Amendolagine et al., 2019; Martínez-Galán et al., 2019). Given the booming of integrated production systems spanning several countries and the application of advanced technology and sophisticated skills in international production, it is important for countries to conduct OFDI and attract high quality FDI, which contributes to the optimal allocation of production factors in global markets and the upgrading of GVCs. In fostering the upgrading of global value chains, FDI plays a positive role, while it can also play a negative role due to its “low-end locking” effect. This paper examines the effect of FDI on global value chains and introduces the interaction between FDI and research and development spending to figure out whether a country’s research and development spending is conducive to breaking the “low-end locking” effect of FDI and raising a country’s position in the global value chains. This paper also examines the effect of OFDI on global value chains and sheds This Journal is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License Su and Fu: The Impact of the Outward and Inward FDI on Global Value Chains International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues | Vol 11 • Issue 6 • 20212 lights on the ways a country promotes its global value chain participation and fosters its upgrading within industries in global value chains. The remaining part of the study is structured as follows: Section 2 presents a review of the literature. The analytical framework and data sources are discussed in Section 3. Section 4 presents results and discussion, and the final Section 5 concludes. 2. LITERATURE REVIEW There is considerable literature on the impact of a country’s OFDI on its industrial upgrading, and some suggest that as one of the determinants of OFDI, the technology-seeking objective enables enterprises conducting OFDI to seek the advanced technologies and strategic resources which can not be obtained in their domestic markets (Deng, 2007), thus enhancing their technological strength and further promoting the domestic industrial upgrading (Neven et al., 1996; Wu and Huang, 1997), while some analyze the reverse technology spillover effect of OFDI (Branstetter, 2000; Pottelsberghe and Lichtenberg, 2001; Zhao and Liu, 2008). The notion of reverse technology spillovers of OFDI put forward by Kogut and Chang (1991) is different from the technology- seeking effect illustrated above, as reverse technology spillover emphasizes the potential and intangible influence of countries with technological advantages on the technology transfer in the investment, during which process the enterprises conducting OFDI often do not have to pay the cost of technology learning. Kogut and Chang put forward this notion by studying Japanese companies’ investments in the United States. It argues that the reverse technology spillover effect of OFDI can also increase the total factor productivity, promote exports, improve the innovation of enterprises, and contribute to their technological progress (Mao and Xu, 2014). Focusing on the role of direct investment in the upgrading of global value chains which can be quantified based on non-competitive input-output tables1, Li and Zhang (2017), and Yang and Li (2018) measure the GVCs and find that there is a positive effect of direct investment on a country’s position in the global value chains. Compared with the export complexity index and the vertical specialization share (VSS), the KPWW2 based on non-competitive input-output tables further divides a country’s domestic value- added into additional components that reveal the destination of a country’s exported value added, including its own value-added that returns home in its imports. However, OFDI also has a “crowding-out effect,” causing a decrease in the domestic investment and having a negative impact on domestic technological progress brought about by investments. 1 Different from the competitive input-output table, the intermediate products of the non-competitive input-output tables are distinguished according to the source (export and domestic production). 2 Koopman, R., Powers, W., Wang, Z. (2010), Give Credit Where Credit Is Due-Tracing Value Added in Global Production Chains. National Bureau of Economic Research. The KPWW method is named using the capital letter of the authors’ names of the above mentioned paper. In addition, the technology gap between enterprises in some cases is too large to make a reverse technology spillover play a part. For these two reasons, the effect of the reverse technology spillover of OFDI on technology upgrading may not be obvious or significant. FDI can raise the position of a country’s manufacturing industry in global value chain by increasing the inflow of foreign intermediate products, but FDI may also hinder the upgrading of manufacturing in global value chain through the competitive effect of imported intermediate products and the low-end locking effect (Tang and Zhang, 2017). Based on the literature above, the role of the outward and inward FDI in the upgrading of GVCs is a mixed one, and the evidence is not adequate on the impact of outward and inward FDI on the global value chain participation. This paper examines the effect of outward and inward FDI on global value chains and also presents whether a country’s research and development spending is conducive to breaking the “low-end locking” effect of FDI and raising a country’s position in the global value chains. 3. DATA AND METHODOLOGY 3.1. GVC Indicators Based on the decomposition of gross exports, Koopman et al. (2010) constructs indicators that imply a country’s global value chain participation and position, namely the GVC participation index and the GVC position index. The GVC participation index is defined as follows: GVc_participation = (IV+FV)/E (1) Where Gvc_participation denotes a country’s participation in global value chain production networks. IV is the indirect domestic value added, FV is the foreign value added, and E denotes total exports. The indirect domestic value added in a country’s total exports can be defined as (I) in the Table 1. Gvc_position = ln(1+IV/E)−ln(1+FV/E) (2) Where Gvc_position denotes a country’s position in global value chain production networks. The GVC position index indicates the gap between a country’s indirect value-added exports and foreign value-added exports. The higher the index, the more intermediate goods the country exports to the rest of the world, indicating that the country is likely to be in the upstream of the global value chain. It can be noted that the GVC indicators computed above imply a country’s position and participation in GVCs, but they can’t tell whether the GVCs the countries participate in tend to be “regional” or “global.” The index constructed by Los et al. (2015) indicates whether the value chain is featured by the regional production division or the global production division, based on which it can be implied that whether a country should promote regional or multilateral trade agreements in order to increase its welfare. If the value chain is dominated by the regional production division, regional trade agreements are a better choice to help improve welfare under the value chain trade. If the value chain is dominated by a global one, a multilateral trade Su and Fu: The Impact of the Outward and Inward FDI on Global Value Chains International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues | Vol 11 • Issue 6 • 2021 3 agreement is a better choice to help improve the welfare (Los et al., 2015). Los et al. (2015) expand the method of Feenstra and Gordon (1999) and the multinational division of production, and further examine the feature of a country’s participation in the value chain based on the distribution of final product value- added among countries participated in the global production network which is represented typically by the Asia Factory, the North America Factory, and the Europe Factory (Baldwin and Lopez-Gonzales, 2013). The function is set as follows: FINO i j VA k i j, ,� � � � �� ��k (3) Where FINO(i,j) denotes the final output value of product (i,j), and VA(k)(i,j) denotes the value added by country k in its production. FVA i j VA k i j FINO i j VA j i j, , , ,� � � � �� � � � � � � �� � �� �k j k (4) Where FVA(i,j) is defined as all value added outside the country-of completion of product (i,j). FVAS i j FVA(i,j) FINO i j, / ,� � � � � (5) The importance of foreign value added is expressed as a share of all value added in production of (i,j), presented by FVAS(i,j). It should also be noted that FVA can be decomposed into regional foreign value added (RFVA) and global foreign value added (GFVA). RFVA i,j = VA(K)(i,j)-VA(j)(i,j) keregionof j � � � (6) Where RFVA(i,j) in the value of product i with country j as country-of-completion is defined as the value added contribution of the region to which country j belongs minus the contribution of the country itself. The share of RFVA in the value chain of (i,j) is defined as: RFVAS i,j =RFVA i,j /FINO(i,j)� � � � (7) The global value added is defined as the value added contribution of all countries outside the region of country j: GFVA i,j = VA(K)(i,j) keoutsideregionof j � � � (8) The share of GFVA in the value chain of (i,j) is defined by: GFVAS i,j =GFVA i,j FINO i,j� � � � � �/ (9) 3.2. Research Model GVC_POSit=β0+β1 OFDIit+γ Xit+αi+ƛt+ɛit (10) Where the subscript i denotes country and t denotes year. Dependent variable GVC_POSit represents global value chain position. OFDI (OFDIit) is employed as independent variable. Xit represents control variables, including FDI (FDIit) market size (GDPit), natural resource abundance (RESit), institutional quality (INSit), technology and innovation capacity (TECit), and human resource endowment (HRit). αi is the fixed effect of the country, ƛt controls the time trend, and ɛit is the random error term. In order to examine the impact of OFDI technology reverse spillover and FDI technology spillover on the participation and the position of global value chains, this paper introduces interaction (ODTECit) between OFDI (OFDIit) and technology and innovation capacity (TECit) on the basis of formula (10) and interaction (FDTECit) between FDI (FDIit) and technology and innovation capacity (TECit) on the basis of formula (10): GVC_POSit=β0+β1 lnOFDIit+β1 lnODTECit+γ Xit+αi+ƛt+ɛit (11) GVC_POSit=β0+β1 lnOFDIit+β1 lnFDTECit+γ Xit+αi+ƛt+ɛit (12) To examine the impact of OFDI on the global value chain participation, GVC_PARit is adopted to represent the dependent variable: GVC_PARit=β0+β1 lnOFDIit+γ Xit+αi+ƛt+ɛit (13) To examine the impact of OFDI technology reverse spillover and FDI technology spillover on the participation of global value chains, this paper introduces interaction item (ODTECit) between Table 1: Gross exports decomposition Gross exports (E) Domestic value-added Foreign value-added (FV) Domestic value-added embodied in exports of final goods and services absorbed by the direct importer Domestic value-added embodied in exports of intermediate inputs used by the direct importer to produce its domestically needed products Domestic value-added embodied in intermediate exports used by the direct importer to produce goods for third countries (I) Domestic value-added embodied in intermediate exports used by the direct importer to produce goods shipped back to source Value-added from foreign countries embodied in exports of final goods Value-added from foreign countries embodied intermediate in exports This table presents the gross exports decomposition. The decomposition method by Koopman et al. (2010) and Wang et al. (2015) is employed Su and Fu: The Impact of the Outward and Inward FDI on Global Value Chains International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues | Vol 11 • Issue 6 • 20214 OFDI (OFDIit) and technology and innovation capacity (TECit) on the basis of formula (13) and interaction item (FDTECit) between FDI (FDIit) and technology and innovation capacity (TECit) on the basis of formula (13): GVC PAR OFDI ODTEC X it it it i t it _ ln lnit � � � � � � � � � � � � � � � � � 0 1 2 (14) GVC PAR OFDI FDTEC X it it it i t it _ ln lnit � � � � � � � � � � � � � � � � � 0 1 2 (15) 3.3. Variables (1) Global value chain position (POS) and global value chain participation (PAR): Based on the gross export decomposition (Koopman et al., 2010), and the methods of Cen (2015) and Wang et al. (2015), this paper calculates the GVC participation and position indices, which are adopted to represent a country’s global value chain participation and global value chain position, respectively. (2) Outward foreign direct investment (OFDI): OFDI can be conducted to obtain strategic resources, break the “low-end locking,” and thus foster the upgrading of the value chain (Li et al., 2017). Strategic resources tend to be featured by the incompleteness of the external market, so alliance learning becomes the main way to obtain this resource (Barney, 1991). Compared to FDI, OFDI enables investors to have better access to strategic resources. This paper selects the stock of OFDI to measure OFDI, according to Liu et al. (2017). (3) Foreign direct investment (FDI): FDI can raise the position of a country’s manufacturing industry in global value chain by increasing the inflow of foreign intermediate products, but FDI may also hinder the upgrading of manufacturing in global value chain through the competitive effect of imported intermediate products and the low-end locking effect (Tang and Zhang, 2017). This paper takes the stock of foreign direct investment in various countries as the sample. (4) Market size (GDP): This paper selects a country’s GDP level as an indicator to measure the country’s market size, according to Wheeler et al. (1992). This paper uses the GDP based on the constant dollar price in 2015. (5) Human resource endowment (HR): This paper uses the secondary school enrollment rate as a measure of human resource endowment with reference to Li et al. (2018). (6) Natural resource endowment (RES): This paper measures a country’s natural resource endowment using the share of host country ore, fossil fuel and metal exports in total exports, according to Buckley et al. (2007). (7) Technology and innovation capacity (TEC): This paper uses the share of R & D costs in GDP of home country as a measure of a country’s technology and innovation capacity with reference to Chen et al. (2014). (8) Institution quality (INS): This paper uses global governance indicators including Voice and accountability (VA), Political stability and absence of violence (PV), Government effectiveness (GE), Regulatory quality (RQ), Rule of law (RL), and Control of corruption (CC) to measure institution quality on a weighted average basis (Kaufmann et al., 2012). 3.4. Data Global value chain participation and position indicators are computed based on the World Input-Output Tables (WIOTs) released in 2016. The newly released WIOTs in 2016 covers data from 56 industries in 43 economies from 2000 to 2014. The database provides data on the world’s major economies and is adopted in studies of global value chains and trade value added. The data of OFDI and FDI are collected from the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development Stat (UNCTAD). Market size (GDP) is collected from the United Nations Stats (UN). Natural resource endowment (RES) is collected from the World Bank Databank (WB). Technology and innovation capacity (TEC) and human resource endowment (HR) are collected from the UNESCO Institute for Statistics (UIS). Institution quality (INS) is calculated based on the Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI). Voice and accountability (VA), Political stability and absence of violence (PV), Government effectiveness (GE), Regulatory quality (RQ), Rule of law (RL) and Control of corruption (CC) are collected from the Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI). 4. RESULTS AND DISCUSSION 4.1. GVC Indicators Figure 1 presents the GVC position index in the year 2000 and 2014. In the year 2000, Russia stands top in the GVC position 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 R us si an F ed er at io n T he R ep ub lic o f K or ea T he U ni te d S ta te s of A m er ic a C hi na B el gi um N et he rla nd s C an ad a Ita ly G er m an y Ja pa n Fr an ce U ni te d K in gd om The GVC position index in 2000 The GVC position index in 2014 Figure 1: The GVC position index The GVC position index is calculated based on the World Input-Output Tables database (WIOTs) in 2000 and 2014. In this section, the ranking of twelve major exporting countries is presented. The twelve major exporting countries listed are collected based on the ranking in gross exports in 2013 from the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) database Su and Fu: The Impact of the Outward and Inward FDI on Global Value Chains International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues | Vol 11 • Issue 6 • 2021 5 index, followed by South Korea3, the United States, and China. It should be noted that, compared with other countries, the United States has witnessed a sharp increase in the GVC position index in 2014, making it stand at the top in the rankings in 2014. The top to low ranking of countries in GVC position index in 2000 is as follows (Figure 1): Russia, South Korea, the United States, China, Belgium, Netherlands, Canada, Italy, Germany, Japan, France, and United Kingdom. Table 2 presents the changes in the ranking of countries in GVC position index over the period 2000-2014. Countries such as China, Germany, and Netherlands have seen an increase in their GVC position indices, indicating that these countries have gained a higher GVC position in the global production network. The GVC position index of Japan, France, United Kingdom, and other countries are relatively stable, while countries including Russia, Italy, Belgium and Canada have seen declines in the GVC position. The top to low ranking of countries in GVC position index in 2014 is as follows (Table 2): Russia, South Korea, the United States, China, Belgium, Netherlands, Canada, Italy, Germany, Japan, France, and United Kingdom. The GVC indicators computed above imply a country’s position and participation in GVCs, but they can’t tell whether the GVCs the countries participate in are regionally or globally fragmenting. Table 3 shows that Belgium, Italy, China, Japan, South Korea, and Canada have seen an increase in their regional foreign value added shares in 2014, which means that the value chains of these countries are regionally fragmenting. While United Kingdom, Germany, France, Netherlands, and the United States have witnessed a decrease in their regional foreign value added shares. It should also be noted that Belgium, United Kingdom, Germany, France, Netherlands, China, Japan, Germany, and the United States have had an increasing global share of foreign added value, which means that the value chains of these countries are globally fragmenting. This trend indicates that the shares of some countries such as Belgium, China, Japan, and Germany are increasing in two ways, at both regional and global level, suggesting that it can be more complicated for these countries to decide whether to promote regional or multilateral trade agreements so as to increase their welfare. However, this feature of the GVCs of these countries can also mean that they have more opportunities and options to benefit from the production division network, although they have to take more factors into account. 4.2. Empirical Results This section discusses the empirical results. After computing GVC indicators, this paper proceeds to examine the impact of outward and inward FDI on the GVCs. Table 4 presents the description, sources of data, and descriptive statistics of the key variables employed. As the data collected in this paper is long-panel data, the two-way fixed effect model is applied according to the long-panel data model assumption. In this paper, dummy variables are introduced to control individual effects and time trends. The basic regression 3 The Republic of Korea. is estimated using feasible generalized least squares (FGLS). To solve auto-correlation of error terms, heteroskedasticity, and cross-sectional correlation problems, standard errors corrected by panels are used. Table 5a reports results for model (10), (11), and (12). In model (10), (11), and (12), the effects of OFDI and FDI on GVC positions (POS) are investigated. The results presented in columns (1), (2), and (3) show that the coefficients of OFDI are positive and statistically significant, indicating that the impact of OFDI is positive. This is in line with the expectations in theories, in which OFDI can be conducted to obtain strategic resources, break the “low-end locking,” and thus foster the upgrading of the value chain (Li and Zhang, 2017). The coefficients of FDI are statistically significant and negative, indicating the negative impact of FDI. FDI can hinder the upgrading of manufacturing in global value chain through the competitive effect of imported intermediate products as well as the low-end locking effect, although it may also raise the position of a country’s manufacturing industry in global value chain by increasing the inflow of foreign intermediate products (Tang and Zhang, 2017). The results presented in Table 5a also show that the coefficient of the interaction (ODTEC) between OFDI and TEC is positive and statistically significant, indicating that the reverse technology spillover effect of OFDI is positive. Column (3) shows that the coefficient of the interaction (FDTEC) between FDI and TEC is positive, which implies that a country’s high-tech innovation can be conducive to breaking the “low-end locking” effect of FDI, and raise a country’s global value chain position. However, this mediating effect of TEC is offset by the negative effect of FDI. The coefficients of the control variables in Table 5a are in line with expectations in theories. The impact of a country’s market size (GDP) is positive. With the expansion of a country’s economic scale, foreign exchange reserves increase, which attracts more foreign direct investment, and thus is conducive to fostering the upgrading of a country’s global value chain. The impact of natural resource endowment (RES) is positive. A country with natural resource endowment has sufficient resource to promote Table 2: The GVC position index Year 2000 2010 2014 Belgium 0.1287(5) 0.1343(5) 0.1288(6) Canada 0.0889(7) 0.0663(9) 0.0799(8) China 0.1531(4) 0.2071(3) 0.2240(3) France 0.0421(11) 0.0286(11) 0.0318(11) Germany 0.0681(9) 0.0948(7) 0.0918(7) Italy 0.0724(8) 0.0815(8) 0.0716(9) Japan 0.0558(10) 0.0397(10) 0.0392(10) Netherlands 0.1140(6) 0.0951(6) 0.1467(5) The Republic of Korea 0.1641(2) 0.2196(2) 0.2287(2) Russian Federation 0.1955(1) 0.1723(4) 0.1675(4) United Kingdom 0.0371(12) 0.0212(12) 0.0295(12) The United States of America 0.1613(3) 0.3518(1) 0.3601(1) The GVC position index is calculated based on the World Input-Output Tables database (WIOTs) over the period 2000-2014. The figures in the parentheses are the ranking of countries in the GVC position Su and Fu: The Impact of the Outward and Inward FDI on Global Value Chains International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues | Vol 11 • Issue 6 • 20216 industrial development, which gives industrial development more opportunities to focus on the advancement of technology, and aim at technology rather than resources when conducting OFDI. This is conducive to raising the position in global value chains. The impact of a country’s ability of high-tech innovation (TEC) is positive. The improvement of technology and innovation can Table 3: Regional and global shares of FVAS (%) Year Belgium Canada China France Germany Italy 2000 2014 2000 2014 2000 2014 2000 2014 2000 2014 2000 2014 FVAS 46 54.4 52.4 50.6 52.2 55.4 46.7 46.1 48.2 50.7 48.7 50.5 RFVAS 24 28.2 27.8 28.3 25.3 26.8 27.1 20.1 25.5 21.8 23.8 27.2 GFVAS 22 26.2 24.6 22.3 26.9 28.6 19.6 26.1 22.7 28.9 24.9 23.3 Japan Netherlands United Kingdom The United States of America South Korea Year 2000 2014 2000 2014 2000 2014 2000 2014 2000 2014 FVAS 46.7 48.8 52.2 57 47.6 45.3 44 43 53.8 57.6 RFVAS 24.1 25.7 28.8 27.6 27.8 22.1 25.3 23.2 25.7 29.3 GFVAS 22.6 23.1 23.4 2 9.4 19.8 23.2 18.7 19.8 28.1 28.3 The index is calculated based on the World Input-Output Tables database (WIOTs) in 2000 and 2014 Table 4: Description, sources of data, and descriptive statistics Variable Description Source Mean S.D. Min Max PAR Global value chain participation WIOTs 0.7921 0.2408 0.6942 0.8457 POS Global value chain position WIOTs 0.1354 0.1082 0.1109 0.3728 OFDI OFDI UNCTAD 14.0987 1.3126 8.7918 15.7489 FDI FDI UNCTAD 12.8978 1.0891 10.0984 16.9732 GDP Market size UN 17.3524 1.0972 14.9321 18.6140 RES Natural resource endowment WB 13.6446 16.9873 1.7631 32.1879 TEC Technology and innovation capacity UIS 1.9821 0.6932 0.6137 3.9786 HR Human resource endowment UIS 1.7872 1.8318 0.4213 3.7341 INS Institution quality WGI 0.6933 0.2571 0.5324 0.8907 VA Voice and accountability WGI 0.7781 0.2141 0.5229 0.9842 PV Political stability and absence of violence WGI 0.6382 0.1627 0.4772 0.8760 GE Government effectiveness WGI 0.7973 0.3214 0.3017 0.9971 RQ Regulatory quality WGI 0.7991 0.2179 0.5152 0.9816 RL Rule of law WGI 0.7980 0.1057 0.4931 0.9074 CC Corruption control WGI 0.6701 0.1844 0.5122 0.9891 The data are collected from the World Input-Output Tables (WIOTs), the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development Stat (UNCTAD), the United Nations Stats (UN), the World Bank Databank (WB), the UNESCO Institute for Statistics (UIS), and the Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI) Table 5a: Basic regression results Variables (1) (2) (3) POS POS POS OFDI 0.105*** 0.107*** 0.106*** (3.94) (4.41) (4.12) FDI −0.124*** −0.122*** −0.131*** (−4.71) (−4.95) (−4.92) GDP 0.296*** 0.301*** 0.270*** (5.81) (4.52) (5.77) RES 0.314*** 0.320*** 0.311*** (5.98) (5.73) (5.78) TEC 0.231*** 0.219*** 0.240*** (3.62) (2.76) (2.51) INS −0.113*** −0.108*** −0.117*** (−9.76) (−9.87) (−10.12) HR −0.041 −0.029 −0.031 (−2.01) (−1.96) (−1.83) ODTEC 0.067*** (2.26) FDTEC 0.082*** (3.16) _cons 17.101*** 16.291*** 17.210*** (8.17) (7.90) (8.20) N 210 210 210 t statistics in parentheses. * P<0.05,**P<0.01,***P<0.001 Table 5b: Basic regression results Variables (4) (5) (6) PAR PAR PAR OFDI 0.098*** 0.091*** 0.092*** (2.16) (1.97) (2.01) FDI 0.081*** 0.079*** 0.083*** (2.24) (2.31) (2.27) GDP −0.063*** −0.065*** −0.064*** (−2.51) (−2.47) (−2.53) RES −0.030*** −0.027*** −0.029*** (−1.74) (−1.81) (−1.70) TEC 0.014*** 0.016*** 0.013*** (1.34) (2.02) (1.41) INS 0.020 0.032 0.021 (1.03) (1.42) (1.06) HR −0.042 −0.038 −0.041 (−2.03) (−1.96) (−2.10) ODTEC 0.023*** (2.26) FDTEC 0.031*** (1.91) _cons 2.327*** 2.218*** 2.384*** (11.57) (11.41) (12.31) N 210 210 210 t statistics in parentheses. * P<0.05,**P<0.01,***P<0.001 Su and Fu: The Impact of the Outward and Inward FDI on Global Value Chains International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues | Vol 11 • Issue 6 • 2021 7 increase the value added of its export products, and foster the upgrading of global value chains. In Table 5b, columns (4), (5), and (6) report the results of the effects of OFDI and FDI on GVC participation (PAR). The results presented in Table 5b show that the coefficients of OFDI and FDI are both significant and positive, which is in line with Li et al. (2017). In columns (5) and (6), the coefficients of the interaction are significant and positive, which implies that the ability of technology and innovation of a country has a positive mediating effect on a country’s embedding in global value chain. It can be noted that the coefficient signs of the core variables remain the same when introducing control variables. 4.3. Robustness test System generalized method of moments (SYS-GMM) is applied to test the robustness which can be used to solve endogeneity. The AR(1) and AR(2) test and Sargan test results all imply that the SYS-GMM is effective. Based on the basic regression model, the lagged variables are introduced. Table 6a presents the results which imply that the coefficients of the core variables basically remain the same. Table 6a reports robustness test results for model (1), (2), and (3), in which the effects of OFDI and FDI on GVC positions (POS) are investigated. The results presented in Table 6a show that the coefficients of OFDI and FDI are statistically significant, indicating that the impact of OFDI is positive, while the impact of FDI is negative. The results presented in Table 6a also show that the coefficients of ODTEC and FDTEC are positive and statistically significant, indicating that the reverse technology spillover effect of OFDI and FDI is positive, which implies that a country’s high- tech innovation can be conducive to raising a country’s global value chain position. In Table 6b, columns (4), (5), and (6) report the results of the effects of OFDI and FDI on GVC participation (PAR), which indicate that the coefficients of OFDI and FDI are both significant and positive. It can be noted that the coefficients of ODTEC and FDTEC are significant and positive, indicating that the mediating effect of the ability of technology and innovation of a country is positive. 5. CONCLUSION A country’s OFDI not only promotes its global value chain participation but also fosters its upgrading within industries in global value chains, while FDI inhibits the upgrading of global value chains, although FDI can promote a country’s participation in the international fragmentation of production. The coefficient of interaction between a country’s FDI and its technology and innovation capacity is positive, which indicates that a country’s technology and innovation capacity has a positive mediating effect which is conducive to breaking the “low-end locking” effect of FDI and can raise a country’s position in the global value chains. The shares of FVAS of some countries such as Belgium, China, Japan, and Germany are increasing in two ways, at both regional and global level, suggesting that it can be more complicated for these countries to decide whether to promote regional or multilateral trade agreements so as to increase their welfare. However, this feature of the GVCs of these countries can also mean that they have more opportunities and options to benefit from the production division network, although they have to take more factors into account. Table 6a: Robustness test results Variables (1) (2) (3) POS POS POS L.POS 0.812*** 0.811*** 0.814*** (5.32) (4.97) (5.96) OFDI 0.072*** 0.078*** 0.074*** (1.88) (2.21) (2.03) FDI −0.083*** −0.084*** −0.079*** (−1.93) (−1.81) (−2.72) GDP 0.086*** 0.081*** 0.085*** (2.26) (1.52) (1.81) RES 0.051*** 0.053*** 0.046*** (1.23) (1.31) (1.21) TEC 0.060*** 0.055*** 0.059*** (1.54) (1.47) (1.50) INS −0.026*** −0.021*** −0.024*** (−1.12) (−1.01) (−1.03) HR −0.027 −0.022 −0.034 (−1.21) (−1.32) (−1.47) ODTEC 0.057*** (1.71) FDTEC 0.062*** (1.83) AR (2) test p values 0.281 0.279 0.296 Sargan test p values 0.116 0.121 0.113 cons _ 3.247 3.441 3.423 (1.17) (1.61) (1.58) N 180 180 180 t statistics in parentheses. * P<0.05,**P<0.01,***P<0.001 Table 6b: Robustness test results Variables (4) (5) (6) PAR PAR PAR L.PAR 0.863*** 0.858*** 0.861*** (5.58) (5.47) (5.63) OFDI 0.077*** 0.081*** 0.073*** (1.57) (1.72) (1.24) FDI 0.080*** 0.086*** 0.095*** (1.84) (1.91) (2.02) GDP −0.053*** −0.051*** −0.063*** (−1.31) (−2.01) (−2.16) RES −0.061*** −0.072*** −0.069*** (−1.73) (−1.81) (−1.65) TEC 0.044*** 0.050*** 0.047*** (1.33) (1.53) (1.51) INS 0.014*** 0.012*** 0.015*** (1.01) (1.44) (1.74) HR −0.103 −−0.051 −0.070 (−1.28) (−1.06) (−1.12) ODTEC 0.096*** (1.82) FDTEC 0.089*** (1.74) AR (2) test p values 0.173 0.178 0.165 Sargan test p values 0.216 0.232 0.224 _cons 1.782 1.931 2.109 (1.58) (1.72) (2.98) N 180 180 180 t statistics in parentheses. * P<0.05,**P<0.01,***P<0.001 Su and Fu: The Impact of the Outward and Inward FDI on Global Value Chains International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues | Vol 11 • Issue 6 • 20218 REFERENCES Amendolagine, V., Presbitero, A., Rabellotti, R., Sanfilippo, M. (2019), Local sourcing in developing countries: The role of foreign direct investments and global value chains. World Economy, 113, 73-88. Baldwin, R., Lopez-Gonzales, J. (2013), Supply-chain trade: A portrait of global patterns and several testable hypotheses, World Economy, 38(11), 141-142. Barney, J.B. (1991), Firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. Academy of Management Review, 17(1), 99-120. Branstetter, L. (2000), Is Foreign Direct Investments a Channel of Knowledge Spillovers? Evidence from Japan’s FDI in the United States. NBER Working Paper No. 8015. Buckley, P.J., Clegg, L.J., Cross, A.R., Liu, X., Voss, H., Zhang, P. (2007), The determinants of Chinese outward foreign direct investment. Journal of International Business Studies, 38, 499-518. Cen, L.J. (2015), The division of labor and trade status of China in global production network based on TiVA data and GVC index. International Trade Issues, 1(3), 13-131. Chen, Y., Zhai, R.R., Guo, N.S. (2014), A study on the determinants of China’s foreign direct investment based on multivariate distance perspective. Systems Engineering Theory and Practice, (11), 2760-2771. Deng, P. (2007), Investing for strategic resources and its rationale: The case of outward FDI from Chinese companies. Business Horizons, 50(1), 71-81. Feenstra, R.C., Gordon, H.H. (1999), The Impact of outsourcing and high technology capital on wages: Estimates for the U.S., 1979-1990. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 907-940. Humphrey, J., Schmitz, H. (2002), How does insertion in GVCs affect upgrading in industrial clusters? Regional Studies, 36 (9), 1017-1027. Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., Mastruzzi, M. (2012), The Worldwide Governance Indicators: A Summary of Methodology, Data and Analytical Issues. World Bank Working Paper No.5430. Kogut, B., Chang, S.J. (1991), Technological capabilities and Japanese foreign direct investment in the United States. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 3, 401-413. Koopman, R., Powers, W., Wang, Z. (2010), Give credit where Credit is Due: Tracing Value Added in Global Production Chains. National Bureau of Economic Research. Li, C., Zhang, C. (2017), China’s OFDI and GVC upgrading in manufacturing. Economic Issues Exploration, 11, 114-126. Li, L., Liu, B., Wang, X.X. (2017), FDI spillover effect and China’s GVC participation. World Economic Research, 4, 58-135. Liu, H.Y., Liao, Q.M. (2017), Contribution of China’s OFDI to domestic manufacturing employment.World Economic Research, 56, 67-135. Los, B., Marcel, P.T., Gaaitzen, J.V. (2015), How global are global value chains? A new approach to measure international fragmentation. Journal of Regional Science, 55(1), 66-92. Mao. Q.L., Xu, J.Y. (2014), Does OFDI by Chinese enterprises promote enterprise innovation. World Economy, 37(8), 98-125. Martínez-Galán, E., Martínez-Galán, E., Fontoura, M. (2019), Global value chains and inward foreign direct investment in the 2000s. World Economy, 42(1), 175-196. Neven, D., Siotis, G. (1996), Technology sourcing and FDI in the EC: An empirical evaluation. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 14(5), 543-560. Pottelsberghe, B., Lichtenberg, F. (2001), Does foreign direct investment transfer technology across borders? The Review of Economics and Statistics, 83(3), 490-497. Tang, Y.H., Zhang, P.Y. (2017), FDI, GVC embedding and export domestic value added. Statistical Study, 34(4), 36-49. Wang, Z., Wei, S.J., Zhu K.F. (2015), General trade computation: Official trade statistics and measurement of global value chains. Chinese Social Sciences, 9, 108-127. Wheeler, D. (1992), International investment location decision: The case of US firms, Journal of International Economics, 33, 57-76. Wu, B., Huang, T. (1997), A new analysis model of foreign direct investment. Economic Research, (7), 25-31. Yang, R.F., Li, N.N. (2018), Status of industrial agglomeration, FDI and manufacturing global value chain. International Trade Issues, (6), 68-81. Zhao, W., Liu, L. (2008), Outward direct investment and R&D spillovers: China’s Case. In: Conference Proceeding of “Emerging Multinationals” Outward Foreign Direct Investment from Emerging and Developing Economies.