404 not found p263501coll9_10.pdf a typology of communication strategies for corporate advocacy annette n. shelby school of business administration georgetown university washington, d. c. that american business has a poor public image has been well documented.[l] further, continuing attacks on business in the mass media have no doubt contributed to the negative image. increasingly, organizations are coming to grips with the image problem and are responding, particularly to media attacks. corporate advocacy advertising, for example, has received widespread attention.[2] whatever the medium used and whether by choice or necessity, corporate spokespersons are becoming advocates for their companies' actions and positions. though akin to public relations, advocacy goes beyond image building to make a case for, support, or defend the corporate point of view, policies, and actions. put simply, the focus of advocacy-whether in speeckmaking or op-ed advertising-is argument.[3] communication strategies provide the framework or structure for argument, prescribe the advocate's options, and thus limit the rhetorical choices to be made. whereas arguments are situation-specific, strategies may be imposed on the conflict independent of content. strategies are thus more universal and reflect policy decisions. this paper presents a conceptual analysis of communication strategies available to the corporate spokesperson. it sets out a typology and describes advantages and disadvantages of the alternatives. nine types of response patterns are identified here: ignore the attack, withdraw or avoid, sleight-ofhand, confrontation, redefinition of the issues, present company position, confirmation, coalition-building, and proactive advocacy. ignoring attacks a traditional way of dealing with hostility toward an organization is to ignore publicly attacks that are made. since refusing to take notice of an attack can minimize conflict while responding may escalate a controversy, the strategy is sometimes useful in handling assaults on the organization. it does "take two to fight." a disadvantage of the strategy, however, is that silence is a message, which is likely interpreted as relinquishment or guilt. if -33_ charges go unanswered, they are often assumed to be true. by not answering attacks, the organization may acquiesce to its detractors and their claims. withdrawl or avoidance a second strategy useful to advocacy is withdrawl from or avoidance of attack or argument. though acknowledging that an attack has been made, the advocate chooses not to respond to it. typical withdrawl or avoidance responses include: "no comment"; "we have no official response to that at this time"; "the president (or whomever) is unavailable for comment." advantages of the withdrawal/avoidance strategy are similar to those of ignoring attacks made on the organization. the advocate does not likely escalate the debate or risk putting the organization on the record, particularly in areas that are extremely sensitive for political or legal reasons. disadvantages of the strategy must also be carefully weighed, howev.er. the i'no comment" response may suggest guilt or be interpreted as corporate arrogance, which would have important negative public relations implications. finally-and perhaps most crucially-the withdrawl/avoidance strategy allows the attacker to draw the issues and present evidence unchallenged. sleight-of-hand sleight-of-hand suggests evading or side-stepping the issue. typical propaganda techniques fall within the rubric of sleight-of-hand: ad hominem argument or namecalling (shifting the emphasis to the person rather than the argument); bandwagon (everyone is doing it); shifting ground (moving to another and irrelevant issue); hasty generalization (drawing conclusions based on incomplete or unrepresentative data); and emotionalism. the primary characteristic of sleight-of-hand is that it obscures the major issue or point of contention. corporate advocates often use sleight-of-hand to side-step indefensible positions. the strategy allows the advocate to focus the discussion on a secondary, perhaps minor or irrelevant issue or fact. thus, it may diffuse or minimize conflict. the strategy has a number of negative ramifications, however. for one thing, it is ethically questionable. not only does it avoid the issue, but also it can be personally damaging (as in namecalling or ad hominem argument), incorrect (as in hasty generalization), or misleading (as in shifting ground). beyond the ethical implications, the strategy is potentially dangerous to use since it only shifts emphasis temporarily. after the sleight-of-hand magic tricks are over, the attacker's position remains substantively unchallenged. particularly if the issue has been generated by or publicized in the mass media, it will likely resurface-often with even stronger force because of the superficiality or irrelevance of its initial defense. _34_ confrontation another strategy organizations are beginning to use to counter attacks leveled against them is to challenge facts and arguments of the opposition or present counter arguments to justify their own position. the successfulness of the confrontative strategy depends on two things: whether the facts and arguments do, in fact, support the organization's position; and, whether the organization can gain access to the necessary media in order to get a hearing for its case. corporations have limited access to the mass media, particularly to television and radio. though companies may buy advertising space in the print media, the national networks prohibit corporate advertising that is issue oriented. some organizations are investigating alternative channels through which to send their messages. for example, a number of organizations are providing to schools educational materials that include the company viewpoint. citizens' lobbies are springing up which are protesting such information dissemination. if organizations are able to get access to necessary media and if their arguments and evidence are convincing to their audiences, they may establish credibility for their position. further, they may undermine their adversaries, particularly when they are able to prove opposing arguments to be incorrect and evidence factually inaccurate. the challenge, of course, is to disprove the entire case of the opposition. one argument left standing can undermine the corporate case or position. redefining the issues redefining the issues differs from shifting ground in that redefinition aims at a clear understanding and examination of the issues, not an effort to sidestep them. sometimes issues are drawn in a biased or prejorative manner that renders counteragument unproductive, if not impossible. in such cases, the advocate may choose to redefine the issue or place it into perspective through comparison. redefining the issue may mean exposing hidden assumptions or agendas. it may focus on determining the real question being asked or the underlying objection being raised. often the actual conflict is obscured by secondary or highly emotional issues. redefinition may be a useful way to uncover the basic point of controversy on its content level. at other times, it calls for separating multiple questions. occasionally it requires asking questions for clarification. the major advantage of redefining the issues is that it can lead to a clearer understanding of what the major points of contention are. further, it tends to focus the controversy on content issues rather than emotional ones. the major disadvantage of the strategy is that it may result in even greater polarization. by clearly drawing the parameters of the conflict, the advocate _35may leave the opposition little maneuverability and may force a commitment to a particular position. presenting the company position presenting the company position may supplement or serve as an alternative to the strategies of confrontation or redefining the issues. when presenting the company position, the advocate sets out that position point by point, explains reasons for the corporate perspective, and documents company claims. sometimes the advocate will choose to examine the relative advantages and disadvantages of the company position, a strategy that can be effective in increasing credibility with negative audiences. advantages of the "present the company position'! strategy are that the advocate has the opportunity to draw the issues and lay the framework! if not ground rules, for debate. further, by taking the offensive, the spokesperson is more likely to argue the company position from a positive point of view. the major disadvantage of the strategy is that it tends to lack credibility, particularly with negative audiences. the corporate advocate is expected to subscribe to and present the company "line.'! that "line" is therefore apt to be suspect. confirmation the strategy of confirmation agrees to the accuracy or legitimacy of the critic's attack but then shifts to a positive discussion of the company's position. a typical confirming response is, "yes, pollution was a problem; but we've invested heavily in clean-up activities. this is what we're doing.... " "you're right, we have had problems in that area" confirms the criticism. "but we're doing something about it" allows the advocate to shift the discussion to the positive things the company is doing. advantages of confirmation as a strategy are that it does not place the advocate in the untenable position of defending the indefensible, and it gives the company spokesperson credibility as a trustworthy source. the major disadvantage is that the strategy puts the company on record as agreeing it has done something that is improper. particularly when legal issues are involved, that position may be dangerous. coalition~building another useful strategy for advocacy is to build coalitions either with organizations with like concerns or, on occasion, with adversaries. the critical factor in coalition-building is to identify commonalities between the organization and those with whom it would seek to work. the tobacco industry has had great success building coalitions with other farm interests _36_ in influencing legislation. labor and management have worked from common goals in attempting to rebuild the american automobile industry. the major advantage to coalition-building is that by focusing on agreement, polarization may be minimized. the major disadvantage is that disagreement may be forced below the surface where it can fester and grow. coalition-building will be successful to the extent that common goals are more silent than the individual goals of either party involved. proactive approach historically, american corporations have felt little need to explain themselves or their policies to the public, even in the face of fierce antimonopolistic and trade union pressures. the consumer movement, however, along with the influence of the mass media's reporting on issues of public concern, has brought the corporation's business into the public's living rooms. consequently, american business is being required to justify its policies. corporate representatives are often unprepared for the hostility and conflict they encounter. they do not anticipate the public uproar that accompanies controversial policy decisions and have little experience and less confidence in dealing with the underlying value conflicts that erupt. in their efforts to defend their organizations, they are often frustrated, confused, and misunderstood. an alternative to the traditional defensive, reactive approaches to advocacy is a proactive strategy that suggest the necessity of corporate intervention before opposition has crystallized or become vocal. the proactive approach-both preemptive and preventative-involves a minimum of four steps: 1) anticipate questions likely to be raised about the organization and its policies; 2) research the facts, precedents, and implications of corporate policy; 3) develop a public relations and advocacy campaign before systematic and damaging attacks begin; and 4) monitor the results of the campaign. the advocacy plan should be well conceived and comprehensively developed. it should identify the audience to be targeted, specify commonalities between the organization and its potential critics, adapt its message to the targeted audience, determine media to be used, develop a timetable, and include plans for implementation. the advantages of such a proactive stance are obvious: the image problems minimized; the arguments answered before they are allowed to escalate into major points of controversy; the advocate's favorable position gained from drawing the issues. the major disadvantage of the approach is that the organization may invite criticism and argument that may not have otherwise been a priority for its critics. a final caveat: the strategies an organization chooses for advocacy depend to a great extent on the managerial style and orientation of the organization's chief decision-makers. some executive officers are sensitive to the _37_ need for good corporate public relations and support proactive advocacy campaigns. others view advocacy as a stop-gap, "putting out fires'! role. ultimately, the advocate can do little without support from the top. and that is a managerial policy decision. references 1. the opinion research corporation, cited in david liff, mary o'connor, and clarke bruno, corporate advertising: the business response to changing public attitudes (washington d.c.: investor responsibility research center, october, 1980). 2. ethics and advocacy advertising, business ethics report (bentley college, waltham, ma: center for business ethics, 1978); s. prakash sethi, " advocacy advertising in america," keynote address at advocacy advertising conference, toronto, november 25, 1981; s. prakash sethi, advocacy advertising and large corporations (lexington, ma: d.c. health, 1977). 3. david thomas, "corporate advocacy: development in forensics," speech communication association national convention, anaheim, ca, november, 1981; robert l. heath, "corporate advocacy: an application of speech communication perspectives and skills-and more,!' communication education, 19 (september 1980), pp. 370-1. _38_ a typology of communication strategies for corporate advocacy volume 40(1) p.i from the editor dear readers: as the journal of business strategies enters its 40th year of publication, we are proud to look back at our rich history, and excited to look forward into the future. i would like to share some highlights from the last year: 2022 was our first full year operating on the new open journal systems platform, using the new url http://business-strategies.org, as well as our first year operating as an open access journal. the move towards an open access online publication has started to pay large dividends already. between january 2022 and december 2022, our total monthly readership (i.e. downloads of full text articles) has increased five-fold! we expect that the increase in visibility will continue to attract high quality research to be published in the journal. the increase in readership was accompanied by an increase in manuscript submissions as well. as we continued to improve the quality and efficiency of our doubleblind peer review process, we can summarize our 2022 activity as follows: days to first editorial decision: 13 average days to accept: 102 desk reject rate: 47% after review reject rate: 41% acceptance rate: 12% in order to continue the upward trajectory of the journal, we are implementing several major changes, starting in 2023 with volume 40: first, the journal’s appearance has received a major face-lift. we have updated the layout of published articles, as well as adopted a new logo that now appears in the top right corner of every title page. the new layout design of the published articles is a modern and professional approach that signals the quality of our publication in an online environment. second, –and most significantly– we are moving to a “publish-as-you-go” scheme. this means that we no longer wait to accumulate several articles into an issue before publication. rather, articles are continuously added to current issues as they are accepted and complete the production process. as an online publication, we are free of the constraints imposed by print publishing, and publishing articles on-the-go will reduce publication lag for our authors, and make the newest research available to our readers more quickly. we are looking forward to an exciting future for the journal of business strategies. i encourage you to submit your work to us at http://business-strategies.org, and hope that you will encourage your colleagues to do the same. best wishes, christian raschke, editor http://business-strategies.org http://business-strategies.org problem loan identification and management (plim) system bart p. hartman and vincent c. brenner department of accounting louisiana state university baton rouge, louisiana reed f. bilbray american bank and trust company baton rouge, louisiana gradual deregulation has increased the pressure on financial institutio~s to produce profits once easily obtained in the protected banking industry. the recent economic recession highlighted this pressure as keener competition became necessary for survival. when interest rates on deposited funds soared and loan demand softened, institutions assumed more risk to remain profitable. as a result, financial institutions loaned money to countries, companies, or individuals that were more risky than normal. the effects of such a policy are evident in both the sizable loan losses being reported and in the number of banks facing financial difficulties. institutions are discovering that these higher risk loans are contributing to losses that often negate the profits such loans provide. loan losses are often a result of the institutions' poor procedures for problem loan identification and management. the ability of an institution to recognize when a loan is experiencing difficulty is increasingly important in minimizing loan losses. this paper examines a problem loan identification and -management (plim) system useful for quickly identifying potential problem loans in an institution's portfolio and techniques to manage them efficiently. the information presented was gather in part through interviews and from guidelines of two well-established mid-sized commercial banks in the southwest. a case history of a problem loan was provided by one of the banks and is used to illustrate the methods of identifying and managing a problem loan. 25 identifying problem loans various items can provide an early warning of potential problem loans. exhibit a sets forth ten early warning signals. exhibit a early warning signals for problem loans 1. borrower's deteriorating financial statements 2. loan payments past due 3. borrower experiencing account overdrafts 4. loans are renewed without reduction in principal 5. borrower is experiencing personal financial problems 6. significant decreases in borrower's average account balances 7. borrower is experiencing foreclosures, civil suit judgments, etc. 8. inquiries received from other lending institutions regarding borrower 9. borrower's failure to file requested information, particularly financial data 10. borrower seeks extension of loan term the plim system for identification and detection of potential or actual problem loans consists of several methods which are designed to produce signals, any or all of which could quickly indicate the necessity to begin further investigation. the methods include: (1) portfolio and financial statement analysis, (2) past due reports, (3) overdraft listings, financial institution inquiries, and checking account variability, (4) outside sources of information, (5) renewed loans without principal reductions, and (6) other unusual factors. the loan review department working with the responsible loan officer should use these methods to manage the bank's loan portfolio. portfolio and financial statement analysis each quarter, the bank's loan portfolio is analyzed by the loan review department. the analysis usually takes a top-down approach which begins with an overall portfolio analysis. this analysis is similar to an evaluation of which securities to include in a stock portfolio. for example, some banks have a policy of maintaining one-third of its loan portfolio in each of three specific loan areas real estate, commercial, and consumer. such a policy is aimed at spreading the bank's risk so as to minimize the effect of a drastic downturn in one of the areas. the portfolio analysis is used to review the mix of outstanding loans to determine if bank policy is being followed and to assess current risk exposure. after the portfolio mix by type of loan is reviewed, the mix within each of these portfolios should be reviewed. for example, in the commercial loan area, a review should be made to determine the mix of industries, type of 26 loan collateral etc. there should not be an over emphasis on one industry because if the industry falls upon hard times the bank could experience significant losses. the goal again is to spread the risk. the overall portfolio review is followed by a review of each individual loan officer's portfolio. the officer's entire portfolio is reviewed because frequently the loan follows patterns that reflect management ability and/or economic exposure. a lengthy list of exceptions is a strong indication of documentation problems and immediate corrective actions should be instituted to limit the bank's exposure on the loans. loan officers typically specialize in a particular industry or region resulting in the concentrated portfolio mirroring the respective economic trend. a track record should be maintained for each loan officer in terms of adequacy of documentation, etc. as well as his history of loan profits to losses. such a record can be used in employee evaluations as well as for pinpointing individuals who are very successful or who may need additional training or increased supervision. to complete the top-down approach, the company itself is analyzed. when annual financial statements of the company are received, ratios are calculated and horizontal and vertical analysis are performed. today this analysis is frequently done using a micro computer and spreadsheet software. to assist in the financial statement analysis, robert morris and associates annual studies are used for industry average data for various businesses. the payment history is also reviewed to determine the current status of the account. the result of this compilation of data is reviewed by the loan officer and loan review officer to settle any discrepancies or questions and to correct any problems that may exist. past due report in most banks a past due report is issued at regular intervals and is contrasted with the loan officer's portfolio analysis. since timeliness is essential, the past due reports should be prepared weekly. this report is frequently the first indicator of a specific problem loan. the loan review officer should meet at regular intervals with the loan officers to discuss their past due accounts. again, because of the important of timeliness, this meeting should be on a weekly or biweekly basis. the bank should set a policy concerning when an account is considered past due. the length of time should be sufficiently long to eliminate the detailed review of loans where payment may have been delayed by mail or by other nonsignificant delays. a period of 15 to 20 days after the due date is recommended for considering a loan past due. banks should establish a particular past due date when the loan receives special or detailed treatment or analysis. for example, once a loan reaches 90 days past due it should be immediately placed in the hands of a special loan officer and several actions instituted such as accounting status, collateral valuation and risk classification. 27 overdraft lists, financial institution inquiries, and checking accounts these three indicators alert either the loan officer or loan review officer of potential managment, sales, or cash flow problems in a company. frequent appearance on the daily overdraft list should indicate that the company does not have enough cash to support operations and could result in late or missed payments on the outstanding loans. frequent overdrafts may also indicate that the borrower does not have an adequate accounting staff. if this is the case, the bank may suggest that the client obtain the necessary accounting services so that he can more efficiently operate his business. any inquiry from another bank or financial institution on the company should be studied as well. frequently such inquiries mean that the client may be seeking to borrow additional funds. while a new loan may satisfy a short-term need of cash for the company or expand their production capacity, the overall risk or exposure of the institutions involved may be increased because of the long-term inability of the company to raise cash from its operations to service the increasing debt. sometimes a company's checking account can also signal potential problems. for example, if sudden changes in account balances from historically high levels to low or insignificant amounts occur, this could indicate funds mismanagement, a sales decline, or rapid operating expenses increases, any of which might cause future loan payment problems. outside sources of information the loan officers should be responsible for keeping abreast of current economic and financial developments as well as with news items involving clients or a client's industry. loan officers should read local and national newspapers and periodicals such as the american banker and the wall street journal. at the local level, they should also review publications of the public records division of the city government. such publications list all court proceedings and parties involved in foreclosures, civil suit judgments, divisional proceedings, mortgages and conveyances, assignments, etc. one bank officer indicated that this is probably the single most important publication used by loan review officers to determine legal activity in the credit environment. renewed loans without principal reductions loans are frequently renewed when the borrower cannot meet the current payment schedule, normally a result of cash flow problems. if there are no principal reductions within a reasonable period of time after the renewal, an inadequate cash flow may exist. the bank may wish to establish a policy regarding the allowed number of renewals without principal reduction before the loan is reviewed in detail. 28 on a theoretical level, a renewed loan without principal reduction might not be considered as a problem loan. the impact of inflation on real interest rates may put the loan in a different light. for example, a loan renewed after a year of ten percent inflation has seen a real decrease in the principal amount owed because of the cheaper dollars needed to repay the loan. presumably, the interest rate charged to the borrower will recoup this real principal reduction. aside from this theoretical argument, lenders still expect a principal reduction of the loan on schedule. other signals of potential problems other indicators commonly include miscellaneous and infrequently occurring items. a customer who fails to file current financial reports or other requested information with the bank could signal a problem. significant devaluations of assets by the company from one statement to the next could also indicate problems. banks should establish a monitoring system to track problem loans by industry or type of business. when a problem loan arises, such a system can provide an early warning concerning possible problems with other clients in the same industry or line of business. finally, if the bank should know of personal financial problems of one or more principal parties of the business, the bank should make an effort to assure themselves that the problems do not extend to the bank loan. problem loan identification a case study to illustrate the application of some of the problem loan identification techniques, an actual case history provided by one of the banks interviewed is presented. because of the confidential nature of the information, the name of the company and bank have been changed. gusher, inc., is a corporation formed in 1979. the company drills for oil and gas throughout the southwest region of the u.s. it was formed with a substantial amount of capital and was managed by proven, capable individuals. a loan for $5,620,000 was made by southwest bank for the purpose of purchasing two newly fabricated drilling rigs in january of 1981. payments were made as agreed through september, 1982. at this point, southwest's loan review department began receiving signals of a potential problem loan with gusher. upon reviewing the bank's portfolio concentration in the first quarter of 1982, it was determined that the bank had an excessive number of i'rig" loans, including the loan to gusher, with respect to other types of loans. appropriate notification was made to the other officers of the unhealthy concentration of loans. this was considered necessary because the oil and gas drilling industry continued to remain depressed during the first quarter of 1982 as a result of the high cost of drilling and the weakening price of and demand for petroleum products. an analysis of gusher's 1981 year-end 29 statements indicated that a potential decline in revenues was likely because of the economic conditions. the past due report was used to determine that gusher, inc. was in trouble when it was late with its september, 1982 payment. in december, 1982, when it was reported that payments were over ninety days late, a special loan officer took the account and began a series of actions and negotiations. these are discussed in a later section. southwest's system enabled it to address quickly the gusher loan. when bank management detected a large number of oil and gas rig loans in its portfolio, it was able to limit its potential exposure in this area by declining any more loan requests. managing problem loans the purpose of loan management is to prevent any unnecessary loss to the bank or unnecessary difficulties for the borrower. the management process should aid in a timely settlement and in proper financial treatment of the problem loan. the various aspects of loan management are discussed below. accounting status banks typically account for loans on an accrual basis of accounting which allows an institution to claim interest income when it is earned (accrued) rather than when it is received. once a loan has reached the point where it is placed in the hands of a special loan officer, for example when it is ninety days past due, a common policy of institutions is to place the loan on a nonaccrual basis until, according to bank policy, an established number of stable payments are received and sufficient collateral is obtained. in the gusher loan situation, the loan was placed on a nonaccrual basis during march, 1983 when it was 180 days past due. all previously accrued interest was removed from the bank's income for 1983. collateral evaluation a collateral valuation is of utmost importance in determining how to manage a loan. all loans should be analyzed to determine their extent of collateralization. such information is essential in the classification of loan risk and is also a necessary input to the proper accounting treatment of problem loans. if the institution finds a problem loan to be fully collateralized, generally the loan will continue to be accounted for on a nonaccrual basis without a change in valuation. in a fully collateralized situation, the bank is secured and should receive the full amount of the loan through possible future repayment or sale of the collateral. on the other hand, if it is determined that the loan is undercollateralized, the fdic requires the institution to reduce the outstanding principal to the amount of equity in the collateral and charge-off the rest, i.e. take a loss on the unsecured amount. 30 institutions do not like to foreclose or charge-off portions of loans, but if it is necessary as a last resort, a proper valuation of the collateral must. be made. gusher's two rigs were originally appraised at $7,500,000 by the frabricator. the basis of the appraised value of a rig is a function of its revenue earning capacity. during 1982, day rates for drilling rigs plummeted to the point where the rigs were worth approximately $1,575,000 (21 % of estimated original value) on a ninety day quick sale basis and approximately $3,541,500 (47% of estimated original value) on a reasonable market basis. as a result, southwest bank had to record a loss on the loan to comply with fdic requirements. the amount of the loss will be discussed in the next section. risk classification once an estimation of the value of the loan's collateral is determined, the institution should perform a classification of the risk on all loans. for example, an eight-tier rating system may be used highest quality, very good quality, fair quality, olem (other loans exceptionally mentioned), substandard, doubtful, and loss. loans receiving a risk classification above olem generally do not present a problem to the bank. this risk classification should be conducted periodically since such items as financial strength, valuation of collateral, etc, may change. if a loan receives a downgraded classification, particularly to one of the lower classifications, it should be carefully reviewed by the loan officer to determine if some action is necessary. such a system can cut loan losses by providing an early signal of loans that may be approaching problems. when a loan receives a rating of olem, it usually indicates that there are deficiencies in the borrower's financial situation, such as deteriorating financial ratios, cash shortages, etc. a substandard rating is given if there is little or no liquidity, cash flow for debt service is marginal, and payout through normal operations is doubtful. it is also substandard if debt repayment could depend in part on fixed asset liquidation or if loans are secured by acceptable collateral, where the collateral value is less than the amount owed. a loan classified as doubtful has all the weaknesses inherent in one classified substandard with the added provision that the weaknesses made collection or liquidation in full, on the basis of current existing facts, highly questionable and improbable. the possibility of loss is extremely high, but because of certain important and reasonably specific pending factors which may work to the advantage and strengthening of the loan, its classification as an estimated loss is deferred until its exact status may be determined. loans classified as a loss are considered uncollectible and of such little value that their continuance as a loan of,the bank is not warranted. classifying a loan frequently involves both the bank and its examiners. each loan classification below olem lends itself to a percentage that must be taken as a loss substandard (10 percent), doubtful (50 percent), loss (100 31 percent). these loss amounts are only estimates and the fdic will usually dictate the amounts which must be written off. in the gusher example, as the market for the drilling rigs and other petroleum products changed, the collateral valuations and risk classifications also fluctuated because the value is a function of its revenue earning capacity. after the last payment on the gusher loan, the principal outstanding amounted to $5,518,000. the collateral had a 90-day quick sale value of $1,575,000, and a reasonable market value of $3,541,000. given these circumstances, the fdic required southwest bank to take action on the gusher loan. essentially, the fdic split the loan into three categories, a substandard amount, a doubtful amount, and a loss amount. the loss amount was determined to be the difference between the principal outstanding and the reasonable market value ($5,518,000 $3,541,500 = $1,976,500). the loss amount was charged against the bank's reserve for loan losses account (similar to allowance for bad debts). the effect of this was to write off that portion of the loan. the substandard amount of the loan was defined by the fdic to be the quick sale value of the collateral and they required southwest to charge 10% of this amount against income and to credit the reserve account. in addition, the doubtful amount was defined as the difference between the reasonable market value and the quick sale value of the collateral ($3,541,500 $1,575,000 = $1,996,500) and the fdic required southwest to charge 50% of this amount ($983,250) against income and to credit the reserve account. thus in total, the fdic required southwest to immediately write off $1,976,500, and to charge another $1,140,750 ($157,500 + $983,250) against the loan as a potential loss. workout of problem loans when the problem loan has been recognized, the bank should immediately try to do whatever is necessary to salvage the company and the loan. the bank should schedule the initial meeting with the client as soon as possible. this initial meeting should include (if possible) the cpa, attorneys and other principles. this meeting should be used to discuss the problems openly, review the financial position, and determine the relationship and status with other creditors. the latter is important, since the collapse of one client may, at times, have a substantial detrimental impact on other clients. at the same time, the bank should perform an internal evaluation of the situation. the credit department should perform an analysis of the business including cash flow, and a ratio analysis. a proposed plan can be devised by the bank and presented to the client for discussion. when the customer and the bank agree on a plan, the bank should have the customer sign an informal agreement stipulating terms of the agreement. administration of the workout plan after the bank and the customer agree on the workout plan, the bank 32 should set up a file on the customer dealing solely with the workout plan. the new file is updated continuously with information regarding the plan. where appropriate, the new terms of the loan are entered into the bank's computer system. the appropriate officer is notified of the status of the loan for monitoring just the same as the other loans of the bank. if the loan workout plan is not followed by the customer as agreed, another meeting should be scheduled to assess any new problems, and possible situations. bankruptcy and other litigation in all dealings, the bank should stress that litigation is considered only as a last resort, and that the bank hopes the customer will consider bankruptcy only as a last resort. if indeed litigation becomes a probable consequence, the bank's attorney should be called in immediately to discuss the case. the attorney's recommendations are usually followed. if bankruptcy is filed by the customer, the bank must arrange to attend the first meeting of creditors at the bankruptcy court. before the meeting, the bank should provide information regarding the loan amounts and all pertinent information related to the loan to the court. after that meeting the court records are normally reviewed to determine the probable settlement for the bank. once the probable amount is determined, the bank should adjust the value of the loan and record additional losses where necessary. conclusion although the bank is concerned with securing its position on the problem loan, it should also be concerned with the future of the borrower. the bank's goal should be to work with the troubled debtor to do whatever is feasible, within the constraint of minimizing loan losses, to help the debtor work out his financial difficulties. a foreclosure usually eliminates the opportunity for that borrower to continue to provide jobs, taxes, and goods for the community. therefore, banks have a responsibility to work with the borrowers for a reasonable period of time in the hope that the borrower can survive. this assistance could be in the form of more favorable terms on the present loan or even additional loans to develop or modernize a product line to generate more revenues. the financial expertise of the loan officer should always be available to assist the borrower in the recovery process. in the gusher case, the bank loan officer is continuing to work with the company to resolve the problem loan. the procedures outlined above for the plim system should assist banks in the early identification of problem loans. this process can greatly assist the bank in minimizing loan losses. an early warning system can allow the bank to work with clients to overcome problems before they become serious. proper management of problem loans will also reduce loan losses as well as provide a mechanism to make available the much needed assistance to the 33 clients with financial difficulties. thus any effective plim system should benefit the bank, the client and the local community. references the materials for this article were obtained from personal interviews with commercial loan officers of four mid-sized banks in baton rouge, louisiana. they have requested that their banks not be named in the article. 34 problem loan identification and management (plim) system implementing strategic change in manufacturing organizations john e. oliver department of management and information systems valdosta state college \taldosta, georgia gary b. roberts school of business kennesaw college kennesaw, georgia and kerr watson stokely managernent center the university of tennessee knoxville, tennessee one of the most colnmon changes of strategy occurring in manufacturing organizations today is a new 'emphasis on product quality. when the mission of improved quality is operationalized, it involves the setting of quality improvement objectives and the design of programs to implement the ne\-\' strategy. one of the most popular programs for implernent.ing improved product quality is statistical process control (spc) (2). spc esta blishes current levels of quality variance in each st.age of the manufacturing process in order to provide a basis for formulating improvement objectives. then, continued measurernents of quality variances are made to motivate and insure quality improvement through reduced variance a.t each stage in the process. thus, spc is used to formulate quality improvement objectives and to implernent the quality improvement strategy, as well as to evaluate and control strategy implementation. the implementation of a strategy of improved product quality using sp(; provides a. uniquely useful opportunity to study the complete strategy implementation process. th:e organizations in this study are all involved in the manufacture of components for the automobile industry and are all pursuing a strategy of improved product quality. they are implementing that strategy using statistical process control. the purpose of the study "vas to see whether managers in different types of organizations use different mechanisms to implement the new quality strategy. strategy implementation mechanisms galbraith and nathanson (3), after an exhaustive literature review, listed nine mechanisms for implementing strategy hierarchy, rules, goal setting, 1 direct contact, interdepartmental liaison roles, temporary task forces, permanent teams, integrating roles, and integrating departments. to avoid duplication of terms and to clarify definitions, the following labels and definitions have been used in this research: 1. chain of command the boss personally observes and directs the implementation of a new procedure through verbal instructions to the subordinates .. when problems arise the boss usually directs behavior. 2. rules and standard operating procedures behaviors are specified in advance in the form of rules. rules generally eliminate the need for further communication between the boss and subordinates unless specific problems arise. new procedures are implemented through the publication and distribution of standard operating procedures. 3. targeting or goal setting behavior is not specified. employees are allowed to select the way that they a.chieve the goals and objectives specified by the organization. new procedures are presented to employees in the form of targets and they are then free to choose the exact means to reach them. 4. direct contact individuals talk to each other when they are jointly affected by a problem. problems are generally not referred up the chain of command but are resolved by the participants involved. 5. liaison roles the liaison role is a typical example of a specialized role designed to facilitate communication between two interdependent departments and to bypass the long lines of communication involved in upward referral. for example, the engineering liaison in a manufacturing plant is part of the engineering organiza.tion but is physically located in the plant to serve the production organization. these roles link functional departments of the organization. 6. temporary task force the task force is a form of horizontal contact designed for problems across multiple departments. the task force is a temporary group made up of representatives from each of the affected departments. some are full-time members; others may be part-time. it exists only as long as the problem: remains. when a solution is reached participants return to their normal tasks. 7. permanent implementation teams typically formed around frequently occurring problems. teams are permanent groups which meet daily or weekly to discuss problems affecting the group. they solve all the problems which require commitments that they are capable of making. larger problems are referred upward. 8. integrating roles the response of the organization to the concern for decision quality is to create new roles in the organization structure. 2 these roles are called integrating roles. the managers who occupy them do not supervise any of the actual work. instead they assist those who do, so that the work is coordinated in the best interest of the organization. some common titles for this role include: "materials manager," "product manager," "project manager," "program manager," and "unit manager" . 9. integrating departments integrating departments consist of more than one person whose purpose is to assist those individuals and departments who do the actual work. examples of such departments include "product management" and "project management" departments. four types of organizations four types of organizations were found empirically b)7 oliver (7) in his initial studies with the organization description questionnaire: hierarchic, professional, entrepreneurial, and group oriented. each of t.hese four types represents a different internal environment. as campbell, dunnette, la\vler, and weich (1) suggested, the internal environments 'vary in terms of tile amount of individual autonomy that is allowed to organization members, the degr~e of structure that is imposed, the reward orientation, the style of leadership exercised, and the way conflicts are managed. in the hierarchic organization, individual a.utonomy is limited. responsibility and authority are delegat.ed in controlled doses b~y managers at higher levels of the hierarchy. independence is controlled by job descriptions, rules~ regulations, and guidelines. initiative is limited by a system of standard operating procedures, specialization, and close super\rision. the degree of structure is high \\1ith a great deal of formaliza.tion of procedures, centralization of decisions, and direct supervision exercised. re\vards are administered by superiors based on specific, well-defined, and objective criteria like time worked, items processed, errors, etc. the re""ards are distributed on the bases of seniority, merit, and position. there is little consideration a.cc.orded subordinates in terms of warmth or support, and participation is generally kept to a minimum. conflicts are seen as being bad for t.he organization and are discouraged. the most acceptable way of dealing with conflict is to appeal to higher levels in the hierarchy for resolution. in the professional organization, a good deal of individual autonomy is granted. responsibility is broad, with independence and initiative encouraged, so that the professional makes important decisions and takes action within the established body of knowledge and theory of the profession or technical specialty. \lery little structure exists with the exception of formalization. direct supervision is not needed since the code of behavior, professionalism, association, and peer review serve as substitutes for it. decision-making is decentralized. rewards are generally based on very general criteria and are often measured subjectively. th~ rewards generally go to those whose professional accomplishments are judged to be most significant. leadership in the 3 professional organization is characterized by a good deal of warmth, participation, and support, especially from colleagues. conflict is encouraged in the professional organization because it leads to penetrating analysis and creative syllthesis. such conflict is seen as useful and good and is managed through a problem solving approach. the entrepreneurial organization exhibits the greatest amount of individual autonomy with each individual given broad responsibility for accomplishment, complete independence and initiative, and the freedom to pursue goals by whatever means are appropriate. structure is simple or non-existent with little or no formalization, centralization, standardization, or direct supervision. rewards are based on the simple criterion of successful completion of the task or failure. therefore, immediate feedback on success or failure is required and rewards follow automatically. since the individual is left alone to cornplete the task, there is little support, warmth, or participation. conflict is inherent in the task since the individual competes against himself, others, tirrle, and other obstacles to achievement. conflicts must be managed by the individual using whatever techniques are available. this usually means that solutions are forced by the individual, using drive or achievement motivation to overcome the obstacles. the word "entrepreneurial" is not used here to describe the simple structure of the typical small business but rather to describe the entrepreneur-like freedom or autonomy and the attendant risk that is \videly distributed among organization members, as when jobs are enriched or commissioned sales people are given the freedom to set and pursue goals in their own \\'ay with only results being monitored. the group organization replaces individual autonomy with group autonom)'. while individuals may only have narrow responsibilities assigned, with independence and initiative limited, the group, functioning without supervision, takes on responsibility and initiative for the whole operation, which would be reserved for upper level management in the hierarchic organization. there is little or no direct supervision or centralization, but some structure is provided through a degree of formalized procedures. rewards are generally based on specific, objectively measured criteria and distributed by some group incentive plan. since leadership is emergent and democratic, a great den.] of consideration is evident in the form of support, warmth, and ultimate participation. when conflicts occur, they may be perceived as either good or bad and are handled through group confrontation, discussion, and problem solving. the four organization types are presented here as pure or ideal models based on miner's (5) limited domain theories and oliver's (7) empirical work. obviously, the world of organizations is not so neat and simple. most organizations cont.ain some elements of all four types. for instance, hierarchy is a pervasive organization form and some elements of hierarchy will be found in almost all organizations. however, evidence indicates that most organizations can be classified into one of the four types (7). 4 the four types are independent of industry. firms within a given industry may possess anyone of the four types of internal environments or even have different types in various units of the organization. an example of how different types may be found in one industry is the automobile industry. in the united states, most automobiles have traditionally been produced on the assembly line. cars are assembled by workers who perform the same routine, highly specialized tasks over and over while under direct supervision. this is a predominately hierarchic organization. in zama, japan, however, nissans move down an automated assembly line where robots perform the routine tasks and workers are highly trained technicians and troubleshooters who work without close supervision. the workers' technical knowledge and professional orientation guide their behavior. this is a predominately professional organization. in kalmar, sweden, volvos are assembled by autonomous groups of workers in specially designed bays without immediate supervision. the self-directed groups plan, organize, and control production and are paid on a group incentive basis. this is a predominately group type internal environment. organization type, then, would seem to be a determinant of the kinds of strategy implementation mechanisms that an organization might use as well as a determinant of the effectiveness of a particular implementation method for a particular organization. the purpose of this study is to test whether managers in different types of organizations use different mechanisms to implement strategy. in figure 1, the x's indicate which mechanisms are expected to be used in each organization type. the study sainple the data used in this study were gathered from a stratified random sample of 400 executives involved in a training program at a major southeastern university. the subjects represent 67 a.merican and canadian manufacturing organizations in the process of implementing a strategy of product quality improvement via a statistical process control program. usable responses were obtained from 181 of the subjects, yielding a 45.25% response rate. measures nine six-point likert scale items similar to the one below were used to measure the usage of the nine strategy implementation mechanisms: 5 direct contact individuals talk to each other when they are jointly affected by a problem. problems are generally not referred up the chain of command but are resolved by participants involved. never used o rarely used 1 sometimes used 2 often used 3 very often used alvays used 5 the oliver organization description questionnaire (oodq) (7) \\?as used to classify the respondents' organizat.ions as hierarchic, professional, entrepreneurial, group~ or some combination of the four. the oodq is a forced-choice questionnaire \\:hich yields a hierarchic score, a professional score, a task score, and a group sc.ore." a t.otal of fifteen items are scored for each domain scale so that possible scores range from 0 to plus 15. the following is an example of an oodq it.em: 1. in my work, duties are determined by (a) management (b) my profession or ocupation (c) my work group (d) me, based on the goal i am trying to accomplish in addition to the two questionnaires, respondents reported their organization level as top level executive, middle manager, first line supervisor, or professional (engineer, consultant, etc.). organization size was coded for each firm based on the number of employees, a.s listed in standard and poors directory. procedure organiza.tions were classified by highest oodq score. multivariate analysis of variance (manova) and univariate anova tests were conducted to determine whether there were significant differences in the reported usage of strategy implementation' mechanisms in the four types of organizations, in different size organizations, a.nd by organization level. tukey's c.v. tests were used to determine which differences were significant. 6 table 1 mean ratinls of usale of strately implementation mechanisms in four types of oraadizations total hierarchy professional entrepreneurial group sample mechanisms (n=117) (n=10) (n=30) (n=14) (n=181) chain of command 2.58 2.83 2.28 2.14 2.38 s.o.p.'s··· 2.58eg 2.83g 1.94 1.43 2.42 goal-setting·· • 2.25 2.87 3.22" 3.21" 2.56 direct contact··· 2.79 3.48" 3.33" 3.64" 3.02 interdep. liaison 2.42 3.00 2.28 2.86 2.49 temp. task force· 2.60 3.17 2.86 3.36 2.76 perm. imp. team·· 2.29 3.09 2.61 3.36" 2.51 integrating role 2.34 2.22 2.44 2.79 2.32 integrating dept. 2.03 2.04 2.08 2.14 2.05 • mean differences significant p <.05 •• mean differences significant p < .01 ••• mean differences significant p <.001 h = significantly greater than hierarchic sample (p <.01) e = significantly greater than entrepreneurial sample (p <.01) g =significantly greater than group sample (p < .01) results table 1 contains the mean scores of usage ratings for the mechanisms in each organization type, as well ,as the e.ntire sample. significant differences are summarized in the discussion section of this pa.per. table 2 lists the mean scores of usage rati~gs for the mechanisms in four different sized organizations. the differences b.re summarized in the discussion. differences in usage of the mechanisms by executives at each level in the organizations are reported in table 3 and summarized in the discussion. above-average usage is shown in figure 1 by circles (0). circles which contain x's indieate that above-average use was hypothesized and confirmed. seventeen or the twenty hypothesized above-average usages were confirmed. three or those hypothesized were not supported by the data, and five unexpected above-average usages were reported. discussion as mintzberg (6) and others have documented, direct contact is the most popular mechanism for implementing strategy-ranking first in all four types of organizations, all sizes of organizations, and all levels. apparently, managers and professionals still prefer face-to-face contact to get things done. oddly enough, it is more often used in larger rather than smaller org.anizations; and first jine supervisors prefer it. the second most popular mechanism is the temporary task force. while this research does not clearly indicate why the task force is so popular, it can be said that it is the least disruptive, costly, and most flexible of the mechanisms. it was the second most-used mechanism in three of the four 7 table 2 mean ratings of usage of strategy implementation mechanisms in four sizes of organizations. mechanisms chain of command s.o.p.'s· goal-setting·· direct contact*· interdep. liaison temp. task force* perm. imp. team·· integrating role integrating dept. very large (0=65) 2.42 2.18 2.83 3.47 2.89 3.34 3.16 2.44 2.39 large (n=64) 2.32 2.14 3.00 3.31 2.74 2.66 2.55 2.52 2.08 medium (0=34) 2.72 2.07 2.93 3.29 2.71 3.05 2.91 2.04 1.99 small (n=18) 2.48 2.18 2.40 3.02 2.10 2.74 2.32 2.41 1.57 • mean differences significant at p <.0/.*mean differences significant at p <.00/ ivery lorge = >50,000 employees lorge =10,000-50,000 employees medium = /,000-/0,000 employees small = i direct contact ~ ~ 8 interdepartmental liaison roles x 0 8 temporary task forces 8 8 8 permanent implementation teams 8 0 ~ integrating roles 8 8 integrating departments x x 0 0 x :: hypothesized above average usage o =actual reported usage above the mean for the total sample figure i hypothesized and actual reported use of strategy implementation mechanisms by organization type types of organiza.tions and third most-used in the entrepreneurial type, while being most often used by professionals and mid-level managers. although goal setting was the third most-used mechanism overall, its use varied a great deal among the fouf types of organizations. it was second only to direct contact in entrepreneurial organizations where it was hypothesized to be most appropriate, but was eighth out of nine in hierarchic organizations and fifth in the professional type. its unpopularity in hierarchies may be due to the difficulty of changing goals or redirecting emphasis away from their rigid and traditional, bureaucratic goals, policies, and procedures. as expected, permanent implementation teams, which were fourth in popularity overall, were most used in the group type organizations where their use was rated equally with temporary task forces. the use of permanent teams was ranked third and fourth in professional and entrepreneurial organizations, respectively, but seventh in hierarchies. this low usage in hierarchies may reflect the reluctance of hierarchic managers to create long-lived committees which might become opposing forces or obstacles, or it may indicate that the established hierarchic structure is a sufficient and existing "permanent implementation team." interdepartmental liaison roles were ranked fifth out of nine in overall usage putting them at the midpoint of popularity among strategy implementation mechanisms in this study. their use did not vary significantly by size or level of organization. while standard operating procedures, which ranked sixth overall, were reportedly used most often in professional organizatio~s, their use ranked third (tied with chain-of-command) in hierarchies. as expected, their use is most theoretically congruent with hierarchies and professional organizations and is supported by the data. the reported use of chain-or-command, which ranked seventh out of nine overall, was also greatest for hierarchies as was hypothesized. though this hypothesis was not supported statistically, the rank of third most popular does indicate some support for the notion that chain-of-command as a strateg.y implementation mechanism is primarily appropriate to the hierarchic organization. perhaps the lack of clarity in this data is due to the pervasiveness of chain-of-command in all or most organizations. the use of integrating roles and departments as strategy implementation mechanisms, at least in this sample, appears to be rare, with no significant differences among types, sizes, or levels of organizations. this study indicated that as firms move through their life cycle, they may utilize different mechanisms. this study indicates that there may be a life cycle effect in the use of both temporary task forces and permanent implementation teams with small and large organizations using them less than the medium and very large. this could indicate that firms growing from small to medium size experience a reduction in the effectiveness of standard operating procedures and begin to "grope in groups." the teams work for awhile, but their effectiveness fades w"lth time and growth. then, as organizations grow 10 from large to very large, they again turn to "group groping." the pattern of usage for sop's is somewhat different, with significantly greater usage in small and very large firms than in medium and large ones. the use of goalsetting is just the opposite. neither small nor very large firms use goal-setting to the degree that a medium or large one does. sop's and goal-setting may be incongruent mechanisms which hinder each other or cannot be used effectively together. conclusions the findings in this study have limited generalizability due to: the small number of professional, entrepreneurial, and group type organizations represented in the sample; the nature of the single strategy being implemented; and the fact that all of the firms are manufacturers in related industries. further study is needed on a broader variety of organizations implementing a variety of different strategies in order to fill in the missing pieces of the puzzle. however, this study provides support for the general hypothesis that different strategy implementation mechanisms are used in different organizational types and sizes, as well as by executives at different levels of the organization. r.eferences 1. campbell, john p., dunnette, marvin d., lawler, edward e. iii, and weick, karl e., man.agerial behavior, performance, and effectiveness (new york: mcgraw-hill, 1970), p. 393. 2. deming, w. e. (1982) quality productivity, and competitive position. cambridge: ma.ssachusetts institute of technology, center for advanced engineering study. 3. galbraith, j. and nathanson, d. 1978 strategy implementation: the role of structure and process, st. paul, mn: west publishing company. 4. lawrence, paul r. and jay w. lorsch. organization and environment: managing differentiation and integration. boston: graduate school of business, harvard university, 1967. 5. miner, j. b. 1979. "limited domain theories of organizational energy." c. c. pinder and l.b. moore (eds). middle range theory and the. study 0/ organizations. leiden, netherlands: martinus nijoff: 273286. 6. mintzberg, h. the nature of managerial work. new york: harper and row, 1973. 7. oliver, j. e., 1982. "an instrument for classifying organizations." academy of management journal. 25 (4): 855-866. 11 implementing strategic change in manufacturing organizations the strategic use of bankruptcy prediction models: an aid to executive decision making sukumar c. debnath college of business administration prairie view a & m university prairie view, texas aubrey r. fowler, jr. college of business administration nicholls state university thibodaux, louisiana stephen c. bushardt college of business administration university of southern mississippi hattiesburg, mississippi the last decade has seen a flood of business failures in the united states. these failures, ranging from the smallest of entrepreneurial firms to corporate giants, have had a significant impact on the general well being of the u.s. economy, have led to the loss of thousands of jobs, and have cost investors and creditors millions of dollars. in addition the news media give reports, almost daily, of other firms that are exhibiting financial difficulty and facing the imminent possibility of insolvency and the need to seek protection under bankruptcy law. firms in such diverse industries as airlines, meat packing, and computers all appear to be on the brink of seeking reorganization under chapter 11 or liquidation under chapter 7 of the federal bankruptcy code. these business failures are frequently offered as a major criticism of a capitalistic system and the supposed "crisis" created by them as justification for changing to a more controlled economy. however, the fact of bankruptcy and the economic losses associated with it are ac'tually a control mechanism th~t properly rempves economic units that are incapable of effectively competing thereby weeding out the inefficient and rewarding those that are able to meet the needs of the market and properly manage their resources. in effect, bankruptcy is one of the expenses to an economy that allows for both the acceptance of risk and the rewards associated with success. therefore, bankruptcy should not be viewed solely from the viewpoint of the firm involved and those associated with it. furthermore, it should be noted that bankruptcy serves a positive functi<>ll when eliminating inefficient journal of bu8ineu strategie8, volume 4, number 2 (fa111987) 87 competitors as a result of their own financial weakness and that under today's bankruptcy law the act of seeking protection under chapter 11 may relate to issues other than immediate threat of insolvency. for instance, firms may use bankruptcy protection to abrogate a collective bargaining contract. however, given the economic hardship created by business failures, it seems obvious that any tool or technique that could help avoid such failures would be a valuable aid to business decision makers. one such useful technique would be an early identification of those firms at risk of encountering financial difficulty. over the years a number of efforts have been made to devise analytical models useful in predicting corporate financial failure. these efforts have led to the creation of several models with a high degree of predictive ability which are able to detect potential failure as early as three to five years in advance. purpose since the future condition of a company with respect to its financial well being can be very important to a variety of parties (le., executives, investors, employees, or regulatory agencies), an ability to accurately predict financial problems can have a significant impact on decisions· regarding their involvement with companies showing a potential for failure. for example, executives of such companies would have more time in which to determine the causes leading to failure and work to correct them. potential investors would also have a better assessment of the risk they undertake. with financial failure a growing problem in the u.s. ([3], [5], [20)) it would seem that the availability of models capable of predicting such failure is increasingly important. their use will assist in the recognition of potential problems, in helping to identify the underlying causes of those problems, and as a starting point for the development of corrective action. with this in mind the purpose of this paper is to: 1. review the bankruptcy prediction models (bpm's); 2. discuss the use of the bpm's for internal analysis and problem solving; 3. discuss the use of bpm's as a tool for evaluating firms as potential acquisition targets; and 4. briefly identify other possible applications of bpm's. the essential thrust of the paper will be to evaluate the strategic value of bpm's as an important tool in executive decision making. why businesses fail there are a variety of reasons why businesses fail. however, it is generally accepted that the fundamental underlying cause of failure is poor management. this position is supported in the literature ([6], [7], [11)) and has been recognized for a (',onsiderable length of time. among the elements of poor management contributing to failure are: 88 1. faulty decision making, 2. poor allocation of resources, 3. failure to correct operating inefficiencies, 4. poor choice of products and marketing strategy, 5. poor financial management, and 6. inadequate planning. there are, of course, other factors, external to the organization, that can lead to failure. in particular, the overall status of the national economy and the competitive situation are important contributors to failure ([3], [6]' [7]). other contributing factors include: 1. governmental regulation, 2. technological innovation, 3. natural disasters, 4. labor problems, and 5. changes in cultural/social values. when failure occurs it is frequently a shock to most who are associated with the firm involved. particularly when large firms declare bankruptcy the event receives national attention and the public at large is led to wonder how such rich and powerful organizations could fail. there is a tendency to look for singular causes of a disastrous nature when the reality is that financial collapse is seldom sudden and rarely from a single cause [20]. the above observation serves as the foundation for the development of models to predict failure. if those factors that are symptomatic of failure and which show those symptoms in advance can be identified, the failure may be predicted and, with proper management in the interim, avoided. therefore, the bpm's are tools that may improve poor management by identifying in a timely manner potential problems and give some indication oftheir underlying causes. a review of bankruptcy prediction models since the early 1900's, researchers have sought ways of identifying companies that are developing a potential for encountering significant financial problems. these research efforts have resulted in the development of a number of empirically derived bankruptcy prediction models that offer sufficient predictive ability to be of assistance to managers involved in strategic planning. 89 most of the earlier models ([8], [9], [12), [15], [19), [22]) relied on comparative ratio analysis as the basis for their predictions. in them, researchers compared a variety of common financial ratios of failed firms to matching nonfailed firms or industry averages as a basis for determining critical values for those ratios. firms that failed to meet those critical values were determined to be in jeopardy of severe financial consequences. as useful models, these early efforts suffered from a major problem in that each offered several ratios as a basis for comparison. unfortunately, these models failed to provide a single, comprehensive basis for determining potential financial problems due to contradictory results. this issue has been addressed in more recent years through the use of discriminant analysis as a means of identifying significant predic.tor variables (still financial ratios) and their relative importance and interrelationship through the development of a discriminant function to predict financial well being. using these functions a firm or other user of the model computes a score based on the values of the significant variables, model coefficients and constants and compares this score with a single critical value for determining risk of severe financial difficulty (see [1]' [4], [10], [18], and [21]). these models offer a high degree ofpredktive ability, ranging in accuracy from a high of 99% for a one year prediction [21] to a high of 78% for a five year prediction [10]. in spite of this predictive ability the use of bpm's has been criticized. a major problem associated with the models is their inconsistency in selecting significant variables from essentially similar sets of financial ratios. this makes it difficult to determine which model to use and suggests that the accuracy of a given model may be dependent on the general economic environment in which it is applied [14]. a second important criticism involves the limited theoretkal basis for much of the empirical work leading to the development of the models and their ignoring of causal relationships between the financial ratios and failure [17]. in essence, the financial ratios serve as symptoms of potential failure but do not indicate the causes of such failure. for instance, a retail firm that shows a deterioration in its average collection period has a problem, but the ratio itself simply indicates the existence of the problem, not the underlying cause. the deterioration may result from overly liberal credit terms, improper billing and record keeping procedures, or a shift in the economic well-being of the customer base. if the change in the ratio is seen as indicating an important problem, a firm's objective might be to improve that ratio and to accomplish that it must identify the underlying reason for the unacceptable ratio and concentrate on correcting it. therefore, the bpm's are diagnostic tools identifying problems rather than prescriptive tools for avoiding bankrupt~y. an additional criticism is that firms encountering financial problems may delay in reporting financial data which may create accuracy problems in predicting pending failure based on recent operations [13]. 90 a bankruptcy prediction model in use given these models and criticisms of them, a brief overview of one in operation might benefit the reader. in a study reported in 1983 [5], the zeta model was compared with the relative financial strength system published as part of the value line investment survey. in the study the two models were found to be comparable in their ability to predict financial disaster for business firms. using the zeta model 68 of 73 major bankruptcies occurring during the years 1977 to 1982 were predicted based on their zeta score. table i, as exerted from altman and spivack ([5], p. 63), shows the total results of the study and table 2 shows examples of selected companies. table 1 time of financial statement in periods before bankruptcy n umber of firms results 0 1 2 3 4 companies correctly classified 68 62 47 37 34 companies incorrectly classified 5 9 19 23 23 total companies 73 71 66 60 57 percent correct 93 87 71 62 60 percent incorrect 7 13 29 38 40 average score -4.72 -2.62 -1.44 -0.79 -0.53 table 2 examples and results of zeta score use, selected companies n umber of months bankruptcy zeta with company date sc~re negative score a m international 4-14-82 -4.6 20 allied artists 4-5-79 -7.07 120 bobbie brooks 1-17-82 -1.98 103 braniff airlines 5-13-82 -3.40 28 lionel 2-82 -15.79 64 mansfield 'rire 10-79 -8.20 22 sambo's 11-81 -3.51 35 seatrain lines 2-11-81 -2.41 115 white motor co. 9-4-80 -1.41 116 wicker cos. 4-25-82 -0.92 15 91 for all of the companies covered in the study the average lead time by which the zeta score predicted bankruptcy was 53 months. furthermore, as shown by average scores and pointed out by the authors, the trend toward greater negativity appears to be as important in predicting bankruptcy as does the negative score itself. bankruptcy prediction models for internal analysis in recent years, the concept and practice of strategic management has taken on greater importance for business organizations. a fundamental aspect of strategic management is the ability to forecast future events as a basis for current decision making. therefore, the ability to predict an event of such importance as bankruptcy has significant value to the strategic decision maker. in a strategic sense, survival is one of the fundamental objectives of most business organizations. bankruptcy prediction thus acquires an even greater importance, since financial insolvency is one of the strongest possible threats to continued existence. the need, then, is to be aware of bpm's and to be able to use the information available from them in a manner conducive to avoiding the developing problem. fundamental to their use is to remember that the bpm's are diagnostic rather than prescriptive. they indicate that something needs to be done but not what to do. it is the responsibility of the strategic manager to utilize the bpm results to first assess the causes of the pending problem and then to determine how best to avoid that problem. the models' use of financial ratios as the basis for their predictions provide a warning signal and some indication of where imbalance in the firm's operations exists. for instance, a firm using the zeta-model [4] and calculating a zeta score indicative of pending bankruptcy can look at the ratios comprising the discriminant function and compare them with industry standards. those that are substandard provide a basis for determining why the problem is developing. using the zeta model the ratio of retained earnings to total assets is the most important predictor of trouble. therefore if the re/ta ratio for a firm is substantially less than for other firms, particularly those in its industry, the firm has an indication that it relies too heavily on external sources of funds and that it suffers from either or both of substandard profitability, thereby reducing the ability to retain earnings, or overly generous dividend policies, thereby satisfying short term stockholder needs for income while jeopardizing their long term interests. other examples using other ratios or other models can be given. however, the important issue is that the information is potentially available, not the specific details of its use. once an appropriate bpm has been selected and applied to a finn's financial data base, the strategic manager has at hand an important basis for decision making. if the results are favorable, giving no indication of pending trouble, the strategist can then concentrate on improving existing operations and taking advantage of opportunities in the market place. furthermore, strategists in such a position can use favorable bpm results to enhance their firms' standing in the eyes of investors or lenders, 92 making for greater accessibility to capital markets. the strategist might also use a favorable bpm result as a basis for evaluating the impact of changes in the firm's operations or financial structure that affect the predictor variables. for instance, the impact of a heavy debt financing for new operations might be assessed by using the bpm to predict the change in, and status of, the predictor score after allowing for the expected results of the debt financing to manifest themselves. in essence, the bpm can be used as a simulation model to determine the advisability of engaging in certain actions on the basis of their impact on organizational survivability. if the results of the bpm, when applied to current operational results, is unfavorable the signal is for management to concern itself more with finding and correcting the underlying causes rather than seeking growth or general improvement. since bpm's have the capacity to predict problems several years in advance, an effective use of such models should provide ample time in which to avoid those problems. in addition, the longitudinal use of the model can help to evaluate the effectiveness of corrective actions by comparing a series of bpm predictor scores. if the scores show a trend toward or into favorability they indicate that the decisions being made are working as desired. if, however, the scores are unchanged or the trend is toward more unfavorable scores the indication is that the problem still exists and that further corrective action is required. the basic importance of the bpm's to the practice of strategic management is that they provide decision makers with an additional tool with which to assess the future. as such, they can be used to signal a need for action to avoid potential problems and can serve as an evaluative tool for helping to assess the impact of major strategic decisions. if the premise that survival is fundamental to the success of business organizations is accepted, then bpm's can serve a vital function in helping to insure survival by providing timely and potentially critical information. bankruptcy prediction models for external analysis in addition to using bpm's to assess one's own firm, the strategic decision maker can use them to assess the financial well being of other firms. such analysis can be of significant value in determining the relative competitive position of firms and in appraising the value and attractiveness of potential acquisitions or merger partners. if the bpm's are used to assess the bankruptcy potential of competitors the results might have an impact on planning for competitive actions. clearly a firm showing a potential for financial problems is less likely to respond effectively to initiatives in the competitive arena. just as dearly, a firm in a more favorable financial position than its competitors can counter the competition's moves and take actions of its own that might place substantial pressure on the competition. therefore, bpm's can serve as a part of the basis for competitive decisions by helping to identify positions of strength to be exploited and positions of weakness to be avoided. in 93 this instance the bpm is a comparative model assessing the relative financial strength of two or more firms competing in the same marketplace. an alternate use of the bpm's in external analysis is to evaluate the present financial well being of a firm targeted for merger or acquisition and to assess the financial impact of such actions. on one hand, the bpm's may be used to seek firms showing sound financial positions as a means of adding that strength to the acquiring firm and reducing the risk of acquisition. on the other hand, bpm's can identify firms in trouble under the assumption that they might be more readily available, might require a smaller investment to acquire, and might benefit most from an infusion of capital and managerial expertise from the acquiring firm. in either c.ase, the bpm's give important information regarding the firm or firms of interest and thereby provide a sounder basis for deciding what course of action to take, what value to place on the target firm(s), and what risk is created by pursuing the merger or acquisition. other uses of bankruptcy prediction models the primary focus of this paper has been to suggest how bpm's might be used to assist strategic managers in making decisions regarding their own firms. there are, however, other potential uses of these models that are worth mentioning. other firms can use the bpm's to evaluate us just as we can evaluate them. given the public nature of much of the information regarding the operating results of most major corporations it is reasonable to assume that others can estimate our financial well being and long term prospects with accuracy approaching our own. this might create an added impetus to use and react to bpm's since failure to do so might give an unacceptable competitive advantage to those firms which might benefit from our troubles. investors can use bpm's to help their evaluation of the risks associated with a particular firm. whether these investors take the form of subscribers to a stock issue, purchasers of stock via the various stock markets, or lenders, the information provided by the bpm's can affect their investment decision. they may use it to make the go/no-go decision, may use it to determine the type of investment, or may use it to determine the appropriate stock price/interest rate for the investment. these decisions by potential investors will have direct or indirect impact on the firm involved and serve as an additional inducement to firms to correct problems causing an unfavorable result when evaluated with a bpm. government regulatory agencies may use the bpm's as a part of their regulatory review of the firms they are concerned with. such review may include an assessment of current operations and the quality of firm management, may be used to evaluate requests for rate or other changes desired by regulated firms, or may be used as a basis for requesting relief from regulatory restrictions by firms suffering from the adverse financial consequences of compliance. as with investors, bpm's can provide information to regulators that will help determine the relationship between the agency and. the firm being reviewed. 94 a final important user of bpm data is the employees, particularly unionized employees, of the firm being evaluated. since employee expenses are a major cost item for almost all firms, the effect of decisions related to pending financial problems requiring cost reductions will have a significant impact on employees. with their own bpm data, employees or their union representatives can more reliably assess the accuracy of company statements regarding financial doom than if they rely solely on those statements. the union is, therefore, in a better position to bargain for the benefit of its members, to assess the risks associated with their contractual demands, and to sell to members unfavorable contracts made necessary by company inability to pay. alternatively, the results of a bpm showing little potential for bankruptcy may counter company predictions of pending problems or show that the granting of certain benefits or concessions to the union will have no impact on subsequent operational results. at the very least, bpm results will advise employees of the potential for insecurity in their jobs and the financial well being of their employer. conclusion researchers have developed a number of bankruptcy prediction models that serve to assess the potential for future financial problems based on today's operational results. an astute use of the information provided by such models can be of significant value to those parties who are interested in the future of a company. in particular, the use of bpm's can provide strategic decision makers with a sufficiently timely warning of potential trouble to allow for an assessment of the causes of the problem and to devise the necessary corrective action. therefore, the routine use of a bpm as part of the firm's internal assessment process offers a substantial benefit to the organization at a negligible annual cost. the key to the effectiveness of the use of a bpm is the selection of the most appropriate model and then insuring that it is used regularly and in a proper manner. the intention here is not to recommend any particular model but to suggest that, conceptually, a bpm is a useful tool in strategic management and the various models available should be reviewed in detail by interested managers for the purpose of selecting the one which best fits their needs. for those firms interested in using a bpm for one or more of the uses described, it is suggested that a brief review of the literature referenced will provide access to the actual procedures and techniques needed to apply the models. in some cases the model is published and available for anyone's use. in others the model is proprietary and references are given to its developers for contact on a consulting basis. references 1. altman, edward 1. "financial ratios, discriminant analysis and the prediction of corporate bankruptcy." the journal of finance, vol. 23, september 1968, pp. 589-609. 95 2. "the success of business failure prediction models-an international survey." journal of banking and finance, vol. 8, june 1984, pp. 171-198. 3. "why businesses fail" journal of business strategy, vol. 3, september 1983, pp. 15-21. 4. altman, edward i., robert g. haldeman, and p. narayanan. "zeta analysis: a new model to identify bankruptcy risk of corporations." journal of banking and finance, vol. 1, june 1977, pp. 29-54. 5. altman, edward i. and spivack, joseph. "predicting bankruptcy: the value line relative financial strength system vs. the zeta bankruptcy classification approach." financial analysis journal, vol. 39, november 1983, pp. 60-67. 6. argenti, j. corporate collapse: the causes and symptoms, london, uk: mcgraw-hill book company (uk) ltd., 1976. 7. barrickman, ray e. business failures: causes, remedies, and cures. washington, dc: united press of america, inc., 1979. 8. beaver, william h. "altenative accounting measures as predictors of failure." the accounting review, vol. 43, january 1968, pp. 113-122. 9. "financial ratios as predictors of failure." empirical research in accounting: selected studies, supplement to journal of accounting research, vol. 4, 1966, pp. 71-111. 10. dambolena, ismael g. and khoury, sarkis j. -"ratio stability and corporate failure." the journal of finance, vol. 35, september 1980, pp. 1017-1026. 11. dun and bradstreet failure record, new york: dun and bradstreet, inc., 1981. 12. fitzpatrick, paul j. "a comparison of ratios of successful industrial enterprises with those of failed firms." certified public accountant, october, november, december 1932, pp. 598+. 13. lawrence, edward c. "reporting delays for failed firms." journal of accounting research, vol. 21, autumn 1983, pp. 606-610. 14. menash, yaw m. "an examination of the stationarity of multivariate bankruptcy prediction models: a methodological study." journal of accounting research, vol. 22, spring 1984, pp. 380-395. 15. merwin, charles l. "financing small corporations in five manufacturing industries 1926-1936." national bureau of economic research, 1942, pp. 93+. 96 16. sadd, victor and williams, robert t. causes of commercial bankruptcies. washington, dc: u.s. government printing office, 1932. 17. scapens, robert w., robert j. ryan, and leslie fletcher. "explaining corporate failure: a catastrophe theory approach." journal of business finance and accounting, vol. 8, no.1, 1981, pp. 1-25. 18. sharma, subhash and mahajan, vijay.. "early warning indicators of business failure." journal of marketing, vol. 44, fall 1980, pp. 80-89. 19. tamari, m. "financial ratios as a measure of foreca.sting bankruptcy." management international review, vol. 4, 1966, pp. 19+. 20. thompson, c. j. "danger signs of corporate insolvency." financial executive, vol. 50, june 1982, pp. 47-51. 21. toffler, richard and tisshaw, howald. "going, going, gone four factors which predict." accountancy, vol. 88, march 1977, pp. 5052+. 22. winaker, a. and smith, r. f. "changes in financial structure of unsuccessful industrial companies." bureau of business research bulletin, university of illinois press, vol. 51, 1935. 97 the strategic use of bankruptcy prediction models: an aid to executive decision making strategic responses to ballot questions by the private sector alan n. hoffman school of business the university of connecticut storrs, connecticut there has been a renewed interest among researchers to understand how regulation restricts the ability of private industry to do business. miles [19] recently wrote about the history of the tobacco industry and how it became the first major test of corporate social responsibility. the tobacco manufacturers lost their access to public broadcast media, warnings were placed on their labels, and their image and pride were wounded. yet, they developed a series of response strategies that concentrated on domain diversification and overseas expansion that changed the look of the big six from single-business firms to global-multibusiness corporations. mitnick defines regulation as: "... the public administrative policing of a private activity with respect to a rule prescribed in the public interest" ([20], p. 7). most regulatory scholars ([4],[7]) propose that there exists a system of regulation or life cycle, that is, a series of steps from the initial legislation to the establishment of a regulatory agency. farris and sampson [9], shepard [26], and wilcox and shepard [31] have each developed models of the distinct stages of regulation. however, there has been little attention paid to the role of regulatory initiatives and referenda in the regulatory literature and their effects on the performance of private industry. the present article, designed with this shortcoming in mind, shifts the focus away from the traditional regulatory process and takes an in-depth look at this non-traditional method of regulation. background in the past ten years there has been a significant increase in the number of ballot questions whose intent has been to regulate the activities of private industry. such initiatives can be extremely costly. since 1978, there have been more than fifty ballot proposals that have directly affected the regulation of several key industries: banking, defense, bottling, farming, cable television, telecommunications, and tobacco. there are two explanations why the threat of circulating initiative petitions is an integral part of the strategy of lawmaking. the first reason revolves around a state legislature's reluctance to adopt special interest legislation. the initiative process has proved to be an extremely valuable mechanism for representing special interests in our society. laws to mandate the return of bottles and cans is an example of a regulation that has been adopted by means 19 of the initiative process. the second reason for the resurgence of initiatives is that special interest groups often wish to have their proposals adopted in the exact form they were written, rather than "having them amended to death." lee [15] argues that those groups who utilize initiatives most are not significantly different form those groups who normally lobby state legislatures. initiative campaigns in the private sector the renewed interest in the initiative process may arise from the large amounts of money spent by both sides in waging these legislative battles in the public arena. for example, california voters have been subjected to several extraordinarily large and expensive regulatory initiative campaigns in the past few years. in 1980, the tobacco manufacturers spent more than $6 million to defeat a proposal to limit smoking in public areas. additionally, in the primary election of 1980, more than $6 million was spent to defeat an oil profits tax proposal. regulatory initiatives are not unique to california. in 1982, there were regulatory proposals in ten other states. one popular initiative question concerns returnable bottles. proponents of the bottle bills generally argue that returnable bottles conserve natural resources and result in a cleaner environment. opponents generally take an economic approach and claim that laws requiring returnable bottles lead to price increases in excess of the bottle deposit to cover the increased costs associated with storage, transportation, and recycling facilities. such states as michigan, massachusetts, maine, and iowa all have returnable bottle laws (michigan and massachusetts by referendum). it should be noted that these proposals are often not enacted on their first ballot attempt. in 1983, the voters of cambridge, massachusetts, voted down a citywide referendum that called for cambridge to become a nuclear free zone which would have outlawed any work, including research, on nuclear weapons or their components within the city limits after october, 1985. if cambridge had approved the proposal, draper laboratories, a privately owned spinoff of mit, would have been forced to leave the city. the banking industry has also become the target of several initiative campaigns. in three states, washington, michigan, and colorado, there have been ballot questions that would place restrictions on banking operations. in colorado, voters defeated a proposal which would have allowed branch banking. in 1982, the voters of the state of washington defeated a proposal which would have limited retail credit interest rates. the citizens of nebraska, who have witnessed large amounts of their fertile farm land being bought up by corporations, voted in 1982 to prohibit corporations (other than family farm corporations) from purchasing farm and ranch land in their state. it is now evident that initiative campaigns can cost several million dollars to wage. some of the most expensive initiative campaigns are outlined in table 1. 20 tobie 1: recent fuitiative campaigns with cost greater than '5 milliona year state issue outcome cost 1984 arizona control health costs failed > $5,000,000 1984 california lottery passed > $10,000,000 1982 california gun control failed $10,000,309 1982 california returnable bottles failed $7,076,574 1982 michigan ban automatic fuel failed $7,409,002 increases/elect psc 1981 ohio competitive worker's failed $6,000,000 compo insurance 1980 california rent control failed $6,835,433 1980 california oil profits tax failed $6,067,356 1980 california restrict smoking failed $6,000,000 asource: national center for initiative review, englewood, co, 1986 the use of fuitiative and referendum in the regulation of business ever since the brandeis court upheld government regulation of business without infringement of "due process," businesses have faced increasing costs of regulation. energy, transportation, pharmaceuticals, banking, and telecommunications are examples of a few industries that are presently regulated. according to a 1976 study by the congressional budget office, regulation of business generally takes one of the following forms: 1. ~t] impacts the operating business environment of broad sectors of private enterprise, including market entry and exit; rate price, and profit structures; and competition; 2. ~t] impacts specific commodities, products, or services through permit, certification, or licensing requirements; and 3. [it] involves the development, administration, and enforcement of national standards, violation of which could result in civil or criminal penalties which result in the types of impact described above ([20], p. 2). in most legislative bodies there is a maze of parliamentary rules and procedures that traditionally have been used by the minority to prevent or delay a vote on an issue that is favored by the majority ([30], p. 14). strong supporters of our democratic system of government find this manipulation of the rules to be one of the most serious breakdowns in the representative system of government [30]. the referendum and the right of initiative were developed to close this legislative loophole. 21 by the mid-nineteenth century, it was commonplace to require that state constitutional amendments be approved by the voters.... by 1900, americans were no strangers to the concept of approving changes in their fundamental laws by use of the referendum. that they should have the power of initiating such changes was, to many, a logical extension of their power; the right of initiative was adopted quickly in twenty-one states. neither the initiative nor the referendum, however, has ever been employed at the national level ([15], p. 46). it is important to distinguish between the initiative and the referendum processes. the initiative is the sole vehicle available to the electorate to propose legislation without the consent of the legislature. the referendum, on the other hand, ''is merely a popular veto on the acts of a legislative body. it's an instrument of negation. it is conservative, while the initiative is radical" ([30], p. 131). in an attempt to determine the percent of initiatives that eventually become law, magelby, klein, and thomas analyzed initiative results over a recent five year period and found that, when bottle bills were placed in the regulation category, "the s'llccess rate for business/labor regulation would be almost 35 percent-by far the best success rate for all categories" ([16], p. 23). in 1982, less than 30 percent of all proposals titled in initiative states actually qualified for ballot placement. there are four potential types of requirements for qualified ballot placement which, to a certain degree, vary from state to state. these requirements include (1) total number of required signatures, (2) statewide distribution of signatures, (3) certification of signatures, and (4) length of petitioning period. every initiative state has a minimum number of signatures required to place an initiative on the statewide ballot. the number of required signatures is usually a function of the number of votes cast for governor during the previous election. statewide distribution of signatures is required in several states to prevent voters from acting on issues that affect only a small segment of the state population. other states, however, have no distribution requirement, making it significantly easier to place an initiative on the statewide ballot (le., signatures may come from only one county in the state). requirements which are used to validate either all or a small "random" sample of signatures to certify authenticity are not standardized across states. finally, in three states (ohio, florida, and montana) signatures gathered in an unsuccessful petition drive can be carried forward and used in future initiative campaigns to meet signature requirements. in maine, signatures can be carried forward for one year and used in renewed initiative campaigns. a model of priv8te sector str8tegic responses to initi8tive petition responses initiative campaigns can be extremely expensive to wage. however, businesses that are unsuccessful in defending themselves from attacks via the 22 ballot box may find the implementation of regulations even costlier. businesses can scarcely afford to react to special interest groups action, instead, an anticipatory strategy is necessary. . , . (t)he first duty of strategic management is to stay abreast of organizational resources (potential as well as realized) and the opportunities and risks presented by organizational environments (potential as well as operational) ([19], p. 14). the policy problems of business, like those of policy in public affairs, have to do with the choice of purposes, the molding of organization identity, the unending definition of what needs to be done, and the mobilization of resources for the attainment of goals in the face of aggressive competition or adverse circumstances ([3], p. iv). a reactive campaign may have adverse effects on the business climate and should, if possible, be avoided by taking proactive measures at the earliest opportunity. since most modern business is conducted in dynamic an uncertain environments, thompson [27] argues that organizations should develop coping strategies to reduce the impact of uncertainty. many authors suggest that organizations can reduce uncertainty in two ways. first, organizations may reduce uncertainty through the adaptation of specified organizational structures. second, uncertainty can be reduced through the formulation of strategies aimed at altering the organization's structural environments to bring about a response-sensitive organizational-environment alignment ([1],[18],[19,[23],[27]). given the complexity of modern political environments, a model of how corporations might respond to an initiative campaign is illustrated in figure 1. this model is based on a 1982 case study of privately owned energy companies in michigan and consists of the following six phases: • prevention • organization building • coalition building • influencing public opinion • legislative action • mounting an opposition campaign 23 figure 1 model of strategic responses to ballot questions phase i phase ii phase i ii phase iv phase v phase vi prevention ~ i organization' ~ building coalition building ~ influence i~i legislative 1-1 1 mount an public opinion action opposition campaign i. prevention ii. organization building 1. open lines of 1. appoint executive. communication. 2. establish interorgan2. joint legislation. izational linkages. 3. negotiation. 3. retain legal counsel. 4. co-optation. 4. establish political steering committee 5. take the public pulse. 5. create a separate identity. v. legislative action 1. compromise legislation that would render the initiative unnecessary. 2. legislative alternative. i ii. coalition building 1. employees. 2. allies and vendors. 3. fundraising. 4. opinion leaders. 5. newspaper endorsements. 6. spokesmen. vi. mount an opposition campaign 1. retain professional campaign advice. iv. influence public opinion 1. citizens commission. 2. public relations campaign ~ n phose i: prevention in the course of normal legislative lobbying by special interest groups, the threat of circulating an initiative petition has often been used as an effective coercive tactic. modern business must be aware of this potential political occurrence and take steps to monitor such actions [10]. the needs and wants of special interest groups must be considered when formulating corporate policy. organizations that have no formal lobbying mechanism should subscribe to a legislative or an initiative monitoring service. there are several monitoring services, such as the national center for initiative review in englewood, colorado, that track circulating initiative petitions and publish a monthly newsletter on their activity. once there is evidence that petitions are circulating that might affect an organization's operations, a public opinion poll should be commissioned. in a large state, like michigan, a geo-attitudinal poll should be taken. this information is useful to assess the relative strengths and weaknesses of an organization's position. since everyone in the state votes on the same question, support for or against the proposal might be restricted to a specific region of the state. a good poll should measure more than just the amount of support or opposition to a question. it should additionally attempt to understand the public's general feeling toward the organization itself. polling should be repeated to measure changes in public opinion in response to publicity or implementation of the response strategy. the timetable for these repeated measurements are a function of the funds available for polling. funds for polling should not be an area of cost cutting since the information garnered is critical in the development and evolution of the organization's responses to adverse initiative campaigns. phose it: organization building if prevention measures are unsuccessful, there are a series of anticipatory steps which can be undertaken to increase the probability of eventual success in an initiative campaign, while minimizing the cost of the effort. the first step is to build an organization capable of responding to any potential political situation. since businesses most often face political battles with legislatures, and not the general public, a new organizational form is necessary. the size and structure of the new organizational form is a fun<;tion of two factors: (1) the results of the geo-attitudinal poll, and (2) the signals received from the legislative monitoring program. the first task for an organization faced with a potential initiative battle is to appoint an executive to coordinate the organization's response strategy. it is important that this executive be practical, have some previous experience in public affairs, and be knowledgeable about the issue and the state's political structure. the executive's first task is to establish ties with firms that would be similarly affected by the initiative. the coordinator should then solicit their support to join in a unified effort to defeat the ballot proposal. interor25 ganizational coordination should reduce duplication of effort and maximize human end financial resources. a political steering committee should be established to give the effort a pu blic identity distinct from the corporate organization( s). the steering committee shquld seek professional campaign and legal advice. strategic planning, communications, research, polling, and compliance with intricate campaign finance and election laws are a few areas the committee may want to discuss with professional consultants. phase iti: coalition building the political steering committee is responsible for formulating and implementing the response strategy and overseeing all fund-raising and budget decisions. the committee should begin by expanding its base to include other concerned individuals and groups that share in their opposition to the ballot initiative. two separate coalitions should be formed: one consisting of employees and shareholders, who have a vested interest in the continuing success of the fum, and another consisting of allies and vendors (i.e., other firms who would be either directly or indirectly affected by the new regulation). a well-built coalition will have far greater resources (i.e., people and money) and stand a better chance for ultimate success than a loosely coupled network of organizations with competing factions. for example, bottlers found that supermarkets and corner grocery stores were natural allies for their cause because these establishments would have to make provisions for storing and sorting returned bottles and cans. the most important resources a corporation has is its employees, shareholders, and allies. the overall cost of a campaign can be sharply reduced by educating these groups on the issues and training them to handle many of the administrative duties associated with a campaign effort. however, the use of employees can be expensive if they utilize company time to campaign. another critical resource to any organized effort is money. a full-fledged campaign can cost millions of dollars, as evidenced most recently in michigan and california. the establishment of a coalition of allies and vendors can be a valuable source of funds and will allow the cost of a campaign to be spread over several firms, instead of one firm absorbing the full financial burden. the use of outside political consultants makes sense when the complexity of the task becomes unmanageable for company executives. the response strategy can be formulated and implemented by these outside consultants. phase iv: influencing public opinion a comprehensive communications plan needs to be created based on the poll results and other research data at the company's disposal. the communications plan should include such items as direct mail, selected advertising, non-corporate endorsements, and third party spokespersons, with no vested interests, speaking out through a coordinated speakers bureau. radio and television commercials need to additionally be developed to communicate the 26 message of the campaign to the different geographic and demographic target groups within the state. phase v: legislative action businesses can utilize their existing lobbying force to propose compromise legislation that would satisfy both sides and render a campaign unnecessary. a costly campaign showdown should be avoided if at all possible since the results can never be absolutely predicted. compromise legislation may not be attainable because of a lack of agreement between the legislature and the governor. an alternative strategy may be to persuade the legislature to place an alternative question on the ballot that would provide another avenue to defeat the original initiative. all initiative states provide the legislature with the power to place an alternative competing question on the 'ballot. phase vi: mounting an opposition campaign a michigan case study in 1982, consumer advocates in the state of michigan successfully placed an initiative on the statewide ballot that, if adopted, would have adversely affected the economic stability of michigan's three major privately-owned energy providers: the detroit edison company, consumers power company, and the michigan consolidated gas company. this initiative-based proposal, labeled proposition d, called for a ban on all automatic rate increases except when approved at "full cost of service" hearings. the initiative also limited the frequency of these hearings. the consumer groups in michigan achieved a measure of success, despite spending only about $100,000, because their strategy and organization were both highly effective. they were successful in two ways: (1) they forced the private energy companies to support legislation that would abolish automatic fuel adjustments, and (2) they obtained free publicity from their legal maneuvers which allowed them to capitalize on a general hostility among voters toward energy providers. this second area of success arose from the practice of exerting legal challenges to the energy companies' ballot alternative. additionally, the consumer groups were organized at the grass-roots level which allowed them wide exposure and valuable free labor. in june, 1982" after an intensive lobbying effort by energy companies, the michigan state legislature voted to place an alternative referendum, labeled proposition h, on the november ballot. the consumer groups challenged the constitutionality of the alternative referendum in the courts and in september, 1982, the michigan supreme court ruled that the alternative proposal should be placed on the ballot to give the voters a choice. the energy companies made four strategic decisions from the outset that were critical to their ultimate success in defeating the initiative question: 27 • they pooled and committed whatever human and financial resources were necessary to wage a unified campaign • they sought outside counsel to plan and execute their strategy • they fully utilized their legislative options • they established a public coalition separate from their corporate identities to broaden their base of support, allowing a diverse constituency to join their effort (i.e., labor, business, and civic groups) the energy companies response strategy was unique in that: • it allied three competitors against a common problem • it developed a coalition of labor and business support • it supplied the voters an alternative ballot question to vent their frustration toward higher energy bills • it was the second most costly initiative campaign to that date, costing $7,409,002 results in november, 1982, 51 percent of the voters of michigan gave proposal d, the citizen initiative, a yes vote while the energy companies' alternative referendum, proposal h, received nearly 57 percent. legal precedent in michigan has held that if two similar ballot questions both receive a majority vote, the question with the greatest number of affirmative votes prevails. proposal h outpolled proposal d by 198,000 votes. it was an expensive victory for the energy companies. discussion private energy companies, like many other industries, operate in full view of the public and are prepared to respond to regulation from normal government channels. most corporations have established public relations departments and have in-house lobbyists that deal with regulatory agencies, state legislatures, and congress. while many other organizations operate in the public domain, they are not used to being regulated by the general public. most organizations have established contacts with local politicians, opinion leaders, and newspapers. these are not the type of citizen groups that usually initiate a regulatory petition drive. for example, the dart-kraft company is used to responding to regulation concerning the price and quality of dairy products by the food and drug administration (fda). however, they did not perceive that they would become part of the solution to another important problem-hunger in the united states-by becoming directly affected by president ronald reagan's cheese 28 giveaway program. dart-kraft's cheese sales decreased nearly six percent when the giveaway began and the lobbyists of dart-kraft were unsuccessful in their attempt to influence the congress and the fda to modify the program. the inability to revise the program may be attributable, in part, to the immense popularity of the program with the general public. there have been several changes in the use of the initiative since its inception, from the initial purpose of ratifying constitutional amendments and local charters. not 811 states have the right of initiative, nor does there exist a national referendum process. however, initiatives are popular in those states that have them. in california, 85 percent of the voters thought that direct legislation was a good idea [16]. finally, many businesses are finding that elected representatives no longer respond to lobbyists the way they once did. today's representatives are listening more to the constituents they represent. business executives need to learn how to get their message to the general public as a way to influence future legislation rather than relying on the lobbying system. hopefully, this article is a step in that direction. references 1. aldrich, howard and pfeffer, jeffrey. "environments of organizations," annual review of sociology, vol. 2, palo alto, ca: annual review inc., 1976. 2. anderson, jack. "tax revolt: the opening of the u.s. wide movement," de8eret new8, june 13, 1978, p. a3. 3. andrews, kenneth r. the concept of corporate strategy, revised edition, homewood, il: richard d. irwin, 1980. 4. backoff, robert w. "operationalizing administrative reform for improved governmental performance," admini8trative science quarterly, vol. 6, no.1, may, 1974, pp. 73-106. 5. bolt, ernest c., jr. ballob before bullet8: the war referendum approach to peace in america, charlottesville, va: the university of virginia press, 1977. 6. butler, david and ranney, austin. referendums: a comparative study of practice and theory, washington, dc: american enterprise institute for public policy and research, 1978. 7. davis, lance e. and north, douglass c. in8titutional change and american economic growth, cambridge, ma: cambridge university press, 1971. 8. everett, david. "utilities use subtle offense to win at the polls," the detroit new8, november 7, 1982. 29 9. farris, martin t. and sampson, roy j. public utilities: regulation, management and ownership, boston, ma: houghton mifflin, 1973. 10. grefe, edward a., fighting to win: busineljs political power, new york, ny: harcourt, brace jovanovich, 1981. 11. hoffman, alan n., cynthia spanhel, and rolf carlson. ''the answer book," unpublished monograph, matt reese and associates, 1982. 12. initiative quarterly, 1.1, englewood, co: national center for initiative review, october 1982, pp. 7-8. 13. kilpatrick, james. "the year of the taxpayer," san f'rancmco chronicle, june 2, 1978, p. 52. 14. kraft, joseph. "populist hedonism," washington poljt, june 11, 1978, p. c7. 15. lee, alton. the referendum device, new york, ny: macmillan book co., 1981. 16. magleby, david b., walt klein, and sue thomas. "the initiative in the 1980s: popular support, issue agendas, and legislative reform of the process," paper presented at the 1982 annual meeting of the american political science association. 17. mathews, jay. "initiative process gains popularity," waljhington poljt, may 29, 1982. 18. miles, raymond e., charles c. snow, and jeffrey pfeffer. "organizationalenvironment: concepts and issues," induljtrial relationlj, vol. 13, no. 3, pp. 244-264. 19. miles, robert h. coffin nails and corporate strategies, englewood cliffs, nj: prentice-hall, 1982. 20. mitnick, barry m. the political economy of regulation, new york, ny: columbia university press, 1980. 21. mitnick, barry m. ''the strategic uses of regulation and deregulation," busineljlj horizonlj, march/april, 1981, pp. 71-83. 22. navarro, peter. "our stake in the electric utility's dilemma," harvard business review, may/june 1982, pp. 87-97. 23. pfeffer, jeffrey, and leblebici, huseyin. ''the effect of competition on some dimensions of organizational structure," social forcelj, vol. 52, no.2, pp. 268-279. 30 24. price, charles m. 'the initiative: a comparative state analysis and assessment of a western phenomena," western" political quarterly, vol. 28, june 1975, pp. 243-263. 25. quinn, robert s. 'the initiative: who needs it? ," maine sunday telegram, march 14, 1982, p. 4d. 26. shepard, william g. the treatment of afarket power: antitrust, regulation, and public enterpri!le, new york, ny: columbia university press, 1975. 27. thompson, james d. organizations in action, new york, ny: mcgrawhill, 1967. 28. vitali, samuel a., and vento, gerald t. "problems with the initiative and referendum process," unpublished working paper, peralta, gilligan and vitali, 1982. 29. walsh, lawrence r. 'the role of public relations in initiative campaigns," unpublished working paper, hill and knowlton, 1982. 30. wilcox, delos. government by all the people, new york, ny: dacapo press, 1972. 31. wilcox, clair, and shepard, william g. public policies toward business, third edition, homewood, il: richard d. irwin, 1966. 32. will, george. "california votes to undo what has been done," los angeles times, june 8, 1978, p. b7. 31 strategic responses to ballot questions by the private sector volume 34, number 2 111 real estate investment decisions i: commercial office property acquisitions jonathan breazeale sam houston state university • huntsville, tx case description the primary subject matter of this case concerns the financial analysis of the acquisition of a commercial office property. secondary issues examined include aspects of office reits – with which most business students are unfamiliar. the case has a difficulty level of four, appropriate for undergraduate seniors. the case is designed to be taught in a single 80 minute class period and is expected to require three to four hours of outside preparation by students (depending on their level of spreadsheet familiarity). case synopsis you are a member of the investment committee and serve as an outside director on the board of city view office, a publicly traded real estate investment trust (reit) with a focus on commercial office properties. it is the fourth quarter of 2005, and management’s acquisition team has just submitted a package for your approval that will solidify the offer that has just been presented on the forum, a beautiful six-story class a property in the energy corridor of houston, texas. your vote will determine whether or not the firm moves forward with the purchase. real estate investment trusts (reits) real estate investment trusts (reits) were created by congress in 1960 to allow small investors access to capital intensive, large-scale real estate. small investors are allowed to pool their equity in reits just as they would in any other corporation, enabling them to participate in an industry that was formerly inaccessible for the purpose of diversifying their personal portfolios. reits own and, in many cases, operate income-producing real estate of a specific type or types. for instance, there are reits that own office buildings, industrial properties, apartments, hotels, shopping centers, timber, or a combination of these and other types of real estate. reits may also own financial assets such as mortgages and other real estate financing. the most important aspect of a reit is that it does not pay corporate income taxes as long as it meets certain requirements the most important of which 112 journal of business strategies is that it distributes 90% of its otherwise taxable income to its shareholders each year in the form of dividends. it is a great advantage for equity investors to receive untaxed distributions, but the reit is faced with the difficulty of having to access capital markets frequently for external funding since it cannot use much of its net income to fund investment in new assets. in other words, reits have very small amounts of retained earnings on their balance sheets. due to the large amount of depreciation arising from investment in long-term fixed assets and the large gains/losses that can result from the sale of large assets, reits utilize measures of financial performance that deviate somewhat from gaap measures reported by other public corporations. the national association of real estate investment trusts® (nareit – www.nareit.com) is an industry organization that provides services to reits and acts on behalf of its member firms in lobbying and other political efforts. nareit defines the measure funds from operations (ffo) as net income (on a gaap basis) excluding gains or losses from sales of most property as well as depreciation of real estate (national association of real estate investment trusts, inc., 2007). this provides a measure of operating performance more consistent with the recurring nature of the reit’s operations rather than net income that is influenced by large one-time transactions such as asset sales or large changes in depreciation brought about by either sales or acquisitions. therefore, ffo provides a measure that is more consistent with the types of assets held by reits and allows for better comparison of the operating performance of multiple reits as well as trend analysis of individual reits year after year. while ffo provides a more consistent measure of operating performance for the real estate industry, it is not well suited to provide a measure of how much cash is available for a reit to pay its all-important dividends. as a result, some reits also disclose funds available for distribution (fad) which might also be reported as cash available for distribution (cad) or adjusted ffo. while ffo is “standardized” across the industry, the calculation of fad is not. however, fad is essentially ffo less capital expenditures (tenant improvement allowances, leasing commissions, non-revenue enhancements, capital improvements to new acquisitions, etc.) that reduce the actual amount of cash that is available to distribute to shareholders. at the start of 2005, there were more than 200 publicly traded reits on u.s. stock exchanges with assets valued at nearly $1 trillion. office properties comprise approximately 19% of the total value of assets owned by reits making them the largest property type in which reits are invested (national association of real estate investment trusts, 2007). volume 34, number 2 113 city view office properties city view office has been taking it on the chin recently. falling occupancy and rental rates nationwide, along with rising insurance and electricity costs, have resulted in an inability to cover the dividend for the past three years. hot money has also entered every major real estate market in the country – making the acquisition of assets more difficult with the high cost of corporate capital. fortunately, city view office has just closed on a joint venture with a large public employee pension fund that will allow them to pursue investment opportunities with acceptable lower yields. additional yield for city view will come from management, leasing, and construction management fees associated with their wholly-owned realty service subsidiary. terms of the joint venture state that city view realty services has a 10-year non-cancelable contract for these services on every acquisition made by the joint venture. table 1 summarizes the joint venture’s current purchasing criteria. table 1 city view office properties’ published joint venture acquisition criteria size: 100,000 to 1,500,000 square feet, multi-story (250,000 for new markets) quality: class a, aor b+ leasing: 70% to 100% leased to quality credit tenants yield: 7.0% capitalization rate based on 92% occupancy, risk and quality of tenants. unleveraged irr of 8.0%. ownership: 100% fee simple parking: parking must adequately accommodate market and building code requirements as well as service the building at 100% occupancy. replacement cost: current replacement cost cannot exceed the purchase price. replacement cost is the total development cost to recreate the property – and its economics – in today’s dollars. markets: new york boston washington d.c. atlanta chicago houston los angeles phoenix tenants: preference for buildings with a major tenant (30% or more of the total rentable square feet) with at least 5 years remaining on lease. debt: purchases are conducted in all cash. disclaimer: at its sole discretion, city view has deviated and may deviate from its published criteria. 114 journal of business strategies houston office market houston has been a bright spot in an otherwise dismal climate of economic expectations. both occupancy and rental rates are on the rebound – as evidenced by the pace of construction in a majority of the submarkets. and, despite the recessionary overtones heard nationwide as a result of the retraction of inflated residential values, the heavy energy presence in houston has somewhat insulated the commercial office market from the current economic downturn. oil prices continue to climb, and that is good news for houston. city would love to own more property in a market where expansion is actually occurring. table 2 summarizes the current state of both the houston energy corridor submarket and the overall houston market. table 2 class “a” office market statistics market metric energy corridor total houston market size 5,917,994 square feet 58,145,642 square feet vacancy 5.7% 15.5% average rental rate $22.68 $20.67 the energy corridor has long been known as the home of many top players in the energy industry. in close proximity to the forum, british petroleum, exxon mobil, conoco phillips, shell oil, citgo, halliburton, schlumberger and aker maritime all lease substantial amounts of office space. since oil and gas are the revenue generators for these firms, rental rates are very closely tied to oil and gas prices. when oil prices are high, these firms expand their operations and need additional office space. historical rental rates for the energy corridor for the last 8 years have been $25.00, $22.90, $20.50, $24.23, $21.81, $21.79, $21.84, and $22.68, respectively. the forum the forum is a 150,000 square foot, six-story, class a office building located within the energy corridor of houston, texas. it is 100% leased to four quality credit tenants, the largest of which (aaa oil) occupies almost 75% of the building. the existing tenant base has a weighted average gross rental rate of $20.29 and a remaining lease term of 44 months. baring an unforeseen catastrophe, the initial yield of the investment appears solid. the property is located on a 5.3 acre site, volume 34, number 2 115 and a 596 space parking garage services the building (approximately 4 spaces per 1000 square feet of rentable office space). the building and garage were completed in 1999, so no substantial capital expenditures are projected in the near future. the current quoted gross rental rate is $23.00 per foot, and the seller is offering the property on a 100% fee simple basis. the typical floor plate is approximately 25,000 square feet, and each floor is serviced by three dover geared passenger elevators. an additional service elevator is located at a loading dock, and two hydraulic elevators service the four-level garage structure. construction consists of a cast-in-place reinforced concrete slab at grade. the superstructure is comprised of reinforced cast-in-place concrete framing which includes columns, shear walls, elevated concrete floor slabs and roof slabs. exterior walls are precast panels with fixed aluminum framed insulated glass windows. the roof is constructed of multi-ply bituminous built-up roofing membrane over the concrete deck and is toped with aggregate. two 269-ton trane rotary liquid chilled water units provide air conditioning to the building, and all systems are controlled by a johnson controls energy management system. the building uses pneumatic thermostats. the property is well lit on the exterior, and a superior life safety system is in place for fire and other contingencies. management has provided you with the timeline submitted by the seller’s broker in the offering memorandum. this information is contained in table 3. table 3 seller’s desired transaction timetable august 25, 2005 announcement mailing delivered to prospective purchasers investor registration commences september 2, 2005 distribution of offering memoranda to registered parties inspection tours conducted by appointment only informational meetings with property management and interested parties additional material will be made available for review: form purchase and sale agreement boundary survey/site plan preliminary title report tenant leases historical operating information property tax information as-built floor plans operating budget 116 journal of business strategies october 5, 2005 offers are due by letter of intent (loi) in the broker’s office by 5 p.m. investors are encouraged to include verifiable financial information, transaction references and financial references together with their lois. october 12, 2005 finalist(s) selected finalist interviews/conference calls reference checks investigation of funding capabilities october 14, 2005 selection process completed notification to all remaining parties letter of intent executed october 21, 2005 purchase & sale agreement executed formal due diligence period commences information delivery to purchaser november 18, 2005 due diligence period ends earnest money deposit non-refundable december 2, 2005 closing financial projections and market assumptions management has included the forum’s rent roll and the broker’s pro forma cash flow statement that was included in the offering memorandum – along with the included assumptions. tables 4, 5 and 6 detail these crucial sets of information. volume 34, number 2 117 t ab le 4 . r en t r ol l ta bl e 4 r en t r ol l 118 journal of business strategies t ab le 5 . t he f or um p ro f or m a c as h f lo w ta bl e 5 t he f or um p ro f or m a c as h f lo w . . . volume 34, number 2 119 table 6 notes to pro forma cash flow statement (1) average annual occupancy is subject to the broker’s projected lease-up schedule and 12 months of downtime between non-recurring leases. (2) market rental rate / rsf is the assumed market base rent expressed as a gross rate with the tenant being responsible for its prorate share of recoverable operating expenses in excess of a base year amount. the market rental rate for 2006, 2007, and 2008 is $23, $24, and $25, respectively. following 2008, the market rental rate increases 3% annually. (3) base rent is projected pursuant to the terms of existing leases and the following assumptions: all expiring leases are subject to 12 months of downtime and seven-year renewal terms. aaa oil is subject to an 80% renewal probability, while the other tenants are subject to a 65% renewal probability. effective 09/01/2005, the green company (suite 200) reduces its square footage from 16,694 sf to 14,909 sf and continues to pay a base rental rate of $26.85. effective 09/01/2005, griffin gas (suite 225) expands by 1,692 sf to 10,175 sf and extends its current term from 02/28/2006 to 02/28/2011. the rate for the expansion space is $23.00, while the rate for the original premises (8,483 sf) remains at $24.15 until 02/28/2006. on 03/01/2006, the rate for the original premises changes to $23.00. effective 09/01/2005, the management office, which provides no income for the duration of the analysis, expands by 93sf to 1,665 sf. (4) expense recoveries reflects charges to tenants for their respective pro rata share of escalatable operating expenses. aaa oil reimburses in proportionate share of operating expenses on a “nnn” basis plus a management fee equal to 3% of its base rental and recoveries (excluding the standard property management fee). all other tenants reimburse their proportionate share of recoverable operating expenses that exceed a stated or base year amount. moonguard’s $9.00 expense stop resets to a 2006 base year effective 11/01/205, while the green company’s $8.00 expense stop remains constant throughout the analysis. griffin gas’ original square footage (8,483) is subject to an $8.93 expense stop through 02/28/2006, while the expansion space (1,692) is subject to a 2006 base year effective 09/01/2005. griffin’s entire space is subject to a 2006 base year effective 03/01/2006. per griffin’s lease, reimbursements ) ) 120 journal of business strategies are limited by the controlled growth of the property’s recoverable operating expenses. operating expenses cannot increase by more than $8,483 annually through 08/31/2006 and by $10,175 annually thereafter. base year stops are assumed for all renewals other than aaa oil, which assumes a nnn recovery upon renewal. (5) parking income is based on management’s 2005 budgeted amount and inflates 3% annually. (6) telecom income reflects the 2005 schedule rental income from sprint ($18,000) and at&t ($3,417) agreements inflated 3.25% per annum. (7) miscellaneous income consists of management’s 2005 budgeted amounts for overtime utility charges ($50,100) and parking sales tax ($4,358) that inflate 3% annually. (8) collection loss reflects a 1% reduction to schedule base rent for non-credit tenants. the loss factor is not applied to aaa oil or griffin gas during their initial terms. (9) cleaning includes charges for contract cleaning, window washing, trash removal, a day porter, cleaning supplies, and other cleaning expenses. management’s 2005 budgeted amount inflates 3% annually. (10) utilities include the cost for electricity, water, and sewer. management’s 2005 budgeted amount of $356,600 is reduced by $50,100 to exclude directly billed overtime electricity, which is reclassified as a non-recoverable expense. the net amount of $306,500 inflates 3% annually. (11) repairs & maintenance represents all maintenance-related costs for the building including engineer salary and benefits, electrical, hvac, plumbing, elevators, roof, painting, exterminating, supplies, life safety, interior landscaping, and other maintenance related items. management’s 2005 total budgeted amount inflates 3% per annum. (12) security consists of contract charges for guards’ salaries and equipment monitoring. management’s 2005 budgeted amount inflates by 3% per annum. (13) landscaping & grounds expense includes budgeted amounts for exterior landscaping and sweeping. the 2005 budgeted amount inflates by 3% per annum. (14) general & administrative includes various business related costs associated with operating the building such as property manager salary and benefits, management office rent, corporate overhead, telephone, garage expenses, accounting fees, tax consulting fees, and other office related expenses. management’s 2005 budgeted amount inflates 3% per annum. volume 34, number 2 121 (15) management fee is calculated as 2% of effective gross revenue in each year of the analysis. (16) insurance reflects the total liability insurance premiums for the building. management’s 2005 budgeted amount grows by 3% per annum. (17) association dues reflect annual assessments by the owner’s association. management’s 2005 budgeted amount inflates 3% annually. (18) real estate taxes for the first year of the analysis reflect the projected 2005 property taxes that will be paid in 2006. the first year taxes are estimated by inflating the actual aggregate 2004 tax rate of $3.09125 by 3% and applying the result to the 2004 assessed value of $18,332,620. property taxes for 2006, which are paid in 2007, assume the property is reassessed to 70% of the sales price and are subject to the inflated 2005 tax rate of $3.18399 inflated by 3%. thereafter, property taxes increase 3% annually. (19) non-recoverable includes directly billed overtime electricity ($50,100), parking sales taxes ($4,358), and delivery expense ($1,000). the aggregate amount inflates 3% per annum. (20) tenant improvements reflects the total cost to build out leased office areas for both new and renewing tenants. new leases on second-generation space receive a $15 allowance, while all renewing leases are granted a $6 allowance. the assumed amounts for the tenant improvement allowances are expressed in 2006 dollars. tenant improvement allowances for second-generation space grow annually by the general inflation rate. (21) leasing commissions are calculated as 6% of the net effective value of the lease on new leases and 5% for all renewals. all leasing commissions are assumed to be funded 100% upon occupancy. (22) capital reserves of $.10 per square foot are funded in 2006 and increase 3% annually thereafter. references national association of real estate investment trusts. (2007). frequently asked questions about reits: answers to fundamental questions about reits. washington, d.c. 122 journal of business strategies instructors’ notes real estate concepts included in the text of the case are details related to real estate investment trusts (reits). this information is not necessarily pertinent to the calculations required to make decisions about whether to purchase the property in question (the forum), but rather to expose students to an industry they might not otherwise be exposed to in a typical course in financial management. reits (both public and private) are a driving force in the market for commercial real estate, and they own many of the properties that other types of businesses lease space from to conduct their operations. in other words, students stand a good chance of a reit being their commercial landlord. the details in the included offering memorandum closely resemble that of an actual property that sold in the energy corridor of the houston office market in 2005. the name of the property and tenants have been altered, but the express permission of the selling broker to use the offering memorandum has been given. it is an actual real estate deal in a large submarket of a major us city. the math involved in the analysis of the purchase is just difficult enough to give students a feel for how complex real estate valuation can be – especially the estimation of expected future cash flows. the property has four tenants – which is a sweet spot. a single tenant property is substantially easier to analyze. a thirty-tenant property is substantially more difficult. suggested questions for students as students analyze the merits of this investment opportunity, here is a list of questions intended to spark discussion of this capital budgeting opportunity. possible solutions are included. 1. should you purchase the building? answer: as with all capital budgeting questions, the answer depends on the npv of the investment opportunity. student answers here will vary. there are many potential inputs and considerations when identifying the marginal cash flows associated with the office property. students should not rely on the analysis conducted by the selling agent. the agent’s motivation is to generate as high of a sales price volume 34, number 2 123 for the property as possible. he or she will make the numbers look as rosy as can be for the existing set of contracts. students should be skeptical of all the inputs. remember, real estate is sold via a firstprice sealed-bid auction, and the principles of the winner’s curse certainly applies. the buyer should conduct the financial analysis assuming the worst case scenario. an example of this is parking revenue. current tenants are paying for parking, but remember that this is a suburban office property in houston, texas. land (and parking) are in abundance. chances are good that as tenants renew, they will be less likely to pay top dollar for parking spaces as the building ages. 2. what is an appropriate offer price? answer: a detailed excel analysis is available from the author via email at btrazeale@shsu.edu. a conservative estimate for an appropriate purchase price is between $18-20 million. note that our solution is extremely conservative. we’ve included none of the rooftop income or parking revenue in the analysis. we’ve not assumed any increase in rental rates (or expenses) over the next ten years. it may be the case that these adjustments may need to be made in order to be competitive, but technology changes (rooftop). also, our solution provides expected future cash flows on an annual basis. more precise estimates should be calculated on a monthly basis since rent is paid twelve times a year. 3. what makes you comfortable about the purchase? answer: the number one thing that real estate purchasers are concerned about is the financial well-being of the tenants on the rent roll. each of the firms are of quality credit, and that is comforting (although a formal credit analysis is anticipated during due diligence). another nice thing about the property is that it is a relatively new property. capital expenditures in the first years of ownership (other than leasing costs) should be minimal. the roof and heating/ cooling system are in good shape – as is the garage, elevators and life safety systems. eco_wbg sticky note jbreazeale@shsu.edu 124 journal of business strategies 4. what makes you uncomfortable about the purchase? answer: the property is 100% leased to four tenants, but each of them do not occupy 25% of the property. aaa oil is the 800-pound gorilla. the financial success of the investment will be determined by whether or not they intend to renew their lease at the property. their renewal option has sweeteners, but will they be enough to keep aaa oil at the building – paying rent? 5. what type of change(s) in your assumptions would cause you to change your answer to question (2)? answer: aaa oil is modeled as having a 75% likelihood of renewal. if they are less likely to renew than that, then the purchase offer should be lower. their option to renew states that they can renew at 95% of the current market rate (currently $23.00). will they really stay at that price? they currently only pay $18.61 per square foot per year. increasing from $18.61 to $21.85 is an extra $362,000 per year in rent. that may be enough for them to leave – unless you are willing to accept a lower rental rate. 6. what aspects of this real estate case differ from other industrial problems or cases that you’ve worked through in the past? answer: student answers to this question will vary with their previous experience. most student experiences have likely involved production questions (quantity and price) to obtain expected future cash flows. here they are asked to evaluation lease contracts (effectively receivables). brief biograpical sketch of author dr. jonathan breazeale is associate professor of finance at sam houston state university – where he teaches business finance, financial markets and institutions, and security analysis and portfolio management. his research interests include real estate, financial education, and working with students interested in publishing research – at both the undergraduate and graduate levels. prior to becoming a professor, dr. breazeale was vice president of parkway properties, inc. (nyse: pky), a public real estate investment trust (reit) invested in office properties. the experience curve's role in strategic planning mark kroll and roxanna hannan department of management sam houston state university huntsville, texas managers attempting to assess their position in the industry in which they compete, and understand where their firm and industry are headed might benefit from a concept which has been around for a while: the experience curve. the experience curve, or learning curve, was first popularized during world war ii, as government contractors searched for ways to predict costs and time requirements for construction of ships and aircraft (15). later, the boston college group (bcg) used it as one of the foundations upon which they built their "beg growth-share matrix." this paper examines the current status of the experience curve, and its value in the strategic management process. first, the concept of the experience curve is reviewed, along with reasons why costs behave as it suggests. then the relationship between the experience curve and market share is developed, and implications are outlined. next, some of the shortcomings of this relationship are discussed. finally, some guidelines for deciding when and how the experience curve should be used are provided, along with an illustration. the experience curve revisited while the applications of the experience curve, and names given it have changed over the years, the basic concept remains the same. experience curves represent attempts to model the often observed fact that costs in many industries go down as accumulated output increases. while the rate of decline varies from industry to industry, the decline of costs is often highly predictable when constant dollars are used as the unit of measure. it is postulated that every time cumulative output doubles, per unit costs go down by a certain percentage (which is often determined using historical data for the industry). for instance, if an industry is found to have an eighty percent experience curve, and the first unit costs $10 to produce, then the predicted cost for unit two would be $8 ($10 x .80). unit four's predicted cost would be $6.40 (or $8.00 x .80). unit eight's predicted cost would obviously be $5.12, eighty percent of unit four's cost, and so on. exhibit 1 34 illustrates the relationship between accumulated volume (horizontal axis) and direct cost per unit (vertical axis) (7, p. 109). exhibit 1: accumulated volume and cost per unit direct cost/ $10 un; t $ 9 $ 8 $ 7 $6 $ 5 $ 4 $ 3 $ 2 $ 1 $ 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 accumulated volume this cost behavior has been found to exist in a variety of industries, although the cost coefficient varies by industry. the experience curve for margarine production has consistently been found to be about 79%. italian refrigerator manufacturers report an 82% experience curve. even service industries such as life insurance have reported significant experience curve effects over the last thirty-five to forty years (1). reasons for declining costs there are three basic reasons why the experience curve effect exists. these include exogenous progress, economies of scale, and basic improvement learned from cumulative output (4). exogenous progress. this first source includes such factors as improving technologies, improved production layouts, more efficient maintenance schema and better distribution of the final product. in addition, the introduction of new technology to improve performance becomes feasible as higher volume levels justify such commitments. for example, introducing computer controlled production and automation allows management to focus less on routine administrative and managerial duties and more on product advancement and further cost reduction. however, these improvements require that the company achieve enough volume to justify· such costly investments (7, p. 112). as a firm moves down the experience curve, exogenous progress follows something of a compounding effect, allowing the firm to become even more efficient and thus 'lowering its costs even further. 35 economies of scale. economies of scale, or the decrease in average unit costs as productive capacity is expanded, explains a large portion of decreases in costs. economies can usually be achieved in nearly every step of the production process. high volume production increases the availability of improved technology. often resources can only be profitably used when incorporated into fairly large operations. backward and forward integration of manufacturing processes and business activities, which often permits significant savings, can be justified only by large firms operating in stable environments. also, increases in scale often result in a decrease in the firm's cost of capital relative to competitors. as the cost of capital decreases, the company gains an obvious strategic advantage over competitors (11). basic improvement. the last source of cost reduction is basic labor and management improvement gained from cumulative experience. the repetitive performance of a task allows an individual and an organization to learn more about that task and develop skills to complete the task in more efficient ways. such learning leads to specialization and standardization, product improvements through design modification, better utilization and substitution of materials, rationalization of the product-mix and improvements' in the manufacturing process. strategic implications of the relationship between experience and market share the experience curve is normally used 'as a guide in forecasting cost behavior and as such has important strategic internal and external implications. internally, it can provide forcasted cost targets useful in controlling performance. externally, the experience curve permits competitive comparisons (2). this process of comparison has led to a linkage between the experience curve and relative market share. experience curve-market share relationship it has been suggested that if firms competing in a given industry face a fairly uniform experience curve, the company with the greatest cumulative output will have the lowest costs in the industry and therefore the highest profitability (2). in most instances, the firm with the greatest market share will be the one with the greatest cumulative output. as a result, the firm with the largest market share is typically furthest out on the experience curve (having the most accumulated experience) and therefore has the lowest cost. this gives the company not only a cost advantage, but positions the firm so that it can lead the industry in technological innovation and exogenous progress, further enhancing its competitive position. this logic seems to have been in part validated by the results of the profit impact of market strategy study (pims) (9) which identified and measured the major determinants of return on investment (roi). the study found that in various industries each 10 percentage point gain in market share was generally 36 accompanied by a 5 percentage improvement in pre-tax return on investment (roi). the linkage between profitability and market share has also been supported by additional studies of various unrelated industries. in the household and personal care products industry for instance, when firms are ranked according to market share (horizontal axis, exhibit 2) and operating margin (vertical axis, exhibit 2) the results show that as market share increases so do profits (2). exhibit 2: market share and operating margin operating 50 margin 10 5 colgatepalmolive lever brothers procter and gamble 1.0 strategic implications 5.0 10.0 50.0 100 percent of market the relationship between market share and profitability has some important implications for pricing strategies and long-term company survival. exhibit 3 represents the relationship between accumulated output and direct cost per unit (7, p. 114-115). as can be seen, firm a has a significant cost advantage over its competitors. firm d is a marginal firm whose survival will largely be determined by the strategic moves of firm a, which is capable of waging sustained price wars. in such a situation each firm will need to make some fundamental strategic decisions. firm a, if aware of its cost advantage, will need to identify and develop options relative to firms b, c and d. firm d must decide whether to stay in the industry as a marginal competitor, liquidate, or incur the costs necessary to achieve a greater market share. if firm d chooses to remain as a marginal player, it will likely survive only as long as firm a wishes to avoid direct price competition. 37 exhibit 3: company survival cost/ unit b a accumulated output company survival. bruce henderson (1979), building upon the logic just presented, proposes that a stable, competitive industry never has more than three significant competitors, the largest of which has no more than four times the market share of the smallest. this proposition has some important implications. first, if there are many firms competing, a shake-out will inevitably occur in the absence of outside constraints on the competitors. the market leaders (firms a and b in exhibit 3) will likely apply pressure on the low marketshare firms (firms c and d) until the two largest competitors are the only non-losers. second, in order to survive, a firm's volume must grow at a rate faster than the market as a whole or their market share will decrease. when market share decreases, at the very least, large amounts of cash must be used to gain it back which will penalize profits. thirdly, the quicker investments in marginal firms, such as firm d in exhibit 3 are cashed out the better, as such firms are likely to become cash-traps requiring perpetual reinvestments of positive cash flows to compensate for loosing years. investments in firms other than the top one or two are quite risky. pricing implications. in terms of new product pricing, a decision must be made whether to charge a price which reflects the eventual experience curve related savings, or price reflecting initial unit costs. a lower price might be used to gain market share, though as shown later, this does not always work. an alternative is to set a high initial price and enjoy high profits as costs decline, before competitors eventually force prices down. either way, when new competitors start to enter, prices normally decline faster than costs are declining for the average firm. this is true because of the relatively high cost position on the experience curve of the average firm. 38 shortcomings of the experience curve market share phenomenon the experience curve-market share phenomenon and its implications seem straight-forward; leaving the impression that only market share leaders will be profitable and the experience curve will ultimately determine profitability. however, there are limitations to the usefulness of the relationship for strategic planning, and market share is not the only route to profitability. some limitations the experience curve is not a concept that can be applied to all firms in all industries, and those firms that can use the concept need to recognize three major limitations. discontinuation. first, the benefits of learning by doing, at least at the manufacturing level, discontinue after a certain level of output is attained. at some point, the accumulated volume necessary to double output becomes so great and the reduction in costs resulting from a doubling of output so small as to render the experience curve irrelevant (6). change of strategy. secondly, when a firm which has focused exclusively on the market share-volume-cost relationship reaches the limits of that relationship, it may find development of new strategies difficult (14). a company sometimes loses its innovativeness and flexibility because all its energies have been directed toward pursuing the experience curve in one field or product. new strategies can also be very costly if they involve a major change in the technology the company is familiar with and has invested heavily in. the classic example of this is henry ford and his model t. his heavy investments of time and money in the production of the model t were for a time very profitable, until consumers demanded something else. at that point, ford motor lost its innovative edge. since so much was invested in the specific production of the model t, product change was very costly. the resulting setback caused ford to lose market share and leadership of the industry (1). sometimes the transition can be so difficult and costly that it even forces companies out of business. such was the case with the shift from manual to electric typewriters, and mechanical adding machines to electronic calculators (1). spillover effect. finally there is a "spill-over effect" associated with the experience curve phenomenon. a company may reduce its costs not only through its own experience to date, but also through industry-wide experience. the spill-over effect accelerates the process of cost reduction for the entire industry and often reduces the incentive for firms to aggressively pursue cost-reducing measures. this is especially true in industries where the learning process is a matter of public record, as has been the case in the nuclear power plant construction industry (12). 39 alternative approaches the experience curve, as shown earlier, has its limitations and should not be used by all companies. it may be possible to compete effectively without single-mindedly pursuing market share. innovation appears to be the key to alternative strategies. a study done of the nation's most successful mid-size companies found that 74 percent have an innovative product, service or marketing approach (3). innovation is a common thread running through porter's (10) strategic alternatives to pursuing high market share. product differentiation and targeting are two of his more interesting alternatives. differentiation. studies have shown that market share is less important for infrequently purchased or specialty (differentiated) products. the reason appears to be that such products involve greater consumer risk, and consumers are willing to pay extra for quality assurance (12). for example, perdue company differentiated their product by producing a better quality name-brand chicken and was able to command a 10 cent per pound premium (3). targeting. porter's second alternative strategy is to target a particular market segment. this allows the firm to develop a particular strength, charge a higher price and stay profitable. river laboratories, a leading producer of research animals, detected an unmet market for high quality, genetically defined labor rats. in the same way, lenox developed a lucrative bridal market for its china (3). using the experience curve although the experience curve has many limitations and market share is not the only way to compete in the market place, there are certain times when the concept is viable and awareness of its implications are crucial to survival. when to use the experience curve the industry structure, relative positions of key competitors and the level of government involvement are critical variables which must be analyzed in deciding whether the experience curve is relevant (5). industry. included in an analysis of the industry are such factors as: industry life stage, technology risk and prices. the experience curve strategies usually gain greatest leverage in the early stages of a product's life cycle. the reason for this is that cumulative output doubles much more frequently in the early stages of a product's life cycle. for instance, optical fibers and vacuum cleaners follow approximately the same experience curve, but it presently takes two years to double optical fiber output and twenty for vacuum cleaners. second, when analyzing the industry, technology is important. if a company faces technological uncertainty and decides to produce before uncertainty is resolved (get an experience curve head start), the benefits can be 40 great, as was the case for corning glass in the optical fibers market. however the risks and possible losses can also be great, as rca learned with video disk players. finally, experience curve strategies are particularly appropriate in industries where demand is especially price sensitive. a price cut which results in significant volume growth will allow the company to move further down the experience curve and reduce prices further. texas instruments (ti) did this in the calculator market. they made the first major cost-cutting advances and were able to cut prices on previously high priced calculators. this allowed ti to capture a large share of the market, allowing further progress down the experience curve. competitor analysis. if a firm faces weak competition (usually undercapitalized with high cost structures) the experience curve could be beneficial. if the competition is strong though, an aggressive pricing strategy might backfire on the challenging company. hewlett-packard attempted an aggressive pricing strategy in the calculator market but would not compete with ti. hewlett-packard then decided to focus on the premium end of the market instead of battling head-to-head with ti. government intervention. the government affects the viability of the experience curve through competitive policies and the cost of capital. government concerns about predatory pricing and attempts to monopolize can sometimes thwart efforts to use experience curve pricing strategies. government subsidies, tax rates, and depreciation policies can alter the competitive positions of firms within an industry. additionally, high domestic interest rates, in part a result of government deficits and tax policies, put american firms at a cost disadvantage to foreign firms. applying the experience curve before presenting an application of the experience curve a couple of key points need to be made about its use, these are the importance of shared resources within product groups and the fact that a firm may face multiple experience curves at various stages in the value added chain (or the various stages in the development, production, and delivery of products or services). shared resources. in many industries the experience base may be derived from more than just one product. often product groups share the same components, production facilities or delivery systems. when such interrelationships exist the combined experience curve position for the product group should be the focus of analysis (4). the british motorcycle industry found out the hard way about the importance of product group management (8). various classes of motorcycles share many parts and manufacturing processes. the british manufacturers did not realize that in order to maintain a competitive cost position for one product they had to retain the market positions of others, because together they represented accumulated output. initially, they benefited from dropping smaller motorcycle product 41 lines through lower r&d spending. but in the long run they suffered from a loss of cost leadership. the value-added chain. in addition to shared costs, the value-added concept is important in the application of the experience curve. the firm's position on the experience curve at each stage of the value-added chain should be determined. such analysis should not only include manufacturing, but also research and development, procurement of raw materials, fabrication, assembly, marketing, sales and distribution (hax and majluf, 1985). there should be a stage-by-stage comparison of the firm with its leading competitors. the firm's relative strengths should be isolated and exploited. when phillip-morris entered the beer industry with the acquisition of miller brewing it gained market share by exploiting its experience in market segmentation and product innovation (i.e., the introduction and promotion of miller life) (13). an illustration in order to place a firm on an industry production experience curve, along with its major competitors, four steps are required. first, assuming the firm in question uses technology comparable to its competitors, production cost data for the firm must be gathered which will be used to estimate the experience curve behavior for the industry, such as is presented in exhibit 4. note that in this illustration, only direct labor costs are being examined. exhibit 4: cost data for firm z cost data unit unit direct cost dlrect number labor hours/unit per hour labor costs 1 100 $ 12 $1,200.00 2 85 12 1,020.00 4 72.25 12 867.00 8 61.41 12 736.80 16 52.20 12 626.40 32 44.37 12 532.45 64 37.71 12 452.58 128 32.06 12 384.70 256 27.25 12 327.00 512 23.16 12 278.0cr 42 with the above data, the second step can be completed, estimating the rate of decline in costs which occurs with each doubling of production. this step involves calculating some simple percentage cost changes: $1,010 $1,200 = 85%; $ 867 $1,020 = 85%; $736.80 $864 = 85% while each of these sample calculations suggest an 85 percent experience curve (or a 15 percent decline in costs with each doubling of output), the percentage may sometimes vary, and an average may have to be taken. having estimated the production cost behavior for the industry, the third step requires the analyst to formulate a model which will permit estimation of unit production costs at various levels of accumulated output. to do this the following model is u~ed. c x = (k) x log njiog 2 where: ex = direct unit costs required to produce the unit x = unit number k = direct unit costs required to produce the first unit n = learning curve coefficient or factor in the case illustrated here, if the firm is about to produce its 513th unit, the first unit's cost was $1,200, and the experience curve coefficient has been estimated to be 85 percent, the predicted cost would be: c s13 = ($1,200) 513 log.85llog 2 cs13 = ($1,200) 513 -.2344 cs13 = 1200 1 513. 2344 cs13 = $277.93 assume the firm whose cost experience was just analyzed (referred to below as firm z) confronts two major competitors who use similar technology. further assume one of the competing firms, firm a is thought to have 20 percent more accumulated output than firm z. the other firm, firm b, is assumed to have 10 percent less accumulated output than firm z. to complete the fourth step the current cost position of each competitor is estimated as .follows: 43 firm 2' s current accumulated output = 512 units firm a's accumulated output 512 x 1.20 = 614.4 units firm a's unit cost: ca = ($1,200) 614.4 -.2344 ca = $266.42 firm b's accumulated output = 512 x .90 = 460.8 firm b's unit cost: cb = (1,200) 460.8-. 2344 cb = $285.00 placing the firms on an experience curve on log-log-scales, the relative positions are as shown in exhibit 5: exhibit 5: industry experience curve direct costs 1200 600 240 120 123 4 (1 og-l og seal e) 5 10 50 100 1000 accumulated volume as mentioned earlier, it is assumed that firm z's cost behavior is representative of the industry. it is also assumed that the management of firm z has a fairly accurate estimate of the other two firm's accumulated volume. 44 however, it is possible that a competitor may have more or less sophisticated technology which might place it on a different experience curve. as illustrated in exhibit 6, firm c, a new entrant to the industry, enters with superior technology, causing its costs to follow a lower experience curve track. exhibit 6: experience curve shift due to new technology direct costs firm z firm c (log-log scale) there is also the possibility that a new entrant or former laggard in the industry, such as firm b in the earlier illustration, may be able to close the gap due to the spillover effect, which was discussed earlier. finally, it may be quite difficult to get an accurate assessment of the accumulated output of the competition. to correct each of these problems management must make a ''best guess'! of the situation given the information available. obviously, the application of the experience curve in strategic analysis is as much art as science. summary quite simply, experience curve logic suggests that as volume is accumulated costs of production decrease in a predictable, exponential manner. the sources of this cost reduction are exogenous progress, economies of scale, and basic improvements learned from cumulative output. the most important implication of the experience curve is that the firm with the greatest 45 market share will have the lowest costs and enjoy a number of strategic advantages. in fact the market share-experience curve-profitability relationship implies that only those firms with large market shares can be expected to survive. in many instances the industry leader will determine the destiny of the other firms in the industry. the experience curve concept also has major implications for pricing strategies. while the experience curve model is not without its shortcomings, both antidotal and statistical evidence exists which supports the validity of the concept. there are a number of shortcomings and caveats associated with the experience curve. the strategic importance of the experience curve effect is probably minimal for mature or declining industries. no competitive advantage may be accrued from accumulated production if there is significant spillover or exchange of experience-based learning among competitors. in fact, if a firm becomes to enamored with the experience curve it may lose its ability to recognize and respond to coming changes in the industry. an industry in which non-price competition is prevalent may not be susceptible to experience curve analysis. finally, government attitudes toward predatory pricing may diminish the usefulness of experience curve analysis. concluding, the single-minded pursuit of market share might not always be the answer, and may in fact be dangerous. a firm may be able to compete profitly through continuous innovation and careful targeting of their markets. for further reading on the experience curve concept and its application see: abernathy william j. and kenneth wayne, "limits of the learning curve." havard business review, september-october 1974, pp. 109-119. albert, kenneth j., handbook of business problem solving, mcgraw-hill, inc., new york, new york, 1984. porter, michael e., competitive strategies: techniques for analyzing individuals and competitors, free press, n.y., 1980. yelle, louis e., "the learning curve," decision sciences, vi0 1979, pp. 302-28. references 1. abernathy, william j. and kenneth wayne, "limits of the learning curve." havard business review, september-october 1974, pp. 109119. 2. albert, kenneth j., handbook of business problem solving, mcgrawhill, inc., new york, new york, 1984. 3. clifford, donald jr. and richard e. cavanagh, "innovation builds winning performance," advertising age, december 1985, pp. 42-44. 4. ghemawat, pankaj, "building strategy on the experience curve," havard business review, march-apri11985, pp. 143-149. 5. ghemaat, pankaj and michael a. spense, "learning curve spillovers and market performance," quarterly journal of economics, vida 1985, pp. 839-852. 46 6. hall, graham and sidney howell, "the experience curve from the economist perspective," strategic management journal, julyseptember 1985, pp. 197-212. 7. hax, arnold c. and nicholas s. majluf. strategic management, prentice-hall inc., englewood cliffs, new jersey, 1984. 8. keschell, walter. "the decline of the experience curve," fortune, 5 october 1981, pp. 139-146. 9. newton, j.k., "market share-key to higher profitability," long range planning, vol 18 no.1, 1985, pp. 64-72. 10. porter, michael e., competitive strategies: techniques for analyzing individuals and competitors, free press, n.y., 1980. 11. sallenave, jean" paul, "the uses and abuses of experience curves," long range planning, vol 18 no.1, 1985, pp. 64-72. 12. schoeffler, sidney, robert d. buzzell and donald f. hearny, "impact of strategic planning on profit performance," havard business review, march-april 1974. 13. thompson, arthur a., "competition in the u.s. brewing industry," cases in strategic management, business publications, plano, texas (written by a. j. strickland iii and arthur a. thompson, jr.) 1985. 14. woo, carolyn y., "market share leadership-not always so good," havard business review, january-february 1984, p. 50 (3). 15. yelle, louis e., "the learning curve," decision sciences, vi0 1979, pp.302-28. 47 the experience curve's role in strategic planning in-substance defeasance of debt: a solution to a management problem w. alfred mukatis and dahli gray department of accounting oregon state university corvallis, oregon defeasance of debt has been recognized for many years. in defeasance a debtor includes in the debt instrument the legal right to transfer the debt with assets adequate to meet the debt obligation to a trust. in this way the debt is extinguished without being retired. the creditor, holding the debt instrument, knows the debtor may set up a trust to extinguish the debt without retiring it. benefits of defeasance to the debtor include: (1) no payment penalties for early debt retirement; (2) recognition of unrealized gain in the income statement, which enhances earnings per share (eps) and other indicators of performance; and (3) removal of debt from the balance sheet, which enhances the debt-to-equity ratio and other indicators of financial strength. given the tight credit market, debtors are motivated to present high eps and low debt-to-equity ratios. beginning in the 1980s debtors have been using in-substance defeasance to obtain similar benefits. in-substance defeasance of debt is used where defeasance of debt is not included as an option in the debt instrument. the creditor is not forewarned that the debtor might transfer the debt with assets adequate to meet the debt obligation to a trust and, thereby, claim the debt is extinguished. also, the creditor need not be informed when the debt is in-substance defeased. the financial community has enthusiastically embraced this technique. some companies have gone so far as to create debt with the intention of immediately employing in-substance defeasance; i.e., "instantaneous defeasance" to obtain the benefits of defeasance. exxon corporation in 1982 eliminated $515 million of debt from its balance sheet and posted a $132 million profit by buying high-yield treasury securities and placing them in a trust to retire low-interest debt (15). following exxon, american hospital supply corporation issued zero-coupon eurobonds at 11.56% which it matched with a purchase of "stripped/ u.s. treasury bonds yielding 12.25%. new debt of $(2 million was buried in the balance sheet of their unconsolidated subsidiai')l american hospital supply finance corporation (21). 4 lazard realty, inc. in 1984 used in-substance defeasance to unlock equity in 11,000 garden apartments purchased in 1979. second mortgage rates were too high to use for refinancing. so lazard bought $74 million (maturity value) in government securities for $62 million (current value), and placed them in an irrevocable trust to repay a preexisting $74 million debt. it thus reported a $12 million gain in the income statement (13). the fasb banned the use of instantaneous defeasance as of september 1984 (8). james c. treadway jr., an sec commissioner, said: "i am strongly opposed to instantaneous defeasance" and called it "a distortion of accounting principles" (1). but even when not instantaneous, in-substance defeasance is controversial. roman l. weil, director or the institute of professional accounting, stated that in-substance defeasance (which he calls "de facto" defeasance) presents "managers with the opportunity to boost reported earnings, lower the debt-equity ratio and (in some cases) increase their own compensation" (20). representative john d. dingell, democrat from michigan, criticized the sec for not taking "a stronger stand" against in-substance defeasance, "which its critics claim allow companies to create instant profits"(3). john evans, a retired sec commissioner said "i'm queasy about it [in-substance defeasance] because the debt is still legally debt, and the creation of earnings appears to be a charade" (2). in-substance defeasance is viewed by some as "an accounting device companies use to wipe long-term debt off their books" (17). companies are accused of having "concocted so many ways to hide or disguise borrowings that deciphering their true liabilities is often impossible. sometimes, debt isn't acknowledged anywhere; at other times, it's there, but finding it would take a financial wizard with hours of free time and a computer/ (4). in-substance defeasance was referred to as the "equivalent of vanishing debt!' by forbes, which criticized the process because "a borrower can retire debt at a discount, and companies are allowed to show the discount as earnings'! (14). in spite of these criticisms the fasb approved the use of in-substance defeasance within the parameters set in sfas 76. this article illustrates how to achieve profits and avoid losses in implementing sfas 76. the parameters surrounding in-substance defeasance per sfas 76 are discussed, and options regarding the types of trusts with tax implications of each type are also presented. in-substance defeasance defined in-substance defeasance of debt is extinguishment of debt, as specifically addressed by the sfas no. 76 extinguishment of debt (10). but legally the debt still exists. sfas 76 subordinates the form of the contractual debtor/ creditor relationship to its substance but mandates specific action to achieve in-substance defeasance as follows: the debtor irrevocably places cash or other assets in a trust to be used solely for satisfying scheduled payments of both interest 5 and principal of a specific obligation and the possibility that the debtor will be required to make future payments with respect to that debt is remote. in this circumstance, debt is extinguished even though the debtor is not legally released from being the primary obligor under the debt obligation (10, para. 3). the fasb has placed the following specific restrictions on trust assets used for in-substance defeasance: the trust shall be restricted to owning only monetary assets that are essentially risk free to the amount, timing, and collection of interest and principal. the monetary assets shall be denominated in the currency in which the debt is payable. for debt denominated in u.s. dollars, essentially risk-free monetary assets shall be limited to any combination of the following: (1) direct obligations of the u.s. government, (2) obligations guaranteed by the u.s. government, and (3) securities that are backed by u.s. government obligations as collateral under an arrangement by which the interest and principal payments on the collateral generally flow immediately through to the holder of the security. however, some securities described in the previous sentence can be paid prior to scheduled maturity and so are not essentially risk free as to the timing of the coll~~tionof interest and principal; thus, they do not qualify for ownership by the trust (10, para. 4). securities which are callable or convertible cannot be used for insubstance defeasance unless the callable/convertible options are cancelled. costs of placing assets in the trust are taken into account as follows: the monetary assets held by the trust shall provide cash flows (from interest and maturity of those assets) that approximately coincide, as to timing and amount, with scheduled interest and principal payments on the debt that is being extinguished.... if, in conjunction with placing assets in trust to effect an extinguishment of debt, it is expected that trust assets will be used to pay related costs, such as trustee fees, as well as to satisfy scheduled interest and principal payments of a specific debt, those costs shall be considered in determining the amount of funds required by the trust. on the other hand, if the debtor incurs an obligation to pay any related costs, the debtor shall accrue a liability for those probable future payments in the period that the debt is recognized as extinguished (10, paras. 4, 5). 6 in-substance defeasance illustrated in-substance defeasance is allowed when applied to previously outstanding debt, but not to debt issued in contemplation of in-substance defeasance (i.e., instantaneous defeasance). the fasb technical bulletin on insubstance defeasance warns against placing assets in an irrevocable trust about the same time as debt is incurred. corporate directors should take care to either state in the minutes that newly authorized debt is not being issued in contemplation of in-substance defeasance or make no statement on the issue. the directors could currently authorize the issuance of debt, which in the future would qualify for in-substance defeasance so long as it was not issued with that intention. violating the generally accepted accounting standard as mandated in sfas 76 and its technical bulletin might result in an adverse audit opinion or public disapproval by the sec. the following examples illustrate the possible benefits of in-substance defeasance when one stays within the restrictions set by sfas 76. assume it is now june 30, 1986, and the company wishes to in-substance defease an outstanding debt of six hundred,~ $1,000 maturity value, 18% bonds issued at par to mature june 3d, 2012. they purchase u.s. government securities paying 12% annual interest, which will provide cashflow adequate to meet the bond interest and principal payments plus costs of establishing and maintaining a trust to manage both the u.s. securities and the company debt. the trustee takes physical possession of the u.s. securities and supporting debt documentation necessary to make and record the interest and final principal payments and keeps a separate set of financial records regarding management of the assets and debt. depending on the type of trust established, the trust may be liable for tax on the asset income. the unrealized loss resulting from the above example amounts to $430,359 and must be reported in the income statement but not the balance sheet. see table 1 for detailed calculation of the loss and recommended journal entry. table 1 calculation of in-substance defeasance loss cost to set up trust $ 4,000 annual interest payment $600,000 (18%) $108,000 annual trust administration fee 18,000 12e3,ooo times annuity present value factor for 7.8957 994,85926 years at 12% principal at maturity 600,000 times present value factor for 26 years at 12% .0525 30°° required trust principal 1,030,359 carrying value of bonds ~~o-,~q unrealized loss on in·substance defeasance $ 430,359 journal entry bonds payable $600,000 loss on in-substance defeasance 430,359 long-term investment $1,030,359 7 to show a gain one needs a lower interest rate on the outstanding debt, a higher interest rate on the trust assets or both. using the assumptions above and in table 1 except for the bonds being originally issued at 6% instead of 18% results in a gain of $232,881. the calculation and its recommended journal entry are shown in table 2. table 2 calculation of in-substance defeasance gain cost to set up trust annual interest payment $600.000 (6%) annual trust administration fee times annuity present value factor for 26 years at 12 r c principal at maturity times present value factor for 26 years at 12% required trust principal carrying vaiue of bonds unrealized gain on in-substance defeasance s 4.000 s 36.000 6.000 42.000 78957 331.619 600.000 .0525 31.500 367.119 600.000 s 232.881 rtp=a+r~]k1 + r t journal entry bonds payable $600.000 long-term investment $ 367,119 gain on in-substance defeasance $ 232.881 the equation to determine when the breakeven point (be) occurs is as follows: + [fn(b) + nc] x[l (1 _1 )}1) r (l+r)n where rtp = a = b c = fn = n = r the initially required trust principal initial setup costs of trust, stated interest rate on debt based on an annual rate, annual trust administration fees, maturity value of debt, life of debt (and trust) in years, and effective annual interest rate on trust assets be occurs when rtp = fn . if rtp > fn a loss is recognized and when rtp < fn a gain is recognized. to find the effective interest rate at the breakeven point, rip is set equal to fn and equation 1 is rearranged to: r = [~:] +r_r1 +rb +nc] x [1 -_112)l(1 +rtj l fn (1 + r)nj in deriving equations (1) and (2) it is assumed that: (a) all money values are in the same units, e.g., dollars; (b) interest payments are made annually, and 8 the principal is paid at maturity; (c) trust assets earn a constant annual return; and (d) the debt was issued at par. if the debt was issued at a discount or premium, be and the gain or loss is determined by comparing rtp to the carrying value of the debt (cvd) rather than fn . equation (1) may be used to calculate whether the desired gain can be attained. an iterative process is used in equation (2) to determine an effective annual interest rate to break even. by way of example consider the case where: rtp = fn = $1,000,000, a = $10,000, b = 0.1, c = $10,000 (1 % of initial assets), and n = 10 years the authors first guess a value of ro of 0.15 (15%) and in three iterations obtained the following results: r (left side) 0.189 0.200 0.202 0.202 r (right side) 0.150 0.189 0.200 0.202 difference 0.039 0.011 0.002 0.000 thus the trust would -have to earn 20.2% per year to break even on a debt with an interest rate of only 10%. equations (1) and (2) may be appropriately modified when the principal is repaid as an annuity rather than as a lump sum at maturity. the eps increase from in-substance defeasance results when the cost of the debt is less than the return on the trust assets. overall interest rates must substantially increase for risk-free assets, like federal treasury instruments, to have a greater yield than typical company debt. in efficient capital markets bond prices should decrease in recognition of the higher interest rates, enabling a possible gain on the in-substance defeasance. this single period eps' increase improves the debt-to-equity ratio and other indicators of performance and strength for the current period, and the improvement will extend into future periods. in addition to careful consideration of the factors summarized in equation (2), a debt manager must establish the in-substance defeasance trust within particular parameters. to assist in this effort the general aspects of trusts are presented followed by specific characteristics of trusts applicable to insubstance defeasance. general aspects of trusts all trusts maybe categorizes as implied, constructive, or express (5, 16). 9 figure i summarizes the three basic trust types. an implied trust arises by operation of law when a party who intends to create a trust fails to completely manifest that intent. the court will usually decree that a trust exists in favor of the intended beneficiary or where the intended beneficiary cannot be ascertained then in favor of the creator. this is known as a resulting trust. if the court did not furnish a recipient for the trust assets, the trustee might be able to retain the benefits against the settlor's (debtor's) wishes since the former holds legal title to the trust property. a constructive trust is created by law to remedy a wrong. for example, if one party fraudulently obtains property from another, the court can order the wrongdoer to hold the property in trust for the former owner. figure 1 basic trust types express impl ied constructi ve intended and intended but either not intended. imposed completely not stated at all or by courts to prevent stated not completely stated injustice applicable to may be applicable to not applicable to in-substance in-substance defeasin-substance defeasance ance where an express defeasance trust fails to name a remainder beneficiary express trusts, that is, those intentionally created for a valid purpose are applicable and are discussed next. a resulting in-substance defeasance trust could arise where the creator of an express trust neglects to name a recipient of assets remaining after satisfaction of the debt. sfas 76 mandates against return of assets to the settlor (debtor), so a remainder beneficiary is required. attention should also be made to naming a trustee and providing for successor trustees since without a trustee, the trust could fail. characteristics of in-substance defeasance trusts express trusts may be classified in different ways including: (a) intervivos vs. testamentary; (b) revocable vs. irrevocable; (c) simple vs. complex; and (d) grantor vs. nongrantor. an intervivos trust becomes effective while the settlor is alive, whereas a testament~ry trust is part of a will and becomes effective on the settlor's death. testamentary trusts cannot be created by corporations since property transfers which occur when a corpomtion terminates are treated differently than when an individual dies. trusts may be -expressly made revocable or irrevocable. a revocable trust allows the settlor to effectively retain control of the assets. however, an in-substance defeasance trust must be irrevocable per sfas 76. a simple trust by its terms distributes current income only, must distribute all its current income, and has no charitable beneficiaries. if the trust accumulates income or distributes part or all of its corpus, it is complex. 10 many trusts are simple in some years and complex in others. any trust not dry when it terminates is complex in the year of termination because it will distribute something other than current income. under sfas 76, the trust can be simple or complex or both in different years depending on how the debt is structured. in years when the scheduled repayment of debt requires payment only of interest (and administrative expenses and/or taxes) until some maturity date, and the current income matches the interest payment, (and administrative expenses and/or taxes) the trustis simple. however, for a company to show a gain on the balance sheet, it is expected that the annual income on the trust would be greater than the interest to be paid on the debt and associated expenses. hence, income would accumulate until maturity when the debt is retired, and the trust would be complex in every year. there should be no unusual consequences to the defeasance aspects whether the trust is simple of complex in any given year. figure ii summarizes the requirements for a trust used to in-substance defease debt. figure ii in-substance defeasance trust requirements no no no no no no no no 11 tax aspects of the trust selected normally a trust constitutes a separate entity. however, under the grantor trust provisions of the internal revenue code (irc) the settlor (or another person) may be treated as owner of some or all of the assets and accordingly taxed on some or all the trust income (12, sections 671-679). sections 671, 673, 678, and 679 of the irc might be applicable to whether grantor status obtains under the sfas 76 parameters. to avoid grantor status under section 671, the debtor should take care not to assign only future income to the trust but might, for instance, assign a series of bonds. section 673 provides that a settlor will be treated as the owner of any portion of a trust in which either the trust principal or income may reasonably be expected to revert to the settlor within ten years after the date of transfer. since sfas 76 will not allow reinvestment of income, a remainder will probably result which could revert to the settlor underthe resulting trust doctrine. the settlor can avoid grantor status by designating a remainderman for any surplus. the remainderman should be given no power to control disposition of any remainder to avoid taxation under section 678. no conflict with sfas 76 should arise in naming a beneficiary of assets remaining at the debt's maturity. if the trustee is named as remainder beneficiary, any surplus might be deductible to the debtor as a reasonable cost of doing business under ire section 162(a). if a charity were to receive the remainder then because of the sfas 76 requirement of structuring the payouts to coincide closely with the required payments, no charitable deduction would be allowed. to obtain a charitable deduction there must be more certainty to the payout as under a charitable remainder annuity trust, a charitable remainder unitrust, or a pooled income fund (12, section 664(d)(1), section 664(d)(2), and section 642(c)(s). grantor status under irc section 679 can be avoided by using a u.s. trust. for foreign trusts, grantor status may still be avoided in certain cases such as where the beneficiary is not a u.s. citizen either actually or constructively. initially, the fasb appeared to view the trust as a separate taxable entity from the debtor. in paragraph 5 of their revised exposure draft the fasb included "taxes on trust income" as an example of "costs expected to be paid by the trust" (9). in response to this view touche ross & co. stated the following: paragraph 5 refers to providing, at the outset, for "taxes on trust income." ordinarily, such trusts are grantor trusts and the federal income tax consequences thereof are included in the grantor corporation's tax return. because the trust itself is rarely a taxable entity for federal purposes, we suggest some elucidation what the board intended ... (18)? 12 dart & kraft commented as follows: in determining the amount of investment assets needed to defease a set amount of company debt, should the matching of fund inflows and outflows be done on a pretax or after-tax basis? does the placement of investment assets in a grantor trust (which does not have a tax existence separate from the sponsoring company) or a trust that stands alone for tax purposes have a bearing on this? we believe that the matching of fund flows should be done on a pretax basis regardless of the type of trust involved (7). these issues raised by touche ross & co. and dart & kraft will be explored next. although touche ross and co. stated that i'[o]rdinarily such trusts are grantor trusts" (18), there is no such requirement in sfas 76 and no reason in principle they must be. in fact, satisfaction of the sfas 76 requirement of making remote the possibility that the debtor would have to make further payments may mandate selection of an independent trustee. an independent trustee might lessen chances of mismanagement (intentional or negligent) by the debtor and lower the chances that the debtor would be required to make further payments. an independent trustee by itself will not guarantee nongrantor status to the debtor but is one step in that direction. since selection of the trustee can affect not only the grantor status of the trust but also the remoteness criteria of sfas 76 it should be given due consideration. the reason for the statement by dart & kraft, that liew ]e believe that the matching of fund flows should be done on a pretax basis" is not clear. first, consider a grantor trust. the income tax consequences inure to the debtor, and the trustee need not be concerned with them. calculation of the trust assets needed is relatively easy because one needs only to know the administration and setup fees and the presumably fixed interest rate on the investment. also there is no change in grantor status or tax consequences if for some remote reason the trust becomes dry before the debt is satisfied, or the trust terminates with assets remaining. in the former case, the settlor can simply add assets and in the latter case any surplus would go to the named recipient. to place the assets in a grantor trust on an after-tax basis might diminish the possibility that an occurrence such as bankruptcy of the debtor leaves the debt unsatisfied. but bankruptcy taken by the debtor, in and of itself should not lessen the remoteness of the debtor having to make further payment since the bankruptcy would very like discharge the debt. at the same time, matching of fund flows on an after-tax basis would require the grantor to predict personal future tax consequences for a number of years, a feat that seems extraordinarily difficult if not impossible. an occurrence such as bankruptcy taken by the debtor would have the same effect as on a pretax basis. calculation of the amount of assets needed in a nongrantor trust on a 13 pretax basis would be the same as for a grantor trust. but in the former situation the debtor would be required to make annual contributions for taxes based on the trust as a taxable entity .and the trust language should provide for these annual contributions. bankruptcy taken by the debtor in and of itself should not adversely affect the remoteness of the debtor having to make additional payments since again the debt would probably be discharged. to maintain nongrantor status where an excess remains after the debt is paid, the trust should name an appropriate remainder beneficiary. however, if the trust becomes dry before the debt is paid the nongrantor status should not be affected but the trust language should deal with additional payments by the debtor. for nongrantor trusts on an after-tax basis it should also be feasible to calculate the amount of initial assets required, assuming tax laws and r~tes remain constant over the life of the trust. on that basis the amount required for tax payments ·by the trustee could be calculated with certainty. if tax law changes occur, the trust language should take into account possible contributions by the·debtor and disposition of any remainder. care would have to be taken not to change the nongrantor status of the trust. again, bankruptcy should not have any effect on the remoteness of future payments for the same reasons stated above. thus for a grantor trust in an after-tax situation the difficulty of calculating tax consequences clearly points to placing assets on a pretax basis. for a nongrantor trust the reason is not so compelling and the debtor could reasonably place the assets in trust on a pre or after-tax basis. additional considerations express trusts may use a·provision to avoid the often time consuming and expensive judicial approval of the trustee's accounting. but sfas 76 param~ eters allow creation of a trust without the creditor-beneficiary's knowledge, while requiring the possibility of the debtor having to make future payments be remote. it might be wise in this or perhaps in all situations, for a court to approve the accounting to satisfy the requirement that the possibility of further payment be remote. without court approval, mismanagement (intentional or negligent) may be more probable, thereby increasing the probability that further payments are required. if court approval is not obtained, then at a, minimum the trustees should be independent of the debtor even though in principle one person could serve as both. the sfas 76 requirement of assets being irrevocably placed in trust solely for satisfaction of the debt is easily accomplished in theory by basic drafting of the trust instrument. however, are the assets really irrevocably placed in trust? no clear answer exists where the trust is created as a fraud on other creditors or the debtor files for bankruptcy after creation? in the former situation the defrauded creditors can file a creditor's suit in equity to obtain the trust assets (6). in the latter situation the trustee in bankruptcy may be able to obtain the trust assets if the debtor created a preference for one 14 creditor over other creditors (19, section 547) or committed fraud under the bankruptcy act (19, section 548). the independent trustee could evaluate the likelihood of fraud or bankruptcy rather than have the debtor make that judgment. the sfas 76 requirement that the possibility of further payment by the debtor be remote leaves open a similar question of who makes that determination (11). since the technique can be very attractive to the debtor while having a potential for misleading unsophisticated investors, it is again suggested that someone independent of the debtor make the decision. the use of an independent person to judge both the remoteness of the debtor having to make future payments and the good faith of the debtor might quash some of the criticism leveled at in-substance defeasance. summary and conclusion defeasance of debt has bee~ a useful and recognized technique for many years. in-substance defeasance, a controversial new technique has been enthusiastically embraced by the financial community but approved by the fasb only within certain limitations. the fasb has banned the technique if it constitutes instantaneous in-substance defeasance defeasance~one primary purpose of using in-substance defeasance is to recognize an unrealized gain on the income statement and remove debt from the balance sheet, thereby enhancing a company's debt to equity ratio. this article has provided guidelines for using in-substance defeasance within the parameters set by the fasb. two equations are presented to show when a gain or loss occurs and the interest rate needed to breakeven for the case where income on the assets in an in-substance defeasance trust is used to service the debt and the corpus remaining at the debt's maturity is used to retire the debt principal. characteristics of trusts appropriate for in-substance defeasance are examined and presented in figure ii. they may be structured as grantor or nongrantor trusts depending whether the debtor wishes to incur the income tax consequences depending primarily on the relative tax brackets of the debtor and the trust. the authors suggest that for grantor trusts the assets be placed in the trust on a pretax basis; for nongrantor trusts a pretax or after-tax basis may be used. it is the debtor who decides whether the in-substance defeasance trust is within the sfas 76 parameters. since the technique offers the debtor significant benefits while at the same time may be misleading to all but the most sophisticated investors, the authors suggest that someone independent of the debtor decide whether sfas 76 requirements are being met in order to quash some of the criticisms of in-substance defeasance. references 1. berton, lee and ann monroe. "fasb mulls ban on defeasance 15 method which firms issue debt to post gains," wall street journal, september 12, 1984, p. 6. 2. berton, lee. "fasb adopts, 4-3, controversial method that critics assert allows 'instant' profit." wall street journal, november 3d, 1983, p.7. 3. __. "house unit probing sec's monitoring of accounting rules," wall street journal, january 31, 1984, p. 56. 4. __. "loose ledgers: many firms hide debt to give them an aura of financial strength," wall street journal, december 13, 1983, p. 1. 5. bogert, g.g. and g.t. bogert, trusts and trustees, 2d ed revised (st. paul, minn.: west publ. co., 1984),_section 1. 6. creditor's rights and remedies, (portland, oregon: oregon state bar, c.l.e., 1978), section 9.1. 7. dart & kraft comment letter to the fasb regarding exposure draft (revised), extinguishment of debt, october 13, 1983. 8. "fasb acts to ban use of defeasance applied to new debt," wall street journal, september 13, 1984, p. 4. 9. financial accounting standards board, exposure draft (revised), extinguishment of debt, stamford, co.: fasb, 1983. 10. financial accounting standards board, statement of financial accounting standards no. 76, extinguishment of debt, stamford, conn.: fasb, 1983. 11. financial accounting standards board, technical bulletin 84-4 oct. 17, 1984 p. 4. 12. internal revenue code. 13. "investor takes cue from corporations," wall street journal, may 22, 1985 p. 37. 14. konrad, walecia. "numbers game: reading between the pictures," forbes, january 30, 1984, p. 126. 15. peterson, pamela, david peterson and james ang. "the extinguishment of debt through in-substance defeasance," financial management, 14, 1 (spring 1985), 59-67. 16. schantz, w.t. commercial law for business and accounting students: a complete business law text and cpa law review (st. paul, minn.: west publ. co., 1980), p. 1130. 17. "sec approves rules on-device to keep debt off balance sheet," wall street journal, december 23, 1983, p. 3. 18. touche ross & co., comment letter to fasb regarding exposure draft (revised), extinguishment of debt, september 12, 1983, p. 10. 19. united states code ann., title 11 bankruptcy (1979 and west supp. 1985). 20. weil, roman l. "deor misfeasance? a look at the new fasb ruling," barron's, december 5, 1983, p. 50. 21. weiss, stuart. "the accounting watchdog~ have been outfoxed again," business week, november 26, 1984, p. 168. 16 in-substance defeasance of debt: a solution to a management problem 138 journal of business strategies the nexus of immigration and economic conditions in australia burcu ozcan firat university • elazig, turkey abstract in this study, we aim to analyze the causal linkages between immigration and economic conditions unemployment and per capita incomein australia over the period of 1966-2013 by using causality tests developed by toda and yamamoto (1995) and hacker-hatemi-j (2006). the results support one-way causal relationships running from both unemployment and per capita income to immigration. however, immigrants do not have a significant impact on the economic conditions of australia. on the contrary, the high level of income and the low unemployment rate are the pulling factors of immigrants into australia. based on these results, some crucial policy implications would be suggested. keywords: immigration, income, unemployment, causality, australia introduction immigration seems to be more than a simple labor supply shock because it may induce efficient specialization in the labor market by differentiating skill levels and causing more competition (peri, 2008). there are many different economic, political and social reasons for immigration such as war and political pressure, causing people to leave their home countries and to migrate into other nations that are wealthier and safer (troshchenkov, 2011). besides, declining transportation and information costs, as well as widening income differences between developing and developed countries along with accelerating population growth rates in developing countries are the main factors of immigration (jean & jimenez, 2011). based on escalating trends in immigration waves worldwide, scholars from different disciplines have started to analyze the reasons and the results of immigration for various countries. in particular, as a population influx, immigration has led many economists to develop models designed to measure its social and economic impacts on receiving countries’ economies (aydemir & borjas, 2006). however, economic theory cannot provide a definite conclusion for predicting the effects of immigration, in particular on the labor market of the host country (fromentin, 2013). in this regard, some scholars (see borjas, 1994; boddvarsson, 2008; damette volume 33, number 2 139 & fromentin, 2013; troshchenkov, 2011) assert that immigration has a little or no adverse impact on native employment opportunities. for instance, jean and jimenez (2011) argue that irrespective of their skill levels, new immigrants generate additional product demand and thereby raise profitability in the short-run and the capital stock in the long-run, with a positive impact on the demand for all types of labor. additionally, many oecd countries see immigration as a potential solution to compensate for their labor shortages against their aging population problems (boubtane et al., 2013). alternatively, there is also a negative view highlighting that immigrants steal native labors’ jobs, increase the unemployment level, depress the wage rates and financially strain the welfare systems in the receiving country as they are mostly unskilled (feridun, 2007; gross, 2004, pope & withers, 1993). based on the contrasting ideas mentioned above, economic theory indicates that two competing effects (supply-side effects versus demand-side effects) could explain the impact of immigration on the labor market of a host country (see feridun, 2004, 2005, 2007; fromentin, 2013; latif, 2015).supply-side effects highlight the presence of substitutability or complementarity between native and foreign labors. in the case of substitution, there is an increasing competition between citizens and immigrants, resulting in declining wage rates. in such a situation, immigration may cause unemployment among natives who are not willing to work at these lower wages (boubtane et al., 2013). however, in the presence of complementarity between indigenous and foreign labors, the new inflows of immigrants would augment the productivity of domestic employees and raise their wage levels and employment opportunities (see borjas, 2001; boubtane et al., 2013; feridun, 2004, 2005; fromentin, 2013). in this respect, the degree of substitutability or complementarity between native and foreign workers determine the final effect of immigration on the domestic labor market. relative to the demand-side effects, through their spending on goods and services in a direct way and through industrial and government expenditures on their behalf in an indirect way, immigrants lower the unemployment rate and increase wage levels for the native labors (islam, 2007). based on the say’s law in the economic theory, immigrants as consumers demand their own labors (bodvarsson et al., 2008). in other words, immigration provides a derived demand for labor by contributing to aggregate demand and may not deepen the unemployment problem (pope & withers, 1993). because the domestic labor market effect of immigration is difficult to be determined a priori (islam, 2007), this study aims to analyze whether immigration is a burden or a contribution to the australian economy over the period of 1966 140 journal of business strategies 2013. it will also contribute to the related literature in the following ways. first, australia deserves particular research attention since it is one of the best countries to inhabit by international comparisons of wealth, education, health, and quality of life. among oecd countries, australia ranked ninth in respect of foreign population inflow in 2013 (see fig. 1). it has metropolitan cities such as melbourne, identified as the world’s most liveable city in 2015 with residents from more than 140 nations.1 additionally, the inflow of foreign population into australia has followed a rising trend, increasing from 69,808 in 1984 to 251,850 in 2013 (see fig. 2).2 the australian department of migration and border protection 3 (2015) reported that australia’s overseas-born population grew by 51.2 percent to 6.4 million people including legal and non-legal immigrants between 19962013. thus, immigration still continues to be the major component of population growth in australia. additionally, approximately 68 percent of australian immigrants are skilled and educated, and their main birthplaces are mostly developed countries such as the united kingdom and new zealand. figure 1 inflows of foreign population in australia (1984-2013) source: oecd, international migration database. 1 see http://themysteriousworld.com/10-most-liveable-cities-in-the-world/ 2 this number only includes legal immigrants; i.e. people obtaining lawful permanent resident status. see https://www.border. gov.au/about/reports-publications/research-statistics/statistics/live-in-australia/migration-programme 3 see https://www.border.gov.au/reportsandpublications/documents/statistics/migration-trends13-14-glance.pdf2 this number only includes legal immigrants; volume 33, number 2 141 figure 2 inflows of foreign population in 2013 among oedc countries source: oecd, international migration database. second, there are only three empirical studies examining the nexus of immigration and economic conditions for australia (see konya, 2000; pope & withers, 1993; withers & pope, 1985). however, this study differs from them by using current data and a novel causality test developed by hacker and hatemi-j (2006). this new causality test does not require prior analysis to define the order of integration or co-integration features of the variables. also, it has more power than other tests in cases of non-normal and autoregressive conditional heteroscedastic error terms and has a bootstrap distribution that is a good approximation for the empirical studies with small samples. literature review there are a number of studies attempting to identify the impacts of immigration on the host country’s labor market. however, they mostly obtain evidence of causality running from unemployment to immigration instead of from immigration to unemployment (see feridun, 2007; islam, 2007; withers & pope, 1985). the early empirical studies, dating back to the 1980s, applied simple methods such as ordinary least squares (ols) and/or instrumental variables. for instance, withers and pope (1985), using a statistical causality method and a conventional structural model for the years of 1948-1982, found that immigration has no significant impact on unemployment. however, there is a high and meaningful effect running from unemployment to migration for australia. pope and withers 142 journal of business strategies (1993), using two-stage least squares, supported a bidirectional negative causality between immigration and unemployment in australia over the period 1861-1991. for canada, marr and siklos (1994), using quarterly data for the period of 19621990 and applying nonparametric multivariate spectral method, indicated that unemployment decreases immigration before 1978, while immigration positively contributed to unemployment after 1978. pischke and velling (1997), using ols for the late 1980s, found no detrimental effect of immigration on native workers’ employment in germany. dustmann et al. (2005), using data from the british labor force survey and employing the approaches of ols and instrumental variable for the years 19832000, found no substantial evidence that immigration has effects on unemployment and wage levels. based on a production function and a seemingly unrelated regression approach, akbari and devoretz (1992) analyzed the impact of immigrant workers on the employment conditions of canadian-born workers in 125 canadian industries for 1980 and suggested no economy-wide displacement of canadian-born workers by immigrants. by using nonlinear ols, dolado et al. (1994) analyzed the effects of migration for 23 oecd countries based on a solow growth model augmented by migration and human capital over the period of 19601985. their results indicated that if immigrants have a high level of human capital, their negative output and growth effects diminishes. there are also recent time series studies applying novel methods. some of them found that immigration has little or no significant impact on the host country’s labor market and economic development level (see feridun, 2005; islam, 2007; shan, 1999). for instance, using quarterly data for the years 1983 to 1995, shan (1999) found no causality between immigration and unemployment in either direction for australia and new zealand in the framework of the causality test of toda and yamamoto (1995). islam (2007) examined the relationship between unemployment and immigration in canada through cointegration and granger causality tests for the period of 1961:q1-2002:q1. the results confirmed that, in the short-run, there is a one-way negative causality running from unemployment to migration, from migration to wage and from the per capita gdp to migration. however, there is no observed increase in aggregate unemployment rate due to migration in the longrun. the studies by feridun (2004, 2005, and 2007) investigated the causality between immigration, gdp per capita and unemployment using co-integration and granger causality tests for finland (1981-2001), norway (1983-2003) and sweden (19802004), respectively. feridun (2004, 2005) obtained evidence that, when the level of immigration goes up, gdp per capita also increases. however, regarding the relationship between unemployment and immigration, feridun (2004) found that volume 33, number 2 143 rising immigration levels result in a higher unemployment level, whereas feridun (2005) obtained that immigration has no any impact on unemployment rate, and vice versa. in another study, feridun (2007) supported a long-run bidirectional causality between immigration and gdp per capita and a one-way causality from unemployment to immigration. for the british columbia region of canada, gross (2004), using the johansen cointegration test and a vector error correction (vec) model over the period of 1980:q1-1995:q4, found that immigration causes unemployment and raises the real wage in the short-run, while it lowers unemployment in the long-run. in another study, gross (2002), employing a general equilibrium model, the johansen cointegration test, and a vec model, obtained result that show immigrants increase unemployment in the short-run, whereas they lower the unemployment rate in the long-run for the french labor market from 1975 to 1994. there are also time series studies highlighting that immigration has a beneficial impact on native employment. for instance, fromentin (2013), using cointegration test and a vec model over the period of 1970-2008, found evidence of a negative causality running from immigration to unemployment in both the short and long-run. konya (2000), through the causality tests proposed by granger (1969) and toda and yamamoto (1995) for 1981:q2 to 1998:q4, found a negative causality running from immigration to long-run unemployment rate for australia. data and methodology data we use gdp per capita, unemployment rate, and net migration rate data for the period of 19662013 for australia. gdp per capita data (constant 2005, us dollar) are collected from the world bank development indicators database. the unemployment rate, measured as the percentage of the total labor force that is unemployed but looking for a job and willing to work, are from the oecd labor force statistics. the net migration rate data, indicating the difference between immigrants and emigrants for a country per 1000 inhabitants, are obtained from oecd international migration statistics. all variables are used in their natural 4 see there are also panel data studies (see angrist & krugler, 2003; basile et al., 2010; boubtane et al., 2013; damette & fromentin, 2013; ghatak & moore, 2007; ghatak et al., 2008; jean & jimenez, 2011; latif, 2015). however, we abstained the detailed explanations for them for the sake of brevity. 5 we couldn’t include wage variable into the analysis due to unavailability of data for the time period of this study.3 see https://www.border.gov.au/reportsandpublications/documents/statistics/migration-trends13-14-glance.pdf2 this number only includes legal immigrants; 6 entries of persons admitted on a temporary basis are not included in this statistic. 144 journal of business strategies logarithmic forms in the analyses, and some statistical features of variables are tabulated in table 1. table 1 descriptive statistics of variables statistics ingdp inun inmig mean 25590.10 5.973 6.531 median 24461.31 6.090 6.141 maximum 37494.17 10.97 14.87 minimum 15217.90 1.445 1.007 std. dev. 6720.868 2.599 2.774 skewness 0.374577 -0.161 0.541 kurtosis 1.840232 2.385 3.416 jarque-bera 3.812584 (0.1486) 0.965 (0.617) 2.691 (0.260) notes: probabilities were provided in parentheses for the jarque-bera test. the null hypothesis for jarque-bera test is that the variable has a normal distribution. lngdp, lnun, and lnmig represent the natural log of per capita gdp, unemployment rate and net migration rate, respectively. as seen in table (1), the measures of skewness and kurtosis, as well as the test statistic of jarque-berra, support the null hypothesis of a normal distribution for all variables. methodology hacker hatemi-j causality test (2006) the relationship between immigration and economic conditions is extensively analyzed through the granger causality test in the literature. however, granger and newbold (1974) asserted that regression analysis based on the asymptotic distribution theory does not work well, and spurious results can be obtained in the case of non-stationary variables. also, sims et al. (1990) indicated that if there are nonstationary variables, the vector autoregressive (var) model cannot be used in level form irrespective of the co-integration features of the variables. in such a case, toda and yamamoto (1995, ty hereafter) suggested a wald test statistic that asymptotically has a chi-square distribution irrespective of the order of integration or co-integration features of the variables in the model. ty (1995) proposed the following augmented var p+d model: volume 33, number 2 145 (1) eq. (1) can be defined in a compact way as follows: (2) where the modified wald (mwald) test statistic defined in eq. (3) is introduced by ty (1995) to test the null hypothesis for non-granger causality: (3) where = kronecker product, y = ap x n(1+n(p+d)), vu is the estimated variance-covariance matrix of residuals in eq. (2), and = vec(f), where vec implied the column stacking operator. the mwald statistic asymptotically has a x2 distribution based on the assumption that error terms are normally distributed, with the number of degrees of freedom equal to the number of restrictions to be tested. ty (1995) asserted that the usage of asymptotical distribution theory is valid in the case of eq. (2). however, hacker and hatemi-j (2006, hh hereafter) proved that mwald test statistic over rejects the null hypothesis, particularly in cases of non-normal and autoregressive conditional heteroscedastic (arch) error terms by utilizing monte carlo simulations. they also underlined that asymptotic distribution could be a poor . . . 146 journal of business strategies approximation for the empirical studies with small samples. hh (2006) indicated that, for the mwald test, the empirical bootstrap size is close to the correct size in different cases when the extra lags are greater than or equal to the integration order of both variables. to carry out the bootstrap simulations, eq. (2) is first estimated with the null hypothesis of granger non-causality. for each bootstrap simulation, the simulated data is generated, , where f represents the estimated value of parameters in eq. (2). the bootstrap residuals depend on t random draws with replacement from the regression’s modified residuals, each with equal probability of 1/t. then, the mean of the resulting set of drawn adjusted residuals is subtracted from each of the modified residuals in that set. the regression’s raw residuals are modified to have constant variance through the usage of leverages. the bootstrap simulation is run 100,000 times to compute the bootstrap critical values and the mwald test statistic is calculated each time. thereby, the empirical distribution for the mwald test statistic can be produced. before implementing the causality test, we need to determine the maximum integration order (dmax ) of the variables of interest. for that aim, augmented dickeyfuller (1979, adf hereafter) and phillips-perron (1988, pp hereafter) unit root tests were utilized, and their results were tabulated in table (2). table 2 augmented dickey-fuller and phillips-perron unit root test results level adf-constanttrend adf-constant pp-constanttrend pp-constant inun -1.4118 (0.8446) -2.0937 (0.2480) -1.4118 (0.8446) -2.0881 (0.2502) inmig -3.3324c (0.0735) -3.0841b (0.0346) -3.2889c (0.0806) -3.0499b (0.0375) ingdp -2.4237 (0.3632) -1.3653 (0.5911) -2.7199 (0.2337) -1.2948 (0.6244) first-difference adf-constanttrend adf-constant pp-constanttrend pp-constant inun -6.0625a (0.0000) -5.6996a (0.0000) -6.0683a (0.0000) -5.8002a (0.0000) inmig -4.4155a (0.0055) -4.2870a (0.0015) -7.5180a (0.0000) -7.5554a (0.0000) ) ) volume 33, number 2 147 ingdp -5.6767a (0.0001) -5.6996a (0.0000) -5.6164a (0.0002) -5.6499a (0.0002) notes: probability values are tabulated in parentheses, a, b and c indicate 1%, 5%, and 10% significance levels, respectively. schwarz information criterion was used in the lag length selection in the adf test; bartlett-kernel as a spectral estimation method and newey-west bandwidth as a bandwidth selection method were utilized in the pp test. lnun, lnmig and lngdp indicate the natural log of unemployment rate, net migration rate and per capita gdp, respectively. as reported in table (2), all variables are stationary in their level or first differences, i.e. they are i (1) or i (0). therefore, dmax in the ty (1995) and hh (2006) causality tests was decided as one. it is also necessary to define the optimal lag length (p) of the var model. based on the results of akaike information criterion, three lags were selected as an optimal lag order of var model.7 finally, we augmented var (3) model with an extra one lag and estimated var (4) model. the results of the causality tests are tabulated in table (3). as seen in table (3), the both ty and hh causality tests support the presence of one-way causal relationships running from unemployment to immigration and from gdp per capita to immigration. however, immigration does not appear to have any significant impact on the economic conditions of australia. as a visual inspection, we also plot immigration with gdp per capita and unemployment and got a negative relationship between unemployment and immigration (see fig. 3). therefore, based on fig. 3 as well as on the causality tests’ results, it could be concluded that increasing level of unemployment leads to decreases in immigration inflows. this result is in line with the studies of feridun (2007), islam (2007) and withers and popp (1985). however, it is in sharp contrast with the studies of konya (2000), who found a negative causality running from immigration to unemployment, and pope and withers (1993), who obtained a bidirectional negative causality between immigration and unemployment. 7 autocorrelation and heteroscedasticity problems were solved by estimating var (3) model. 148 journal of business strategies table 3 results of toda yamamoto and hacker and hatemi-j causality tests causualities mwald (ty) mwald (hh) critical values 1% 5% 10% inmig inun 2.7621 (0.4298) 2.762 15.027 9.724 7.548 inun inmig 18.754 a (0.0003) 18.753a 13.735 9.000 6.977 inmig ingdp 3.5765 (0.3110) 3.576 14.182 9.211 7.202 ingdp inmig 10.326 b (0.0160) 10.326b 13.627 8.767 6.834 notes: probabilities were provided in parentheses; a and b indicate 1% and 5% significance levels, respectively. modified walt test statistics were tabulated for both tests and the critical values for the hh causality test were provided at 1%, 5%, and 10% significance levels, respectively. ty indicates toda and yamamoto (1995) causality test, while hh shows hacker and hatemi-j (2006) causality test. lnun, lnmig and lngdp show unemployment rate, net migration rate and per capita gdp, respectively. critical values were obtained through 100,000 bootstrap replications. figure 3 plots of immigration with per capita income and unemployment (in logarithmic form) source: author’s own calculation however, immigration does not appear to affect the unemployment rate of australia, probably due to the presence of both substitutability and complementarity among native and immigrant laborers. in this respect, the adverse impacts of substitution on the employment level of australia appear to be compensated for through the positive effects of complementarity. additionally, as gross (2004) asserted, a quality effect may offset the adverse quantity effect from the immigration rate through the high levels of skill and human capital that immigrants have. volume 33, number 2 149 furthermore, foreign workers accept jobs that are rejected by native workers and fill labor or skill shortages in the host labor markets, which does not lead to an increase in the unemployment rate. besides, due to the absorptive capacity of the australian labor market and high-speed adaptation capabilities of immigrant workers, immigration may not aggravate the unemployment level in australia (damette & fromentin, 2013). regarding the relationship between gdp per capita and immigration, there is only a one-way causality running from gdp per capita to immigration. economic development and a high standard of living are expected to pull more immigrant inflows to australia. as such, as latif (2015) states, it is probable that rising gdp per capita provides a signal to potential immigrants about job prospects. however, immigration does not appear to have a significant impact on gdp per capita. this insignificant result implies that the immigrants’ human capital levels are high enough to compensate for the adverse effects caused by a reduction in the capital–labor ratio as a result of migration inflow (boubtane et al., 2013). our result is similar with those of islam (2007) and morley (2006), whereas it is in sharp contrast with feridun (2004, 2005). conclusion and policy implications in this study, we aim to analyze the relationship between immigration, gdp per capita and unemployment over the period of 1966 2013 for australia by employing the causality tests proposed by toda and yamamoto (1995) and hacker and hatemi-j (2006). the results provided evidence of one-way causality from both gdp per capita to immigration and from unemployment to immigration. the economic conditions (unemployment level and income level) appear to affect immigration inflows to australia. in this regard, the low level of unemployment is one of the pulling factors for immigrants into australia. however, immigration does not have any significant impact on the australian labor market. this is not an odd result because as boubtane et al. (2013) state, the empirical studies mostly conclude that immigration does not reduce the labor market prospects of natives. concerning the relationship between gdp per capita and immigration, the results indicate only a one-way causal relationship from gdp per capita to immigration. as such, the higher per capita income level australia has, the more people immigrate to australia. however, immigrants do not appear to affect the income per capita level of australia. overall, our results revealed that immigration inflows do not harm the employment prospects of australian residents. as a policy implication, the australian 150 journal of business strategies government does not need to arrange restrictive immigration policies to prevent new immigrant inflows because they are not harmful to the domestic labor market. as stated before, australian immigrants have a high level of human capital, and thus they should not be seen as threats to the australian economy. moreover, through new integration policies, immigrants could quickly adjust to their new life conditions, and their non-significant employment and income effects would be turned into significant and positive ones. references akbari, a. h., & devoretz, d. j. (1992). the substitutability of foreign-born labor in canadian-production: circa 1980. the canadian journal of economics, 25, 604-614. angrist, j. d., & kugler, a. d. (2003). protective or counter-productive? labor market institutions and the effect of immigration on eu natives. the economic journal, 113, 302–331. aydemir, a., & borjas, g. j. (2006). comparative analysis of the labor market impact of international migration: canada, mexico, and the united states. (nber working paper no. 12327). cambridge, ma: national bureau of economic research. australian department of immigration and border protection. (2015) australia’s migration trends 2013–14 at a glance. retrieved from https://www.border. gov.au/reportsandpublications/documents/statistics/migration-trends13-14glance.pdf basile, r., girardi, a. & mantuano, m. (2012). migration and regional unemployment in italy. the open urban studies journal, 5, 1-13. bodvarsson, o. b., berg, h. f. v. & lewer, j. j. (2008). measuring immigration’s effects on labor demand: a reexamination of the mariel boatlift. labor economics, 15, 560–574. borjas, g. j. (2001). does immigration grease the wheels of the labor market? brookings papers on economic activity, 1, 69–119. borjas, g. j. (1994). the economics of immigration. journal of economic literature, xxxii, 1667–1717. boubtane, e., coulibaly, d. & rault, c. (2013). immigration, unemployment and gdp in the host country: bootstrap panel granger causality analysis on oecd countries. economic modelling, 33, 261–269. volume 33, number 2 151 damette, o., & fromentin, v. (2013). migration and labor markets in oecd countries: a panel cointegration approach. applied economics, 45, 2295-2304. dickey, d.a., & fuller, w.a. (1979). distribution of the estimators for autoregressive time series with a unit root. journal of the american statistical association, 74, 427–431. dolado, j., goria, a., & ichino, a. (1994). immigration, human capital and growth in the host country. journal of population economics, 7, 193–215. dustmann, c., fabbri, f., & preston, i. (2005). the impact of immigration on the british labor market. the economic journal, 115, 324-341. feridun, m. (2007). immigration, income and unemployment: an application of the bounds testing approach to cointegration. the journal of developing areas, 41, 37-49. feridun, m. (2005). investigating the economic impact of immigration on the host country: the case of norway. prague economic papers, 4, 350-362. feridun, m. (2004). does immigration have an impact on economic development and unemployment? empirical evidence from finland (1981-2001). international journal of applied econometrics and quantitative studies, 1, 39-60. fromentin, v. (2013). the relationship between immigration and unemployment: the case of france. economic analysis & policy, 43, 51-66. ghatak, s., mulhern, a., & watson, j. (2008). inter-regional migration in transition economies: the case of poland. review of development economics 12, 209– 222. ghatak, s., & moore, t. (2007). migration and the eu labor market: granger causality tests on a panel var. (discussion paper). kingston upon thames, u.k.: faculty of arts and social sciences, kingston university granger, c. w. j. (1969). investigating causal relations by econometric models and cross-spectral methods. econometrica, 37, 424–438. granger, c. w. j. & newbold, p. (1974). spurious regression in econometrics. journal of econometrics, 2, 111–120. gross, d. m. (2004). impact of immigrant workers on a regional labor market. applied economic letters, 11, 405-408. gross, d. m. (2002). three million foreigners three million unemployed? immigration flows and the labor market in france. applied economics, 34, 1969–83. hacker, r. s. & hatemi-j, a. (2006). tests for causality between integrated variables using asymptotic and bootstrap distributions: theory and application. applied economics, 38, 1489–1500. 152 journal of business strategies islam, a. (2007). immigration unemployment relationship the evidence from canada. australian economic papers, 46, 52-66. jean, s., & jiménez, m. (2011). the unemployment impact of immigration in oecd countries. european journal of political economy, 27, 241–256. konya, l. (2000). bivariate causality between immigration and long-term unemployment in australia, 1981-1998. (working paper no. 18). melbourne, australia: victoria university applied economics. latif, e. (2015). the relationship between immigration and unemployment: panel data evidence from canada. economic modelling, 50, 162–167 marr, w. l., & siklos, p. l. (1994). the link between immigration and unemployment in canada. journal of policy modeling, 16, 1-26. morley, b. (2006). causality between economic growth and immigration: an ardl bounds testing approach. economics letters, 90, 72–76. oecd. (2016). international migration database. retrieved from https://stats.oecd.org/index.aspx?datasetcode=mig oecd. (2016). labor force statistics. retrieved from http://www.oecd.org/ employment/labour-stats peri, g. (2008). immigration accounting: u.s. states 1960-2006. (discussion paper series no: 05). london: centre for research and analysis of migration. phillips, p. c. b. & perron, p. (1988). testing for a unit root in time series regression. biometrika, 75(2), 335–346 pischke, j. s., & velling, j. (1997). employment effects of immigration to germany: an analysis based on local labor markets. the review of economics and statistics, 79, 594-604. pope, d., & withers, g. (1993). do migrants rob jobs? lessons of australian history, 1861-1991. the journal of economic history, 53, 719-42. shan, j. (1999). immigration and unemployment: new evidence from australia and new zealand. international review of applied economics, 13, 253-260. sims, c. a., stock, j. h., & watson, m. w. (1990) inference in linear time series models with some unit roots. econometrica, 58, 133–144. toda, h. y., & yamamoto, t. (1995). statistical inference in vector auto regressions with possibly integrated processes. journal of econometrics, 66, 225-250. troshchenkov, s. (2011). influence of immigration on the unemployment rate: the case of denmark. (master’s thesis, umea university, sweden). retrieved from https://www.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:523614/fulltext01.pdf withers, g. & pope, d. (1985). immigration and unemployment. economic record 61, 554-563. volume 33, number 2 153 world bank. (2016). development indicators database. retrieved from http://databank.worldbank.org/data/reports.aspx?source=world-developmentindicators brief biographical sketch of author dr. burcu ozcan got her phd degree in economics from istanbul university in 2011. she is now an associate professor of economics in the faculty of economics and administrative sciences at firat university in turkey. she teaches macroeconomics and monetary economics. her primary research areas are energy economics, information economics and development economics. she was a visiting professor in the business administration college at sam houston state university from april through september, 2016. organizational performance: strategic persistence versus strategic change rolf d. dixon west texas a&m university canyon, texas kimberly b. boal texas tech university lubbock, texas abstract the relationship of strategy to organizational performance has been of great interest to strategic management scholars. however, the relative contribution to organizational performance of the content of strategic decisions as opposed to the implementation of strategic decisions is not agreed upon in the literature. if it is primarily what strategy you select that leads to higher performance, then strategic change is good. on the other hand, if it is primarily how well you implement any given strategy that leads to higher performance, then strategic persistence is good. this study considers the relative contribution of strategic change versus strategic persistence as they relate to organizational performance in the banking industry. introduction two views have been espoused by strategic management scholars relating to the relationship of strategy to performance. one suggests that a firm's performance ultimately will depend on the content of the organization's strategic decisions what an organization decides to do. the miles and snow (1978) and porter (1980) strategy typologies are well known major contributors to the idea of generic strategies that lead to higher organizational performance when appropriately matched with a firm's current operating environment. this view would suggest that if an organization is not performing well with its current strategy the answer will be to change to another strategy. another view, espoused by scholars such as galbraith (1983), parnell (1994), and peters (1984), suggests that an organization's success will be based not on what strategy is selected, but, rather, on how well an organization manages its internal strategy implementation processes internal capabilities developed over time. taken from this perspective the organization that is not meeting its performance goals should seek to improve its internal implementation processes rather than change its strategic direction. 186 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 this paper seeks to contribute to our understanding of the value of organizations maintaining their strategic direction over time (strategic persistence), as opposed to that of changing strategies, as it relates to the issue of resulting performance levels for those organizations. the banking industry was utilized as the investigation arena for this study. banking over the last 20 years has gone from a period of environmental stability, to a period of environmental instability; this allows an investigation of the impact of strategic persistence on performance within the context of both a stable industry environment and an unstable industry environment. within each period (stable versus unstable) the performance level of firms that had pursued a constant strategy was compared to that of firms that had changed their strategy. strategic groups, defined as collections of firms pursuing a common strategy, were utilized as the mechanism for this comparison. firms that did not change their strategic group membership for the time period of this study are referred to as constant firms-firms persisting with a particular strategy. firms that either entered or left mid-period a strategic group are referred to as shifting firms-firms exhibiting a change in their strategic direction. managers, driven by a need to establish and maintain high performance levels in their organization, have a vested interest in t111s question is organizational performance a primary function of what an organization decides to do, or of how well it does that which it is already doing? strategic groups the concept of strategic groups was first introduced by hunt (1972) in his dissertation study of the white goods industry. strategic groups have been identified as collections of firms grouped by similar strategic actions and responses to a shared operating environment (cool and schendel, 1987). over the 24 years that have followed hunt's initial study, strategic group research has developed as a significant and popular arena for the investigation of organizational behavior and performance (barney and hoskisson, 1990; mcgee and thomas, 1986; thomas and venkatraman, 1988). fiegenbaum and thomas (1995) have indicated that strategic groups act as important reference points for firms' strategic behavior. the use of strategic groups within the banking industry allowed collections of firms that are pursuing similar strategies. within a strategic group over time, there should be found some firms that have been members of that strategic group for a substantial period of time and some firms that are relatively new members of that strategic group. segmenting these two types of firms within each strategic group makes possible the explicit investigation of the impact of strategic persistence, as identified by long-term strategic group membership, on firm performance. fall 1996 dixon & boal: organizational performance 187 industry environment a contextual issue also considered in this study was to what extent, if any, did the conditioris of industry environmental stability and instability impact the relationship between strategic persistence and finn performance. in tcrms of the management of strategy, the dimension of dynamism/instability, which involves a lack of predictable patterns, acts to reduce the ability of firms to individually and collectively understand what strategics produce the best perfonnance results, and to have the time available to understand all the issues involved in the. successful implementation of any given strategy. further, keats and hitt (1988) indicated that the dimension of instability has a greater impact on an organization's perfonnance than do either munificence or complexity, the other dimensions most commonly utilized to characterize the environment (dess and beard, 1984). thus, the dimension of instability provided the ideal context for investigating the role of the environment on the issues of this study. research hypothesis strategic persistence and performance this research investigates the impact of strategic persistence within strategic groups on perfonnance. for the purposes of this study, firms that remain within a particular strategic group for the duration of the stable or unstable period of time are referred to as "constant" member firms exemplifying strategic persistence. finns that entered or left one or more strategic groups within the stable or unstable period of time are referred to as "shifting" member firms exemplifying strategic change. specifically, to investigate the impact of strate~ gic persistence versus strategic change on perfonnance we test for statistically significant differences in the overall mean levels of performance found for "constant" member firms and for "shifting" member finns. further, we test for significant differences in the variances in perfonnance levels (performance homogeneity) found within both categories of strategic group member firms. in addition, we conduct the statistical tests of our hypotheses during a period of industry stability and a period of industry instability to investigate whether or not environmental stability or instability have any systematic impact on the relationship between strategic persistence and change to performance. hypothesis 1: during conditions of industry stability, the constant firm sets and the shifting firm sets will not exhibit different levels of peifonnance. hypothesis 2: during conditions of industry instability, the constant firm sets and the shifting firm sets will not exhibit different levels of peiformance. 188 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no.2 hypothesis 3: during conditions of industry stability, the constant firm sets and the shifting firm sets will not exhibit different levels of performance homogeneity. hypothesis 4: during conditions of industry instability, the constant firm sets and the shifting firm sets will not exhibit different levels of performance homogenei~v. methods industry sample two prior studies specifically considered the issue of strategic groups in the banking industry. amel and rhoades (1987) investigated whether or not strategic groups could be found in the banking industry, based on a selection of banking industry-specific variables. reger (1988) investigated whether or not managers in the banking industry cognitively identified strategic groups and their firm members. results from these studies suggested that strategic groups do exist in the banking industry, and that the concept of strategic groups is cognitively meaningful to practitioners. further, the banking industry lends itself well to the issues being considered in this study as this industry has gone through significant periods of stability and instability over the past 25 years. the banking industry files contained on compustat provided the sample population for this study. the compustat banking file contains banks of all sizes, as well as from all regions throughout the united states. this file provided a sample of 62 banks for the stable time period of study and 109 banks for the unstable time period. time period selection the research issues of this paper were investigated within the contexts of a period of stability and a period of instability for the banking industry as a whole. dess and beard (1984) define industry environmental stability as a condition where there are only small amounts of change in the key strategic dimensions or conditions facing a particular industry. thus, industry stability should lead to a condition of industry understanding and predictability. three dimensions have become standard in the typing of the environment: munificence, dynamism or instability, and complexity (dess and beard, 1984). keats and hitt (1988), in their study of the impact of the environmental dimensions of munificence, instability, and complexity on organizations, found that the dimension of instability had a greater impact on the behavior and subsequent performance of an organization than did either of the other two dimensions. therefore, the dimension of instability was chosen as the most appropriate to the focus of this study. this study established time periods of relative environmental instability and stability in a manner consistent with the approach utilized by tosi, fall 1996 dixon & boal: organizational peiformance 189 aldaq, and storey (1973), snyder and glueck (1982), and keats and hitt (1988). due to the major role of interest rates in both the revenues and expenses of banks in general the measure of instability was a coefficient of variation, calculated on the prime rate as reported by the federal reserve board, since interest rate changes have been noted as a major source of environmental instability in the banking industry. this study considered the entire period of 1968-1987, the time period on the 20 year banking data file available from compustat. from the analysis of this data file two distinct time periods were found, one which best reflected a period of industry stability 1968-1972, and one which best reflected a period of industry instability 1978-1982. byway of comparison, snyder and glueck (1982) reported coefficients of variation for industries ranging from .24 in the electronics industry (the most unstable) to .10 in the confectionery products industry (the most stable). in our study, the coefficients of variation for the two time periods selected for the study were .06 for the time period of 1968-1972, and .24 for the time period of 1978-1982, providing, therefore, measures for instability and stability in the banking industry that equalled or exceeded those of the snyder and glueck study. furthermore, the choice of these two time periods were externally validated by the opinion of industry specialists (compton, 1987; haraf and kushmeider, 1987), and by the charting of bank failure rates and changes in the prime rate over time. for example, bank failure rates more than doubled during the unstable period of time, relative to that of the stable period of time; and prime rates, which remained basically stable during 1968-1972, fluctuating less than 3 percentage points, ranged over 12 percentage points during the 1978-1982 time period. variable selection this study used a list of scope and resource deployment variables selected by academics and practitioners for their ability to reflect the unique strategic decision alternatives available to managers in the banking industry. the sources for this variable list include amel and rhoades (1987), pohlman (1985), reger (1988), rosenblum and pavel (1985), sinkey (1989) and professors scott macdonald and steven sears of the institute for banking and finance studies at texas tech university. the following variables, used in the present study, reflect the strategic scope and resource deployment choices generally available to banks. these variables were derived from the compustat annual bank file for the time periods of 1968-1972 and 1978-1982. scope variables: (1) loans/total assets (2) treasury securities/total assets (3) state and local government securities/total assets (4) federal funds/total assets 190 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no.2 (5) trust revenue/total assets (6) time deposits/total assets (7) demand deposits/total assets (8) foreign deposits/total assets resource deployment variables: (9) premises, furniture, and equipment/total assets (10) officer and employee salaries and wages/total assets performance variable selection pohlman (1985) identified the following measures of performance that are of specific value to the banking industry and which are used in this study: (1) return on equity (2) return on assets (3) profit margin while the limitations of accounting data have been noted by barney and hoskisson (1990), the variables selected for this study reflect standard practice in strategic group studies, as a review of the 52 strategic group studies since 1972 indicates that over forty of the studies utilized accounting data as the basis for cluster analysis (dixon, 1994). further, in an effort to minimize error, all clustering variables and the resulting groups were subjected to validation by industry expert opinion. cluster analysis procedure for this study, firms within the banking services industry were clustered into strategic groups for each year of the two five-year periods via a non-hierarchical and disjointed clustering technique. a question relative to the choice of a cluster analysis procedure is whether one wishes to obtain disjointed clusters where each firm is found within one and only one cluster. as the major focus of this study was to investigate the influence of a firm's constant, versus shifting, membership in a strategic group on performance, a cluster analysis technique was needed that forces closed strategic group boundaries, thereby allowing firms to belong to only one strategic group at any point in time. the sas institute, inc. procedure of proc fastclus provides the non-hierarchical and disjointed cluster analysis best suited for the issue of the present study and was for the above-stated reasons deemed the most appropriate clustering technique to use in this study. the determination of the appropriate number of strategic groups for each year of the study was based on a review of the r2, the cubic clustering criterion value, and the psuedo-f value generated for each iteration of the clustering technique. a ruleof-thumb identified by fiegenbaum (1987) for the r2 values as a cut-off point in cluster analysis is that one should not increase the number of clusters past the point where the r2 values are increasing at a rate of less than 5%. the proc fastclus procedure generates for each number of strategic groups a cubic clustering criterion and a psuedo-f statistic. these two statistics indifall 1996 dixon & boal: organizational performance 191 cate the appropriate number of strategic groups as being that point at which these two statistical measures peak. strategic group membership status sixty-two banks during the stable time period of 1968-1972, and 109 banks during the unstable time period of 1978-1982, were clustered by their strategic profile, as indicated by the cluster analysis loadings on each of the strategic variables, into five strategic groups (consisting of 4,7, 8, 21, and 22 banks each) during the stable time period and into three strategic groups (consisting of 12, 38, and 59 banks each) during the unstable time period. following the establishment of the appropriate number of strategic groups, as determined by the procedure discussed in the section above, these resulting groups were then further validated by industry expert opinion. then for the two time periods of study, sub-group categories of constant strategic group firm members and shifting strategic group firm members were established for each of the years 1968-1972 and 1978-1982. this was accomplished by a mobius procedure which compares the location of all firms included in strategic group 1 in year n to their strategic group location in year n + i (sudharshan, fiegenbaum, and thomas, 1991). the firms located on the diagonal for the entire five years of each period (stable and unstable) are the constant member firms; all others are categorized as shifting member firms. this procedure was done for all strategic groups for each of the five years of the stable period of 1968-1972 and each of the five years of the unstable period of 1978-1982. hypotheses testing procedures performance means differences, as indicated in hypotheses i and 2, are analyzed by an anoya test available in proc glm of sas. performance variances, as indicated in hypotheses 3 and 4, are analyzed by an f test available in proc trest of sas. results identification of strategic groups the determination of the appropriate number of strategic groups for each year of the study was based on a review of the r2, the cubic clustering criterion value, and the psuedo-f value generated by the cluster analysis procedure. for the stable period of 1968-1972 five major strategic groups were consistently found. the groups as established by the clustering technique were verified by a recognized banking industry expert. a review of the strategic profiles established by the relative weight given each of the strategic variables in the clustering technique utilized in this study resulted in the following groups being identified. they were: (l) commercial banks seeking core deposits, such as certificates of deposits, (2) smaller local banks acting as good corporate citizens by investing heavily in local securities offerings, (3) traditional 192 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 banks following a match-funding strategy with loans equaling deposits, (4) investment banks, and (5) money center banks seeking foreign deposits. using the identical procedure as above described for the unstable period of 19781982, three major strategic groups were consistently found to be operating within the banking industry. they were identified as: (1) banks which followed the conservative policy of loaning their excess liquidity to other banks, (2) aggressive commercial banks offering short term loans in an effort to maximize gains from rapidly changing interest rate changes,and (3) money center banks seeking foreign deposits. differences in performance means to test for differences in performance means between constant and shifting strategic group firm members, a two-factor model was used. factor 1 indicated a firm's status as either a constant or a shifting strategic group firm member. factor 2 indicated the specific strategic group of which each firm was a member. the analysis was done as detailed for each of the 10 years of the study on three performance variables: return on equity, return on assets and before-tax profit margin. seeking to further our understanding of whether there are performance consequences of strategic group membership, this procedure allowed an investigation into the statistical impact of a variety of performance measures. for the stable time period of 1968-1972, hypothesis 1 was rejected one out of five years for the return-on-equity measure, four out o( five years for the return-on-assets measure, and three out of five years for the before-tax profit measure (table 1). during this period of industry stability, statistically significant differences between mean performance levels for the sub-groups of constant member firms and shifting member firms occurred a little over 50% of the time, depending upon the measure of performance chosen. table 1 performance mean differences between constant and shifting strategic group firm members: stable period perfonnance variables roe roa profit * p-value < .10 ** p-value < .05 *** p-value < .01 1968 1.99* 9.18** 6.62*** 1969 1970 2.60** 1.84* 7.54*** 6.91*** 3.86*** 2.13** 1971 .52 1.76* .52 1972 1.43 3.11 *** 1.13 the results for the unstable time period of 1978-1982, however, do not indicate a general rejection of hypothesis 2 (table 2). for each of the three fall 1996 dixon & boal: organizational performance 193 performance variables, the null hypothesis was rejected only four times out of the fifteen cases available. this would indicate that performance differences between constant and shifting strategic group firm members essentially disappear during times of industry environmental instability. table 2 performance mean differences between constant and shifting strategic group firm members: unstable period performance variables roe roa profit * p-value < .10 ** p-value < .05 *** p-value < .01 1978 1.01 1.55 1.95* 1979 1.19 1.26 1.41 1980 1.37 1.67* 1.70* 1981 3.44*** 1.12 1.04 1982 1.06 1.47 1.66* equality of performance variance for each of the five years of the stable time period (1968-1972) and the unstable time period of the study (1978-1982), an "f" statistic was computed, testing the null hypothesis of equality of variance for the three performance measure means between the sub-group of constant member firms and the subgroup of the shifting member firms. table 3 provides the results of this test for the stable period of 1968-1972. for the performance measure of returnon-equity, hypothesis 3 was not rejected in any year investigated, indicating no statistically significant differences in the variance for this measure between the constant and shifting firm sets. the performance measure of return-an-assets rejected the hypothesis in three out of the five years of the stable period. therefore, for the stable time period of 1968-1972, there is little statistical evidence supporting unequal performance variances between the constant member firm sub-groups and the shifting member firm sub-groups. table 3 constant versus shifting strategic group firm sets test of equality of variance: stable period performance variables roe roa profit * p-value < .10 ** p-value < .05 *** p-value < .01 1968 1.13 4.07*** 1.78 1969 1.63 3.63*** 1.38 1970 1.08 2.90*** 1.44 1971 1.14 1.06 1.09 1972 1.04 1.54 ll7 194 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no.2 table 4 provides the re.sults for the testing of equality of variance for the three performance measures between the constant and shifting member firm sets for the unstable industry time period of 1978-1982. for the performance measure of return-on-equity hypothesis 4 failed to be rejected four out of the five years of this period. for the return-on-assets measure hypothesis 4 again failed to be rejected four out of five years. the hypothesis failed to be rejected for the before-tax profit margin measure two out of five years. again, the statistical results generally failed to support unequal performance variances between the sub-groups of constant and shifting member firm sets. table 4 constant versus shifting strategic group firm sets test of equality of variance: unstable period performance variables 1978 1979 1980 \98\ \982 roe i.o! 1.19 1.37 3.44*** 1.06 roa 1.55 1.26 1.67* 1.12 \.47 profit 1.95* 1.41 1.70* 1.04 1.66* * p-value < .10 ** p-value < .05 *** p-va1ue < .0\ discussion this study suggests that, within strategic groups, firms that have remained constant members will have different performance characteristics than will be found for those firms that have not been constant members of a particular strategic group over a given period of time. for the stable time period of 19681972, constant member firms exhibited higher performance levels than did shifting member firms in 73.3% of the cases. further, during the unstable period of time, constant member firms exhibited higher performance levels than did shifting firms in 72.5% of the cases. the empirical results of this study suggest, therefore, that the inconsistent findings in previous studies between strategic group membership and performance could be partly due to researchers not controlling for the confounding influences of strategic group composition. our results suggest that, within each strategic group, firms that have remained members over time will have higher levels of performance than will firms that are newer to the strategic group, and especially so during times of industry environmental stability. therefore, strategic groups with a high ratio of constant to shifting member firms can be expected to have different performance characteristics than would strategic groups with a low ratio of constant to shifting member firms. this finding is consistent with the general idea of strategic persistence, or "practice makes fall 1996 dixon & boal: organizational performance 195 perfect." it is reasonable to expect that firms will do that better which they have experience doing. further, sub-groups of constant member firms were expected to exhibit significantly less variance in their performance measures than found for the sub-groups of shifting member firms. however, little statistical support was found for this proposition for either the stable time period of 1968-1972 or the unstable time period of 1978-1982. conclusion by tracking the strategic group membership of firms over two five-year time periods, this study supported the proposition that strategic groups do appear to exist in terms of collections of firms that exhibit, over significant periods of time, a tendency to make similar strategic decisions. this would suggest that, within an industry, strategic groups do have an impact on the strategic choices and decisions made by the firms that comprise that industry. while firms can change their strategic group membership, and by definition their strategies, this study found that the highest performers were those that stayed the course, i.e., firms that pursued over a longer period of time a single strategy outperformed those firms that switched strategies over the time periods of the study. further, this research raises issues with one of the fundamental tenets of strategy, that a firm attempt to co-align itself with its environment. prior research suggests that firms can exercise strategic choice in choosing their strategic orientation and that they can change their strategies as they attempt to achieve this environmental alignment. however, research also suggests that strategic change to achieve such an alignment will not necessarily result in superior performance, relative to those that do not change. this is consistent with other work on generic strategies that suggests firms without a coherent strategy will have lower levels of performance than will firms which follow a consistent strategy. based on the results of this study, we would suggest that strategic persistence appears to be a more viable approach to achieving superior financial performance than is strategic change. we do not suggest that strategic change in an effort to enhance environmental co-alignment, or fit, is not a useful concept. rather, that strategic change, due either to a lack of necessary organizational capabilities and/or the misreading of the environment, is as likely to cause a misfit as it is to create a fit references amel, d. and s. rhoades. strategic groups in banking. working paper no. 87-1. fi~ nancial structure section, division of research and statistics. board of governors of the federal reserve system, 1987. 196 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 barney, j. and r. e. hoskisson. "strategic groups: untested assertions and proposals." managerial and decision economics 11 (1990): 187-198. compton, e. the new world of commercial banking. lexington, ma: lexington books, 1987. cool, k. and d. schendel. "strategic group formation and performance: u.s. pharmaceutical industry, 1963-1982." management science 33 (1987): 11 02-1124. dess, g. and w. d. beard. "dimensions of organizational task environments." administrative sciences ouarterly 29 (1984): 52-73. dixon, r. "performance homogeneity among strategic groups constant member firm sets and shifting member firm sets in the banking industry," ph.d dissertation, texas tech university, 1994. fiegenbaum, a. "dynamic aspects of strategic groups and competitive strategy: concepts and empirical examination in the insurance industry." ph.d. dissertation, university of illinois at urbana-champaign, 1987. fiegenbaum, a. and h. thomas. "strategic groups as reference groups: theory, modeling, and empirical examination of industry and competitive strategy," strategic management journal 16(6), (1995): 461-476. galbraith, j. "strategy and organizational planning." human resource planning, (1983): 63-77. haraf, w. and r. kushmeider. restructuring banking and financial services in america. washington, dc: american enterprise institute for public policy research, 1987. hunt, m. "competition in the major home appliance industry 1960-1970," ph.d. dissertation, harvard uni versity, 1972. keats, b. and m. hitt. "a causal model of linkages among environmental dimensions, macro organizational characteristics, and performance." academy of management journal 31(3), (1988): 570-598. mcgee, j. and h. thomas. "strategic groups: a useful linkage between industry structure and strategic management," strategic management journal 6 (1986): 141160. miles, r.e. and c.c. snow. organization strategy, structure, and processes. new york: mcgraw-hill, 1978. mintzberg, h. and j. quinn. the strategy process. new jersey: prentice hall, 1991. fall 1996 dixon & baal: organizational performance 197 parnell, j. "strategic consistency versus flexibility: does strategic change really enhance performance?" american business review 12(2), (1994): 22-29. peters, t. "strategy follows structure: developing distinctive skills." california management review (spring, 1984): 111-125. pohlman, j. "a framework for strategic planning." in handbook for banking stratm, eds. r. aspinwall and r. eisenbeis. new york: john wiley & sons, 1985. porter, m. competitive strategy. new york: the free press, 1980. reger, r. "competitive positioning in the chicago banking market: mapping the mind of the strategist." ph.d. dissertation, university of illinois at urbana-champaign, 1988. rosenblum, h. and c. pavel. "banking services in transition: the effects of nonbank competitors." in handbook for banking strategy. eds. r. aspinall and r. eisenbleis. new york: john wiley & sons, 1985. sinkey, j. commercial bank financial management in the financial services industry. new york: macmillan, 1989. snyder, n. and w. glueck. "can environmental volatility be objectively measured?" academy of management journal 25 (1982): 185-192. thomas, h. and n. venkatraman. "research on strategic groups: progress and prognosis." journal of management studies 26(6), (988): 537-556. tosi, h., r. aldaq, and r. storey. "on the measurement of the environment: an assessment of the lawrence and lorsch environmental uncertainty questionnaire." administrative sciences ouarterly 18 (1973): 27-36. rolf d. dixon, (ph.d., texas tech university), is an assistant professor of management at west texas a&m university where he is teaching strategic management and contemporary management problems. research areas of interest includes strategic groups as predictors of organizational behavior and performance and management issues in a cross-national environment. prior research has appeared in such journals as health care strategic management journal and the journal of transnational management development. kimberly b. boal, (ph.d., university of wisconsin), is an associate professor of management at texas tech university. currently he is visiting at the pennsylvania state university where he is teaching organizational theory and researching problems associated with integrating merged companies. prior research has appeared in such journals as strategic management journal, academy of management journal, journal of management, organizational behavior and human performance, and leadership quarterly. as well as several scholarly book chapters. organizational performance: strategic persistence versus strategic change volume 32, number 1 55 dynamic effects of u.s. budget deficit and labor productivity-real wage gap on us stock market performance matiur rahman mcneese state university • lake charles, louisiana muhammand south carolina state university • orangeburg, south carolina abstract this paper investigates the dynamic effects of annual u.s budget deficit as a ratio of gdp and labor productivity-real wage gap on us stock market performance. the sample period runs from 1950 through 2012. the standard cointegration methodology is appropriately applied. all the aforementioned variables are nonstationary in levels revealing i(1) behavior. the coefficient of the error-correction term of the vector error-correction model (vecm) has expected negative sign with statistical significance confirming long-run unidirectional causality stemming from the independent variables to the stock market return. however, the speed of adjustment towards a long-run equilibrium is slow as reflected in the low numerical coefficient of the error-correction term. the evidences on short-run interactive feedback effects are also very weak. keywords: budget deficit, productivity-real wage gap, unit root, cointegration, vector error-correction model jel classification code: e60, g10 introduction u.s. federal budget deficits have been perennial at sustainable levels throughout the us history excepting several years, occasionally. the net effect of the budget deficits on stock market returns is confounding and uncertain through interest rate and price channels depending on the methods of financing. this issue remains a puzzle inspiring numerous empirical studies. in theory, rising deficit boosts federal demand for loanable funds that, in turn, lifts interest rate and crowds out private investment. this decline in private investment reduces corporate capital stock with which to work. this contracting capital stock decreases future earnings growth and cash inflows. in addition, rising interest rate used as a discount factor depresses stock prices. monetization of increases in budget deficits through quantitative eas56 journal of business strategies ing lowers interest rates and causes higher expected inflation. both exert opposing influences on stock prices. in finance, the valuation of stocks depends on the expectation of the current and future cash flows from equities, the risks inherent in those flows, and rate at which those flows are discounted. stock prices are also influenced by changes in economic activity, interest rate, and inflation, among other macroeconomic fundamentals. their net effect on stock market at some point of time is ambiguous. efficient market hypothesis in weak-form further claims that budget deficits have little effect on future stock prices as the past deficits are already incorporated in the current stock prices. stock price behaviors have important bearings on private sector capital formation, market liquidity, allocative efficiency and economic prosperity meriting further empirical inquiries. the unprecedented rise in u.s. budget deficit and uncharted behavior of u.s. stock market during 2008-2010 renewed interest in studying further the relation between budget deficits and stock prices. economic theories are unsettling to provide a clear explanation to this uneasy and complex relationship. the effects of rising budget deficits due to income tax cuts or federal spending spree or both on stock prices primarily depend on the state of the economy and the methods of financing the deficits. to explain further, (i) increase in income tax reduces disposable income to spend on consumption goods. this reduces aggregate demand. given the aggregate supply constraint, prices of consumer goods decline resulting in depressed corporate earnings and hence lower stock prices, ii) financing by federal borrowing from loanable funds market raises interest rate that, in turn, reduces stock prices, and (iii) partial or full monetization of deficits by accommodative monetary easing lowers interest rate without risk of surging inflation, if the economy is at lessthan-full employment. this will help lift stock prices. furthermore, if the economy is at full employment, monetary easing will raise the fear of future resurgence of inflation with dampening effects on stock market as rational investors will reshuffle their portfolios by reallocating funds from financial assets to real assets for hedging purposes. thus, the net effect of budget deficits on stock prices at best is uncertain. labor productivity and real wage gap is another piece of puzzle in macroeconomics literature. the growth in real hourly compensation in the us nonfarm business sector has slowed to 0.4 percent a year from 2.4 percent a year over 1960-1973 (bosworth and perry, 1994). the relationship between labor productivity and nonfarm real wage is nonlinear (quadratic) with inverted u-curve (tang, 2012). so, the net effect of this gap on stock prices is again confounding and uncertain. in common sense term, a rising gap raises corporate profit that is used partly to pay higher divivolume 32, number 1 57 dends to shareholders. this, in turn, boosts stock prices. although labor productivity is an important determinant of wage, gains are distributed more in favor of capital than labor since workers are being paid discernibly below their marginal revenue products. the absence of a strong relationship between labor productivity and real wage is unlikely to boost consumption growth with a subdued effect on stock prices due to lackluster sales growths. the primary objective of this study is, thus, to explore the influences of us annual budget deficit as ratio of gdp and labor productivity-real wage gap on u.s. stock market. the standard cointegration framework is invoked to investigate this intricate issue of great importance in view of their puzzling nature. in particular, the casual nexus of stock market and labor productivity-real wage gap is heavily underresearched. the rest of the paper is organized as follows. section ii provides a brief review of the related literature. section iii outlines the empirical methodology and describes data. section iv reports empirical results. section v offers conclusions. brief review of related literature tobin (1969), in his general equilibrium approach of the financial sector, highlighted the role of stock returns as the linkage between the real and the financial sectors of the economy and showed how both money growth and budget deficits can have an important impact on stock returns. in this connection, theoretical discussion/ models are also put forth by (blanchard, 1981, and shah, 1984). it is a well-known fact that government actions (or fiscal decisions) are likely to influence future monetary policy actions (thorbecke, 1997; and patelis, 1997). based on theory and empirical evidences, the expected directional impact of the budget deficit on stock returns should be negative. government budget deficits exert upward pressure on the nominal interest rate or the discount rate, as applied to the firm. this, in turn, lowers expected returns as the risk premium increases (geske and roll, 1983). geske and roll also note that increases in risk premia due to federal budget deficits expose investors to an uncertainty surrounding the reaction of the federal reserve and thus further confound the equity market behavior. several studies have focused on the relationship between fiscal policy (budget deficits) and stock market behavior. these studies examined primarily stock market efficiency with respect to fiscal actions (e.g., rogalski and vinso, 1977; darrat, 1988; darrat and brocato, 1994; and lee, 1997). although the theoretical motivation on the effects of fiscal policy on the stock market (or asset prices) have been laid out more than thirty years ago (e.g., tobin, 1969; blanchard, 1981; and shah, 58 journal of business strategies 1984), the empirical front on the issue has been lagging, both for the u.s. and other countries (darrat, 1988; and ali and hasan, 2003). perhaps, this was due to the assumption of barro’s (1974) ricardian equivalence proposition (of debt-neutrality), which asserts that deficits do not matter if individuals correctly expect and discount future tax increases from current tax decreases thus leaving their net worth unaffected. subsequent investigations, however, have produced mixed results. for instance, some studies have shown support for the proposition (e.g., evans, 1987a, b; and boothe and ried, 1989), others have produced results to the contrary (frenkel and razin, 1986; and zahid, 1988). conventional analysis suggests that sustained budget deficits have profound implications on interest rates, national saving and the external account (gale and orszag, 2003, 2004; engen and hubbard, 2005). thus, going beyond the traditional analysis, large future deficits entail additional risks to the economy which includes a loss in domestic and foreign investor confidence and adverse effects on the exchange rate. specifically, a loss in investor and business confidences would cause a shift of portfolios away from home-currency assets into foreign-currency assets, thereby placing a downward pressure on the domestic currency and an upward pressure on the interest rate. this would limit the ability of the country to finance its liabilities and increase the country’s exposure to exchange rate fluctuations. in contrast, higher government deficits may also encourage higher money growth, resulting from an accommodative behavior of the federal reserve or a decline in interest rates. empirical evidences on this behavior have offered mixed results. specifically, allen and smith (1983) and barnhart and darrat (1989) report a negative relationship between federal budget deficits and money growth. furthermore, deleeuw and holloway (1985) and hoelscher (1986) provide evidence of a positive linkage between the above. therefore, this is still an issue of further empirical investigation. additionally, the effects of money growth on stock returns can be approached from two theoretical perspectives, namely, the efficient market approach (cooper, 1974; and rozeff, 1974) and the general equilibrium portfolio approach. the first approach simply argues that all past information incorporated in the money supply data is reflected in current stock returns and so money supply changes should have no impact on stock returns excepting a possible contemporaneous effect. the second perspective suggests that investors attempt to hold an equilibrium position among all assets, including money and equities. an exogenous shock that increases the money supply would temporarily disturb this equilibrium until investors substitute money for other assets. so, equities respond to monetary disturbance with a lag and that lag volume 32, number 1 59 could, theoretically, be linked to an interest-rate effect, a corporate-earnings effect, a risk-premium effect and so on (hamburger and kochin, 1971). the conventional wisdom about the role of stocks is that they provide a hedge against inflation or the fisherian hypothesis of positive relationship of nominal equity returns with inflation. however, evidences provided by fama and schwert (1977), geske and roll (1983), and mccarthy et al., (1990) suggest a negative relationship between stock returns and inflation. a re-examination of the issue by james et al., (1985), wei and wong (1992), and lee (1992) found support for this hypothesis, while park (1997), siklos and kwok (1999) and laopodis (2006) found evidence against it. thus, this issue is still stirring empirical controversies and remains to be empirically resolved. more recently, quayes (2010) studied the association between budget deficit and stock prices by integrating the effects of inflation and demographic structure. results from the cointegration analysis show that both budget deficit and inflation have negative impact on stock prices. saleem, et.al. (2012) examine the long-run causal relationship between budget deficit and stock market for india and pakistan. results show that due to high development expenditures in pakistan, a long-term positive relationship is observed between budget deficit and stock market. in india, a negative relationship is observed between both variables due to increase in current expenditures. in pakistan, a causal relationship runs from budget deficit to stock market while no causal relationship exists between budget deficit and stock market in india. empirical studies investing the labor productivity and wage relationship are abundant. to cite a few recent ones, mora, et al. (2005) investigated the relationship between wages and labor productivity in 11 european countries for 1981-2001 and found that the gap between nominal wages and labor costs decreased. however, they did not observe a similar decrease of the gap between real wages and labor productivity. lopez-villavicencio and silva (2010) analyzed macroeconomic data of oecd countries between 1985 and 2007. they found that wage increase exceeded productivity growth of permanent workers. for temporary workers, it was just the opposite. narayan and smyth (2009), using the co-integration technique, investigated the relationship among inflation, real wages and growth of labor productivity in the g-7 countries for 1960-2004. they found a positive relationship between real wages and productivity growth. verbic and kuzmin (2009) explored the relationship between wages and labor productivity in slovenia over 1998-2007. they confirmed the hypothesis of high dependence of wages on labor productivity. sidhu (2010) 60 journal of business strategies found that labor productivity had a strong influence on determining wages in the indian economy. one percent increase of labor productivity led to about 0.39 percent increase of wage rates in india. tang (2012) empirically investigated the impact of real wages on labor productivity in the malaysian manufacturing sector using annual data for 1980-2009. this study found a quadratic relationship (i.e. inverted u-shaped curve) between labor productivity and real wage instead of a linear relationship. to our knowledge, the empirical literature on this issue is very scant. a widening labor productivity-wage gap contributes to surges in stock prices. rising productivity boosts aggregate supply (as). but real wage gains lag behind labor productivity gain. as a result, profits rise sharply causing an upsurge in the demand for company shares raising their prices (batra, 1999 and 2003). using quarterly us data for the period of 1970-2000, rashed and samanta (2005) demonstrated a strong positive relationship between labor productivity—wage gap and the stock price within a macroeconomic framework, as suggested in batra (1999). empirical methodology and data the estimating base equation is specified as follows: spr t= α + β1 bdgt + β2 prct + et (1) where, spr = us s&p 500 return, bdgt = annual us real budget deficit as ratio of real gdp, and pcr = labor productivity-real wage gap (productivity/real wage). the causal effect of each explanatory variable on s&p 500 is unidirectional, not bidirectional. so, reverse specifications of equation (1) are not necessary. prior to testing for cointegration, the time series properties of the variables involved are examined. to test for unit root (nonstationarity) in the variables, the efficient modified dickey-fuller test (df-gls), the efficient modified phillips-perron test (elliot et al. 1996; ng and perron 2001) and their counterpart kpss (kwiatkowski, phillips, schmidt and shin 1992) test for no unit root (stationarity) are implemented instead of the standard adf and pp tests for their high sensitivity to the selection of lag-lengths. it is important to examine the time series properties of variables since an application of the ordinary least squares (ols) to estimate a model with nonstationary time series data results in the phenomenon of spurious regression (granger and newbold, 1974) invaliditating the inferences through the standard t-test and joint f-test (phillips, 1986). to be cointegrated, variables must possess the same order of integration, i.e., each variable must become stationary on first-order differencing of level data depicting i(1) behavior. volume 32, number 1 61 second, the cointegration procedure, as developed in johansen (1988, 1992, 1995) and johansen and juselius (1990), is implemented that allows interactions in the determination of the relevant macroeconomic variables and being independent of the choice of the endogenous variables. it also allows explicit hypothesis testing of parameter estimates and rank restrictions using likelihood ratio tests. the empirical exposition of the johansen-juselius methodology is as follows: ∆vt= τ + ωvt-1 + ∑ ωjvt-j + mt (2) where, vt denotes a vector of spr, bdg and prc, and ω = αβ’. here, α is the speed of adjustment matrix and β is the cointegration matrix. equation (2) is subject to the condition that ω is less-than-full rank matrix, i.e., r < n. this procedure applies the maximum eigenvalue test (λmax) and trace test (λtrace) for null hypotheses on r. both tests have their trade-offs. λmax test is expected to offer a more reliable inference as compared to λtrace test (johansen and juselius (1990), while λtrace test is preferable to λmax test for higher testing power (lütkepohl, et al., 2001)). however, the johansenjuselius test procedure is also not immune to supersensitivity to the selection of laglengths. the optimum lag-lengths are determined by the aic (akaike information criterion), as developed in akaike (1969). third, on the evidence of cointegrating relationship among the variables, there will exist an error-correction representation (engle and granger, 1987). the vector error-correction model takes the following form: ∆sprt = β1et-1 + ∑  ϕiδsprt-i + ∑  δj δbdgt-j + ∑  ψj δprct-j + ut (3) equation (3) corresponds to original equation (1). here, et-1 is the error-correction term of equation (3). if β1 is negative and statistically significant in terms of the associated t-value, there is evidence of a long-run causal flow to the dependent variable from the relevant explanatory variables. if δj’s, ϕi’s, and ψj’s do not add up to zero, there are short-run interactive feedback relationships in equation (3). annual data from 1950 through 2012 are employed. the time-span over 60 years is quite sufficient for meaningful cointegration analyses (hakkio and rush, 1991). data sources include new york stock exchange for s&p 500(spr), u.s. department of commerce for nominal budget deficits (bdg) and real gdp; and bureau of labor statistics for labor productivity and hourly real wage. nominal budget deficits are deflated by consumer price indices of corresponding years. annual data 62 journal of business strategies are used for all variables due to availability of budget deficits data only on yearly basis, although quarterly data are available for other variables. empirical results first, to describe the nature of data distribution of each variable, the standard statistical descriptors are computed. they are reported as follows: table 1 descriptive statistics sample: (1950 2011) series mean median stdev skewness kurtosis jaraque-bera spr 5.2458 4.7809 1.261 0.19338 1.8302 23.9212 bdg -15.0106 -14.4790 23.8862 -2.3498 9.5430 167.6576 prc 0.8630 0.8374 0.10453 0.34089 1.7000 55.56644 the above standard descriptors confirm near-normality in the data distribution of each time series variable in terms of mean-to-median ratio being close to unity and moderate skewness. the jarque-bera statistics also reaffirm the above inference. second, pairwise simple correlation coefficients of the variables are reported as follows: table 2 correlation matrix series spr bdg prc spr 1.000000 0.138875 0.63384 bdg -0.44603 1.000000 -0.42927 prc 0.633842 -0.429275 1.000000 as evidenced in table 2, each correlation coefficient has expected sign. the coefficients range from -0.44603 to 0.63384, as observed above. third, time series property of nonstationarity/stationarity in each variable is examined by the applications of df-gls, ng-perron and kpss tests. their calculated values are reported as follows: volume 32, number 1 63 table 3: unit root tests* series level first differences df-gls ng-perron kpss df-gls ng-perron kpss spr -1.1263 -1.4132 0.957 -6.5366 -26.677 0.1148 bdg -0.50929 -1.9411 0.5735 6.402502 -28.4310 0.24003 prc -1.70283 -5.444 0.6201 -8.62633 -29.568 0.08928 *the modified dickley-fuller (df_gls) critical values are -2.653 and -1.954 at 1% and 5% levels of significance, respectively. the modified phillips-perron (ng-perron) critical values are -13.00 and -8.10 at 1% and 5% levels of significance, respectively. the kpss critical values are 0.7 and 0.347 at 1% and 5% levels of significance, respectively. as depicted in table 3, df-gls, ng-perron and kpss tests reveal nonstationarity of each variable by rejecting the associated null hypothesis at 1% and 5% levels of significance. each variable also displays i(1) behavior since first-differencing of level data restores stationarity, as shown above. fourth, as all the variables are nonstationary in levels and depict i(1) behavior. as a result, λtrace and λmax tests are applied to explore the possibility of cointegration. their computed values are reported as follows: table 4 johansen multivariate cointegration test results series: spr, bdg, prc hypothesized no. of ce(s) eigenvalue trace (λtrace) statistic 0.05 critical value prob.** none* 0.452968 49.64508 29.79707 0.0001 at most 1* 0.241613 17.67290 15.4947 0.0231 at most 2 0.05530 3.015119 3.841466 0.0825 trace test indicates 1 cointegratedeqn at 0.05 level. *denotes rejection of the null hypothesis at the 0.05 level. **mackinnon-haug-michelis (1999) p-values 64 journal of business strategies hypothesized no. of ce(s) eigenvalue maximum value (λmax) eigen 0.05 critical value prob.** none* 0.452968 31.97218 21.13162 0.0010 at most 1* 0.241613 14.65778 14.26460 0.0433 at most 2 0.055301 3.015119 3.8414 0.0825 max-eigen value test indicates 1 cointegratedeqn(s) at the level 0.05 level *denotes rejection of the null hypothesis at the 0.05 level **mackinnon-haug-michelis (1999) p-values the computed values of λtrace and λmax statistics being higher than their respective critical values at 5% level of significance clearly reject the null hypothesis of no cointegration. in other words, there exists converging relationship among the variables towards a long-run equilibrium. this is due to one cointegrating vector that drives the dynamic system to converge towards a long-run equilibrium. finally, on the evidence of cointegrating relationship among the variables, vector error-correction model (3) is estimated for long-run causal flows with convergence and short-run dynamic interactive feedback relationship among the variables. the estimates are reported in equation (3)', as follows: δsprt = -0.0373 êt-1+ 0.1658δsprt-1 -0.2105δsprt-2 + 0.0018δbdgt-1 (-2.3005) (1.1059) (-1.2726) (1.0018) + 0.0086δbdgt-2 -0.0115δpcpt-1 -0.2634δpcpt-2 (3)' (0.8870) (-0.0357) (-0.8736) 2 = 0.0336, f = 1.2877, aic = -1.1310 as observed in equation (3)', there exists a long-run unidirectional causal flow from the lagged independent variables to the current change in s&p500 (spr). this inference is based on the expected negative sign of the coefficient of the error-correction term (êt-1) and its statistical significance in terms of the associated t-value. but its numerical coefficient (-0.0373) indicates very slow speed of adjustment towards a long-run equilibrium. there are weak evidences of short-run interactive feedback effects within the system in terms of the statistical insignificance as reflected in the associated individual t-values. 2 reveals that merely 3.36% of δsprt is explained by the independent variables. the f-statistic at 1.2877 shows statistical insignificance of the overall equation (3)'. this is also charted graphically in the appendix. these findings are consistent with those of a host of empirical studies, as cited in the literature review section of this paper. volume 32, number 1 65 conclusions to summarize, time series data on stock market return, federal annual real budget deficit as ratio of corresponding annual real gdp and labor productivity-real wage gap are nonstationary in levels and reveal i(1) behavior. all three variables are found cointegrated in terms of both λtrace and λmax tests. the estimates of the vecm confirm long-run unidirectional causal flows from the lagged independent variables to the contemporaneous stock market return with slow speed of adjustment towards a long-run equilibrium. the evidences show very weak short-run interactive feedback effects among the variables. in closing, real budget deficit and labor productivityreal wage gap have long-run implications for us stock market performance with no significant short-run influences. thus, theoretical analyses partly meet empirics in the long run, though not in the short run. references akaike, h., (1969). fitting autoregressive for prediction. journal annals of the institute of statistical mathematics, 21(1), 243-247. allen, s. d., & smith, m.d. (1983), government borrowing and monetary accommodation. journal of monetary economics 12(4), 605-616. ali, s.m., & hasan, m.a., (1993). is the canadian stock market efficient with respect to fiscal policy? some vector autoregression results. journal of economics and business 45(1), 45-59. barnhart, s.w., & darrat, a.f. (1989). federal deficits and money growth in the united states: a vector autoregressive analysis. journal of banking and finance 13(1), 137-149. barro, r.j. (1974). are government bonds net wealth? journal of political economy 82(6), 1095-1117. batra, r. n. (1999). the crash of the millennium: surviving the inflationary depression, new york: harmony books, 1999. batra, r., (2003). common sense macroeconomics, richardson: liberty press, 2003. blanchard, o. j. (1981). output, the stock market and interest rates. american economic review 71(1), 132-143. boothe, p.m., & reid, b.g. (1989). asset returns and government deficits in a small open economy: empirical evidence from canada. journal of monetary economics 23(1), 65-77. 66 journal of business strategies bosworth, b., & perry g. l. (1994). productivity and real wages: is there a puzzle?. brookings papers on economic activity, (1), 317-344. cooper, r. l. (1974). efficient capital markets and the quantity theory of money. journal of finance 29(3), 887-908. darrat, a.f. (1988). on fiscal policy and the stock market. journal of money, credit and banking 20(3), 353-363. darrat, a.f., & brocato, j. (1994). stock market efficiency and the federal budget deficit: another anomaly? financial review 29(1), 49-75. deleeuw, f., & holloway, t.m. (1985). the measurement and significance of the cyclically-adjusted federal budget and debt. journal of money, credit and banking 17(2), 232-242. elliot, g., rothenberg, t.j. & stock, j.h. (1996). efficient test for an autoregressive unit root. econometrica 64(4), 813-836. engle, r.f. & granger, c.j. (1987). co-integration and error correction: representation, estimation and testing. econometrica, 55(2), 251-276. engen, e., & hubbard, r.g. (2004). federal government debt and interest rates. national bureau of economic research macroeconomics annual, 83. evans, p. (1987). interest rates and expected future budget deficits in the united states. journal of political economy, 95(1), 34-58. evans, p. (1987). do budget deficits raise nominal interest rate?. evidence from six countries. journal of monetary economics, 95, 281-300. fama, e.f., & schwert, g.w., (1977). asset returns and inflation. journal of financial economics, 1977, 5(2), 115-146. frenkel, j.a., & razin, a. (1986). the international transmission and effects of fiscal policies. american economic review, 76(2), 330-335. gale, william g., & orszag, p. r. (2003). the economic effects of long-term fiscal discipline. urban-brookings tax policy center discussion paper, no.8, april. gale, william g., & orszag, p. r. (2004). budget deficits, national saving, and interest rates. brookings papers on economic activity, no. 2, 101-187. geske, r., & roll, r. (1983). the fiscal and monetary linkage between stock returns and inflation. journal of finance 38(1), 1-33. granger, c.w.j., & newbold, p. (1974). spurious regressions in econometrics. journal of econometrics 2, 111-120. hakkio, craig s., & rush, m. (1991). co-integration: how short is the long run?. journal of international money and finance 10, 571-581. hamburger, m. j., & kochin, l. a. (1972). money and stock prices: the channels of influence. journal of finance 27(2), 231-249. volume 32, number 1 67 hoelscher, g.p. (1986). new evidence on deficits and interest rates. journal of money, credit & banking 18(1), 1-17. james, c., koreisha, s., & megan, p. (1985). a varma analysis of the causal relations among stock returns, real output, and nominal interest rates. journal of finance 40(5), 1375-1384. johansen, s. (1988). statistical analysis of co-integration vectors. journal of economic dynamics and control 12, 231-254. johansen, s. (1992). testing structural hypothesis in multivariate co-integration analysis of the ppp and the vip for u.k. journal of econometrics, 53, 211-244. johansen s. (1995). likelihood-based inference in co-integrated vector autoregressive models. oxford: oxford university press, 1995. johansen, s., & juselius, k. (1990). maximum likelihood estimation and inference on cointegration with applications to the demand for money. oxford bulletin of economics & statistics 52(2), 169-210. kwiatkowski, d., phillips, p.c.b., schmidt, p. & shin, y. (1992). testing the null hypothesis of stationarity against the alternative of a unit root. journal of econometrics 54, 159-178. laopodis, n. t. (2006). dynamic linkages among the stock market, inflation, monetary policy and real activity. financial review 41(4), 513-545. bong-soo, l. (1992). causal relations among stock returns, interest rates, inflation, and real activity. journal of finance 42(4), 1591-1603. lee, u. (1997). stock market and macroeconomic policies: new evidence from pacific basin countries. multinational finance journal 1(4), 273-289. lopez-villavicencio, a., & silva, j. (2010). employment protection and the non-linear relationship between the wage-productivity gap and unemployment, working paper cepn-cnrs: university of paris nord. lütkepohl, h., saikkonen, p. & trenkler, c. (2001). maximum eigen value versus trace tests for the cointegrating rank of a var process. econometrics journal, 4, 287-310. mccarthy, j., najand, m., & seifert, b., (1990). empirical tests of the proxy hypothesis. financial review, 25, 251-264. mora, t., lopez-tamayo, j., & surinach, j. (2005). are wages and productivity converging simultaneously in euro-area countries?. applied economics, 37(17), 2001-2008. narayan, p., & smyth, r. (2009). the effect of inflation and real wages on productivity: new evidence from a panel of g-7 countries. applied economics, 41(10), 1285-1291. 68 journal of business strategies ng, s., & perron, p. (2001). lag length selection and the construction of unit root tests with good size and power. econometrica (6), 1519. park, s. (1997). rationality of negative stock-price responses to strong economic activity. financial analysts journal 53(5), 52-56. patelis, a.d. (1997). stock return predictability and the role of monetary policy. journal of finance 52(5), 1951-1972. phillips, p.b., (1986). understanding spurious regressions in econometrics. journal of econometrics, 33, 311-340. quayes, s. (2010). does budget deficit lower equity prices in usa?, economic letters, 107(2), 155-157. rashed, j.a., & samanta, s.k. (2005). the productivity-wage gap and the recent stock price increase: an analysis. international review of economics and finance 14, 169-180. rogalski, r., & vinso, j. (1977). stock returns, money supply and the direction of causality. journal of finance 32(4), 1017-1-30. rozeff, m.s. (1974). money and stock prices. journal of financial economics, 1, 243-302. saleem, f., yasir, m., shehzad, f., ahmed, k., & sehrish, s. (2012). budget deficit and stock prices: evidence from pakistan and india. interdisciplinary journal of contemporary research in business, 4(5), 176-185. sidhu, h. (2010). productivity led wage disparity in the indian industry. indian journal of industrial relations, 45(3), 350-366. tang, c. f. (2012). the non-monotonic effect of real wages on labor productivity: new evidence from the manufacturing sector in malaysia. international journal of social economics, 39 (6), 391-399. verbic, m., & kuzmin, f. (2009). coefficient of structural concordance and an example of its application: labor productivity and wages in slovenia. panoeconomicus, 56(2), 227-240. volume 32, number 1 69 brief biographical sketch of authors dr. matiur rahman is the jp morgan chase endowed professor of finance at mcneese state university. he earned his ph.d in economics from southern methodist university. he is a very prolific researcher in macroeconomics, finance and international business. he has published very extensively in wellregarded refereed academic journals in the usa and abroad. dr. muhammad mustafa is a professor of economics at south carolina state university. he is an avid researcher who has published numerous economics and finance articles in refereed us and foreign journals. his specialization is macroeconomics and applied econometrics. appendix figure 1 bdg = budget deficit/real gdp; pcp = compensation/productivity; sp5 = log of sp 500 volume 34, number 57 conventional mortgage interest rate and the effective federal funds rate pass-through natalie hegwood sam houston state university • huntsville, texas m.h. tuttle sam houston state university • huntsville, texas abstract this paper examines the response of the conventional thirty-year mortgage interest rate to changes in the effective federal funds rate. the results indicate complete pass-through; in the long run, the conventional mortgage interest rate responds in a one-to-one manner with the effective federal funds rate. further, results suggest the conventional mortgage interest rate responds symmetrically to changes in the effective federal funds rate in the long run. in the short run, large, frequent increases in the effective federal funds rate create larger increases in the mortgage interest rate relative to periods where the federal funds rate is rising slowly or falling. our results suggest a long-run mortgage interest rate adjustment halflife of approximately twenty months in response to an effective federal funds rate change. jel codes: c22, e43 key words: thirty-year conventional mortgage interest rate, effective federal funds rate, asymmetric adjustment, pass-through introduction given the recent volatility in housing markets, understanding the impact that federal reserve policy has on the mortgage interest rate is vital. changes in monetary policy through effective federal funds rate changes affect market rates of interest. previous research notes the importance of understanding the magnitude and timing of this effect. sellon (2002) notes that the degree of interest rate passthrough and speed of adjustment are critical to understanding the effectiveness of the monetary transmission mechanism and of monetary policy. this study contributes to the literature by examining both the long-run and short-run dynamic relationships between the conventional thirty-year mortgage interest rate and the effective federal funds rate using three threshold auto-regressive models that are common in the current literature. 58 journal of business strategies literature review two critical issues arise when considering the impact of changes in the effective federal funds rate on other credit market rates. first, one must consider the degree to which a given change in the effective federal funds rate passes through to, or changes, the conventional thirty-year mortgage interest rate in the long run. more specifically, long-run pass-through measures the magnitude of the change in the mortgage interest rate in the long run from a change in the effective federal funds rate. in the long run, the mortgage interest rate will change, moving the rate towards its long-run equilibrium value. the long-run adjustment of the mortgage interest rate to equilibrium takes place over several months. therefore, one must consider the short-run, transitory effect of changes in the effective federal funds rate on the mortgage interest rate. these short-run changes include the immediate impact of changes in the federal funds rate on the mortgage interest rate and the mortgage interest rate’s speed of adjustment, or how quickly the mortgage interest rate moves to its long-run equilibrium value. the degree of pass-through between the effective federal funds rate to the conventional thirty-year fixed mortgage interest rate has become a popular way to assess the effectiveness of monetary policy. pass-through is traditionally examined by testing for cointegration between the two interest rates. finding that these two series are cointegrated suggests that they share a long-run equilibrium relationship. traditionally, research supports cointegration between these two interest rates, meaning that these two interest rates move together in the long run. further, the cointegration results provide the degree of long-run pass-through. granger and newbold (1974) note, however, that ordinary least squares regression (ols) may lead to spurious results when using time-series data. in the interest rate pass-through literature, the engle-granger (1987) test is commonly used to overcome the problem of spurious regression. in the engle-granger (eg) test, one performs ols on the variables. the residuals are then subjected to a unit root test in which the null hypothesis is no cointegration and the alternative is cointegration. if one rejects the null hypothesis, then the coefficient on the regressor is an estimate of the degree of pass-through. the cointegration literature notes, however, that the eg method may lead to biased parameter estimates, and in the context of interest rates, biased measures of pass-through. banerjee et al. (1993) show that the eg method omits short-run dynamics, and it is the omission of these dynamics that potentially leads to biased results. the current literature reaches mixed results concerning the degree of passvolume 34, number 59 through in the long run. payne (2006a, 2006b, and 2007) uses the eg method to test for cointegration and measure pass-through. payne (2006a) notes that switching costs and informational market asymmetries may lead to incomplete pass-through from the effective federal funds rate to the conventional thirty-year mortgage interest rate. payne (2006a) finds cointegration and incomplete pass-through for the period april 1971 through october 2005. in a later paper, payne (2006b) finds cointegration with incomplete pass-through using a shorter sample (february 1987 through january 1994), which corresponds to the duration of the specific monetary policy of federal funds rate targeting. in similar work, payne (2007) finds cointegration with incomplete pass-through in the adjustable mortgage interest rate. in contrast, citing the potential bias of the eg method in estimating the cointegrating coefficient, cook (2008) uses an approach by bardsen (1989) and finds complete pass-through from the effective federal funds rate to the conventional thirty-year fixed mortgage rate. hegwood and tuttle (2013) examine the effect of using the engle-granger method when estimating the long-run relationship between short-run interest rates and long-run interest rates on government debt for several countries. their results suggest that the engle-granger method potentially biases the long-run estimates by an average of 38.4 percent. in this research, we employ an alternate, yet common test for cointegration. using this common test, we find evidence of complete pass-through in the long run. this result suggests that mortgage lenders, on average, maintain a constant margin above the effect federal funds rate in the long run. in addition to the degree of pass-through, the short-run pattern of adjustment to the long run equilibrium is also of interest. multivariate tests of symmetric versus asymmetric long run adjustment take the form of threshold autoregressive (tar), where the threshold is set to zero and where the threshold is endogenously determined, or momentum-threshold autoregressive (mtar) models (enders and siklos, 2001). payne (2006a) uses an mtar model and finds long-run symmetric adjustment for the conventional thirty-year fixed mortgage rate. however, for the shorter period, payne (2006b) finds long-run asymmetric adjustment. in similar work, payne (2007) finds long-run asymmetric adjustment when examining the relationship between the effective federal funds rate and the adjustable mortgage rate. this research (payne 2006a, 2006b, and 2007), however, tests for long-run asymmetric adjustment only. the exclusion of short-run asymmetries may bias the long-run asymmetry results. in this research, we test for long-run and short-run asymmetric adjustment in both interest rates using all three threshold models. our findings show that the 60 journal of business strategies mortgage interest rate responds symmetrically to federal funds rate changes in the long run to changes, which supports payne’s findings (2006a and 2007). in the short run, however, the mortgage interest responds asymmetrically to federal funds rate changes when there are “large,” frequent increases in the federal funds rate over a relatively short period. data and unit root tests the monthly thirty-year conventional mortgage interest rate (mr) and the effective federal funds rate (eff) are available from the federal reserve bank of st. louis fred database. the range is april 1971 through february 2016. due to the time-series nature of the data, we test for nonstationarity using traditional unit root tests. as noted by granger and newbold (1974), if the two series are non-stationary and have a single unit root, then ols will lead to spurious results. table 1 reports the results from the augmented dickey-fuller (adf) test (dickey and fuller 1979) and the kwiatkowski, phillips, schmidt, and shin (kpss) test (kwiatkowsi et. al 1992).1 the preponderance of evidence from these unit root tests suggests that both series are non-stationary, i.e. i(1), which supports findings in previous research. the presence of a structural break, however, may lead to the rejection of the null hypothesis of nonstationarity. perron (1989) has shown that a series that is stationary around an occasionally shifting mean or trend will mimic the behavior of a random walk and lead to failure to reject a unit root. we therefore test the two interest rates for a unit root using perron-voglesang (1992) unit root tests that include a single shift of the mean. we employ both an additive outlier (ao) test with an instantaneous single mean shift and an innovational outlier (io) test in which the shift occurs over time. the ao test is a two-stage process, first running the following regression on each time series: the intercept break dummy variable, dut, equals 1 for all t greater than the break date, tb, and zero otherwise. the residuals, ut are saved and regressed against their lagged value and lagged differences in the second stage of the procedure as follows: 1 the null hypothesis under the adf test is non-stationarity of the series, while the null hypothesis under the kpss test is stationarity of the series. volume 34, number 61 the number of lagged differences, k, is determined by the max-to-min method, with kmax set at eight. the dummy variables d(tb)t-i equal 1 if t = tb +1 and zero otherwise. the two regressions are estimated sequentially for each possible break year, tb = k+2, … t-1 where t is the number of observations. the break date is chosen to minimize the t-statistic on ρ. the unit root null hypothesis is rejected if the minimum t-statistic on ρ is less than the appropriate critical value. as shown in table 1, we fail to reject the null hypothesis of a unit root for both the federal funds rate and the thirty-year conventional mortgage rate. critical values are taken from perron-vogelsang (1992). the io test involves running the following regression on each series: where du and d(tb) are the same as in the ao test. the max-to-min procedure is again used to choose the number of lagged differences, k. the break date, tb, is chosen to minimize the t-statistic on α. the results, shown in table 1, fail to reject the null hypothesis of a unit root based on critical values from perron-vogelsang (1992). we therefore conclude that both the effective federal funds rate and the conventional thirty-year mortgage rate are non-stationary processes, and that this result is robust to the addition of a potential structural change in the mean. therefore, cointegration tests are appropriate, because the use of ols leads to spurious results (granger and newbold 1974). 62 journal of business strategies table 1 unit root tests cointegration methods and results cointegration is tested between the two series, given that they both appear to be non-stationary. banerjee et al. (1993) show that omission of short-run dynamic elements in the engle-granger procedure may lead to biased estimates. for example, cook (2008) and hegwood and tuttle (2013) note that the size of the bias in the engle-granger method may be large and result in finding incomplete pass-through. further, the engle-granger procedure has also been shown to possess low power in the presence of asymmetric adjustment to the long run equilibrium (enders and siklos, 2001). this research uses the method of johansen (1991) to test for a long-run relationship between the two series. the pantula principle, as suggested by hjelm and johansson (2005), is used to identify the proper restrictions on deterministic components. these restrictions include the potential addition of a constant and/or time-trend in the long-run relationship. we start with the least restrictive model until cointegration is achieved. the results suggest the inclusion of an unrestricted constant only. therefore, the long-run and short-run relationships include a constant and exclude a time trend. the results of the johansen cointegration test are provided in panel a of table 2. we reject the null of zero cointegrating vectors and fail to reject the null volume 34, number 63 of at least one cointegrating vector. therefore, the result suggests the two series are cointegrated. from the johansen test, the long-run parameter on the effective federal funds rate, q1, suggests positive co-movement between the two interest rates, with a long-run parameter of 0.899; a one percentage point increase in the effective federal funds rate will results in a 0.899 percentage point increase in the conventional mortgage interest rate in the long run. table 2 cointegration test results as mentioned earlier, ambiguity exists concerning pass-through in previous research. payne’s results (2006a and 2006b) suggest incomplete pass-through. cook (2008), however, notes that the engle-granger method suffers from severe bias. when cook corrects for this bias, results yield complete pass-through. panel b of table 2 provides the results from testing the null hypothesis of complete pass-through (q1 = 1). in panel b, we fail to reject the null hypothesis of complete pass-through, which supports the finding of cook. if there is complete pass-through, then our results show that mortgage lenders attempt to maintain, on average, a constant margin of approximately 3.45 percentage points in the long run, given by the estimate of q2 in panel a. tests of asymmetry and results results in the previous section show that the conventional mortgage interest 64 journal of business strategies rate and the effective federal funds rate move together in the long run. further, we find that the mortgage interest rate moves in a one-to-one manner, given the failure to reject complete pass-through. these results, however, do not describe the mortgage interest rate’s speed of adjustment, nor do they provide the short-run, or immediate impact of the changes in the effective federal funds rate or the conventional mortgage interest rate. we utilize an error-correction model (ecm) to examine the dynamic behavior of these two interest rates. specifically, we employ threshold models to test for asymmetric long-run adjustment and asymmetric short-run adjustment in these two interest rates. previous research utilizes threshold models to test for long-run symmetry only (payne 2006a, 2006b, and 2007). to test for asymmetric responses, we employ two models: a threshold autoregressive (tar) model and a momentumthreshold autoregressive (mtar) model. equations (1a) and (1b) provide the general form of the error-correction models. (2) volume 34, number 65 in equations (1a) and (1b), it is the heaviside indicator, and its value is determined via the error-correction variable, εt-1.2 the parameters, d1,d2,b1, and b2 give the long-run, equilibrium adjustment of the conventional mortgage interest rate due to disequilibrium between these two interest rates. in a similar manner, the parameters μ and ω provide the long-run adjustment of the effective federal funds rate. equation (2) provides the derivation of the error-correction variable; it is derived from the long-run relationship estimated via the johansen cointegration test. when the error-correction variable equals zero, the mortgage interest rate is at its long-run equilibrium value determined by the cointegration vector estimated via the johansen test and provided in table 2. for example, from equation (2), a fall in the effective federal funds rate, during periods of expansionary monetary policy, increases the value of the error-correction variable and the size of the disequilibrium between the two interest rates. the heaviside indicator is greater than zero in the tar models when the error-correction term is positive (or greater than τ). during periods of contractionary monetary policy, the error-correction term is negative and the heaviside indicator is equal to zero. one must interpret the mtar results in a slightly different manner. in the mtar model, the change in the error-correction term determines the value of the heaviside indicator. when the mortgage interest rate is below equilibrium due to contractionary monetary policy, the error-correction term is negative and will increase in subsequent periods towards its equilibrium value of zero. therefore, the error-correction term increases in these periods and the heaviside indicator equals one. when the error-correction term and mortgage interest rate decrease during periods of expansionary monetary policy, the heaviside indicator equals zero. the value of the threshold, t, is set to zero to provide the first set of tar results in table 3. in the tar results in table 4 and mtar results in table 5, the value of t is determined endogenously using chan’s (1993) method, as described in enders and siklos (2001). in equations (1a) and (1b), we allow for potential short-run asymmetric adjustments through the interaction of the heaviside indicator with the lagged firstdifferences of the conventional mortgage interest rate and the effective federal funds rate. several investigations include potential short-run asymmetries, while others do not. for example, payne’s (2006a, 2006b, and 2007) study concerning u.s. mortgage 2 we use the long-run parameters estimated in table 2. we do not assume complete pass-through in subsequent results. 66 journal of business strategies interest rates and becker, osborn, and yildirim’s (2012) research on u.k. mortgage interest rates exclude these short-run interactions. valadkhani and anwar (2012), however, estimate potential short-run asymmetries in australia. the inclusion of these short-run interactions is a more general, less restrictive specification, as suggested by enders and siklos (2001). further, other research uses this method. for example, research investigating the co-movement of gasoline and oil prices uses this approach [see, for example, chen, finney, and lai (2005) or bumpass, ginn, and tuttle (2015)]. the primary coefficients of interest in equation (1a) are g and p. the coefficients g1, g2, and g3 measure the short-run response of the mortgage interest rate to changes in the effective federal funds rate when the error-correction variable is greater than t. the p coefficients, alternatively, measure the response of the mortgage interest rate to changes in the effective federal funds rate when the error-correction term is below the threshold. specifically, the test for short-run symmetry in the mortgage interest rate in response to changes in the effective federal funds rate is g=p. the coefficients b and a measure the short-run changes in the mortgage interest rate to lagged changes in the mortgage interest rate when the error-correction term is above the threshold and below the threshold, respectively. similar coefficients in the federal fund rate equation measure the response of the effective federal funds rate in the same manner. in table 3, the threshold parameter, t, is set to zero. therefore, the adjustment parameters, d1 and d2, yield the adjustment of the mortgage interest rate relative to the long-run equilibrium derived in table 2. for example, when εt-1 is greater than zero, the conventional mortgage interest rate is above its long-run value, given by q1efft-1+q2. the long-run adjustment parameters and the short-run response parameters provide the immediate adjustment of the mortgage interest rate and the federal funds rate when the mortgage interest rate is above or below equilibrium. in more general terms, starting at long-run equilibrium, the error-correction term is positive in periods where the effective federal funds rate is falling and it is negative in periods when the effective federal funds rate is increasing. the results in table 3 suggest that the conventional mortgage interest rate responds symmetrically to changes in the federal funds rate in the long run, given by the test of equality of the long-run adjustment parameters, d1 and d2. the estimated half-life of adjustment in the conventional mortgage interest rate in table 3 is between fifteen and twenty-four months.3 3 the half-life is an estimate of the number of months required to eliminate half of the long-run disequilibrium caused by changes in the federal funds rate. the half-life is calculated via t = (ln(0.5))/(ln(1+δi)). volume 34, number 67 given the results from estimating equation (1b), we fail to reject the strict exogeneity of the effective federal funds rate, i.e. we fail to reject the joint hypothesis that the long-run adjustment parameters and the short run mortgage interest rate parameters are statistically zero with an associated p-value of 0.602 (μ = ω = s = 0). therefore, the long-run equilibrium adjustment between these two rates is resolved solely through changes in the conventional mortgage rate in table 3. table 3 tar results, t = 0 as mentioned, previous research concerning u.s. mortgage interest rate asymmetries does not investigate potential short-run asymmetries in either interest rate. in this specification, the short-run response of the mortgage interest rate due to changes in itself and changes in the effective federal funds rate is asymmetric in table 3. specifically, we reject the null hypothesis that the short-run interactions are equal. the results indicate that the response of the mortgage interest rate to changes in the effective federal funds rate is larger when the mortgage interest rate is greater than its long-run equilibrium rate (sp< sg). in other words, the mortgage interest rate exhibits larger short-run changes when the effective federal funds rate is falling relative to periods when the federal funds rate is rising. the difference, however, is not large economically. the results in table 3 also suggest short-run asymmetric changes in the federal funds rate to lagged changes in itself, relative to the threshold. for example, the sum of the coefficients j1, j2, and j3 are statistically and economically larger than l1, l2, and l3. this means the effective federal funds rate exhibits a larger 68 journal of business strategies response to its own lagged changes in periods where the effective federal funds rate is falling. therefore, there are larger adjustments in the effective federal funds rate in periods where this rate is falling during periods of expansionary policy. in table 4, the threshold value is determined endogenously and, is therefore, less restrictive than the specification used to derive results in table 3. results, available upon request, yield a value of t equal to -1.39. combining the results from table 2, the derivation of t yields the following: the value of t indicates that the mortgage interest rate may respond differently during periods of aggressive contractionary policy, i.e. when the spread between the two interest rates given by the long-run relationship is, roughly, two percentage points or less due to large and/or frequent increases in the effective federal funds rate. from january 1990 through the end of the sample, the difference between the mortgage interest rate and the federal funds rate was less than two percent in sixty-nine of the three hundred fourteen months and occurs during periods of contractionary policy by the federal reserve. for example, during the two-year period from january 2006 through january 2008, the spread, or difference between the mortgage interest rate and the federal funds rate averaged 1.4 percentage points, and the spread was below 2.056 percent during the entire period. during these periods, the short-run response of the mortgage interest rate to changes in the federal funds rate may differ relative to other periods. the short-run response of the mortgage interest rate during these periods of aggressive contractionary policy is given by the p coefficients. the long-run adjustment results for the mortgage interest rate, in table 4, are statistically and economically similar to those of table 3. we fail to reject the null hypothesis of the long-run symmetric response of the mortgage interest rate. further, relative to table 3, there is less disparity between the two long-run adjustment parameters (d1 and d2) in the mortgage interest rate equation. the halflife of adjustment of the mortgage interest rate here is between nineteen and twentytwo months. volume 34, number 69 table 4 tar results, t = -1.39 the short-run adjustment in the mortgage interest rate to its own lagged changes in table 4 is also similar to those of table 3. the results show, however, larger short-run changes in the mortgage interest rate due to changes in the effective federal funds rate when t is less than -1.39, or when the spread between these two rates is around 2.056 or less. the short-run adjustment of the mortgage interest rate to lagged changes in the effective federal funds rate, when it is below the threshold, is larger relative to its above-threshold short-run adjustment. therefore, these results indicate an asymmetric short-run response of the mortgage interest rate during periods of aggressive contractionary monetary policy. again, we find strict exogeneity in the effective federal funds rate (p-value of 0.267). in addition, like the results in table 3, the effective federal funds rate responds asymmetrically to lagged changes in itself in the short run with larger shortrun changes when the federal funds rate is falling. this indicates that the federal reserve produced larger, more frequent reductions in the federal funds rate, relative to periods where the federal funds rate was increasing. finally, table 5 provides the results from the mtar model, which is similar to the method employed by payne (2006a). in the mtar model, the threshold is endogenously determined using lagged changes in the error-correction term. in other words, the adjustment process may be different for larger positive or negative changes in the error-correction term relative to smaller positive or negative changes. using the method of chan, our threshold value for t is -0.075. a change in 70 journal of business strategies the error-correction term, i.e. a change in the size of amount of disequilibrium, of less than -0.075 percentage points, holding the mortgage interest rate constant, may cause a different response in the mortgage interest rate relative to a change in the error-correction term that is greater than -0.075 percentage points. in the mtar results, the heaviside indicator equals one when the change in the error-correction term is positive. the change in the error-correction term is positive when the mortgage interest rate is increasing to restore long-run equilibrium. therefore, the g coefficients give the short-run change in the mortgage interest rate due to changes in the effective federal funds rate when the mortgage interest rate is increasing to restore long-run equilibrium. alternatively, the p coefficients provide the short-run change in the mortgage interest rate when this rate is decreasing. table 5 mtar results, t = -0.075 table 5 supports payne’s (2006a) long-run results. we find that the effective federal funds rate is strictly exogenous (p-value of 0.171), and the mortgage interest rate responds symmetrically in the long run. further, the sizes of the adjustment parameters for the mortgage interest rate are similar to those in table 3. we extend the work of payne by examining potential asymmetric short-run changes in the conventional mortgage interest rate. we find, in this specification, that the mortgage interest rate responds asymmetrically to changes in both interest rates in the short run. specifically, the mortgage interest rate exhibits faster shortrun changes in response to lagged changes in both interest rates when the mortgage interest rate is increasing to restore long-run equilibrium (when the lagged change volume 34, number 71 in the error-correction term is greater than -0.075)4. these results support those of table 4 and show that the mortgage interest rate experiences larger changes in the short run in periods where the mortgage interest rate is increasing due to contractionary monetary policy. the results for the effective federal funds rate in table 5 are similar to those in table 3 and table 4. again, we find strict exogeneity in the effective federal funds rate. further, the effective federal funds rate responds asymmetrically to its own lagged changes, as found in tables 3 and 4. summarizing the short-run results for the mortgage interest rate, we find a general asymmetric response. first, the mortgage interest rate responds asymmetrically to its own lagged changes. further, there is an asymmetric shortrun response of the mortgage interest rate to lagged changes in the federal funds rate. there are some similarities in results across these three tables. first, the shortrun response of the mortgage interest rate, during periods of expansionary policy (increases the error-correction term above the threshold value or the change in the error-correction term is negative), is similar in tables 3, 4, and 5. the difference between the results in these three tables occurs when the effective federal funds rate increases. in table 3, the sum of the p coefficients are statistically zero when the threshold equals zero. table 4’s results show, however, that the response of the mortgage interest rate to increases in the federal funds rate is identical to its response when the federal funds rate decreases, but only when the increases in the federal funds rate are “small,” well-dispersed increases. during periods of large and frequent increases in the federal funds rate due to contractionary policy, however, the size of the short-run changes in the mortgage interest rate increases. in table 5, the short-run change in the mortgage interest rate is larger in periods where the mortgage interest rate is increasing to restore long-run equilibrium. these results suggest that the mortgage interest rate closely follows the effective federal funds rate. in fact, the failure to reject complete pass-through suggests a one-to-one movement in the long run with an average spread of 3.45 percentage points, with the mortgage interest rate responding symmetrically in the long run. further, the mortgage interest rate displays short-run asymmetric adjustment to changes in the federal funds rate. less restrictive results in tables 4 and 5 show that the mortgage interest rate exhibits larger increases in the short run during periods of aggressive contractionary policy. 4 the sums of the two sets of short-run coefficients for the effective federal funds rate are statistically zero. the results, however, reject the null hypothesis that all short run coefficients for the effective federal funds rate are statistically zero. 72 journal of business strategies conclusion we reexamine the relationship between the conventional thirty-year mortgage interest rate and the effective federal funds rate. the johansen test suggests that the two interest rates are cointegrated. further, we fail to reject the null hypothesis of complete pass-through, and, therefore, conclude mortgage lenders appear to maintain a constant margin in the long run. like previous research, we fail to reject the null hypothesis of symmetric long-run adjustment in the mortgage interest rate in all specifications. further, we find the effective federal funds rate is strictly exogenous in all specifications. the results in all models indicate a short-run asymmetric response in the mortgage interest rate to changes in both interest rates. in the short run, results show larger changes in the mortgage interest in the short run during periods of contractionary monetary policy. in other words, long-run mortgage market imperfections, such as asymmetric information, may not be as great as that indicated in some of the previous research. this research demonstrates that potential market imperfections cited in previous literature appear temporary in nature. references banerjee, a., j. donaldo, j. galbraith, & d. hendry. (1993). “co-integration, errorcorrection, and the econometric analysis of nonstationary data.” advanced texts in econometrics. oxford university press, oxford, uk. bardsen, g. (1989). “estimation of long run coefficients in error correction models.” oxford bulletin of economics and statistics, 51, 345 – 350. becker, r., osborn, d., & yildirim, d. (2012). “a threshold cointegration analysis of interest rate pass-through to uk mortgage rates.” economics modelling, 29, 2504 – 2513. bumpass, d., ginn, v., & tuttle, m. (2015). “retail and wholesale gasoline price adjustments in response to oil price changes.” energy economics, 52, 49 – 54. chan, k. (1993). “consistency and limiting distribution of the least squares estimator of a threshold autoregressive model.” the annals of statistics, 21, 520 – 533. chen, l. m. finney and lai, k. (2005). “a threshold cointegration analysis of asymmetric price transmission from crude oil to gasoline prices.” economic letters, 89, 233 – 239. volume 34, number 73 cook, s. (2008). “econometric analysis of interest rate pass-through.” applied financial economics letters, 4, 249 – 251. dickey, d. and fuller, w.a. (1979). “distribution of the estimates for autoregressive time series with a unit root.” journal of the american statistical association, 74, 427 – 431. enders, w. and siklos, p. (2001). “cointegration and threshold adjustment.” journal of business and economic statistics, 19, 304 – 311. engle, r. and granger, c. (1987). “cointegration and error correction: representation, estimation, and testing.” econometrica, 55, 251 – 276. grange, c. and newbold, p. (1974). “spurious regressions in econometrics.” journal of econometrics, 2, 111 – 120. hegwood, n. and tuttle, m. (2013). “a comment on tests for asymmetric threshold cointegration with an application to the term structure: cointegration methods matter.” journal of economics, 39, 73 – 77. hjelm, g. and johansson, m. (2005). “a monte carlo study on the pitfalls in determining deterministic components in cointegration models.” journal of macroeconomics, 27, 691 – 703. johansen, s. (1991). “estimation and hypothesis testing of cointegrating vectors in gaussian vector autoregressive models.” econometrica, 59, 1551 – 1580. kwiatkowski, d., phillips, p., schmidt, p. & shin, y. (1992). “testing the null hypothesis of stationarity against the alternative of a unit root: how sure are we that economic time series have a unit root?” journal of econometrics, 54, 159 – 178. payne, j. (2006a). “the response of the conventional mortgage rate to the federal funds rate: symmetric or asymmetric adjustment?” applied financial economics letters, 2, 279 – 284. payne, j. (2006b). “more on the monetary transmission mechanism: mortgage rates and the federal funds rate.” journal of post keynesian economics, 29, 247 – 257. payne, j. (2007). “interest rate pass-through and asymmetries in adjustable rate mortgages.” applied financial economics, 17, 1369 – 1376. perron, pierre. (1989). “the great crash, the oil price shock, and the unit root hypothesis.” econometrica, 57, 1361 – 1401. perron, pierre, & vogelsang, timothy j. (1992). “nonstationarity and level shifts with an application to purchasing power parity.” journal of business and economic statistics, 10, 301 – 320. 74 journal of business strategies sellon, george. (2002). “the changing u.s. financial system: some implications for the monetary transmission mechanism.” federal reserve bank of kansas city economic review, 1st quarter, 5 – 35. valadkhani, a. and anwar, s. (2012). “interest rate pass through and the asymmetric relationship between the cash rate and the mortgage rate.” the economic record, 88, 341 – 350. biographical sketch of authors natalie hegwood is a clinical assistant professor at sam houston state university in the department of economics and international business. she received her ph.d. from the university of houston. her research interests include international monetary economics and applied time series econometrics. she has published articles in international journal of finance and economics, southern economic journal, midwestern business and economic review, the journal of economics, journal of macroeconomics, and economic analysis and policy. m. h. tuttle is an associate professor of economics in the department of economics and international business at sam houston state university. he earned his ph.d. from the university of tennessee. professor tuttle teaches macroeconomics, managerial economics, and statistics. he has published in several peer-reviewed journals including energy economics, defense and peace economics, southern economic journal, economic inquiry, and the journal of economics. the importance of strategy to global competitors: the strategy-performance relationship across cultures jeffrey p. katz department of management kansas state university manhattan, ks marilyn t. zaneski school of accounting university of central florida orlando, fl h.johnhall department of management university of florida gainesville, fl abstract this study examines the role national culture plays in the relationship between the competitive environment, firm strategies, andfirm peiformance by exteruling prior empirical work to the international marketplace. we firul that business strategies remain an important determinant offirm peiformance when considering the effects of national culture, competitive environment, arul irulustry in which firms compete. implications for global managers arulfuture research are discussed. background strategic management has a rich and multi-disciplinary literature regarding the contingency imposed by a firm's competitive environment on strategy choices. studies of the environment's effect on firm strategy and performance draw from organization theory and industrial organization economics (see for example; duncan, 1972; jauch, osborn & glueck, 1980; porter, 1980). contingency theorists believe firms compete in a multidimensional environment that affects the formulation and implementation of organizational strategies intended to achieve sustained competitive advantage (aldrich, 1979; mitroff & mohrman, 1987). according to contingency theory, firms learn to adapt to the opportunities and threats imposed by their external environment or become competitively disadvantaged and are forced to exit the marketplace (caves, gale & porter, 1974; andrews, fall 1997 katz, et al: the importance of strategy 127 1987). previous studies have reported that firms operate in multifaceted domestic environments affecting strategy (rockart, 1979; hambrick. 1983) and perfonnance (scherer, 1970) both separately and interactively. given the increasingly global nature of competition, it is surprising that relatively little research has considered the impact that national culture has on the environment-strategy-performance relationship of the firm. several studies suggest the importance of cultural values in explaining the differences in cross-national performance (hofstede, 1980; shane, 1993; tse, lee, vertinsky & wehrung, 1988). for example, one study examining national culture and performance finds that national culture explains more than half of the cross-national difference in growth patterns (franke, hofstede & bond, 1991). there are some indications that national culture may also impact firm strategies. for example, nakata and sivakumar (1996), in their review of the literature regarding the role of national culture on new product development, call for more empirical research examining the effects of national culture on business strategies. the authors cite the lack of adequate research to properly assess the role of culture on the environment-strategy-performance relationship. the present study, therefore, attempts to address this set of interrelated factors that potentially affect firm performance. specifically, we examine the role that national culture plays on the relationship between the firm's task environment, strategy, and performance by extending the work of mcarthur and nystrom (1991) into the international arena. by assessing the influence of national culture, while controlling for task environment, we find that certain firm strategies remain important detenninants of performance. the next section discusses the concepts of task environment, strategy, and national culture more fully, followed by commentaries on the research hypothesis, methodology, results and discussion. literature the task environment early work describing the relationship between the task environment and firm success (hofer, 1975) primarily focused on industry factors affecting the potential for sustaining sales growth. the task environment considered was industry munificence, i.e., the factors affecting growth rate of industries over time. aldrich (1979) expanded the description of the task environment by adding complexity and dynamism, thereby making the task environment construct tridimensional. environmental complexity describes the level ofuniformitylheterogeneity of firms within an industry while environmental dynamism addresses the variability of industry growth, that is, market instability. thus, the task environment forms the context in which competitive strategies are developed (hambrick & lei, 1985; lee, lee & ulgado, 1993). in the ground-breaking empirical study of task environments, dess and beard (1984) used standard industrial classifications (sic) as a basis for measuring the 128 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 three environmental dimensions. using objective measures, they found systematic differences in the relationship between how firm's allocate resources (strategies) and their task environments. for 52 sample industries, dess and beard provided factor scores and ranks on munificence, complexity, and dynamism, thereby developing objective measures of the components describing the task environment. by applying these objective measures of the competitive environment in the current study, we are able to control for the effects of the task environment on the strategies adopted by the firm. thus, all industries in our study were placed on a level field relative to any special factors that might make certain industries easier to compete in than others. the role of strategy within the confines imposed by the task environments, how a firm uses its resources reflects its approach to the marketplace and ultimately effects its financial performance (hambrick & lei, 1985; andrews, 1987). a strategy framework receiving considerable recent theoretical and empirical attention is the structurestrategy-performance model popularized by porter (1980). this framework proposes that the performance of a company depends on the strategies undertaken within a particular environment. extending the work of porter, mcarthur and nystrom (1991) examined the direct and moderator effects of the task environment on the strategy-performance relationship. they selected their sample of industries from dess and beard's (1984) study and found evidence that the task environment significantly interacts with strategies to affect performance. mcarthur and nystrom argued that the business environment modifies thefonn of the strategy-performance relationship. they recommended the use of all three task environment dimensions in future studies of strategy-performance and suggested that foreign competition may increase the importance of dynamism and complexity on the strategies and performance of the firm. prescott (1986), noting that specific firm performance measures tend to bias empirical results, recommended that future studies use multiple performance measures when examining the firm's strategy-performance relationship. national culture in the global marketplace, the strategy-performance link may be affected by national culture stemming from national factors that include the country's values, norms, and beliefs. hofstede (1980) defines culture as the collective mental programming of the people in a national context. through empirical study, hofstede developed a numeric classification scheme for national cultures. the four cultural dimensions that emerged from his study are individualism-collectivism, masculinity-femininity, power distance, and uncertainty avoidance. individualism refers to the tendency of people to look after themselves while collectivism is the belief in the importance of group decision-making. masculinity is the degree of traditional masculine values, such as assertiveness and matefall 1997 katz, et al: the importance of strategy 129 riality, while femininity emphasizes concern for others and for the quality of life. power distance is the level of acceptance by a society for the unequal distribution of power in organizations. finally, uncertainty avoidance is the extent to which people feel threatened by ambiguity in the workplace. more recent work proposes that national culture influences those areas where technical imperatives are weakest (hofstede, 1983). for example, a weak technical imperative would be the development and implementation of strategies used to accomplish the firm's profit goal. in this context, hofstede's theory of national culture predicts that culture will significantly affect business strategies as vehicles to achieve the profit goal. however, no research is known to have examined whether national culture interacts with business strategies or impacts the outcome of those strategies-firm performance. figure 1 conceptual factors affecting the strategy-performance relationship national cultural industry strategy firm factors • > factors·· > factors·· • > factors > performance economic values industry resource use profitability systems growth legal systems norms firm markets heterogeneity political beliefs market systems instability technology figure i depicts the relationship between national factors, culture, the task environment and strategies potentially affecting firm performance. it is in this context that global competitors attempt to use the resources at their disposal to develop sustainable competitive advantage. therefore, based on the previous, we propose the following hypothesis: hypothesis i: holding differences in national culture, industry, and task environment constant, firm strategies will significantly affect firm performance. methodology to test the research hypothesis, we designed a study measuring the effect of firm strategies on firm performance while holding the effects of culture, the task environment and industry constant. financial data reflecting performance and use of resources (strategies) on 286 international companies was collected from 130 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 compustat's global vantage data base over the 1988-1992 time period. data on the task environment and national culture was derived from dess and beard (1984) and hofstede (1980), respectively. the measures employed are more thoroughly discussed below, and are summarized in figure 2 comparing the concepts discussed in the literature review to the operationalized measures. the control factors used in this study consist of the four measures of national culture and three measures of the task environment. the independent variables of interest are five measures of firm strategies: inventory turnover, capital intensity, financial slack, research intensity and sales growth. the dependent variable employed is an index of firm financial performance. figure 2 operationalized factors affecting the strategy-performance relationship national culture·· • > indi viduali ty masculinity power distance uncertainty avoidance task environment· •• > munificence complexity dynamism firm strategies· ••••• > inventory turnover capital intensity financial slack research intensity sales growth financial performance roa roe roi control factors task environment. to control for the effects of the task environment, data was collected for all firms in each of the five highest and five lowest ranked industries on the munificence, dynamism, and complexity factors developed by dess and beard (1984). to find the relative five highest and five lowest industries, the standardized factor scores in the dess and beard study were rank ordered. the selected sample contains 286 firms representing 30 industries (five industries for each of the three high and low conditions). a validation of the dess and beard (1984) study was conducted by rasheed and prescott (1987), which provides some degree of assurance regarding the accuracy of the rankings used in the present study. national culture. the 286 firms in our sample represent 27 different countries. in order to assess the impact of national culture on business strategies and firm performance, measures capturing national culture were obtained from hofstede (1980). scores for the four cultural dimensions for each country are on a continuous scale ranging from 6 to 112. thus, culture on the national level and task environment on the industry level are assessed using measures independent of firm financial data collected through global vantage. fall 1997 katz, et al: the importance of strategy 131 strategy measures five strategy measures are used as independent variables. since we are interested in assessing the impact of resource use (strategies) on performance, three business strategies used by mcarthur and nystrom (1991) for which international data was available were replicated: inventory turnover, capital intensity, and financial slack. in addition, research intensity and sales growth were also employed to capture technology and market dominance (hambrick, 1983; shane, 1993). while these measures do not generally constitute a complete set of organizational strategies, they tend to provide a good sample ofthe strategies employed by firms in order to compete within industries (porter, 1985). in order to eliminate effects related to firm size, financial ratios were used. specifica1ly, inventory turnover is the ratio of sales to inventory; capital intensity is the ratio of assets to sales; financial slack is stockholders' equity as a percentage of total debt; research intensity is the ratio of sales to research and development expenses; and, sales growth is the annual change in gross sales. all ratios were averaged over the five year period to eliminate any potential effects attributed to cyclical variations due to macroeconomic factors such as exchange rate or regional recessions. dependent variable the measure of finn perfonnance used in this study is an index comprised of the three most commonly used ratios of financial perfonnance: return on equity (roe), return on investment (roi), and return on assets (roa). an index was formed by conducting a principal component factor analysis and then combining the variables into a single index using the respective factor loading score to weight the individual component. the factor weights were .77, .92 and .94 for roe, roi, and roa, respectively (see appendix 1 for the full factor analysis). an index ofperfonnance was used to lessen the impact of country-based financial reporting differences, since there is evidence that financial reporting varies from country to country due to the absence of unified international accounting standards (barrett, 1976; gray, shaw and mcsweeney, 1981; zarzeski, 1996). also, an index of perfonnance has been suggested to capture the multidimensional nature of finn perfonnance within industries (prescott, 1986; tosi & gomez-mejia, 1989). results table 1 reports the means, standard deviations and bivariate correlations for all measures employed. on a bivariate basis, firm performance is directly related to financial slack (r=.30, p<.oi), negatively related to research intensity (r=-.25, p<.ol) and positively related to sales growth (r=.26, p<.ol). inventory turnover and capital intensity are not found to be significantly related to firm financial performance. as expected, the measures of national culture, on a bivariate basis, are not statistically related to firm performance since the model in figure 2 anticipates table 1 means, standard deviation and correlations ...... vj t,j mn st 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 1 performance 12.2 26.8 \.00 2 turnover 7.5 5.3 -.01 \.00 3 capital intensity .42 .25 .08 .09* 1.00 4 financial slack .48 .22 .30** -.05 -.18* \.00 5 research .05 .05 -.25** .05 -.13* .26** \.00 6 sales growth 10.6 19.0 .26** -.04 .09* .18** .17** \.00 7 munificence high .37 .48 -.13* .14* -.27** .02 .35** .19** \.00 8 munificence low .25 .43 -.14** -.14* -.09* .13* .15** -.03 -.43** 1.00 9 dynamism high . 10 .30 .13* -.05 .27** -.13* -.25** -.01 -.25** -.19** ..... 0 ]0 dynamism low .10 .30 .09* -.07 -.11 * .06 -.21** -.11 * -.26** -.19** :;:: ::l ii complexity high .12 .30 .11 * .03 .06 -.14* -.16** -.07 -.38** -.21 ** l:l 12 complexity low .07 .25 .08 .07 .24** 0 -.18** -.05 -.20** -.15** -. 13 uncertainty 55.0 21.1 -.01 -.11 * .15** -.16** -.03 .01 -.06 -.02 ~ 14 power distance 43.2 11.7 .03 -.09* .09* -.09* -.04 -.01 .07 -.04 tx:l :;:: 15 masculinity 62.8 18.2 -.04 -.06 .06 -.04 .01 -.04 -.08 .04 .., 16 individuality 74.9 21.1 -.03 .09 -.17** .11 .09 .02 .04 .03 5' <1l..,.., mn st 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 v) i performance 12.2 ...... 26.8 ~ 2 turnover 7.5 5.3 ...... <1l 3 capital intensity .42 .25 ()q-. 4 financial slack .48 .22 <1l.., 5 research .05 .05 6 sales growth 10.6 19.0 7 munificence high .37 .48 8 munificence low .25 .43 9 dynamism high .10 .30 1.00 ~10 dynamism low .10 .30 -. ii * 1.00 11 complexity high .12 .30 -.12* -.13* 1.00 ...... 12 complexity low .07 .25 -.09* -.09* -.10* 1.00 ~ 13 uncertainty 55.0 21.1 -.06 -.10* .21 ** .08 1.00 z 14 power distance 43.2 11.7 -.09 -.08 .07 .05 .68** 1.00 ? 15 masculinity 62.8 ]8.2 -.07 -.05 .16** .03 .65** .24** 1.00 tv 16 individuality 74.9 21.1 .05 .11 * -.]8** -.09 -.61 ** -.72** -.60** 1.00 fall 1997 katz, et al: the importance of strategy 133 culture to affect finn strategies, rather than finn perfonnance, directly. table 1 provides some insight into significant bivariate relationships between national culture and finn strategies. specifically, uncertainty avoidance is negatively related to inventory turnover and financial slack while being positively related to capital intensity. this makes sense. in cultures where uncertainty avoidance is common, firms tend to have greater levels of organizational bureaucracy (hofstede, 1980) which would be characterized by higher levels of capital intensity and lower levels of inventory turnover. similarly, cultures that avoid ambiguity would tend to promote firms with relatively higher debt because bank relationships are more stable than are investor relationships resulting in lower levels of financial slack. similar to uncertainty avoidance, power distance is negatively related to inventory turnover and financial slack while being positively related to capital intensity. this appears reasonable because countries that attempt to avoid ambiguity are more likely to have higher levels of power distance between those in authority and the typical worker (hofstede, 1980). thus, high power distance countries will tend to have more secretive relationships with banks, thereby incurring lower financial slack. individualism is negatively related to capital intensity and positively related to financial slack. individualistic countries tend to foster higher growth rates among finns (hofstede, 1980), thereby encouraging high levels of sales relative to use of capital; this would result in lower levels of capital intensity. in cultures valuing individualism, such as the united states, finns having higher levels of financial slack would allow managers the opportunity to take quick action when market conditions provide opportunities (hitt & ireland, 1987). masculinity is not significantly related to any of the finn strat~gies. this is somewhat surprising but not inconsistent with the lack of significant masculinity relationships found in other disciplines' studies of culture (peterson, et ai., 1995; shane, 1993). research intensity and sales growth are not related to any of the cultural variables. this may occur because the income statement financial data comprising the two measures may simply fail to effectively capture strategic asset-related allocation decisions of the finn. table 2 reports the results of the regression analysis of finn strategy, culture and environment on finn financial perfonnance. three of the five strategy variables are significantly related to finn perfonnance. specifically, financial slack, a measure that compares stockholder equity to total debt, has a strong and positive effect on finn perfonnance (b=.42, p=.oool). research intensity, a measure of research expenditures to sales, is negatively related (b=-.24, p=.0003) to finn perfonnance. finally, sales growth, a measure of average sales increase over five years, is positively related (b=.27, p=.oooi) to finn perfonnance. contrary to the results reported by mcarthur and nystrom (1991), no interactions among the variables were found to be significant. 134 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 table 2 regression of strategy, environment, and national culture on performance variables b sebeta beta pvalue inventory turnover -.03 .27 -.006 .90 capital intensity -.07 6.87 -.0006 .99 slack 52.56 6.89 .42 .0001 research -126.51 34.32 -.24 .0003 sales growth .38 .07 .27 .0001 uncertainty -.10 .21 -.05 .63 power distance .35 .35 .09 .32 masculinity -.07 .21 -.03 .72 indivi duali ty -.06 .21 -.03 .79 constant -17.28 37.09 0 .64 adjusted r2 .33 f 5.91 pvalue .00001 discussion we began this study by seeking to examine the relationship between business strategies and performance in the global marketplace while taking into account other factors that have been suggested to affect the strategy-performance relationship. by hypothesizing that business strategies would be strong predictors of performance, we sought to assess the roles that national culture, competitive environment and industry effects play in firm performance. our study provides evidence that strategy is a dominant influence on the financial performance of international competitors. this has significant implications for global managers and academic researchers alike. managerial implications the results provide evidence that national culture does not systematically affect firm performance directly but operates through the effects of the task environment and business strategies. the implications of these finding for practicing managers are three fold. first, the findings confirm that national culture effects the firm's competitive environment as suggested by hofstede (1983). this gives global competitors the incentive to assess the impact of culture on the operating environment prior to competing in a particular foreign market. thus, managers from one country who attempt to manage in another country should be cognizant of the potential for different strategies across cultures. from our model of the factors impacting performance, it is evident that culture affects firm strategies through the competitive environment. for example, it has been reported that countries have different emfall 1997 katz. et ai: the importance of strategy 135 phases on financing sources and on government restrictions on businesses. in their recent study examining this issue, osland and cavusgil (1996) examined u.s.lchina joint venture performance. they found that the role of the government was a significant force on the resulting performance of joint ventures. it is, therefore, important for managers to assess the likely role of governments when evaluating the possible strategies for ventures in host countries. osland and cavusgil (1996) found that governments have both a constraining and enabling effect on the strategies and performance of international ventures. second, our findings provide evidence that cross-national competitors within industries effectively use certain strategies to achieve competitive advantage. specifically, financial slack is used as a very successful strategy in the global marketplace resulting in enhanced firm performance. that is, maintaining a certain level of unassigned assets allows the firm to capitalize on opportunities as they arise. this confirms the assertions by mitroff and mohrman (1987) that u.s. firms have the unfortunate habit of believing there is one best way to solve all problems by focusing on short-term performance without considering longer term implications. the common "fallacy of efficiency" that arises from the short term horizon of u.s. managers helps make this factor the most important determinant of success among the firms in our study. in addition, our findings suggest that the unfocused use of research and development resources results in reduced financial performance. this is consistent with the results reported by shane (1993) where national cultural characteristics were found to significantly effect the rates of innovation. thus, the most effective business strategies that managers should consider involve increased financial slack, focused research and development funding, and enhanced market share (sales growth). this is consistent with business strategies profiles of many successful japanese competitors (kono, 1984; porter, 1990). finally, in the broader contex.t it is important to extend our findings to other models of national culture. recent work studying the differences between the cultures of countries found that countries tend to cluster together based on their similarities of workplace factors (ronen & shenkar, 1985). thus, in countries that are clustered together it is more likely that managers will be able to develop successful strategies without significant assessment of the impact of culture on the competitive environment of the host country. in their recent study on the influence of national culture on the strategy of international acquisitions, calori. lubatkin and very (1994) found that firms are influenced by their national heritage when acquiring firms in other countries. their study gives strong support to our belief that being cognizant of national culture allows firms to more easily compete in culturally similar countries because the view of competitive strategies will be more consistent than in countries where the firms are culturally dissimilar. research issues there are a number of issues for future international strategy research. in this study, we found the mediating role of the competitive environment on the 136 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 strategy-performance relationship reported by mcarthur and nystrom (1991) to not be evident when the effects of the environment and industry were controlled. these findings provide a useful departure for future inquiry into the interaction of culture, environment, strategy and performance. since the present study examined primarily single business firms by controlling at the four digit sic level, there is still information needed about the resource decisions of firms that operate in multiple markets, that is, di versified firms. further investigation into the role that culture has on corporate level strategy and resulting performance of the firm is suggested (also see calori et ai., 1994). specifically, questions that still need to be answered include: what role does national culture play in the firm's decision to diversify or integrate and what are the interactive effects of culture on the strategy-performance relationship of the firm? and, are corporate diversification strategies and business strategies consistent patterns for successful firms cross-nationally or does national culture impact the manner in which corporate diversification strategy is implemented? thus, our study of business strategies at the basic level can be expanded to broader corporate strategies, e.g., diversification and integration. a look at broader strategies appears warranted in the international arena where firms function in multiple markets. in addition, future research should begin to focus on the effects of task environment and firm strategy onfinancial market measures of performance, rather than on traditional accounting-based measures of performance. because the overall goal of a corporation is to improve shareholder wealth, market measures capturing this are a logical next step. limitations in some ways, the present study raises as many questions as it seems to answer. for example, why were the moderator effects of the environment reported by mcarthur and nystrom (1991) not found in the present study? one explanation could be that the dichotomous measures used as control variables for the three components of the competitive environment were not fined-grained enough to detect the moderator effect. yet, perhaps the answer lies in the broad-based approach of the present study that considered factors underlying the environmental measures, thereby allowing business strategies to explain the maximum amount of variance in performance. another unresolved question addresses why inventory turnover and capital intensity were not found to be significant predictors of performance as reported by mcarthur and nystrom (1991). perhaps these two business strategies do not vary significantly for the size of firms examined. the firms contained in the present study tended to be very large manufacturing firms that aggressively compete globally. according to scherer (1970), firm size has the effect of reducing the variance in firm approaches (strategies) employed in the marketplace. thus we would expect, for example, the variation in capital intensity of global machine tool firms to be fairly similar. fall 1997 katz, et al: the importance of strategy 137 there is one major limitation of this study. we examined only thirty industries because our research design required a dichotomization of the three task environments: munificence, complexity, and dynamism. we examined only the high and low conditions for each environment in order to determine whether the task environment as an effect on finn performance across companies internationally. this design was necessary, due to the numerous interactions expected across the variables of interest. we believe the limitation is a reasonable trade-off for the information obtained. conclusion this present study is meant to be an investigation of the importance of business strategy on firm performance when simultaneously considering the effects of national culture and competitive environment. we found that three business strategies made a significant difference in firm performance. this gives managers the added emphasis to pay close attention when setting strategic targets, especially when considering financial slack, allocating research funds, and setting market share targets. it is these strategies that were found to be strong determinants of enhanced performance within the firms' competitive markets. given the results of our study, global managers should: (l) seek to enhance the levels of financial slack in their firms to allow adequate resources for capitalizing on opportunities as they arise, (2) use resources for research and development sparingly and only when directed toward market share enhancement, and (3) assess the underlying national culture for each country in which they wish to compete to ensure a thorough understanding of the potential impact of the government and behavior of potential venture partners. it is our hope that future research will provide additional pieces to the cross-national strategy-performance puzzle. references aldrich, h. (1979). orianjzatjons and environments. englewood cliffs, nj: prentice-hall. andrews, k. (1987). the concept of corporate strategy. homewood, il: irwin publishing. barrett, m. e. (1976). financial reporting practices: disclosure and comprehensiveness in an international setting. journal of accountini research. 14(1), 10-26. caves, r., gale, b., & porter, m. (1974). interfirm probability differences. journal of economic literature, 88, 181-192. calori, r., lubatkin, m. & very, p. (1994). control mechanisms in cross-border acquisitions: an international comparison. orianization studies. 15(3),361-379. 138 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 dess, g. & beard, d. (1984). dimensions of organizational task environments. administrative science quarterly, 29, 52-73. duncan, r. (1972). characteristics of organizational environments and perceived environmental uncertainty. administrative science quarterly, 17,313:327. franke, r., hofstede, g & bond, m. (1991). cultural roots of economic performance: a research note. strategic manajiement journal. 12, 165-173. gray, s., 1. shaw, and l. mcsweeney. (1981). accounting standards and multinational corporations. journal of international business studies. 12, 121-136. hambrick. d. (1983). high profit strategies in mature capital goods industries: a contingency approach. academy of manaeement journal. 26. 687-707. hambrick, d. & lei, d. (1985). toward an empirical prioritization of contingency variables for business strategy. academy of manaliemept journal. 28, 763-788. hitt, m. & ireland, r. (1987). building competitive strength in international markets.~ ranlie planning. 20(1), 115-122. hofer, c. (1975). toward a contingency theory of business strategy. academy of manaliement journal. 18, 784-810. hofstede, g. (1983). the cultural relativity of organizational practices and theories. imlr: nal of international business studies, fall, 75-89. hofstede, g. (1980). culture's consequences: international differences in work-related ~. beverly hills, ca: sage publications. jauch, l., qsborn, r. & glueck, w. (1980). short term financial success in large business organizations: the environment-strategy connection. strategic manaeement journal. 1,49-63. kono, t. (1984). strateliy and structure of japanese enterprise. new york: sharpe, inc. lee, m., lee, 1., ulgado, f. (1993). marketing strategies for mature products in a rapidly developing country: a contingency approach. international marketinli review. 10(5), 56-72. mcarthur, a. & nystrom, p. (1991). environmental dynamism, complexity and munificence as moderators of strategy-performance relationships. journal of business research. 23, 349-361. mitroff, i., & mohrman, s. (1987). the slack is gone: how the united states lost its competitive edge in the world economy. academy of management executive. 1(1), 6570. fall 1997 katz, et at: the importance of strategy 139 nakata, c. & sivakumar, k. (1996). national culture and new product development: an integrative review. journal of marketini. 60. 61-72. osland, g, & cavusgil, s. (1996). performance issues in u.s. china joint ventures. california manuement review. 38, 106-130. peterson, m. et at (1995). role conflict, ambiguity, and overload: a 21 nation study. academy of manaeement journal. 38(2), 429-452. porter, m. (1990). the competitive advantage of nations. harvard business review. 73, 73-95. porter, m, (1985). competitjve advantaie. new york: free press, porter, m. (1980). competitjve strateey. new york: free press. prescott, j. (1986). environments as moderators of the relationship between strategy and performance. academy of manaument journal. 29, 329-346. rasheed, a. & prescott, j. (1987). dimensions of organizational task environments: revisited. paper presented at the annual meeting of the academy of management, new orleans, la. rockart, j. (1979). chief executives define their own data needs. harvard business review. 57, 81-98. ronen, s. & shenkar, o. (1985). clustering countries on attitudinal dimensions: a review and synthesis. academy of manaiement journal. 10(3),435-454. scherer, f. (1970). industrial market structure and economic performance. chicago: rand mcnally college publishing. shane, s. (1993). cultural influences on national rates ofinnovation. journal of business venturini. 8(1), 59-73. tosi, h. & gomez-mejia, l. (1989). the decoupling of ceo pay and performance: an agency theory perspective. administrative science quarterly. 34, 169-189. tse, d., lee, k., vertinsky, 1. & wehrung, d. (1988). does culture matter? a cross-cultural study of executives' choice, decisiveness, and risk adjustment in international marketing. journal of marketine. 52, 81-95. zarzeski, m. (1996). spontaneous harmonization effects of culture and market forces on accounting disclosure practices, accountin~ horizons. 10(1), 18-37. 140 journal of business strategies appendix factor analysis of performance variables vol. 14, no.2 variable significance variance factor loading return on equity 2.34 return on investment .54 return on assets .12 finn performance = .77 (roe) + .92 (ron + .78 .18 .04 .94 (roa) .77721 .91989 .94391 dr. jeffrey p. katz is an assistant prl .ie department of management at kansas state university. he received his doctol ". philosophy in strategic management from the university of florida. his current research focuses on the strategic role of firm ownership and cross-national business strategies. his work appears in journals such as the academy of management journal, academy of management executi~, business horizons, human resource planning journal, and the journal of applied business re~ dr. marilyn t. zarzeski, ph.d., cpa, cfp is an assistant professor at the university of central florida. she was formerly associate professor at barry university in miami shores, florida. dr. zarzeski received her doctorate from the university of florida and has received two international accounting research paper awards. dr. h. john hall is director, undergraduate programs in the university of florida's college of business administration. he received his doctor of philosophy from the university of georgia. dr. hall's research focuses on the role decision making plays in the strategic behavior of firms. the importance of strategy to global competitors: the strategy-performance relationship across cultures consequence seriousness, gender, and intentions to blow the whistle on an unethical act tim wise southern arkansas university magnolia, ar tim barnett gene brown louisiana tech university ruston, la abstract in organizations, individuals are sometimes confronted with unethical behavior by subordinates, co-workers, or superiors. some might decide to "blow the whistle" and report the wrongdoing to appropriate authorities. numerous situational and individual-level factors are thoug ht to influence this decision. we examined a situational factor, consequence seriousness, and an individual-level factor, gender. we hypothesized that individuals would be more likely to form whistleblowing intentions when consequence seriousness was high. we also expected women to be more likely to fomz whistleblowing intentions than men. our results supported both hypotheses. individuals were more likely to form whistleblowing intentions when the consequences of the focal act were serious and women were more likely to state that they would blow the whistle than men. introduction sometimes individuals are confronted with wrongdoing in the organizations for which they work. in some cases, they may decide to report (blow the whistle on) the unethical act(s) to appropriate parties. whistleblowing has been formally defined as the disclosure by organization members of an employer's illegal, immoral, or illegitimate practices that are under the control of their employers to persons or organizations who may be able to affect action (near and miceli, 1985,4). numerous personal and situational factors are thought to influence an employee's decision whether to blow the whistle on unethical acts. for example, personality variables such as internal locus of control, religiosity, and high levels of moral development have been linked to whist1eblowing (barnett, bass, and brown, 1996; brabeck, 1984; trevino and youngblood, 1990). characteristics of spring 1997 wise, et at.: consequence seriousness 33 the situation, such as a supportive work group (trevino and victor, 1992; victor, trevino, and shapiro, 1991) and organizational norms encouraging whistleblowing (barnett, cochran, and taylor, 1993; keenan, 1990) also appear to influence employees' decisions whether to report wrongdoing. two other factors thought to influence whistle blowing decisions are (1) the seriousness of the consequences of the focal act and (2) the gender of the potential whistleblower. we suggest that individuals form stronger behavioral intentions to report wrongdoing when the consequences of the wrongdoing are serious. we also argue that women are more likely to form intentions to disclose wrongdoing than men. in this paper, we report the results of an empirical study to test the hypothesized relationships. first, however, we review relevant literature concerning consequence seriousness, gender, and whistleblowing. based on this review, we formalize our hypotheses regarding the study variables. literature review and hypotheses whistleblowing literature draws heavily from theories of bystander intervention, prosodal behavior, and ethical decision making (miceli and near, 1992). research has centered on the antecedents of whistleblowing by employees, as well as organizational responses (i.e., retaliation) to the whistleblower. our literature review focuses primarily on the two research variables of interest, consequence seriousness and gender, and their proposed relationship to whistleblowing decisions. seriousness of the focal act's consequences and whistleblowing prosocial behavior theory suggests that people are more likely to engage in helping behaviors when an observed incident has serious consequences (dozier and miceli, 1985; staub, 1978). for example, bystanders would be more likely to intervene to help seriously injured victims of a head-on collision than drivers involved in a fender-bender. of course, factors unique to individuals will also influence their decision whether or not to intervene. the tendency for individuals to react more strongly to events with serious consequences also applies to actions that pose moral or ethical dilemmas. according to jones (1991), seriousness of consequences is one component of what he terms the "moral intensity" of an ethical issue, which is defined as "the extent of issue-related moral imperative in a: situation" (p. 372). other components of moral intensity include social consensus, proximity, temporal immediacy, probability of effect, and concentration of effect. jones (1991) suggests that actions must reach a threshold level of moral intensity before individuals will recognize the moral content of the situation and engage in ethical decision making processes. all other characteristics of the situation being the same, actions with more serious consequences will have greater moral intensity. moral intensity 34 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 should affect individuals' ethical judgments about actions, as well as their behavioral intentions regarding the actions (jones, 1991). in an organizational context, consequence seriousness should impact employees' reactions to an unethical act (miceli and near, 1992). an employee might be more likely to conclude that an observed act with serious consequences requires a personal response of some kind (dozier and miceli, 1985). graham (1986) suggests that employees will be more likely to believe that blowing the whistle is justified when they perceive that the unethical act will have serious consequences for them, the organization, or society. empirical studies reveal that managers perceive whistleblowing as more acceptable when the wrongdoing in question is serious or has highly negative consequences (clinard, 1983). this may make retaliation against whistleblowers less likely in these situations (miceli and near, 1989; near and miceli, 1986). there is limited empirical evidence supporting the relationship between consequence seriousness and whistle blowing. miceli and near (1985) found that the seriousness of wrongdoing (defined as the level of financial loss) was associated with whistleblowing, particularly whistleblowing to parties outside the organization. another study found that whistleblowers were more willing to openly blow the whistle on unethical acts when the acts had serious financial consequences (miceli, roach, and near, 1988). however, fritzsche (1988) discovered no significant link between the seriousness of consequences and whistleblowing, and miceli, near, and schwenk (1991) found that illegal wrongdoing was no more likely to result in whistleblowing than less serious types of wrongdoing. as shown above, empirical studies regarding the relationship between consequence seriousness and whistleblowing have yielded somewhat inconsistent results. in addition, seriousness has generally been defined in terms of financial loss. seriousness of consequences in terms of environmental issues or health and safety issues has been largely unexamined (miceli and near, 1992). we suggest that, consistent with theories of prosocial behavior (dozier and miceli, 1985) and ethical decision making (jones, 1991) individuals are more likely to form behavioral intentions to blow the whistle on an organizational action when the action is perceived to have serious consequences. in the present study, we define consequence seriousness in terms of an environmental issue that has ramifications for the health of employees and the surrounding community. hypothesis 1: individuals will be more likely to form intentions to blow the whistle on a questionable organizational action when consequence seriousness is high. gender and whistleblowing near and miceli (1985) argue that whistleblowers are more likely to be men than women. they base this supposition on factors affecting the absolute number spring 1997 wise, et al.: consequence seriousness 35 of whistleblowers as well as factors affecting the likelihood of whistleblowing. first, although about 45 percent of all managerial employees are women, less than 5 percent of top executives are women (cascio, 1995). so, men often hold positions within companies where serious wrongdoing is likely to be observed (miceli and near, 1992). women may also have less information about how to report wrongdoing in their organizations (keenan, 1990). therefore, in terms of absolute numbers, it is logical to expect more men to blow the whistle on wrongdoing than women. miceli and near (1992) identify individual-level factors affecting the likelihood of men blowing the whistle. men may have higher levels of self-esteem and greater internal locus of control, which may make them more likely to report perceived wrongdoing (miceli and near, 1992; trevino and youngblood, 1990). in addition, women might be more sensitive to social influence opposing whistleblowing (miceli and near, 1992). a few empirical studies seem to support this position (miceli, dozier, and near, 1991; miceli and near, 19"88). miceli et al. (j 991) conducted an experimental study that held constant the observation of wrongdoing, the nature of the wrongdoing, and controlled for moral development and locus of control. they found that men were more likely to blow the whistle on wrongdoing. miceli and near (1992) suggest that the men and women in this study may have differed in their beliefs regarding the costs and benefits of whistleblowing. despite the above evidence, there are also good reasons to believe that if women have an equal opportunity to observe and evaluate wrongdoing, they will be more likely than men to blow the whistle. gender socialization theory suggests that women are socialized differently than men and that this leads to greater sensitivity about ethical issues (mason and mudrack, 1996). research concerning cognitive development suggests that women may reason differently about ethical issues than men and that women may have a greater ethic of caring (gilligan, 1982). although some empirical studies do not support gender differences on ethics issues «dubinsky & levy, 1985; hegarty and sims, 1978; mcnichols and zimmerer, 1985; sikula and costa, 1994; tsalikis & ortiz-buonafini, 1990), empirical research increasingly uncovers significant differences. harris and sutton (1995) found that female mba students were less tolerant of wrongdoing than their male counterparts. ameen, guffey, and mcmillan (1996) found that women were less accepting of academic dishonesty: two studies concluded that women responded "more ethically" when faced with marketing dilemmas (lane, 1995; malinowski and berger, 1996). in a study with direct implications for whistleblowing, jones and gautschi (1988) found that women were less likely to be loyal to their company when they perceived that it was acting unethically. several other studies have also found that women are less tolerant of perceived unethical behavior (beltramini, peterson, and kozmetsky, 1984; chonko and hunt, 1985; ferrell and skinner, 1988; ruegger and king, 1992; whipple and swords, 36 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 1992). we believe that differences in the way women and men evaluate ethical issues may cause women to form intentions to report wrongdoing. for example, several models of ethical decision making explicitly acknowledge that individuals must first recognize an ethical dilemma as such before they will engage in ethical decision making processes (jones, 1991; rest, 1986). specifically, only individuals who recognize ethical problems will evaluate them in an ethical context, and decide (1) if they have a responsibility to act in regard to the ethical dilemma, and (2) what action they should take. the above research suggests that women may have greater sensitivity to ethical issues than men. if this is the case, women should be more likely to judge issues in a moral context and more likely to conclude that they should take action in regard to the ethical issue. the relevance to potential whistleblowing situations seems clear. we believe that when women have an equal chance to become aware of and evaluate an action of questionable morality that they will be more sensitive to the ethical problem and form intentions to report the unethical act. therefore, we suggest the following research hypothesis: hypothesis 2: women will be more likely than men to form intentions to blow the whistle on a questionable organizational action. method subjects study subjects were drawn from university students at two southern universities. students enrolled in business classes were asked to participate in the study. a total of 128 students participated. seventy-three were female (57 percent). the average age of the students was about 25 years. almost 80 percent were white, with 15 percent black, and 5 percent members of other minority groups. approximately 90 percent of the subjects were juniors, seniors, or mba students. nearly three quarters of subjects (73.6 percent) were employed, with over a third (36.9 percent) categorizing themselves as full-time employees. vignette each participant in the study was presented with an ethical vignette. alexander and becker (1978) suggest that vignettes provide a concrete stimulus that allows study of attitudinal issues. vignettes make it possible for the researcher to vary the characteristics of a hypothetical situation, and observe the effects on individuals' attitudes and judgments. vignettes are widely used in ethics research (weber, 1990, 1992). the vignette concerned a production process for wheat flour in a milling company. the emission control equipment of the company was not handling the emissions of dust adequately. the management of the company decided to introspring 1997 wise, et at.: consequence seriousness 37 duce the new process on the third shift (10:00 p.m. to 6:00 a.m.). this made it less likely that the unhealthy emissions would be detected. each participant was placed in the role of franklin, a foreman on the third shift, who was aware of the excessive emissions from the process. this vignette was adapted from an earlier study by fritzsche and becker (1984). the full text of the vignette is shown in the appendix. independent variables consequence seriousness. the seriousness of the consequences of the milling process was varied within the text of the vignette. in the "low seriousness" version, the second paragraph of the vignette indicated that the dust emission posed no long-term health risk but was a minor irritant to individuals' throats and lungs. in the "high seriousness" version of the vignette, the second paragraph stated that the dust emission could cause serious lung disease and that it was a long-term health hazard. all other aspects of the scenario were identical for each of the two study groups. a pretest revealed significant differences in the perceived seriousness of consequences for the two versions of the vignette (p < .01). in the actual study, onehalf of the subjects were randomly assigned to each of the two versions of the scenario. as a manipulation check, each participant was asked to rate the seriousn~ss of consequences on a 9-point scale. subjects who read the "high seriousness" version of the scenario judged consequence seriousness to be significantly higher than those who read the "low seriousness" version (p < .0 i), indicating a successful manipulation of this variable. gender. the sex of subjects was assessed by self-report. males were categorized as "i;" females as "2." dependent variable the dependent variable in the study was "stated intentions to blow the whistle on the questionable organizational action." in this case, the action was using a milling process that produced emissions in excess of what company emission control equipment could handle. subjects were asked to indicate the probability that they would report the problem to appropriate agencies on a 4-item, 9-point semantic differential scale anchored by the following word pairs: (i) likelyunlikely, (2) probable-improbable, (3) possible-impossible, and (4) definitely would-definitely would not. coefficient alpha for the scale was .97. covariate as indicated earlier, numerous individual-level variables are thought to influence decisions to blow the whistle on unethical acts. one of the more commonly cited is locus of control, a measure of the amount of personal control a person feels over the things that affect their lives (rotter, 1966). internal locus of control has been linked theoretically and empirically to ethical decisions and 38 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 whistleblowing (trevino, 1986; trevino and youngblood, 1990). a measure of internal locus of control taken from a scale developed by levenson (1974) was included in the study as a covariate. the measure consisted of an 8-item, likerttype scale with responses ranging from "1 =completely disagree," to "9 = completely agree." sample items include "i can pretty much determine what will happen in my life," "my life is determined by my own actions," and "i am usually able to protect my interests." coefficient alpha for the internal locus of control scale was .63. analysis an analysis of covariance procedure with stated likelihood of blowing the whistle as the dependent variable, consequence seriousness and gender as grouping variables, and internal locus of control as a covariate was performed. this procedure allowed an examination of the joint and independent effects of consequence seriousness and gender, after the effects of the covariate had been considered. results table 1 shows the results of the analysis of covariance. the main effects were significant in predicting whistleblowing intentions (p < .0001). the interaction between consequence seriousness and gender was not a significant influence on intentions to blow the whistle. the covariate, internal locus of control, fell just short of significance at the .05 level. table 1 analysis of covariance results source of variation covariate locus of control main effects consequence seriousness gender interaction eta2 = .16 f statistic 3 .57 9.82 5.02 15.41 .06 significance level .06 .000 .027 .000 .81 table 2 shows the mean values for whistleblowing intentions by two categories of consequence seriousness (low and high) and for men and women. the spring 1997 wise, et at.: consequence seriousness 39 values of whistleblowing intentions ranged from 1 to 9, with numbers closer to 9 indicating a greater probability of reporting the emissions. the overall mean was 6.23, indicating that as a whole, the subjects were somewhat likely to state that they would report the emission problem to appropriate authorities. table 2 whistleblowing intentions by consequence seriousness and gender mean whistleblowing intentions consequence seriousness high (n=64) low (n=64) gender female (n=55) male (n=73) interactions low seriousness-male (n=26) high seriousness-male (,,=29) low seriousness-female (n=38) high seriousness-female (=35) * p < .005 ** p< .001 6.63* 5.84 6.89** 5.36 4.84 5.82 6.52 7.29 hypothesis i stated that individuals will be more likely to form intentions to blow the whistle when consequence seriousness is high. as table ii shows, the mean value for whistleblowing intentions was 6.63 when consequence seriousness was high, and 5.84 when consequence seriousness was low. this difference was statistically significant (p < .05), which supports hi. hypothesis 2 stated that women would be more likely to form whistleblowing intentions than men. women's mean for whistleblowing intentions was 6.89. the mean for men was 5.36. this difference was also statistically significant (p < .001). this provides support for h2. although the hypotheses for both consequence seriousness and gender were supported, a closer examination of the means in table 2 shows that gender appeared to be the more important factor in predicting whistleblowing intentions. the group most likely to form strong whistleblowing intentions was women assigned to the high seriousness condition (x =7.29). the group least likely to form whistleblowing intentions was men exposed to the low seriousness vignette (x = 4.84). women exposed to the low seriousness condition reported stronger 40 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 whistleblowing intentions (x = 6.52) than men who were assigned to the high seriousness treatment (x = 5.82). the results of the analysis of covariance provides support for both hypotheses. the gender effect was particularly strong. although internal locus of control was associated with stronger whistleblowing intentions, it was not a statistically significant predictor. discussion whistleblowing research has generally followed the person-situation interactionist perspective (trevino, 1986) that forms the basis for most empirical research in the field of business ethics (miceli and near, 1992). numerous individual-level and situational variables are thought to influence whistleblowing decisions. this study provides support for the effect of a situational factor, consequence seriousness, and an individual-level factor, gender. our finding concerning consequence seriousness is generally consistent with previous research (graham, 1986; miceli and near, 1985). consequence seriousness may affect whistleblowing through its impact on the moral intensity of the focal act (jones, 1991). when the consequences of a questionable organizational action are more serious, an individual might be more likely to engage in ethical decision making processes. serious consequences may cause the individual to (1) consider the action unethical, and (2) believe that it requires an appropriate response, which might include whistleblowing. jones (1991) suggests several other factors that affect the moral intensity of an action, including the probability of the consequences occurring, the proximity of victims, and the time lag between the action and the onset of consequences. each of these factors, and others, may affect individuals' reasoning regarding ethical issues. future research should continue to examine such variables' influence on ethical decision making in general and whistleblowing decisions in particular. perhaps the most interesting finding of our study was the effect of a respondent's gender on their intentions to report wrongdoing. previous research suggests that men are more often whistleblowers than women (miceli and near, 1992). our study finds that, given the same information about the action and about response alternatives, women were significantly more likely to form whistleblowing intentions. one possible reason we observed this effect could involve differences between men and women's approach to ethical issues. women may reason differently about ethical issues, and they may be more sensitive to perceived wrongdoing. women may be socialized differently (mason and mudrack, 1996) be more idealistic (forsyth, 1980), and have greater cognitive moral development or ethic of caring (gilligan, 1982). because of this, they may be more likely to report organizational wrongdoing with serious consequences. spring 1997 wise, et at.: consequence seriousness 41 earlier studies of whistleblowing have generally used financial loss as a barometer of the seriousness of the wrongdoing. our study used an environmental issue with health ramifications at the personal and community level. women may be more sensitive to environmental issues (miceli and near, 1992). the greater likelihood of whistleblowing observed in our study could be issue specific. future research should address this issue. in addition, our study had only one response alternative, either to report the wrongdoing to the appropriate parties or do nothing. male subjects might have considered alternatives other than whistleblowing. therefore, one should not conclude from our results that females were "more ethical," only that they were more likely to choose whistleblowing. our findings should be interpreted in light of the methodology employed. our subjects had an equal opportunity to evaluate the action. subjects were not vulnerable to retaliation for making the decision to blow the whistle as they might be in an actual organization. in addition, there was no possibility for confusion about how or to whom reports of wrongdoing should be made. whistleblowing research has generally utilized surveys of actual employees of the federal government. men in these surveys might have been in positions where they were more likely to observe wrongdoing. in addition, in actual workplace settings, female respondents might be less aware of available whistleblowing channels (keenan, 1990) and more fearful of organizational retaliation (miceli and near, 1992). our study was limited by its reliance on an ethical vignette and its use of students as subjects. ethical scenarios allow researchers to reflect real-world decision making situations, to emphasize issues of special interest to the researchers, and to control multiple variables in an experimental setting (cavanagh and fritzsche, 1985). however, responding to a question posed in a hypothetical scenario is certainly not equivalent to actual decision making, but reflects behavioral intentions, which are often, but not always, predictive of ethical/unethical behavior. since it is often not practical to study business ethics situations in the field, scenarios offer a means to test research hypotheses in a carefully controlled environment. in addition, some question the relevance of the business context to a student sample, because of the lack of familiarity that many students have with business settings (weber, 1992). to the degree that students cannot understand organizational realities used in scenarios, their responses may be quite different from subjects who are more familiar with business operations (weber, 1992). this limits the generalizability of research findings based on student samples. although we do not claim that our results are generalizable to the workplace, most of the students in our study were employed (73.6 percent), and almost all were business majors. they should therefore have some awareness of workplace realities. in addition, the scenario used was non-technical and the ethical dilemma was relatively straightforward. the manipulation check indicated that students were able to differentiate between the "high" and "low" seriousness treatments. 42 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 although we used a student sample and cannot necessarily generalize our findings to workplace settings, they are suggestive that employees will evaluate the seriousness ofthe consequences of an unethical act when deciding if and how to respond to the act. in addition, women might be more sensitive to an unethical action with serious consequences, and more likely to decide that they should report the wrongdoing. this is particularly relevant to u. s. companies in the 1990s, since almost half of the labor force is comprised of women. ethical behavior is of concern to both business practitioners and researchers. one of the more difficult issues faced by many employees is how to respond to the perceived unethical actions of their employer. our research suggests that both situational and individual-level factors are important in determining the individual's response to this dilemma. future research should continue to examine this and similar issues regarding whist1eblowing. references alexander, c.. and h.1. becker. "the use of vignettes in survey research." public opinion quarterly 42 (1978): 93-104. ameen, e.c., d.m. guffey, and j.j. mcmillan. "gender differences in determining the ethical sensitivity of future accounting professionals." journal of business ethics 15 (1996): 591-597. barnett, t., k. bass, and g. brown. "religiosity, ethical ideology, and intentions to report a peer's wrongdoing." journal of business ethics 15 (1996): 1161-1174. barnett, t., d.s. cochran, and g.s. taylor. "the internal disclosure policies of private sector employers: an initial look at their relationship to employee whistleblowing." journal of business ethics 12 (1993): 127-136. beltramini, r.f., r.a. peterson, and g. kozmetsky. "concerns of college students regarding business ethics." journal of business ethics 3 (1984): 195-200. brabeck, m.m. "ethical characteristics of whistleblowers." journal of research in personality 18 (1984): 41-53. cascio, w.f. managing human resources. 4th ed. new york: mcgraw-hili, 1995. cavanagh, s.1., and d.1. fritzsche. "using vignettes in business ethics research." in research in corporate social performance and policy. ed. l. preston. greenwich, ct: jai press, 7 (1985): 279-293. chonko, l.b., and s.d. hunt. "ethics and marketing management: an empirical examination." journal of business research 13 (1985): 339-359. spring 1997 wise, et at.: consequence seriousness 43 clinard, m.b. corporate ethics and crime: the role of middle management. beverly hills, ca: sage, 1983. dozier, j.b., and m.p. miceli. "potential predictors of whistle-blowing: a pro-social behavior perspective." academy of management review 10 (1985): 823-836. dubinsky, a.j., and m. levy. "ethics in retailing: perceptions of retail salespeople." journal of the academy of marketing science 13 (1985): 1-16. ferrell, o.c., and s.j. skinner. "ethical behavior and bureaucratic structure in marketing research organizations." journal of marketing research 25 (1988): 103-109. forsyth, d.r. "a taxonomy of ethical ideologies." journal of personality and social psychology 39 (1980): 175-184. fritzsche, dj. "an examination of marketing ethics: role of the decision maker, consequences of the decision, management position, and sex of the respondent." journal of macromarketing 8 (1988): 29-39. fritzsche, dj., and h. becker. "linking management behavior to ethical philosophy: an empirical investigation." academy of management journal 27 (1984): 166-175. gilligan, c. in a different voice. cambridge, ma: harvard university press, 1982. graham, j.w. "principled organization dissent: a theoretical essay." in research in organizational behavior, eds. l.l. cummings and b.m. staw. greenwich, ct: jai press, 8 (1986): 1-52. harris, j.r., and e.d. sutton. "unraveling the ethical decision-making process: clues from an empirical study comparing fortune 1000 executives and mba students." journal of business ethics 14 (1995): 805-817. hegarty, w.h., and h.p. sims, jr. "some determinants of unethical decision behavior: an experiment." journal of applied psychology 63 (1978): 451-457. jones, t. "ethical decision-making by individuals in organizations: an issue-contingent model." academy of management review 16 (1991): 366-395. jones, t.m., and f.h. gautschi iii. "will the ethics of business change? a survey of future executives." journal of business ethics 7 (1988): 231-248. keenan, j.p. "upper-level managers and whistle-blowing: determinants of perceptions of company encouragement and information about where to blow the whistle." journal of business and psychology 5 (1990): 223-235. lane, j.e. "ethics of business students: some marketing perspectives." journal of business ethics 14 (1995): 571-580. 44 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 levenson, h. "activism and powerful others: distinctions within the concept of an internal-external control." journal of personality assessment 38 (1974): 377-383. malinowski, c., and k.a. berger. "undergraduate student attitudes about hypothetical marketing dilemmas." journal of business ethics 15 (1996): 525-535. mason, s.e., and p.e. mudrack. "gender and ethical orientation: a test of gender and occupational socialization theories." journal of business ethics 15 (1996): 599-604. mcnichols, c.w., and t.w. zimmerer. "situational ethics: an empirical study of differentiators of student attitudes." journal of business ethics 4 (1985): 175-180. miceli, m.p., j.b. dozier, and j.p. near. "blowing the whistle on data-fudging: a controlled field experiment." journal of applied social psychology 21 (1991): 301-325. miceli, m.p., and j.p. near. "the incidence of wrongdoing, whistle-blowing, and retaliation: results of a natural occurring field experiment." employee responsibilities and rights journal 2 (1989): 91-108. -----. "individual and situational correlates of whistle-blowing." personnel psychology 41 (1988): 267-282. -----. "characteristics of organizational climate and perceived wrongdoing associated with whistle-blowing decisions." personnel psychology 48 (1985): 525543. -----. blowing the whistle: the organizational and legal implications for companies and employees. new york: lexington books, 1992. miceli, m.p., j.p. near, and c.r. schwenk. "who blows the whistle and why?" industrial and labor relations review 45 (1991): 113-130. miceli, m.p., b. roach, and j.p. near. "the motivations of anonymous whistleblowers: the case of federal employees." public personnel management 17 (1988): 281-296. near, j.p., and m.p. miceli. "organizational dissidence: the case of whistleblowing." journal of business ethics 4 (1985): 1-16. -----. "retaliation against whistle-blowers: predictors and effects." journal of applied psychology 17 (1986): 137-145. rest, l.r. moral development: advances in research and theory. new york: praeger, 1986. rotter. j.b. "generalized expectancies for internal vs. external control of reinforcement." psychological monographs. 80 (1966): 1-28. spring 1997 wise, et al.: consequence seriousness 45 ruegger, d., and e.w. king. "a study of the effect of age and gender upon student business ethics." journal of business ethics ii (1992): 179-186. sikula, a., and a.d. costa. "are women more ethical than men?" journal of business ethics 13 (1994): 859-871. staub, e. positive social behavior and morality: social and personal influences. new york: academic press, 1978. trevino, l.k. "ethical decision-making in organizations: a person-situation interactionist model" academy of management review 11 (1986): 601-617. trevino, l.k., and b. victor. "peer reporting and unethical behavior: a social context perspective." academy of management journal 35 (1992): 38-64. trevino, l.k., and s.a. youngblood. "bad apples in bad barrels: a causal analysis of ethical decision-making behavior." journal of applied psychology 75 (1990): 378-385. tsalikis, j., and m. ortiz-buonafini. "ethical belief differences of males and females." journal of business ethics 9 (1990): 509-517. victor, b., l.k. trevino, and d.l. shapiro. "peer reporting of unethical behavior: the influence of justice evaluation and social context factors." journal of business ethics 12 (1991): 253-263. weber, j. "scenarios in business ethics research: review, critical assessment, and recommendations." business ethics ouarterly 2 (1992): 137-160. -----,. "managers' moral reasoning: assessing their responses in three moral dilemmas." human relations 43 (1990): 687-702. whipple, t.w., and d.f. swords. "business ethics judgments: a cross-cultural comparison." journal of business ethics 11 (1992): 671-678. appendix ethical vignette* franklin works as a foreman for master millers. the company has developed a special milling process which yields a wheat flour that provides a higher uniform texture for bread than conventionally milled flour. unfortunately, the process gives off more dust that the emission control equipment of the company can handle effectively. the company is unable to install new emission control equipment for at least two years, due to the unavailability of a better system. if master millers waits that long to introduce the new milling process, competitors might beat it to the market. 46 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 (low seriousness version) the type of dust emitted by the milling process has been linked to minor irritations of the throat and lungs, but poses little long-term risk to the employees or surrounding community. (high seriousness version) the type of dust emitted by the milling process has been linked to serious lung disease, and poses a long-term threat to the health of the employees and the surrounding community. the general manager has introduced the new milling process during the third shift, which runs from 10 p.m. to 6 a.m. this is the shift on which franklin works. by using the process at this time, the new flour can be introduced and the excess emissions not detected. by the time demand becomes great enough to utilize a second shift, new emission control equipment should be available. question: if you were franklin, what is the likelihood that you would notify appropriate authorities about the excess emission of the dust? *vignette adapted from fritzsche & becker (1984) tim wise (d.b.a., louisiana tech university) is an assistant professor of management at southern arkansas university. he received his d.b.a. in management in 1995. his primary research interest is employee whistleblowing. tim barnett (d.b.a., mississippi state university, 1990) is associate professor of management at louisiana tech university. he has authored or co-authored more than twentyfive articles appearing in journals such as personnel psychology, the journal of business research, human relations, and the journal of business ethics, plus numerous proceedings papers. his current research interests include ethical decision making and ethical issues in human resource management. gene brown (ph.d., university of alabama) is professor of marketing and head, department of management and marketing at louisiana tech university. he received his ph.d. in 1988. he has published more than twenty-five articles in a variety of journals including the journal of marketing research, the journal of business research, the journal of business ethics, and the journal of the academy of marketing science, plus numerous proceedings papers. his research interests include personal selling, retailing, ethics, and methodology. consequence seriousness, gender, and intentions to blow the whistle on an unethical act tax considerations in investment strategies: evidence of functional fixation on asset depreciation richard l. ai/tizer emporia state university emporia, ks d. elaine sanders the university of texas san antonio san antonio, tx abstract tax planning strategies may encourage functional fixation on tax considerations in investment decisions. a desire to reduce income taxes payable may result in the irrational purchase of assets in order to keep depreciation on the income statement. in this case, fixation on tax, which is suggested by past literature involvingfunctionalfixation (haka, friedman, and jones, 1986), could lead to sub-optimal decision-making in settings where after-tax income maximization would be the appropriate response. a controlled experiment was peiformed using m.b.a. students from a southwestern university. the presence or absence of information encouraging the development ofa tax "frame" was the manipulated variable. the results support fixation on tax effects given a framing difference. in addition, a declining incidence of tax fixation was observed to correspond with years of business experience. introduction the usefulness of accounting and other types of data to decision-makers depends not only upon the quality ofthe information but also upon the care with which it is used (hopwood, 1974). among important types of data that decision-makers consider in investment decisions are those relating to tax considerations. while tax planning is an important component of decision making in a business environment, over-emphasizing tax considerations in an investment decision may be a danger, that is, to the degree that other relevant data are not considered or weighted normatively. considering the degree of importance of tax planning's influence on business and management, the effects of tax exposure on decision-making may be considered a prominent force in shaping the course of modem business. awareness ofthe influence of tax considerations on business decisions, though, raises questions regarding the factors that influence the decision-maker's strategies in weighing those factors. decision-makers developing fixed responses based on tax considerations could affect their decision-making judgments, resulting in increasingly costly mistakes as decisions of greater materiality are made (darrell, 1950). 2 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. the lure of a quick tax dollar is often the only justification for a transaction that might have been accomplished with much sounder economic results and equivalent tax savings if more careful and deliberate consideration had been given to the problem (988-989). an example of a fixed response based on tax considerations might include a businessman who purchases new equipment to replace fully depreciated, serviceable equipment. l the fact that depreciation expense is tax deductible may overshadow the fact that it is also a charge against income. consider the following numerical example: a businessperson currently owns a fully depreciated piece of equipment. the equipment is still serviceable and will remain so for the foreseeable future but has no salvage value. to avoid an increase in income taxes payable, this person is considering the purchase of a new asset to replace the old asset. the normative model for this decision would involve computing the net present value of the relevant differential costs in the decision. the investor will derive no benefit other than reduced income taxes from this asset. if the new asset costs $100,000, is a fiveyear macrs property, will have no salvage value, and the investor has a 40% tax rate and 16% cost of capital, then the net present value of the proposed investment would be <$72,989>. the computations are contained in exhibit 1. the cost of the investment far outweighs the benefit in tax savings that will be obtained, and the normative decision would be to retain the old equipment. jones (1997) states that "tax deductions are a by-product of economic costs" which may be lost if the taxpayer eliminates (or reduces) the cost. jones stresses that taxpayers should focus on controlling costs and not on the potential loss of tax benefits. considering the possibility of sub-optimal decision processes, the potential cost to society of fixation on tax considerations becomes high. a pattern of inferior decisions in busi!1ess could result in the misallocation and, ultimately, the waste of relatively scarce resources (darrell, 1950). the purpose of this research is to discern whether tax fixedness inhibits individual optimal decision-making processes. this issue will be addressed in the following sections. the next section contains the theoretical back-ground including the functional fixation and prospect theory literatures and the hypothesis. the third and fourth sections present the methodology employed in the experiment and the analyses and results. conclusions and plans for future research are presented in the final section. en exhibit 1 "0 :j. ::l 0cl net present value analysis ...... \0 time 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 \0 -......l cash flows ini tial cost of new asset ($100,000) ~---. depreciation n~ tax shield .... r<> (40% tax rate) ~ .20 $8,000* ;::s .32 $12,800 i::l... 'il .192 $7,680 ~'. .1152 $4,608 ~ .1152 $4,608 ~ ('j .0576 $2,304 ~;::s '" total cash flows ($100,000) $8,000 $12,800 $7,680 $4,608 $ 4,608 $2,304 c.: ~ ~...... pvif x 1.000 x.862 x.743 x.641 x.552 x.476 x.410 -.~ ;::s '"present value of cash flows ($100,000) $6,896 $9,510 $ 4,923 $2,544 $2,193 $945 net present value ($ 72,989) *.40($100,000 x .20) = $8,000 w 4 journal of business strategies theoretical background vol. 14, no. 1 functional fixation strictly defined, functional fixation refers to the possible effects of repeated uses of data for a given purpose, followed by inhibition of the ability to adapt the data to other uses (ashton, 1976). kagan and havemann (1976) also suggest that functional fixation is the tendency to make a given response to a given stimulus, as adapted to the function of an object. further, weisberg and alba (1981) argue that the function an object serves is a limitation that we impose upon ourselves. a simple example of functional fixation can be found when duncker (1945) challenged subjects with a well-defined problem: attach three small candles to the walj.2 to accomplish this task, the subjects were given three small boxes, some tacks, a few matches, and three candles. in the fixation condition, the three small boxes held the candles, tacks, and matches. in the non-fixation condition, the items were simply scattered on a table top. when the items were held within the boxes, the boxes were designated as "containers" and the subjects were hesitant to use them as part of the experimental tools. when the items were scattered around, subjects much more quickly incorporated the boxes into their decision scheme by attaching the boxes (upside down) onto the wall with the thumbtacks and setting the candles on top. by the same token, an individual who repeatedly uses earnings data for current valuation purposes might have trouble adapting the data to alternative uses, such as predicting future earnings, or a person who must continually strive to reduce income taxes may have trouble seeing an investment as an income increasing activity. evidence of functional fixation has also been documented in accounting contexts. ashton (1976) and swieringa, dyckman, and hoskin (1979) find that individuals who are fixated on accounting numbers are unable to change their use of that data when accounting changes occurred. abdel-khalik and keller (1979) test and find evidence of functional fixation in investment decisions using fifo and lifo changes. haka, et al. (1986) hypothesize that repeated exposure to cost measures might inhibit optimal decision responses by encouraging over-emphasis on cost data when market value data would be more relevant to the decision. the researchers note: fixation on cost and income data may leave individuals without the ability to discriminate, unaware of the appropriate contexts for the use of those data. that is, correct usage of market value data may become difficult for persons continually exposed to a variety of institutions demanding cost data (457). chang and birnberg (1977) note that the issue of functional fixation is "whether the user exhibits a tendency to make a habitual response and, if so, whether he persists when he is informed of a change in the data inputs" (301). spring 1997 allitzer & sanders: tax considerations 5 further, chang and birnberg suggest two important issues involving accounting research and functional fixation: how past experience affects behavior and how to extinguish older, unnecessary patterns of behavior. the present study concerns itself with the former issue. to strengthen construct validity, this study examines the concept of tax fixedness at the expense of utility maximization in light of another area of relevant thought, prospect theory. prospect theory prospect theory focuses on why individuals might violate widely accepted standards of rational choice. tversky and kahneman (1981) suggest that rational decision-making behavior involves consistency and requires that "preferences or utilities for particular outcomes should be predictive of the experiences of satisfaction or displeasure associated with their occurrence" (458). if this predictive nature of rationality is violated, sub-optimal consequences may result from lack of rationality in choices. the importance of prospect theory to this study lies in three areas. first is the notion of "decision frames," a term that tversky and kahneman use to describe an individual's perception of acts, outcomes, and contingencies associated with a particular choice. decision frames are "controlled partly by the norms, habits, and personal characteristics of the decision-maker" (453). in framing a decision, decision makers establish the perspective that they will take for that decision. the process offraming includes defining the problem and deciding what is important to solve it. as the boundaries of the frame are set, some information will be included while some will be omitted; therefore, once a decision has been framed, the decision maker is left with only a partial view of the problem (russo and schoemaker, 1989). consider again the candle-mounting experiment presented earlier. when the boxes are framed as containers, subjects have difficulty considering them as shelves. when the boxes are just items on the table, however, they do not enter the problem with a specific frame and are summarily incorporated into the solution. second is the magnitude of change observed in the outcome relative to the decision maker's reference point. the reference point is set by the decision maker's perception of the problem context, or decision frame. an important precept of prospect theory is that the value function is steeper for losses than for gains. that is, gains and losses of identical magnitude have different significance for people; the losses are considered more important. this makes intuitive sense from a functional perspective. a primary motive of virtually every organism is survival. hypersensitivity to threats, for example, losses, would serve that motive well (yates, 1990). finally, the result of the decision must be measured. an inappropriate decision that fulfills the needs of the decision maker's frame will not be viewed as a 6 journal of business strategies vol 14, no.1 decision failure by the decision maker. still, the long-term effects of the decision could be devastating. in the tax problem presented earlier, the decision maker can frame this problem in one of two ways: as a tax-reducing problem or as an income-increasing problem. if the decision is framed as a tax-reducing problem, the reference point will be set in reference to reducing tax dollars lost (the steep portion of the prospect curve). if the investment is made and income taxes payable decrease, the decision maker feels that the appropriate decision has been made. in accordance with prospect theory, however, the decision maker has actually made his or her decision based on partial information. the overall effect of the transaction on the well-being of the company has not been fully considered. the volume of tax strategy literature in contemporary business publications suggests that tax considerations will continue to play an important role in investment decisions for the foreseeable future. thus, it is in society's interest to maximize the effectiveness of the decision-making skills of individuals whose decisions are influenced by tax considerations. the emphasis in our society on cost and/or income could affect people's decision processes, resulting in a conditioning phenomenon ..... yet, social conventions, such as income taxes, which specify cost and income as crucial inputs, may cause people to react to this choice in unexpected ways. for example, if pervasiveness of cost data has changed simple decision-making behavior, one might observe a person choosing an item with a higher original cost even if it has a lower current value. if such behavior is widespread, there may be a high societal cost due to suboptimal decision-making behavior (haka, et ai., 1986, 456). the current research question is: does tax fixedness inhibit optimal decision-making processes in individuals? prospect theory is easily transferable into tax research. if decision-makers frame a potential investment as a tax-savings strategy rather than as an income-maximizing strategy, the result could lead to an irrational decision. conversely, if decision-makers are able to work with a potential investment choice without casting the problem into a taxation framework, they will make a more appropriate decision. given the literature regarding the effects of functional fixation and prospect theory, this study hypothesizes that (stated in the alternative): individual decision-makers will show a higher incidence of tax fixedness when an investment problem is framed as a tax problem than when it is not. spring 1997 allitzer & sanders: tax considerations methodology 7 experimental design to test the above hypothesis, the researchers designed and tested a role-playing case study. 3 subjects were cast into a scenario in which they assumed the role of a chemist with the opportunity of entering into a ten-year government contract. the only long-term asset the chemist would have to purchase would be an expensive delivery truck. 4 in the "no-frame" condition, subjects were shown the estimated income statements for the first five years of the project (the depreciable life of the delivery truck). subjects were then told that the budgeted income statements were an accurate reflection of actual business for the first five years. further, although they had experienced no major difficulties with the delivery truck, the manufacturer had now (at the end of the fifth year) developed a new and improved delivery truck. a measure of probability was then taken of the subject's willingness to consider the purchase of a new delivery truck at this time. the "tax-frame" condition simply extended the "no-frame" condition. after the subjects were told of the development of a new delivery truck by the manufacturer, they were presented with budgeted income statements for the remaining life of the contract. these income statements were prepared under the assumption that a new delivery truck would not be purchased, therefore depreciation expense ceased in the seventh year causing both income and income tax expense to increase. as in the "no frame" condition, a measure of probability was then taken of the subject's willingness to consider the purchase of a new delivery truck at this time.s the experimental design, then, is a between-subjects randomized control group/manipulation group design (exhibit 2). exhibit 2 experimental design experimental group control group information ----i..... additional -----i..... measure set information fixation information ------------1...... measure set fixation the actual frame used by the subjects for their final decision is an internal state and cannot be accurately measured. to reject the null hypothesis, however, subjects in the "tax frame" condition should fixate on the role of depreciation expense as a method to reduce the income tax liability and should state a higher 8 journal of business strategies vol 14, no.1 willingness to consider the purchase of a new delivery truck in order to keep depreciation on the income statement. in the "no frame" condition, the expiration of depreciation expense is not obvious, and the subjects should focus on the condition of the existing delivery truck and the increase in net income if a new delivery truck is not purchased. as a result, in the "no-frame" condition, the willingness to consider the purchase of a new delivery truck should be lower. sample m.b.a. students at a southwestern university volunteered to serve as subjects for the study. they had completed at least one semester of graduate-level financial accounting and were currently enrolled in a graduate-level management accounting course. graduate students were considered to be an appropriate and useful subject group for this particular study. the students had all been exposed to and tested over the quantitative and qualitative aspects of net present value analysis, the depreciation tax shield, and cash flows needed to complete the task as presented. procedure the experiment began with subjects completing a statement of informed consent. after these statements were completed and collected, the instruments were randomly distributed to the subjects. the instrument consisted of the basic story contained in the case, a cash flow task, the functional fixation task, and the exit questionnaire. subjects were given unlimited time to complete the instrument; however, the average time to complete was approximately 20 minutes. data analyses and results a total of 152 subjects participated in the study. information gathered on the exit questionnaire provided some demographic information about the subjects; 57% were male and 30% were international students.6 on average, the subjects had 1-5 years of actual business experience and 24% stated that they had occasionally or very often used income statement data in making business decisions. two subjects were dropped due to incomplete instruments. as a control measure for the contents of the scenario, subjects were asked to indicate whether the story suggested the need for a new delivery truck at the end of five years. in the scenario, subjects were told that no major problems had been encountered with the existing truck over the past five years. the purpose of this statement was to induce indifference between the two options. eight subjects answered "yes" when asked if the company needed a new truck. a "yes" answer was interpreted as indicating that the subjects read more into the scenario than was actually presented, thus biasing their responses. those eight subjects were subsequently dropped from the data set. spring 1997 allitzer & sanders: tax considerations 9 the remaining 142 data points were analyzed using a 1 x 2 anova with the stated probability of considering the purchase of a new delivery truck as the dependent measure and whether or not the subjects were encouraged to view the investment within a tax frame as the independent measure. the results of the analysis are presented in table 1. the results indicate a statistically significant effect (at a = .10) for tax frame on the probability of considering the purchase of a new delivery truck (f =3.31, p =0.0708). table 1 anova results for tax fixedness n mean sd no frame 71 42.66 34.01 tax frame 71 53.08 34.22 source df ss fvalue pr>f frame 1 3856.34 3.31 0.0708 (n = 142) subjects who were presented information more conducive to establishing a tax-frame for their decision stated a higher probability of considering the purchase of a new delivery truck than subjects who were presented with more openended information. a problem with using an income statement format in an experimental instrument is the fact that depreciation, income tax, and net income all vary directly in relation to one another. if the subjects equated net income with cash flow, their probabilities of considering a new delivery truck could be tied to the perception of increased cash rather than fixation on decreasing the tax liability. thus, all subjects were asked a cash flow assessment question in the experimental instrument: to state their probabilities that a cash withdrawal of $20,000 would be possible in each of the first five years. because net income was less than $20,000 for each of these years, subjects who equated cash flows with net income would state low probabilities for the desired withdrawal. on the other hand, actual cash flows were greater than $20,000 in each of the first five years. all subjects who stated a probability ofless than 50% on the question of cash withdrawals were dropped from the data set on the assumption that they did not consider the actual cash flows in their final decision. as a result, 62 subjects were dropped from the sample, and the 1 x 2 anova with the stated probability of considering the purchase of a new delivery truck as the dependent measure and 10 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 whether the subjects were encouraged to view the investment within a tax frame as the independent measure was again computed. the results of the analysis (table 2) indicate a statistically significant effect for tax frame (at a =.05) on the probability of considering the purchase of a new delivery truck (f = 4.31, p = 0.0413). table 2 anova results for tax fixedness n mean sd no frame 45 47.49 34.89 tax frame 35 63.46 33.14 source df s8 fvalue pr>f frame 1 5020.02 4.31 0.0413 (n =80) after controlling for knowledge of cash flows, subjects who were presented information more conducive to establishing a tax-frame for their decision still stated a higher probability of considering the purchase of a new delivery truck than subjects who were presented with more open-ended information. the implications of these results suggest that individual decision makers who frame investment questions with regard to the tax implications may favor investments that they see as tax reducers rather than as income maximizers. additional anovas were used to observe the effect of information gathered from the exit questionnaire on the dependent variable. the independent variables were gender, international status, years of business experience, and frequency of income statement use for decision-making. the only variable that produced a statistically significant result was years of business experience (f = 2.73, p = 0.0354). generally, the more years of experience the subject reported, the lower the probability of considering the purchase of a new truck. table 3 presents the means for the five levels of experience and the comparison of those means using tukey's studentized range test. spring 1997 allitzer & sanders: tax considerations table 3 means for years of business experience 11 n none 16 less than 1 year 5 1-5 years 25 5-10 years 19 more than 10 years 15 mean 63.13 72.80 59.96 54.00 30.60 group a a b a b a b b multiple comparisons using tukey's studentized range test. different letters signify statistically significant differences at p < .05. the data was tested again for interaction effects between years of experience and experimental condition. no interaction effects were found. main effects were then tested to ascertain whether the framing condition would still exhibit statistically significant differences after controlling for the effect of years of experience. the results are contained in table 4. after controlling for years of experience, the effect of the frame manipulation on the dependent variable remains statistically significant (f = 5.76, p = 0.0189). table 4 anova results for tax fixedness after controlling for years of business experience source experience frame df 4 i ss 13215.60 6052.78 fvalue 3.15 5.76 pr>f 0.0191 0.0189 while no hypothesis existed a priori to suggest a decline in functional fixation given years of business experience, it is interesting to note that this finding may be interpreted as paralleling haka, et. ai's (1986) results. in their study, they found age to be inversely related to fixation on selling prices. older subjects were less likely to fixate on selling prices than younger subjects. in the current study, subjects with more years of business experience were less likely to fixate on tax-reducing investments than were subjects with no business experience. conclusions the results obtained in this study suggest that individuals who fixate on the tax consequences of an investment decision are prone to make sub-optimal deci12 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. i sions. when information was provided to allow subjects to construct a tax-frame for considering an investment opportunity, those subjects found the opportunity much more appealing than did subjects who were presented open-ended information (no frame). additionally, years of business experience were found to relate inversely to the tendency to fixate on tax consequences. if years of business experience can be considered as a proxy for age, then this result supports the findings of haka, et al. (1986). while every effort was made to control internal and external variables that might have affected the results in this study, limitations do exist. in considering the purchase of the new truck, subjects were told that no major difficulties had been encountered with the existing truck to induce indifference between the two options. further, subjects were asked in the exit questionnaire to disclose whether they believed a new truck was needed at this time. the subjects answering "yes" were dropped from the statistical analyses. specific information about differences in the two trucks (potential cost reductions from lower fuel costs, lower repair costs, or lower maintenance costs) were not introduced into the scenario. a limitation of the study is the assumption that the two alternatives were equaliy weighted and that subjects were not considering other possible cost-related scenanos. a second potential limitation of the study is the use of m.b.a. students as subjects. ashton and kramer (1980) suggest that students are an appropriate surrogate for professional decision makers in decisions requiring judgment and decision-making skills with no particular disciplinary expertise. a priori, the current study fit this requirement. given the differences found among years of experience and probability of purchase, however, not using professional decision-makers may limit the ability to generalize the results. finaliy, the age of the references used in the study may be perceived as a limitation in this study, however, functional fixation in decisions of the nature presented here has not been a heavily researched topic in recent years. haka, et al. (1986) is the latest paper to actualiy approach the issue of functional fixation from the viewpoint of interest to the current study. as accountants, we should be keenly aware of the hazards of functional fixation on tax considerations. we should endeavor not to fall prey to this decision error as information providers [as would be dictated by interference theory (haka, et a1., 1986)], and we should be aware of the possibility of these fixating tendencies in our clients. by using normative decision-making procedures (e.g. emphasizing income increasing rather than income tax reducing strategies), we can present information in a manner conducive to optimal decision-making or help clients frame a decision to overcome decision problems like functional fixation. but to truly understand this problem, additional research must be conducted. while the inverse relationship between years of experience and functional fixation supports the results of past research, additional research will assist in spring 1997 allitzer & sanders: tax considerations 13 confirming those results. instruments could more carefully measure business experience and extract specific details of that experience. researchers could then verify the correlation between age and years of experience. in addition, further study should be conducted specifically in the tax arena on the issue of functional fixation and its relationship to both investment strategies and tax avoidance strategies. while the current study casts subjects into the role of an individual making a self-profiting decision, additional research might cast them into an advisory role (tax or financial advisor). differences may exist between the wayan individual frames a decision given their external orientation. also, the effects of interference theory could be tested. while haka, et al. (1986) found no evidence to support interference effects in their study, future research on tax issues could expand the search into the professional environment. one possible study would observe the fixation of students versus professionals. additionally, different levels of students and professionals could be tested (intermediate i students, tax ii students, tax accountants, and financial advisors). in summary, support for functional fixation on tax consequences has been found in the controlled laboratory experiment conducted for this study. the potential of casting a decision into a tax frame has been shown to relate to that fixation, although years of experience seem to mediate fixative effects. further research should be conducted to ascertain when and how fixation occurs. the results can help indiviual decision makers in overcoming this decision problem. notes 1. economically, if he spends a dollar to receive a dollar's worth of reduction (replacing the equipment so as to receive a depreciation deduction), he is better off only when the marginal tax rate exceeds 100 percent. 2. a thorough review of functional fixation can be found in baron (1988), pages 47 -51. 3. a synopsis of the experimental instrument follows in the appendix. 4. by entering into a government contract, we were able to suggest that all other costs and revenues would be constant over the life of the contract, thus eliminating conflicting issues that might have affected net income. 5. this task is analogous to a situation where a tax client's estimated tax liability suddenly increases due to the full-depreciation of assets. in this scenario, however, the client (subject) does not have an accountant telling him or her that the increase in taxes is directly correlated to the cessation of depreciation expense (which could enhance the fixation on the income tax effects of depreciation on the income statement). the omission of a detailed explanation of these effects, that is letting subjects frame the problem for themsel ves, biases against rejection of the null hypothesis and strengthens any statistically significant results that might be obtained. 6. although no theory could be found to support differences in levels of fixation between u.s. and non-u.s. decision makers, a suggestion was made to the authors that the individual and corporate income tax structures in place in other countries might be reflected in the completion of the task by international students. given this very 14 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 relevant comment, a measure was taken of the international status of the subjects as a possible control variable. references abdel-khalik, a.r., and t.f. keller. "earnings or cash flows: an experiment on functional fixation and the valuation of the firm." studies in accounting research #16. sarasota: american accounting association, 1979. ashton, r.h. "cognitive changes induced by accounting changes: experimental evidence on the functional fixation hypothesis." journal of accounting research (supplement 1976): 1-17. ashton, r., and s. kramer. "students as surrogates in behavioral research: some evidence." journal of accounting research 18 (1980): 1-13. baron, j. thinking and deciding. cambridge: cambridge university press, 1988. chang, d.l., and j.g. birnberg. "functional fixity in accounting research: perspective and new data." journal of accounting research (autumn 1977): 300-312. darrell, n. "some responsibilities of the tax adviser in regard to tax minimization devices." in proceedings of the new york university eighth annual institute on federal taxation. albany, ny: matthew, bender & co., 1950: 988-989. duncker, k. "on problem solving." psychological monographs 58 (whole no. 270), (1945). haka, s., l. friedman, and v. jones. "functional fixation and interference theory: a theoretical and empirical investigation." the accounting review (july 1986): 455-474. hopwood, a.g. "leadership climate and the use of accounting data in performance evaluation." the accounting review 49 (1974): 485-495. kagan, j. and e. havemann. £sychology: an introduction. new york: harcourt brace jovanovich, 1976. jones, s. federal taxes and management decisions. chicago: irwin, 1997. russo, j.e. and p.j.h. schoemaker. decision traps: the ten barriers to brilliant decision making and how to overcome them. new york: doubleday, 1989. swieringa, r.j., t.r. dyckman, and r.e. hoskin. "empirical evidence about the effects of an accounting change on information processing." in behavioral experiments in accounting ii, ed. t.h. bums. ohio state university, 1979: 225-59. spring 1997 allitzer & sanders: tax considerations 15 tversky, a., and d. kahneman. "the framing of decisions and the psychology of choice." science 211 (1981): 453-458. weisberg, r.w., and j.w. alba. "an examination of the alleged role of 'fixation' in the solution of several 'insight' problems." journal of experimental psychology: general 110 (1981): 169-192. yates, j.e judgment and decision making. englewood cliffs, nj: prentice hall, 1990. appendix a synopsis of the experimental instrument the case as an aspiring young chemist, you have discovered a derivative of trinitrotoluene (tnt) that is a clearly superior form of the explosive. in the scientific community, your discovery has been nicknamed tnt2• you have estimated that you can safely produce 200 units of tnt2 in a year. the army corps of engineers (ace) recently approached you with the offer of an exclusive contract for all 200 units of your product for each of the next ten years. ace will pay you $1,000 per unit for tnt2• in addition, ace has offered to intervene on your behalf with potential chemical suppliers, allowing you to contract for a fixed per unit rate over the term of your ace contract. if you accept the ace contract, you will only need to purchase one major piece of equipment: a specially-fitted delivery van for transporting the tnt z• after checking with several potential manufacturers, you are confident that you can purchase the delivery van for approximately $100,000. you have enough cash on hand to begin manufacturing tnt 2, but you are still unsure whether the return on your investment is enough to justify the expenditure of your hardearned savings. so, you has taken the matter to your sister, frieda, who is an accountant. after reviewing the financial estimates and computing something called the "net present value" of the project, frieda informed you that the project promises to offer you a return that is above your minimum expectations. in addition, frieda has prepared estimated income statements for the next five years. the projected income statements that frieda prepared for the first five years are presented below. 16 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 tnt2 estimated income statement for the years 19x1 through 19x5 19x1 19x2 19x3 19x4 19x5 sales (200 units @ $1,000) $200,000 $200,000 $200,000 $200,000 $200,000 cost of goods sold (200 units @ $500) 100,000 100,000 100,000 100,000 100,000 gross margin 100,000 100,000 100,000 100,000 100,000 operating expenses 60,000 60,000 60,000 60,000 60,000 depreciation expense* 20,000 32,000 19,200 11,520 11,520 operating income before income taxes 20,000 8,000 20,800 28,480 28,480 income taxes (40%) 8,000 3,200 8,320 11,392 11,392 net income $12,000 $ 4,800 $12,480 $17,088 $17,088 *computed using macrs please consider the following questions independently. question i. you wish to withdraw $20,000 each year for personal use. given the information furnished above, what is the probability that you will have the required amount of cash available in each of the first five years? 0% no-frame condition mark your response with a slash (/). 100% question 2. frieda's estimates were a close approximation of the actual business for tnt2, and you have experienced no major difficulties in either the production or delivery of tne during the first four years. in 19x5, the manufacturing company from which you bought the delivery truck informed you that they had developed new systems which they believed would improve the performance of a new van, should you decide to purchase one. given the information provided above, what is the probability that you would consider the purchase of a new van? 0% mark your response with a slash (/). 100% spring 1997 frame condition allitzer & sanders: tax considerations 17 question 3. frieda's estimates were a close approximation of the actual business for tnt2, and you have experienced no major difficulties in either the production or delivery of tnt2 during the first four years. in preparation for the next five years of production, you have asked frieda to once again prepare budgets. the projected income statements for years 19x6-19yo are presented below. tnt2 estimated income statement for the years 19x6 through 19yo 19x6 19x7 19x8 19x9 19yo sales (200 units @ $1,000) $200,000 $200,000 $200,000 $200,000 $200,000 cost of goods sold (200 units @ $500) 100,000 100,000 100,000 100,000 100,000 gross margin 100,000 100,000 100,000 100,000 100,000 operating expenses 60,000 60,000 60,000 60,000 60,000 depreciation expense* 5,760 0 0 0 0 operating income before income taxes 34,240 40,000 40,000 40,000 40,000 income taxes (40%) 13,696 16,000 16,000 16,000 16,000 net income $ 20,544 $ 24,000 $ 24,000 $ 24,000 $ 24,000 *computed using macrs in 19x5, the manufacturing company from which you bought the delivery truck informed you that they had developed new systems which they believed would improve the performance of a new van, should you decide to purchase one. given the information provided above, what is the probability that you would consider the purchase of a new van? 0% mark your response with a slash (i). 100% dr. richard alltizer, (ph.d., university of oklahoma) spent 14 years in public accounting before earning his ph.d. he is currently an assistant professor at emporia state university in emporia, kansas. dr. alltizer teaches a variety of tax issues and has developed numerous continuing education courses in tax. he has published tax-related re18 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 search in taxation for accountants, taxation for lawyers, and the journal of applied business research. dr. elaine sanders, (ph.d., university of oklahoma) recei ved her phd. after working in the private sector. she is currently an assistant professor at the university of texas at san antonio in san antonio, texas. dr. sanders teaches financial and managerial topics in accounting. her research interests focus on the use of accounting information for decision-making which enables her to conduct research across a broad range of accounting topics. dr. sanders has published in the journal of accounting case research. tax considerations in investment strategies: evidence of functional fixation on asset depreciation volume 40(1) p.1-20 received: june 6, 2022 revision received: september 7, 2022 accepted: september 16, 2022 https://doi.org/10.554155/jbs.40.1.1-20 ceo trustworthiness: its antecedents and effects on corporate governance k. matthew gilleya, roger c. mayerb, bruce a. waltersc, gregory g. dessd, bradley j.olsone a greehey school of business, st. mary’s university, san antonio, tx b poole college of management, north carolina state university, raleigh nc c corresponding author. department of management, louisiana tech university. bwalters@latech.edu d naveen jindal school of management, university of texas at dallas, richardson tx e faculty of management, university of lethbridge, lethbridge ab canada abstract we develop an integrated set of propositions describing the relationships among ceo characteristics, the perceived trustworthiness of the ceo, and the board of directors’ decisions concerning the governance structure of the firm. in particular, we propose that ceo education, tenure, experience, board memberships and founder status affect the board’s perception of the ceo’s ability, benevolence, and integrity (the three key trustworthiness dimensions), and that these trustworthiness perceptions then affect the board’s choice of governance mechanisms with regard to ceo compensation mix, ceo/board chair duality, board size, and outsider representation on the board. our theoretical development suggests that agency theory’s difficulties in explaining corporate governance may be the result of researchers’ failure to incorporate ceo trustworthiness into their models. keywords ceo characteristics, trustworthiness, corporate governance 1. introduction corporate scandals highlight the effects of executive power and trustworthiness on the success or failure of organizations. recent events at theranos, luckin coffee, volkswagen, wells fargo and other organizations demonstrate the dramatic lengths to which unscrupulous executives will go to enrich themselves at the expense of the organization’s stakeholders. such events over the years have led numerous critics in academia and the media to suggest that corporate governance in america’s largest firms has failed to align the interests of top managers with those of the shareholders and other key stakeholders. at the heart of many such criticisms is that complacent, and even complicit, boards are oftentimes unwilling or unable to reign in powerful executives. the board of directors is the governing body that has received the most attention in relation to minimizing inappropriate executive behavior (daily & schwenk, 1996), and the board is deemed the nexus of corporate this work is licensed under a creative commons attribution-noncommercial 4.0 international license. © 2023 the authors. https://doi.org/10.554155/jbs.40.1.1-20 mailto:bwalters@latech.edu gilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 2 governance (finkelstein & hambrick, 1996; hoppmann et al., 2019). since boards of directors are to ensure the alignment of shareholder and executive interests, it is incumbent upon them to assess and adjust the firm’s governance structure and to do so in a way that minimizes the potential risks of moral hazard to the firm brought about by decisions the ceo makes. nevertheless, it is clear that powerful and unscrupulous executives are sometimes allowed to run roughshod over the governance process and, by extension, the best interests of those by whom they are employed. agency theory assumes that the ceo is inherently untrustworthy because he or she is a “rational actor”; that is, the ceo may have something substantial to gain by considering his or her own interests of primary importance (graffin et al., 2020; jensen & meckling, 1976). from an agency theory perspective, unless the interests of the ceo and the firm are directly aligned such that each stands to gain from a given ceo decision, the appropriate action of the board would be to place controls on the ceo so that s/he does not exploit the firm for his or her own gain. that is, the board should choose governance structures that minimize any potential agency costs (joseph et al., 2014; zahra & pearce, 1989). alternatively, stewardship theory suggests that a ceo might make decisions that benefit the firm even at his or her own expense (davis et al., 1997; donaldson & davis, 1991; hernandez, 2012). this is because such a ceo may well attach great utility to outcomes that benefit the organization irrespective of personal gain (chrisman, 2019). when a ceo is motivated to act as a steward, the recommendation would follow that the board should choose governance structures that allow the ceo discretion and latitude to make the decisions that, rather than motivated by the potential for self gain, are motivated by benefiting the organization. thus, we have two different perspectives from which both the board of directors and the ceo might act: an agency perspective and a stewardship perspective. while agency and stewardship theories offer the chance at greater understanding of both the board and the ceo in the context of governance structure, what is left largely unaddressed is the context under which the board will choose an agency versus a stewardship perspective in either imposing or reducing constraints on the ceo in the governance structure it chooses. the governance options most easily influenced by directors are generally believed to be the ceo’s compensation mix and the conduct and structure of the board of directors (including the decision to grant the ceo additional titles, such as board chairperson, and, by extension, more discretion). both executive compensation and board structure have been extensively researched, but most of this work has focused on the performance-related outcomes of corporate governance rather than the factors that affect governance structures themselves. among the largely unanswered questions are: why do some boards grant the ceo the additional role of board chairperson and/or president, while some do not? why are there varying levels of board independence from management? and, why do ceo compensation plans vary across firms with similar characteristics? we argue that the perceived trustworthiness of the ceo is central to answering these questions. we develop an integrated set of propositions highlighting the relationships among ceo characteristics, perceived ceo trustworthiness, and governance structure. we propose that ceo characteristics affect the board’s perceptions of his or her trustworthiness. in addition, we propose that the board’s perception of ceo trustworthiness affects the degree to which the board is willing to put itself and the firm at risk through the firm’s governance structure. in pursuing this line of inquiry, we make several contributions to management theory. first, our paper represents a merging of two previously distinct domains, namely, strategic management’s governance work and organizational behavior’s work on trustworthiness and trust. second, we advance work on governance by further explicating the role of ceos’ personal differences in the governance process. third, we address the extent to which perceived ceo trustworthiness affects corporate governance structure. fourth, we address the antecedents of governance structure, which, as noted above, have received relatively little atgilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 3 tention. finally, we extend theory development on trustworthiness by delineating some of its potential antecedents, which have also received very little attention from either the theoretical or empirical literature. 2. theory development agency theory has long offered a view of the firm in which the board, representing the principals, is pitted against ceos as agents (eisenhardt, 1989), yet we still do not have a clear understanding of the full range of dysfunctional behaviors and their costs to organizational stakeholders and society (bosse & phillips, 2016). agency theory suggests that the interests of owners and their agents can come into conflict, and when this happens, ceos will choose to protect their own interests above those of the principals, or, more specifically, the firm. when the interests of the firm and the ceo are aligned, this presents no problem. that is because the ceo, in making decisions that benefit himor herself, will also be protecting the interests of the firm. this occurs as a side benefit to the firm, but the benefits are nonetheless very real. when they are not aligned and the ceo chooses self-gain over the good of the firm, the firm incurs what are referred to as agency costs. the potential for these agency costs represents risk to the firm, and this risk can be minimized by the choices the board makes with regard to governance structure (krause et al., 2017). for example, the board can align the interests of the ceo with the firm by tying part of the ceo’s compensation to firm performance. or, the board can limit the ceo’s power by appointing someone other than the ceo to be the board’s chair. stewardship theory offers an alternative viewpoint of the relationship between the ceo and the firm (chrisman, 2019; davis et al., 1997; donaldson & davis, 1991; hernandez, 2012). stewardship theory suggests that some ceos make decisions that benefit the firm irrespective of, and perhaps even at the expense of, their own potential for self-gain (hernandez, 2012). that is because such ceos see utility not in their own accumulation of tangible benefits so much as in identifying with the success of the firm. such ceos will forego decisions that benefit themselves if, in doing so, they would bring harm to or miss the chance to benefit the firm. in this instance, the board should be much less concerned about minimizing agency costsandmoreconcernedwithcreatingsituations in which the ceo can do what comes naturally to him or her and benefits the firm. for a ceo who is inclined to act as a steward, the board may do well to choose governance structures that minimize constraints on the ceo and give him/her more latitude. here, the board might not feel compelled to tie a portion of the ceo’s compensation to firm performance and might allow the ceo more discretion by, for example, appointing the ceo to also serve as the board’s chair. davis et al. (1997) gave an extensive treatment of stewardship theory and its comparison to agency theory. they also discussed at length the benefit of having the ceo and the board aligned in their motivations and world views. they suggested that an appropriate match is when a ceo with an agency mindset (meaning he or she is selfinterested) is matched with board that places appropriate constraints on the ceo. another appropriate match occurs when a stewardship-minded ceo is matched with a board that is likeminded and, inturn, minimizesconstraintsontheceo.undesirable situations occur when a ceo with a stewardship focus is paired with a board that assumes the ceo is highly self-interested, or when a highly self-interested ceo is matched with a board that assumes the ceo has a stewardship focus. davis et al. (1997) go on to discuss conditions that might contribute to a ceo adopting a stewardship perspective, citing influences such as the ceo’s value commitment to the organization and the management philosophy of the ceo (control vs. commitment). they also argue that, whereas the appropriate agency scenario minimizes potential costs, the mutual stewardship relationship has the potential to maximize performance. however, only hinted at, and not formally developed in previous work of which we are aware, are the conditions that would influence the board’s perceptions of the ceo’s mindset and whether or not s/he would be considered to be more agencyoriented or stewardship-oriented. while a match gilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 4 is important, to arrive at this point, the board must (hopefully) correctly assess the ceo’s leanings. very simply, a ceo might have a stewardship perspective, but under what conditions will the board provide the ceo with the governance structure to act as a steward? davis et al. (1997) suggested that trustworthiness would be important to this process, but they did not go beyond this suggestion. we draw on this suggestion, first outlining the characteristics of the ceo that will make the board more likely to view him or her as trustworthy and then delineating the effects of these perceptions of trustworthiness on the board’s decisions regarding governance structure. hence, our view places the perceived trustworthiness of the ceo as the intervening variable between the ceo’s characteristics and governance structure. ceo characteristics as antecedents of trustworthiness trust in management has long been thought to be important for organizational performance (argyris, 1994; davis et al., 2000; dirks, 2000), and it has received a considerable amount of attention in the literature. however, one of the problems associated with this work has been the variety of ways trust has been defined and operationalized (bigley & pearce, 1998; sitkin & roth, 1993). to deal with these problems, mayer et al. (1995) developed a conceptual model that separated trustworthiness from trust. trust is defined in their model as a willingness to be vulnerable to the actions of another person or party when that party cannot be monitored or controlled. while trust can be assessed as a willingness to engage in certainactionsthatputoneselfatrisk, it ismanifested as risk taking in a relationship (rtr) with a party in one’s actions or decisions in a specific setting. thus, according to mayer et al. (1995) model, a trustor’s perceptions of a trustee’s characteristics (i.e., trustworthiness) will influence the degree to which the trustor is willing to make himor herself vulnerable to the trustee (i.e., trust). this, in turn, is the primary antecedent to the trustor’s actions and decisions that directly put him or her at risk (i.e., rtr). while other theoretical frameworks are available to invoke trust (lewicki & bunker, 1996; mcallister, 1995; rousseau et al., 1998), we chose to draw upon mayer et al. (1995) because it specifically distinguishes among the trustee’s characteristics, the trustor’s willingness to put himor herself at risk, and the actual behaviors that do so. in the context of the present paper, this allows us to distinguish clearly between the board’s perceptions of the ceo’s trustworthiness and the board’s risk taking (trust manifested) through the decisions they make in the governance structures affecting the ceo. more specifically, the board’s trust intheceois, inpart, manifestedintheextent to which governance structures either impose or lift constraints on the ceo’s autonomy. trustworthiness is a perceived property of the trustee, and it is comprised of the board’s perceptions of the ceo’s ability, benevolence, and integrity. ability refers to “that group of skills, competencies, and characteristics that enable a party to have influence within some specific domain” (mayer et al., 1995, p. 717). it is generally believed to be domain/task specific such that an individual can be seen as capable in some domains but not in others. in a chief executive context, we suggest that ability deals with the extent to which the ceo is perceived by the board to be capable of leading the firm to acceptable levels of performance. as an agent for all the firm’s stakeholders (both those who own shares and those who do not), the ceo’s actions are influenced by the presence of both stakeholder and shareholder representatives on the board of directors (harrison, 1987; luoma & goodstein, 1999). a stakeholder-agency view (hill & jones, 1992) would suggest, then, that directors consider ceos to have ability when they have the skills, competencies, and characteristics necessary to guide the firm toward added value for a wide variety of stakeholders, including both shareholders and non-shareholding stakeholders alike (barney, 2018). benevolence deals with the extent to which the individual in question is thought to be predisposed to act in ways that are advantageous for the trustors (mayer et al., 1995). in this case the trustors are the directors. in the case of the chief executive, benevolence is the extent to which the ceo is believed by the board to care about the board gilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 5 members and their needs, which is likely to put the organization’s needs ahead of his or her own. mayer and colleagues note that, “benevolence is the extent to which a trustee is believed to want to do good to the trustor, aside from an egocentric profit motive” (mayer et al., 1995, p. 718). importantly, regarding the trustee’s belief that the ceo wants to do good, relationships the ceo develops with individual board members can be expected to affect the board’s perception of the ceo’s benevolence. finally, integrity concerns the extent to which “the trustee adheres to a set of principles that the trustor finds acceptable” (mayer et al., 1995, p. 719). in the context of the ceo-board relationship, the board should perceive the ceo to have integrity when s/he is thought to believe that his or her purpose is to maximize the value of the firm to its various stakeholders (including shareholders), and acts consistently to reflect this belief. thus, integrity deals with the ceo’s beliefs, as perceived by the board, about his or her role as a steward of the organization’s resources and constituents, while benevolence deals with the board’s perceptions of the ceo’s intentions to protect the board’s interests. in other words, in applying mayer et al. (1995) conceptualization of integrity to a ceo-board context, what is important to perceptions of integrity is what the ceo is thought to believe about his or her purpose in the organization and putting the organization’s needs first in strategic decisions, not whether he or she intends to take care of the board members’ interests (which would be regarded as benevolence). mayer et al. (1995) address the issue of profit-centricity as it relates to integrity when they note that, “the issue of acceptability precludes the argument that a party who is committed solely to the principle of profit seeking at all costs would be judged high in integrity (unless this principle is acceptable to the trustor)” (mayer et al., 1995, p. 719). given that financial performance maximization is an important principle to shareholders, it may be that ceos will be seen as having more integrity in the eyes of shareholder representatives on the board, in the mayer et al. (1995) conceptualization of “integrity as acceptability,” when they are profitcentric. of course, profit maximization may not be the only basis on which the ceo’s integrity is assessed. profit maximization represents an end state, and directors may care about the means for achieving end states as well. for example, in addition to the emphasis on profit maximization, a board might assess a ceo’s integrity on the basis of how he or she will accomplish profit maximization (i.e., honesty, fairness, etc.); moreover, it may place particular value in balancing the desire to make a profit for the shareholders with the needs of the employees, environment, and other stakeholders. given that non-shareholding stakeholders oftentimes have relatively little representation on boards (crucke & knockaert, 2016), and those types of directors appear to have only a minor effect on organization strategy (hillman et al., 2001), it may be that the most salient factors determining the board’s perception of the ceo’s integrity are those that affect his or her profitability philosophy. we acknowledge, however, that each board member will assess the integrity of the ceo relative to his and her own set of criteria, and these criteria may well differ based on such things as each member’s values and/or the type of role they play on the board (e.g., shareholder vs. non-shareholder). at the core of mayer et al. (1995) model is the idea that perceptions of an individual’s trustworthiness (ability, benevolence, and integrity) are the antecedents of the willingness to trust that person, as well as antecedents of actions that manifest that willingness (rtr). both on the basis of mayer et al. (1995) model and others, much organizational research is focused on what trust is, the effects of trustworthiness on trust and risk taking in relationship, and the consequences of trust and risk taking in a relationship. as for the latter, evidence has emerged that trust can have impacts on such things as individual attitudes and behavioral outcomes (dirks & ferrin, 2002) and on the performance of higher-level units, such as teams and organizations (davis et al., 2000; dirks, 2000). as such, it remains to be determined what specific factors affect a corporate board’s perceptions of the ceo’s trustworthiness, as well as how those perceptions affect corporate governance. what gilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 6 figure 1: relationships among ceo characteristics, perceived ceo trustworthiness, and governancestructure is clear from prior research, however, is that an individual’s characteristics likely affect others’ beliefs in that person’s trustworthiness. with regard to the ceo-board relationship in particular, several ceo characteristics may be uniquely relevant. specifically, we suggest that ceo education, tenure, breadth of functional experience, external boardmemberships, and founderstatus affect the board’s perceptions of the ceo’s trustworthiness. below, we develop propositions specifically dealing with how these factors affect perceived ceo ability, benevolence, and integrity. the proposed relationships are shown in 1. 3. propositions ceo characteristics ceo education. we propose that educationrelated ceo characteristics play an important role in the board’s assessment of the ceo’s abilities and integrity. prior research has used several measures as indicators of top management ability, which we define here as the ceo’s expertise at effectively managing the firm and the decisions that affect it (finkelstein, 1992). prior research has shown a strong correlation between education and an individual’s abilities. becker (1993) argued that education contributes to increased abilities, and that these abilities provide value to organizations. moreover, prior work has shown education level to be related to corporate innovation and strategic change (westphal & zajac, 1995). thus, education level is a possible indicator of ceo ability in the view of the board. in addition, the prestige of the ceo’s alma mater may affect perceptions of his or her ability. chatterjee and pollock (2017) and miller and wiseman (2001) suggested that the university (or universities) attended by a ceo could be an important indicator of perceived ceo attributes. interestingly, the relationship between ceo education and middle manager perceptions of a ceo’s abilities found by miller and wiseman (2001) became stronger gilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 7 when the analysis included tenure of middle management. the more seasoned these managers became, the more emphasis they placed on the importance of elite education. thus, it appears as though individuals with more experience highly value education in others, suggesting that a ceo’s education will be particularly salient to corporate directors, who generally have many years of experience. proposition 1. ceo education level and the prestige of the ceo’s alma mater(s) have a positive effect on board perceptions of ceo ability. it seems reasonable to assume that shareholders, who prefer the ceo to espouse financial performance maximization values as discussed earlier, will believe the ceo is higher in integrity when his or her educational background fits a particular profile. recall that integrity in the ceo context refers to the board’s perceptions of the ceo’s beliefs as to the importance of profit maximization. scholars have argued that individuals with business degrees, and especially those with advanced business degrees, tend to be viewed as possessing greater capacities for strategic decision making (westphal & zajac, 1995). these business school graduates may, in turn, tend to view organizational financial performance as more important than do non-business graduates. we suggest that corporate boards, which are generally dominated by shareholder representatives (hillman et al., 2001), will view ceos as having higher levels of integrity when they possess a degree in a business discipline, especially when the degree is at the graduate level. individuals with business degrees are more likely to be viewed by the board as understanding the “rules of the game” and we believe the board will believe the ceo is likely to lead the organization accordingly. in particular, the mba is seen by many as a hallmark of managerial knowledge. pfeffer and fong (2003) indicate that business-educated executives are valued and thus deemed important in the corporate world. therefore, ceos possessing business degrees should also be viewed by the board as being of greater ability because of the congruence between their educational background and the demands of their position. proposition 2. ceos with business degrees will be perceived by directors to be of greater integrity and ability. ceo tenure. a ceo’s tenure with the organization likely affects the board’s perception of the ceo’s abilities and benevolence. tenure has been widely used in ceo studies as a predictor or control variable, and it has been associated with executive succession (cannella & shen, 2001; chahine & zhang, 2020), compensation (hou et al., 2017), and firm performance (sigler & porterfield, 2001). we are aware of no examinations of the effects of ceo tenure on the board’s perceptions of his or her abilities and benevolence, but it is reasonable to assume that it plays a role. indeed, tenure has been used previously as a proxy for an executive’s human capital (carpenter et al., 2001; finkelstein & hambrick, 1996; geletkanycz et al., 2001; pennings et al., 1998). in addition, hurley et al. (1997) found that career advancement was positively affected by organizational tenure, suggesting that longer-tenured executives are viewed as increasingly competent. in part, this may be because asymmetries between agents and principals regarding their human capital will dissipate over time (quigley et al., 2019). clearly, executives with longer organizational tenures will have become increasingly familiar with the organization’s strategy, culture, competitors, and environment. with increasing organizational tenure, ceos build critical human and social capital that serve to increase their effectiveness, to the benefit of their organizations (pennings et al., 1998). one aspect of social capital that ceos may build with increasing tenure is related to their relationship with the board. specifically, more tenured ceos have had the opportunity to build deeper relationships with the directors, engendering trust and enhanced perceptions of ability, and allowing for heightened reciprocity and decision-making interdependence (cropanzano & mitchell, 2005). in addition, due to the expertise gained from tenure, seasoned ceos are “more reasonably” held accountable for their firms’ performance than are their younger tenured ceo counterparts (buchholtz et al., 1998). gilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 8 moreover, as time passes, the increasing tenure of a ceo within a specific firm may lead to shifts in perceptions of the ceo’s ability, which in turn will affect the firm’s governance structure. thus, directors should view longer-tenured ceos having greater ability. proposition 3. ceo tenure has a positive effect on board perceptions of ceo ability. as noted earlier, in a ceo context, the benevolence component of trustworthiness deals with the extent to which the ceo has the board’s interests in mind when making strategic decisions. mayer et al. (1995) argue that of the three trustworthiness factors, benevolence takes longer to develop. it takes time for ceos to build social capital with their boards of directors (barkema & pennings, 1998), potentially leading the board to believe the ceo has the board’s interests in mind when making decisions. proposition 4. ceo tenure has a positive effect on board perceptions of ceo benevolence. ceo breadth of functional experience. both finkelstein (1992) and daily and johnson (1997) proposed that an important antecedent of expert power for ceos was functional area experience. as a ceo’s breadth of functional experiences increases, his or her understanding of the complex interrelationships among the organization’s diverse range of tasks is enhanced. this is suggested by hurley et al. (1997), who found that diversity of experience positively affected career advancement, implying that those making promotion decisions believe that breadth of experience within the firm may play a role in overall competence. as a result, ceos should be viewed as more able by the board when they have had a broader variety of functional experiences. proposition 5. breadth of functional experience hasapositiveeffectonboardperceptionsofceoability. ceo board memberhsip. another important factor in the board’s perceptions of a ceo’s trustworthiness is the ceo’s involvement on external forprofit company boards. by serving on boards of other organizations, ceos are likely to increase their human and social capital in ways that enhance their apparent abilities and their firm’s performance (geletkanycz et al., 2001; zhu et al., 2020). although a detailed discussion of the organizational benefits of a ceo’s external directorships is beyond the scope of the current paper, such ties help reduce uncertainty surrounding external resource dependencies (pfeffer & salancik, 1978), help increase the breadth of environmental scanning activities, and signal managerial andorganizationalqualitytoexternalconstituents (geletkanycz et al., 2001). as a result, we propose that a ceo’s external directorships will be perceived by the board to enhance the ceo’s ability to run the organization effectively. proposition 6. a ceo’s service on outside for-profit company boards has a positive effect on board perceptions of ceo ability. we also suggest that a ceo’s service on outside boards of for-profit firms will affect the board’s perceptions of the ceo’s integrity. recall that integrity includes perceptions of the ceo’s belief in his or her role as profit-seeker for the firm. ceos serving on outside for-profit boards are more likely to be perceived by their employing company’s directors to understand and identify with their concerns as directors about the firm’s financial performance. in addition, service on outside for-profit boards suggests a degree of social similarity between the ceo and those sitting on his or her company’s board, likely leading those directors to impute a congruence of values on issues of firm performance. as such, we believe that ceos sitting on outside for-profit boards will be viewed by their directors as having more integrity, to the extent that integrity in this context concerns profit-centricity on the part of the ceo. service on non-profit boards may signal ability, but may or may not suggest a commitment to profit centricity, and thus may not contribute to a perception of integrity. proposition 7. a ceo’s service on outside for-profit company boards has a positive effect on board perceptions of ceo integrity. gilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 9 ceo founder status. the ceo’s status as founder of the organization is also likely to affect perceived ceo trustworthiness. we suggest that ceos who are founders of the firms they lead will likely be perceived as being of greater ability and benevolence (lee et al., 2020). regarding ability, founderceos play a key role in setting the firm’s initial direction, outlining objectives, and shepherding the organization in its earliest and most vulnerable days (gimeno et al., 1997; vesper, 1996). in addition, hendricks et al. (2019) argued that founderceos possess deep tacit knowledge of the firm and its operations, have strong relationships with both internal and external stakeholders, and are more strongly identified with and committed to the firm, thus mitigating agency concerns. jayaraman et al. (2000) found inconsistent results when exploring the firm performance effects of a founder-ceo’s continued leadership. nonetheless, the ceo’s abilities were clearly important to the firm’s success, especially given the variety of obstacles through which a founder-ceo must successfully lead his or her organization in the firm’s early years. nelson (2003) found that the stock market reacted more positively to founder ceoled firms than non-founder-led firms. more specifically, the fact that investors will pay a higher premium for founder ceo-led firms’ ipos is likely due to the perceived value of the competencies of the founder-led ceo. thus, we suggest that founderceos are more likely to be perceived by the board as having greater ability than non-founder ceos. proposition 8. founder-ceos will be perceived by the board as having greater ability than ceos who were not founders. the governance effects of ceo trustworthiness the board’s perception of the ceo’s trustworthiness is likely to have far reaching consequences for corporate governance. in general terms, a perceived lack of ceo trustworthiness should increase the board’s concern about agency costs. on the contrary, boards overseeing a ceo who is perceived to have ability, benevolence, and integrity will be less concerned about agency costs. as mayer et al. (1995) note, individuals are willing to put themselves at risk when the other party is perceived to be more trustworthy. in a governance context, high levels of perceived ceo trustworthiness would lead the board to incorporate relatively low levels of rigor in the firm’s governance structure. indeed, strickland (1958) suggests that low levels of trust in employees will increase managerial monitoring of their activities. in addition, del brio et al. (2013) found boards that perceive the ceo to be low in ability and integrity engage in higher levels of monitoring. as a result, we suggest that perceived ceo trustworthiness affects a board’s approach to governing, including setting ceo compensation mix, ceo/board chair duality, board size, and the number of outside directors on the board, all of which are indicators of the rigor of the firm’s governance. given that each of the three dimensions of trustworthiness are separable and can vary independently of one another (mayer et al., 1995), we theorize that ability, benevolence, and integrity may each have unique effects on governance structure. ceo compensation mix. with regard to compensation mix, agency theory (jensen & meckling, 1976) suggests that monitoring costs can be reduced by using compensation structure to align the interests of the ceo with those of the shareholders. in doing so, agency theory indicates that boards should adjust the mix of fixed and performance-contingent compensation such that executives are induced to engage in performancemaximizing behaviors (graffin et al., 2020; stroh et al., 1996). when the ceo’s compensation is heavily reliant on the firm’s meeting its performance targets, executives are discouraged from making ill-advised investments in self-serving strategic initiatives (baumol, 1967; kroll et al., 1990). consistent with agency theory, in cases where directors perceive the ceo to be particularly trustworthy, we suggest that the ceo’s compensation will be comprised of a significantly higher proportion of fixed compensation. we believe the opposite is also true; boards will increase the importance of contingent compensation (such as stock options and bonuses) in a ceo’s pay mix when he or she is perceived to be less trustworthy. we propose that the salient trustworthiness facgilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 10 tors that affect compensation structure are perceived benevolence and integrity. given that abilities or competencies are developed over a lifetime of experiences, boards will recognize that pay structure does little to compensate for relatively lower levels of ceo ability; thus, boards will tend to use other governance mechanisms under conditions of lower perceived ceo ability. further, when boards have more representatives of non-shareholding stakeholders, they will be more likely to increase the importance of non-financial performance (such as environmental impact, employee job security and benefits, supplier relations, and so on) as a contingency for ceo compensation in the face of low levels of perceived benevolence and integrity. nevertheless, financial performance will be the primary contingency upon which less trustworthy ceos’ compensation will be based, given the relatively low representation on boards of stakeholder directors (hillman et al., 2001). proposition 9. ceos who are perceived to be higher on the dimensions of benevolence and integrity will have a lower percentage of contingent compensation. ceo/board chair duality. ceo/board chair duality is clearly suggestive of enhanced executive power and increased risk of self-serving behavior by the ceo. mallette and fowler (1992) found that firms with ceo duality were more likely to adopt a “poison pill” than firms with a separation between the ceo and board chairperson. zantout and o’reilly-allen (1996) found an association between ceo duality and corporate diversification. magnan et al. (1999) found that ceo duality was significantly and positively related to ceo compensation. harrison et al. (1988) found that ceo power leads to entrenchment. finally, hayward and hambrick (1997) found that firms with ceo duality paid greater takeover premiums during acquisitions than firms with separate ceo/chair positions. therefore, duality is generally believed to conveysignificantpowertotheceo.giventhatduality increases the ceo’s ability to force his or her will on the organization, we suggest that each of the three trustworthiness factors affect the likelihood of a board granting the ceo the dual title of board chair. when the chair position is separate from the ceo, board members choose either an outside director or a former executive as the chairperson. we argue that an externally selected chairperson would signal a concern regarding integrity or benevolence. the board wants to ensure that the executive chosen for this important strategic position comes from the outside to safeguard the interests of various stakeholders. on the other hand, a former executive appointment may signal a concern regarding the ceo’s ability, and with the invaluable experience of the former executive, such a team would bode well for effective strategic decision making. in addition to the titles of ceo and board chair, there are other titles frequently combined with ceo that may be indicative of structural power, such as president, chief operating officer, and so on (combs & skill, 2003). top executive with these additional titles of higher authority would have greater influence, since he or she would have much more discretion over critical knowledge and resources than a ceo without these added titles. the consolidation of various positions, which includes board chair, can provide a clear signal to investors that the strategic decision process will be less bureaucratic as well as provide the ceo with a “wide latitude on objectives” (krause et al., 2019, p. 1570). the board will effectively eliminate potential disagreements with key strategic decision makers such as the president. although the president could be viewed as someone who is being groomed for the top executive position, thus engendering teamwork among the executives, another perspective suggests that these positions could just as easily turn combative with the ceo (zhang, 2006). thus, ceos who are perceived by their boards to have ability, benevolence, and integrity will be more likely to hold the dual titles of ceo and board chair, because the board will view this centrality of decision making authority as beneficial to the pursuit of corporate initiatives. as well, boards may grant additional titles such as president to further structure efficient decision making. gilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 11 proposition 10. ceos who are perceived by the board to be higher in ability, benevolence, and integrity are more likely to hold the position of board chairperson and/or president. board size and outsider representation. two factors related to the structure of the board itself may be affected by perceived ceo trustworthiness. these are the size of the board and the proportion of directors who are outsiders. directors are considered here to be outsiders when they have never been employed by the organization (jones & goldberg, 1982; judge & zeithaml, 1992). when directors perceive lower levels of ability, we suggest that they will increase the size of the board. directors clearly bring a variety of skills, social networks, and resource dependence benefits to the task of corporate governance (gnyawali & madhavan, 2001; pfeffer & salancik, 1978), and such skills and networks should prove more valuable in conditions of perceived low ceo ability. by increasing the number of directors, boards may add significant value to organizations with less capable ceos. perceptions of low benevolence and integrity should also lead to increases in board size, but for different reasons. board size is an important indicator of a firm’s passive or vigilant monitoring of the ceo and the other executives (wright et al., 2002). the larger the board, the more difficult it may be for the non-benevolent and/or lowintegrity ceo to pursue a dysfunctional agenda. prior research has suggested that such boards are regarded as most appropriate when there are concerns about agency costs (pearce & zahra, 1992). given that lower levels of perceived ceo benevolence and integrity will likely be viewed by the board of directors as leading to potentially greater agency costs, we would expect board size to be inversely related to perceived ceo benevolence and integrity. proposition 11. perceptions of low levels of ceo ability, benevolence, and integrity will positively affect board size. regarding outsider representation, outsiderdominated boards are more apt to challenge strategic choices that are not conducive to superior firm performance. hill and snell (1988) found that the ratio of outside board members to total board members was positively associated with board involvement in restructuring. evidence suggests that a greater proportion of outsiders on the board is associated with an increased likelihood that the board will replace the ceo after a period of poor corporate performance (coughlan & schmidt, 1985; newman & mozes, 1999; weisbach, 1988). both types of board members (outsiders and insiders) have a duty to ensure that strategies pursued are in the best interest of the shareholders (j. l. johnson et al., 1996). yet, an inside director may feel indebted to the ceo because of his or her employment history with the ceo, and may perceive more benevolence from the ceo based on this existing relationship. therefore, while inside directors will have more knowledge of the daily operations, they will also be less likely to challenge the ceo or other executives on important strategic issues (r. a. johnson et al., 1993). outside board members, however, are not as beholden to the ceo. moreover, these board members are not involved in the daily operations of the company and will not have to deal with the uneasiness of working closely with a ceo with whom they may disagree. also, outside directors may have the added incentive of maintaining their own reputations as directors and avoiding the risks of negative publicity for duties poorly performed (fama & jensen, 1983). firms with outside, more independent boards will be more vigilant in monitoring the ceo, which is particularly important when the ceo is perceived to be low on some combination of integrity, ability, and benevolence. however, where the ceo is perceived to be higher on those dimensions, fewer outsiders will be needed to monitor the ceo, because the board will perceive the ceo to be less of a risk with regard to agency costs. hillman et al. (2000) argue that outside board members serve in three important capacities: business experts, support specialists, and community influentials. business experts impart skills in problem solving and decision making. support specialists provide legitimacy and access to vital gilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 12 resources. community influentials represent nonbusiness perspectives such as outside interests. ceo trustworthiness in these capacities would help determine the type of outside representation boards would seek. for example, boards may want business experts and support specialists if the ceo’s abilities are in question. proposition 12. perceptions of low levels of ceo ability, benevolence, and integrity will positively affect outsider representation on the board. 4. board perceptions of ceo trustworthiness: individual assessments and group decisions. our model, as developed above, suggests that board members will make judgments about the perceived trustworthiness of ceos based on a variety of ceo characteristics. we go on to suggest that it is the board’s perceptions of the ceo’s trustworthiness that will, in turn, directly influence the degree to which the board imposes or lifts constraints on the ceo through the choices the board makes with regard to governance structure. while we acknowledged that different board members may have different perceptions of the ceo’s trustworthiness, what becomes apparent is that, in working toward governance structure decisions, the individuals comprising the board and its decision-making committees must act in unity. given that perceptions of trustworthiness originate within individual board members, the question that arises is how the board arrives at a shared perception on which to act. the effects of trustworthiness perceptions on governance structure decisions represent what currall and inkpen (2002) referred to as a group → person trust situation in their taxonomy of trust in international joint ventures. this group → person label is appropriate for our theorizing in that our context depicts the degree to which a group (the board of directors or a committee thereof) perceivesanindividual (theceo)tobetrustworthy or not. how the board uses the perceptions of its individual members to arrive at governance structure decisions will largely be a function of each board and its established procedures and norms. at one extreme would be the situation in which the board as a whole, or various subcommittees, makes decisions by consensus. here, each board member would need to perceive the ceo to be relatively trustworthy before there would be a decision to remove constraints on the ceo. said another way, the board members would need to share perceptions of ceo trustworthiness. at the other extreme would be a situation in which one of the board members plays a dominant role on the board (or a committee thereof) and other members defer to him or her. this could occur for a variety of reasons, including the rest of the board viewing the dominant member as trustworthy himor herself, and allowing themselves to be vulnerable to him or her. in any event, under such a scenario, the trust relationship boils down to a dyadic phenomenon, or what currall and inkpen (2002) labeled a person → person situation. here, the amount of latitude the ceo is given in the governance structure will largely be a function of not how the board (or a committee) as a collective perceives his or her trustworthiness, but how the dominant individual views it. of course, between these two extremes lie various scenarios in which subsets of the board drive the decision (e.g., majority rules voting patterns and the like). in such cases, the key issue would be the extent to which the majority views the ceo as trustworthy and essentially shares in those judgments. however, this goes beyond the focus of the current paper. we raise these issues here to acknowledge that perceptions of trustworthiness about the ceo are made by individual board members but they oftentimes will be acted upon by the group of board members collectively (either the entire board or a board committee). 5. discussion and conclusions this paper has attempted to link individual ceo characteristics with governance structure by discussing the intervening variable of trustworthiness. in particular, we have suggested that ceos’ education, tenure, functional experience, board membership, and founder status affect the board’s perceptions of the ceo’s trustworthiness. these trustworthiness perceptions will lead the gilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 13 board to exhibit varying levels of trust in their ceos as evidenced in their decisions regarding governance structure. this has important implications for both research and practice. implications for research agency theory and stewardship theory provide alternate theoretical lenses through which the antecedents and outcomes of ceo trustworthiness may be viewed. agency theory suggests that ceos are rational actors concerned with maximizing their own rewards (jensen & meckling, 1976). stewardship theory, by contrast, suggests that ceos will behave in ways that benefit the firm, oftentimes to their own personal detriment (davis et al., 1997; donaldson & davis, 1991). our model suggests that both of these two competing theories may explain governance conditions within the firm quite well, but that the extent to which each apparently explains governance within a firm depends on the underlying trustworthiness of the firm’s top executive. in other words, whether researchers find support for agency theory or stewardship theory in their empirical studies of compensation and governance structure may hinge on trustworthiness, which until now has not been explored as an antecedent of governance. under conditions of high ceo trustworthiness, one would expect the predictions of stewardship theory to hold. those ceos who are characterized by high levels of trustworthiness are given greater authority within their firms to affect organizational outcomes. thus, we would expect greater incidence of duality, higher levels of fixed compensation, fewer outsiders on the board, and a smaller board overall. by contrast, under conditions of low ceo trustworthiness, agency theory should have the most predictive ability in empirical studies dealing with governance and compensation. there are several avenues for future research that may yield theoretical, empirical, and practitioneroriented benefits. first, empirical research on the factors that drive ceo trustworthiness perceptions (and the resulting governance effects) by boards of directors would add richness to the growing body of literature on trust and trustworthiness. such research would extend both theory and empirics. with regard to empirical contributions, scholars would have to determine the appropriate methods for modeling the way(s) in which boards as a group come to make decisions based on individual trustworthiness perceptions. once this was demonstrated empirically, say, by assessing within-board agreement (using, for example, the rwg index of james et al., 1984, 1993) on perceptions of ceo trustworthiness or by assessing the interrater reliability (using, for example, the icc(1) or icc(2) – see bliese, 2000) of perceptions of ceo trustworthiness, the board’s shared perception could be represented by an aggregate of the individual board members’ perceptions of ceo trustworthiness. this is similar to what davis et al. (2000) did when they aggregated employee perceptions of trust in the store manager and related these scores to store performance (though they were not representing the aggregation as a group-level phenomenon). however, doing this empirically in a governance context (i.e., with boards and ceos) would perhaps prove to be particularly challenging. second, future empirical research on the topic may indeed shed light, as we suggest above, on the relative explanatory power of agency theory versus stewardship theory. given the difficulties that prior researchers have had in, for instance, explaining variance in executive compensation, empirical tests employing a trustworthiness approach may be particularly useful in extending the significant body of research on compensation. third, empirical research on ceo trustworthiness perceptions and governance structure/conditions may extend research on trustworthiness by potentially demonstrating the generalizability of the mayer et al. (1995) framework. although this framework has been widely employed, little, if any, of this work has been done with samples of top executives and boards of directors. fourth, research on ceo trustworthiness may include not only observable, objective characteristics but also attitudinal and psychological states. our paper focuses on objective measures; however, the impression created by the ceo’s actions and mannerisms surely provide predictive ability in determining the perceived abilities, benevogilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 14 lence and/or integrity of the ceo. fifth, research could explore more complex relationships among the constructs of interest. consider, for example, nonlinear relationships. the human capital literature generally supports the positive relationship between ceos’ experience and tenure and more favorable perceptions of their ability. in contrast, hildebrand et al. (2020) found that ceos with less prior experience were more likely to have a long-term orientation as well as a more balanced focus between profitability and revenue growth, resulting in higher firm performance. also, studies could explore the interaction effects of, say, ceo board memberships and founder status on ability. ceos who are founders and who sit on multiple for-profit boards may benefit from significantly higher board perceptions of ability because of the associated enhanced credibility and human capital that they would enjoy. finally, governance structure is dynamic across time within organizations, and it clearly varies across organizations. future researchers may wish to consider the frequency and severity of changes in governance (such as changes to the size of the board, the percentage/number of independent directors, duality, and more), and how those changes are driven by perceptions of ceo trustworthiness. in addition, future research may wish to explore the extent to which boards of directors seek out new ceos who fit their governance framework using perceptions of ceo trustworthiness as their indicators of fit. we must be careful to point out that the antecedents of a board’s perception of the ceo’s trustworthiness are surely multifaceted, complex, and difficult to assess/measure. as a result, an important limitation of our paper is that there are likely to be numerous confounding effects that should be controlled for in empirical studies on this topic, such as the financial and operating performance of the firm, among others. given the complex, dynamic, and multifaceted nature of the research questions associated with the relationship between ceo trustworthiness and corporate governance, we propose that much insight can be gained via research methods that employ small sample, intensive studies. as suggested by harrigan (1983, pp. 398–399), "fine grained treatments of strategy benefit from their attention to important details that help researchers characterize the complexities of strategy formulation...(and) can include meticulous attentions to detail, relevance to business practice, and access to multiple viewpoints." such efforts can yield new insights as well as lead to inductive theory building which is invaluable given that research is, of course, a continual process of rediscovery. implications for governance practice our theoretical model implies that corporate governance structure varies across firms, and that this variance hinges on the trustworthiness of the ceo. firms employing ceos who are high on ability, benevolence, and integrity may find that their boards create less value, and that compensation structure is unrelated to subsequent organizational performance (because the ceo would “do the right thing” regardless of pay-related effects). as noted by zahra and pearce (1989), boards perform three primary functions, namely, control, strategy, and service. the control role would be most valuable in situations where the ceo is low in integrity or benevolence. in such cases, the board will engage in both monitoring and incentive alignment such that ceos who have low integrity and/or benevolence are forced to engage in behaviors that are beneficial to the firm, thus minimizing agency costs. however, incurring costs associated with monitoring and incentive alignment is less necessary under conditions of high ceo benevolence and integrity. in addition, the strategy role played by boards is less necessary under conditions of high ceo ability, because highly competent ceos should have the knowledge, skills and abilities to lead the company strategically. finally, the service role of boards of directors may be unaffected by ceo trustworthiness, because much of the service role of boards of directors has little to do with the characteristics of the ceo since those are responsibilities of the board rather than of the ceo. the above discussion is not meant to suggest that boards are irrelevant under conditions of high ceo trustworthiness. clearly, their social and hugilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 15 man capital may still be of value. however, we suggest that corporate governance, and specifically the board of directors, may be viewed as a means for helping low-ability ceos with leadership and strategy issues, and ensuring that ceos with relatively low integrity (in the sense of profit-centricity motives) or benevolence pursue goals preferred by key stakeholders, particularly the board and, by extension, the shareholders. in summary, our model suggests that characteristics of ceos affect the board’s perception of their trustworthiness. these perceptions manifest themselves in risk-taking by the board, specifically in terms of how the board is structured (insiders versus outsiders, number of directors, and ceo/board chair duality), which affects the board’s monitoring function, and how the ceo is compensated (the mix of fixed and performancecontingent pay), which affects incentive alignment. while a great deal of prior research has explored governance, ceo compensation, and trust/trustworthiness, we believe our model provides the first integration of these important topics. accordingly, we contend that research in this vein holds promise for the development of both descriptive and normative theory. references argyris, c. (1994). in s. b. sitkin & r. j. bies (eds.), the legalistic organization. sage. barkema, h. g., & pennings, j. m. (1998). top management pay: impact of overt and covert power. organization studies, 19(6), 975–1003. https://doi.org/10.1177/017084069801900604 barney, j. b. (2018). why resource-based theory’s model of profit appropriation must incorporate a stakeholder perspective. strategic management journal, 39(13), 3305–3325. https://doi.org/10. 1002/smj.2949 baumol, w. j. (1967). business behavior, value and growth [oclc: 228091451]. harcourt brace. becker, g. s. (1993). human capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to education (3rd ed). the university of chicago press. bigley, g. a., & pearce, j. l. (1998). straining for shared meaning in organization science: problems of trust and distrust. the academy of management review, 23(3), 405. https://doi.org/10.2307/ 259286 bliese, p. (2000). in k. j. klein & s. w. kozlowski (eds.), multilevel theory, research, and methods in organizations: foundations, extensions, and new directions. (pp. 349–381). josseybass, inc. bosse, d. a., & phillips, r. a. (2016). agency theory and bounded self-interest. academy of management review, 41(2), 276–297. https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.2013.0420 buchholtz, a. k., young, m. n., & powell, g. n. (1998). are board members pawns or watchdogs?: the link between ceo pay and firm performance. group & organization management, 23(1), 6–26. https://doi.org/10.1177/1059601198231002 cannella, a. a., & shen, w. (2001). so close and yet so far: promotion versus exit for ceo heirs apparent. academy of management journal, 44(2), 252–270. https://doi.org/10.2307/3069454 carpenter, m. a., sanders, w. g., & gregersen, h. b. (2001). bundling human capital with organizational context: the impact of international assignment experience on multinational firm performance and ceo pay. academy of management journal, 44(3), 493–511. https://doi.org/10.5465/3069366 chahine, s., & zhang, y. ( (2020). change gears before speeding up: the roles of chief executive officer human capital and venture capitalist monitoring in chief executive officer change before initial public offering. strategic management journal, 41(9), 1653–1681. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj. 3197 chatterjee, a., & pollock, t. g. (2017). master of puppets: how narcissistic ceos construct their professional worlds. academy of management review, 42(4), 703–725. https://doi.org/10.5465/amr. 2015.0224 https://doi.org/10.1177/017084069801900604 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2949 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2949 https://doi.org/10.2307/259286 https://doi.org/10.2307/259286 https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.2013.0420 https://doi.org/10.1177/1059601198231002 https://doi.org/10.2307/3069454 https://doi.org/10.5465/3069366 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.3197 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.3197 https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.2015.0224 https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.2015.0224 gilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 16 chrisman,j. j. (2019).stewardshiptheory:realism,relevance,andfamilyfirmgovernance.entrepreneurship theory and practice, 43(6), 1051–1066. https://doi.org/10.1177/1042258719838472 combs, j. g., & skill, m. s. (2003). managerialist and human capital explanations for key executive pay premiums: a contingency perspective. academy of management journal, 46(1), 63–73. https:// doi.org/10.2307/30040676 coughlan, a. t., & schmidt, r. m. (1985). executive compensation, management turnover, and firm performance. journal of accounting and economics, 7(1-3), 43–66. https://doi.org/10.1016/01654101(85)90027-8 cropanzano, r., & mitchell, m. s. (2005). social exchange theory: an interdisciplinary review. journal of management, 31(6), 874–900. https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206305279602 crucke, s., & knockaert, m. (2016). when stakeholder representation leads to faultlines. a study of board service performance in social enterprises: faultlines and board service performance. journal of management studies, 53(5), 768–793. https://doi.org/10.1111/joms.12197 currall, s. c., & inkpen, a. c. (2002). a multilevel approach to trust in joint ventures. journal of international business studies, 33(3), 479–495. https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8491027 daily, c. m., & johnson, j. l. (1997). sources of ceo power and firm financial performance: a longitudinal assessment. journalofmanagement,23(2),97–117.https://doi.org/10.1177/014920639702300201 daily, c. m., & schwenk, c. (1996). chief executive officers, top management teams, and boards of directors: congruent or countervailing forces. journal of management, 22(2), 185–208. https: //doi.org/10.1177/014920639602200201 davis, j. h., schoorman, f. d., & donaldson, l. (1997). toward a stewardship theory of management. the academy of management review, 22(1), 20. https://doi.org/10.2307/259223 davis, j. h., schoorman, f. d., mayer, r. c., & tan, h. h. (2000). the trusted general manager and business unit performance: empirical evidence of a competitive advantage. strategic management journal, 21(5), 563–576. https://doi.org/10.1002/(sici)1097-0266(200005)21:5<563::aidsmj99>3.0.co;2-0 del brio, e. b., yoshikawa, t., connelly, c. e., & tan, w. l. (2013). the effects of ceo trustworthiness on directors’ monitoring and resource provision. journal of business ethics, 118(1), 155–169. https: //doi.org/10.1007/s10551-012-1575-0 dirks, k. t. (2000). trust in leadership and team performance: evidence from ncaa basketball. journal of applied psychology, 85(6), 1004–1012. https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.85.6.1004 dirks, k. t., & ferrin, d. l. (2002). trust in leadership: meta-analytic findings and implications for research and practice. journal of applied psychology, 87(4), 611–628. https://doi.org/10.1037/00219010.87.4.611 donaldson, l., & davis, j. h. (1991). stewardship theory or agency theory: ceo governance and shareholder returns. australian journal of management, 16(1), 49–64. https : / / doi . org / 10 . 1177 / 031289629101600103 eisenhardt, k. m. (1989). agency theory: an assessment and review. the academy of management review, 14(1), 57. https://doi.org/10.2307/258191 fama, e. f., & jensen, m. c. (1983). separation of ownership and control. the journal of law and economics, 26(2), 301–325. https://doi.org/10.1086/467037 finkelstein, s. (1992). power in top management teams: dimensions, measurement, and validation. academy of management journal, 35(3), 505–538. https://doi.org/10.5465/256485 finkelstein, s., & hambrick, d. c. (1996). strategic leadership: top executives and their effects on organizations. west pub. co. https://doi.org/10.1177/1042258719838472 https://doi.org/10.2307/30040676 https://doi.org/10.2307/30040676 https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-4101(85)90027-8 https://doi.org/10.1016/0165-4101(85)90027-8 https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206305279602 https://doi.org/10.1111/joms.12197 https://doi.org/10.1057/palgrave.jibs.8491027 https://doi.org/10.1177/014920639702300201 https://doi.org/10.1177/014920639602200201 https://doi.org/10.1177/014920639602200201 https://doi.org/10.2307/259223 https://doi.org/10.1002/(sici)1097-0266(200005)21:5<563::aid-smj99>3.0.co;2-0 https://doi.org/10.1002/(sici)1097-0266(200005)21:5<563::aid-smj99>3.0.co;2-0 https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-012-1575-0 https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-012-1575-0 https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.85.6.1004 https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.87.4.611 https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.87.4.611 https://doi.org/10.1177/031289629101600103 https://doi.org/10.1177/031289629101600103 https://doi.org/10.2307/258191 https://doi.org/10.1086/467037 https://doi.org/10.5465/256485 gilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 17 geletkanycz, m. a., boyd, b. k., & finkelstein, s. (2001). the strategic value of ceo external directorate networks: implications for ceo compensation. strategic management journal, 22(9), 889–898. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.172 gimeno, j., folta, t. b., cooper, a. c., & woo, c. y. (1997). survival of the fittest? entrepreneurial human capital and the persistence of underperforming firms. administrative science quarterly, 42(4), 750. https://doi.org/10.2307/2393656 gnyawali, d. r., & madhavan, r. (2001). cooperative networks and competitive dynamics: a structural embeddedness perspective. the academy of management review, 26(3), 431. https://doi.org/10. 2307/259186 graffin, s. d., hubbard, t. d., christensen, d. m., & lee, e. y. (2020). the influence of ceo risk tolerance on initial pay packages. strategic management journal, 41(4), 788–811. https://doi.org/10.1002/ smj.3112 harrigan, k. r. (1983). research methodologies for contingency approaches to business strategy. the academy of management review, 8(3), 398. https://doi.org/10.2307/257828 harrison, j. r. (1987). the strategic use of corporate board committees. california management review, 30(1), 109–125. https://doi.org/10.2307/41165269 harrison, j. r., torres, d. l., & kukalis, s. (1988). the changing of the guard: turnover and structural change in the top-management positions. administrative science quarterly, 33(2), 211. https: //doi.org/10.2307/2393056 hayward, m. l. a., & hambrick, d. c. (1997). explaining the premiums paid for large acquisitions: evidence of ceo hubris. administrative science quarterly, 42(1), 103. https://doi.org/10.2307/ 2393810 hendricks,b.,howell,t.,&bingham,c.(2019).howmuchdotopmanagementteamsmatterinfounderled firms? strategic management journal, 40(6), 959–986. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.3006 hernandez, m. (2012). toward an understanding of the psychology of stewardship. academy of management review, 37(2), 172–193. https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.2010.0363 hildebrand, c., anterasian, c., & brugg, j. (2020). predicting ceo success: when potential outperforms experience. hill, c. w. l., & jones, t. m. (1992). stakeholder-agency theory. journal of management studies, 29(2), 131–154. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6486.1992.tb00657.x hill, c. w. l., & snell, s. a. (1988). external control, corporate strategy, and firm performance in researchintensive industries. strategic management journal, 9(6), 577–590. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj. 4250090605 hillman, a. j., cannella, a. a., & paetzold, r. l. (2000). the resource dependence role of corporate directors: strategic adaptation of board composition in response to environmental change. journal of management studies, 37(2), 235–256. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-6486.00179 hillman, a. j., keim, g. d., & luce, r. a. (2001). board composition and stakeholder performance: do stakeholder directors make a difference? business & society, 40(3), 295–314. https://doi.org/10. 1177/000765030104000304 hoppmann, j., naegele, f., & girod, b. (2019). boards as a source of inertia: examining the internal challenges and dynamics of boards of directors in times of environmental discontinuities. academy of management journal, 62(2), 437–468. https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2016.1091 hou, w., priem, r. l., & goranova, m. (2017). does one size fit all? investigating pay–future performance relationships over the “seasons” of ceo tenure. journal of management, 43(3), 864–891. https: //doi.org/10.1177/0149206314544744 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.172 https://doi.org/10.2307/2393656 https://doi.org/10.2307/259186 https://doi.org/10.2307/259186 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.3112 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.3112 https://doi.org/10.2307/257828 https://doi.org/10.2307/41165269 https://doi.org/10.2307/2393056 https://doi.org/10.2307/2393056 https://doi.org/10.2307/2393810 https://doi.org/10.2307/2393810 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.3006 https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.2010.0363 https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6486.1992.tb00657.x https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.4250090605 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.4250090605 https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-6486.00179 https://doi.org/10.1177/000765030104000304 https://doi.org/10.1177/000765030104000304 https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2016.1091 https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206314544744 https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206314544744 gilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 18 hurley, a. e., fagenson-eland, e. a., & sonnenfeld, j. a. (1997). does cream always rise to the top? an investigation of career attainment determinants. organizational dynamics, 26(2), 65–71. https: //doi.org/10.1016/s0090-2616(97)90006-1 james, l. r., demaree, r. g., & wolf, g. (1984). estimating within-group interrater reliability with and without response bias. journal of applied psychology, 69(1), 85–98. https://doi.org/10.1037/00219010.69.1.85 james, l. r., demaree, r. g., & wolf, g. (1993). rwg: an assessment of within-group interrater agreement. journal of applied psychology, 78(2), 306–309. https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.78.2. 306 jayaraman, n., khorana, a., nelling, e., & covin, j. (2000). ceo founder status and firm financial performance. strategic management journal, 21(12), 1215–1224. https://doi.org/10.1002/10970266(200012)21:12<1215::aid-smj146>3.0.co;2-0 jensen, m. c., & meckling, w. h. (1976). theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. journal of financial economics, 3(4), 305–360. https://doi.org/10.1016/ 0304-405x(76)90026-x johnson, j. l., daily, c. m., & ellstrand, a. e. (1996). boards of directors: a review and research agenda. journal of management, 22(3), 409–438. https://doi.org/10.1177/014920639602200303 johnson, r. a., hoskisson, r. e., & hitt, m. a. (1993). board of director involvement in restructuring: the effects of board versus managerial controls and characteristics. strategic management journal, 14(s1), 33–50. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.4250140905 jones, t. m., & goldberg, l. d. (1982). governing the large corporation: more arguments for public directors. the academy of management review, 7(4), 603. https://doi.org/10.2307/257227 joseph, j., ocasio, w., & mcdonnell, m.-h. (2014). the structural elaboration of board independence: executive power, institutional logics, and the adoption of ceo-only board structures in u.s. corporate governance. academy of management journal, 57(6), 1834–1858. https://doi.org/10. 5465/amj.2012.0253 judge, w. q., & zeithaml, c. p. (1992). institutional and strategic choice perspectives on board involvement in the strategic decision process. academy of management journal, 35(4), 766–794. https: //doi.org/10.5465/256315 krause, r., li, w., ma, x., & bruton, g. d. (2019). the board chair effect across countries: an institutional view. strategic management journal, 40(10), 1570–1592. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.3057 krause, r., withers, m. c., & semadeni, m. (2017). compromise on the board: investigating the antecedents and consequences of lead independent director appointment. academy of management journal, 60(6), 2239–2265. https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2015.0852 kroll, m., simmons, s. a., & wright, p. (1990). determinants of chief executive officer compensation following major acquisitions. journal of business research, 20(4), 349–366. https://doi.org/10. 1016/0148-2963(90)90011-2 lee, j. m., yoon, d., & boivie, s. (2020). founder ceo succession: the role of ceo organizational identification. academy of management journal, 63(1), 224–245. https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2017.0091 lewicki, r. j., & bunker, b. b. (1996). developing and maintaining trust in work relationships. in trust in organizations: frontiers of theory and research (pp. 114–139). sage publications, inc. https: //doi.org/10.4135/9781452243610 luoma, p., & goodstein, j. (1999). research notes. stakeholders and corporate boards: institutional influences on board composition and structure. academy of management journal, 42(5), 553– 563. https://doi.org/10.2307/256976 https://doi.org/10.1016/s0090-2616(97)90006-1 https://doi.org/10.1016/s0090-2616(97)90006-1 https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.69.1.85 https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.69.1.85 https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.78.2.306 https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.78.2.306 https://doi.org/10.1002/1097-0266(200012)21:12<1215::aid-smj146>3.0.co;2-0 https://doi.org/10.1002/1097-0266(200012)21:12<1215::aid-smj146>3.0.co;2-0 https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405x(76)90026-x https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405x(76)90026-x https://doi.org/10.1177/014920639602200303 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.4250140905 https://doi.org/10.2307/257227 https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2012.0253 https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2012.0253 https://doi.org/10.5465/256315 https://doi.org/10.5465/256315 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.3057 https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2015.0852 https://doi.org/10.1016/0148-2963(90)90011-2 https://doi.org/10.1016/0148-2963(90)90011-2 https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2017.0091 https://doi.org/10.4135/9781452243610 https://doi.org/10.4135/9781452243610 https://doi.org/10.2307/256976 gilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 19 magnan, m., st-onge, s., & calloc’h, y. (1999). feature editorial-governance-power games: when it comes to s ceo’s compensation and performance, who holds the balance of the board? nothing less than good corporate governance is at stake. ivey business journal, 63(3), 38–43. mallette, p., & fowler, k. l. (1992). effects of board composition and stock ownership on the adoption of “poison pills”. academy of management journal, 35(5), 1010–1035. https://doi.org/10.5465/ 256538 mayer, r. c., davis, j. h., & schoorman, f. d. (1995). an integrative model of organizational trust. the academy of management review, 20(3), 709. https://doi.org/10.2307/258792 mcallister, d. j. (1995). affectand cognition-based trust as foundations for interpersonal cooperation in organizations. academy of management journal, 38(1), 24–59. https://doi.org/10.2307/256727 miller, j. s., & wiseman, r. m. (2001). perceptions of executive pay: does pay enhance a leader’s aura?: perceptions of executive pay. journal of organizational behavior, 22(6), 703–711. https://doi.org/ 10.1002/job.110 nelson, t. (2003). the persistence of founder influence: management, ownership, and performance effects at initial public offering. strategic management journal, 24(8), 707–724. https://doi.org/ 10.1002/smj.328 newman, h. a., & mozes, h. a. (1999). does the composition of the compensation committee influence ceo compensation practices? financial management, 28(3), 41. https://doi.org/10.2307/ 3666182 pearce, j. a., & zahra, s. a. (1992). board composition from a strategic contingency perspective. journal of management studies, 29(4), 411–438. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6486.1992.tb00672.x pennings, j. m., lee, k., & witteloostuijn, a. v. (1998). human capital, social capital, and firm dissolution. academy of management journal, 41(4), 425–440. https://doi.org/10.5465/257082 pfeffer, j., & fong, c. t. (2003). assessing business schools: reply to connolly. academy of management learning & education, 2(4), 368–370. https://doi.org/10.5465/amle.2003.11901962 pfeffer, j., & salancik, g. r. (1978). the external control of organizations: a resource dependence perspective. harper & row. quigley, t. j., hambrick, d. c., misangyi, v. f., & rizzi, g. a. (2019). ceo selection as risk-taking: a new vantage on the debate about the consequences of insiders versus outsiders. strategic management journal, 40(9), 1453–1470. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.3033 rousseau, d. m., sitkin, s. b., burt, r. s., & camerer, c. (1998). not so different after all: a cross-discipline viewoftrust. academyofmanagementreview, 23(3),393–404. https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.1998. 926617 sigler, k. j., & porterfield, r. (2001). ceo compensation: its link to bank performance. american business review, 19(2), 110. sitkin,s.b.,&roth,n.l. (1993).explainingthelimitedeffectivenessoflegalistic“remedies”fortrust/distrust. organization science, 4(3), 367–392. https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.4.3.367 strickland, l. h. (1958). surveillance and trust1. journal of personality, 26(2), 200–215. https://doi.org/ 10.1111/j.1467-6494.1958.tb01580.x stroh, l. k., brett, j. m., baumann, j. p., & reilly, a. h. (1996). agency theory and variable pay compensation strategies. academy of management journal, 39(3), 751–767. https://doi.org/10.5465/ 256663 vesper, k. h. (1996). new venture experience: entrepreneurship, text, exercises, cases (rev. ed., 2. print). vector books. weisbach, m. s. (1988). outside directors and ceo turnover. journal of financial economics, 20, 431–460. https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405x(88)90053-0 https://doi.org/10.5465/256538 https://doi.org/10.5465/256538 https://doi.org/10.2307/258792 https://doi.org/10.2307/256727 https://doi.org/10.1002/job.110 https://doi.org/10.1002/job.110 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.328 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.328 https://doi.org/10.2307/3666182 https://doi.org/10.2307/3666182 https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6486.1992.tb00672.x https://doi.org/10.5465/257082 https://doi.org/10.5465/amle.2003.11901962 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.3033 https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.1998.926617 https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.1998.926617 https://doi.org/10.1287/orsc.4.3.367 https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6494.1958.tb01580.x https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6494.1958.tb01580.x https://doi.org/10.5465/256663 https://doi.org/10.5465/256663 https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405x(88)90053-0 gilley et al. / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:1-20 20 westphal, j. d., & zajac, e. j. (1995). who shall govern? ceo/board power, demographic similarity, and new director selection. administrative science quarterly, 40(1), 60. https://doi.org/10.2307/ 2393700 wright, p., kroll, m., & elenkov, d. (2002). acquisition returns, increase in firm size, and chief executive officer compensation: the moderating role of monitoring. academy of management journal, 45(3), 599–608. https://doi.org/10.5465/3069384 zahra, s. a., & pearce, j. a. (1989). boards of directors and corporate financial performance: a review and integrative model. journal of management, 15(2), 291–334. https://doi.org/10.1177/ 014920638901500208 zantout, z. z., & o’reilly-allen, m. (1996). determinants of corporate strategy and gains of acquiring firms. journal of accounting, auditing & finance, 11(1), 119–129. https : / / doi . org / 10 . 1177 / 0148558x9601100105 zhang, y. (2006). the presence of a separate coo/president and its impact on strategic change and ceo dismissal. strategic management journal, 27(3), 283–300. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.517 zhu, q., hu, s., & shen, w. (2020). why do some insider ceos make more strategic changes than others? the impact of prior board experience on new ceo insiderness. strategic management journal, 41(10), 1933–1951. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.3183 https://doi.org/10.2307/2393700 https://doi.org/10.2307/2393700 https://doi.org/10.5465/3069384 https://doi.org/10.1177/014920638901500208 https://doi.org/10.1177/014920638901500208 https://doi.org/10.1177/0148558x9601100105 https://doi.org/10.1177/0148558x9601100105 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.517 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.3183 introduction theory development ceo characteristics as antecedents of trustworthiness propositions ceo characteristics the governance effects of ceo trustworthiness board perceptions of ceo trustworthiness: individual assessments and group decisions. discussion and conclusions implications for research implications for governance practice 48 journal of business strategies oklahoma oil and natural gas severance taxes: a comparative analysis mary n. gade oklahoma state university • stillwater, ok karen maguire oklahoma state university • stillwater, ok francis makamu oklahoma state university • stillwater, ok abstract oklahoma assesses a production tax of seven percent on the extraction of oil, natural gas, and other minerals. however, since july 2002, it has taxed production from horizontal wells at one percent for the first 48 months of production. this is a significant tax incentive relative to the neighboring state of texas, particularly considering the limited evidence of the effectiveness of severance tax incentives for increasing in-state development of immobile resources. this paper examines whether the tax incentive encouraged horizontal development in oklahoma relative to texas. our findings indicate that the incentive is not associated with an increase in development. keywords: severance tax, oil and natural gas, hydraulic fracturing jel codes: h71, h73, q32, q35, q48 introduction the development of horizontal drilling and hydraulic fracturing technologies has triggered a resurgence in oil and natural gas production in the united states. state governments levy different types of production taxes on these unconventional wells, at different rates, with a diverse mix of exemptions, deductions, and incentives. these tax policies are designed to encourage industry activity, development, job creation, and to enhance economic benefits to the state. the state of oklahoma has carried one of the lowest effective tax rates on horizontal wells when compared to peer states.1 the low rate is partly triggered by a 1 throughout the paper, references to horizontal drilling and horizontal wells, refer to those wells that use a combination of horizontal drilling and hydraulically fracturing to access unconventional oil and natural gas resources. these are commonly referred to as fracked or hydraulically fractured wells. see fitzgerald (2012) for a detailed discussion of the economics of fracking. volume 35, number 1 49 four-year production tax holiday that reduces the tax on newly completed horizontal wells from seven to one percent in the first 48 months of production. this tax break has a significant impact on state revenues, but its effect on drilling activity is an open question. this paper empirically examines whether the horizontal wells severance tax incentive has encouraged horizontal drilling activity in oklahoma relative to texas. for the second straight year, oklahomans are faced with nearly a $1-billiondollar budget shortfall (kfor 2017; newson6 2015). according to the oklahoma policy institute, the proposed budget is 15.6 percent below the fiscal year 2009 budget and 39 out of 73 agencies that are allocated state budget funds have been cut by 20 percent or more since then (ok policy 2017). the state’s budget issues have been blamed on a number of factors, including drops in the corporate income tax, an increase in the cost of various tax incentives, and falling oil prices (ok policy 2017; wertz 2016). specifically, the oklahoma policy institute argues that “tax incentives have more than doubled between 2010 and 2014” and that the largest of these incentives are from “lower tax rates on oil and gas production” (ok policy 2017). previous theoretical literature on oil and gas taxes by haughton and tuerck (2006), modeled a proposed indirect processing tax in louisiana on oil and gas produced in the outer continental shelf (ocs) and determined that there would be short term gains in state tax revenue, but they were not sustained over the long term. previous empirical literature has examined the effects of the state’s political environment on oil and gas development and found that price rather than politics determined oil and gas development (maguire 2012). although, on federal lands, the regulatory environment was a key factor in the amount of oil and gas leasing (maguire 2016).2 other work has examined the effects of oil and gas development on regional economic outcomes such as unemployment with mixed results (lee 2015; munasib & rickman 2015; weinstein 2014; weber, 2014; weber 2012; michaels, 2010). to our knowledge, our study is the first to examine the effects of oklahoma’s horizontal well tax incentives. the subject is of interest as oklahoma offers a generous exemption on horizontal production while other neighboring states, such as texas, do not. providing tax incentives would be considered an effective policy for the state if it stimulates development. however, the alternative would suggest that additional production is profitable to firms regardless of the incentives and 2 oklahoma and texas do not have significant federal lands. (blm, public land statistics) 50 journal of business strategies extending tax breaks only harms oklahoma’s economy by reducing its tax revenue. the contemporary tiebout (1956) tax competition literature devotes much attention to the question of whether or not state tax differentials have an empirical impact on the location of economic activity. theoretically, when a jurisdiction lowers its tax rate on a mobile capital base, the net of tax return rises above that available elsewhere, and capital flows in until net of tax returns are equalized across all jurisdictions. the resulting incentive is that a lower tax rate on capital relative to surrounding jurisdictions has the potential to encourage economic activity as part of state development policy. thus, states utilize exemptions, deductions, and other tax incentives in an effort to stimulate economic development. most of the empirical work on state tax incentives centers on the effects of state taxation on geographically mobile capital with mixed results. evidence ranges from a positive influence of incentives on location (bartik 1985; helms 1985; bartik 1989; papke 1991; papke 1994; holmes, 1998; strauss-kahn & vives, 2009) to a small effect or none at all (schmenner 1982; plaut & pluta 1983; carlton 1983; schmenner, huber & cook 1987; blair & premus 1987; dabney 1991; tannenwald 1996; lee 2008). literature reviews also suggest that the results are somewhat ambiguous (wasylenko 1999; buss 2001; and arauzo-carod, liviano-solis, & manjón-antolín, 2010). examination of the effects of state severance tax incentives on oil and gas drilling and production activity requires an alternative perspective. nonrenewable natural resources are geographically immobile. firms engaged in oil and gas production cannot change location to the extent that their main capital consists of the immobile reserve base. therefore, state severance tax preferences cannot encourage relocation across jurisdictions. firms can respond, however, by altering the level and timing of extraction as state tax policy changes. the introduction of horizontal drilling along with hydraulic fracturing technology has expanded the ability of firms to profitably recover natural gas and oil from unconventional sources (eia 2011). however, horizontal drilling comes with higher costs relative to conventional drilling. a horizontal well can cost between 25 to 300 percent more to drill and complete. due to the difference in cost structure, horizontal drilling is restricted to geological plays with low permeability where conventional wells would not be considered economically viable (helms, 2008). there have been few empirical studies that look at how firms in nonrenewable resource industries respond to state tax incentives. they have included simulation and/or econometric studies of the relationship between a specific tax policy and natural resource exploration and production. for example, kunce, gerking, and volume 35, number 1 51 maddux, (2003) simulate the effects of state tax policy changes in wyoming on both the level and timing of exploration and output in the state. the simulation is based on the standard model of natural resource supply from pindyck (1978) and estimates exploration costs, production of reserve additions, and extraction costs for wyoming while incorporating the specific tax parameters that are of interest to the industry. in contrast, leighty and lin (2012) estimate field-specific cost functions based on cost and production data from alaska’s north slope and use those estimated equations to model production decisions and simulate the impact of tax policy on the production rate. lastly, black, mccoy, and weber (2016), find that taxes on the impacts of drilling in pennsylvania, which could act as a deterrent to oil and gas development, have instead not led to significant declines. the conclusions drawn from these studies and others suggest that the volume of oil and natural gas production and drilling activity is insensitive to severance tax rate changes (see also helmski-oskou, narayanan, glover, lyon, & sinha 1992; kunce, 2003; chakravorty, gerking, & leach, 2010; kaiser 2012). in this paper, we build on this existing literature by examining whether oklahoma’s severance tax reduction has led to disparate effects for horizontal versus conventional drilling as compared with texas. our findings suggest that the oklahoma tax exemption has not significantly increased horizontal drilling activity. background oil and natural gas resources oklahoma and texas are not only among the states to apply the lowest oil and gas production taxes in the nation, but are also among the major contributors of oil and gas in the country. the states are selected in this study for their regional proximity as well as their long history of oil and gas production. for the period 1982 to 2013, texas had the highest production (onshore) of natural gas and oklahoma comes in third position (eia 2015). the hugoton gas field which contains one of the largest producing natural gas fields in the u.s. is located in southwestern kansas, but includes parts of the texas and oklahoma panhandles. in 2013, texas accounted for 29 percent of the country’s marketed gas production, well above any other state. oklahoma accounted for 7.1 percent of the u.s. natural gas production and 8.4 percent of the u.s. marketed production in 2013. oklahoma is one of the leading states in terms of the number of gas wells drilled, only behind ohio, pennsylvania, west virginia and texas. texas is also the leading oil producing state with production 52 journal of business strategies levels sometimes exceeding the federal offshore areas. oklahoma ranked fifth in crude oil production in the nation in 2014 (eia 2016). horizontal drilling and hydraulic fracturing horizontal drilling combined with hydraulic fracturing technology allows producers to develop deposits of oil and natural gas that are trapped in deep shale and tight sands formations often one mile below the surface (api 2009). the concept of hydraulic fracturing was developed in 1891, and implemented for the first time in texas around 1929, but it only become commercially viable in the 1980s. the cost of horizontal drilling is generally higher than the conventional vertical drilling, up to 300 percent. however, when financially viable a horizontal drill can produce 2.5 to 7 times the rate and reserves of conventional wells and allow producers to access once economically infeasible resources (king, 1993). for approximately 10 years beginning in the early 2000s, the price of oil and natural gas was rising making more expensive and complicated methods like hydraulic fracturing more attractive.3 it should be noted that gas prices have declined since 2008 and oil prices have fallen significantly recently, leading to a reduction in oil and gas development activity, but this decline occurred largely after our sample period, which ends in 2013 (arezki & blanchard, 2014; asche, oglend & osmundsen, 2012; baffes, kose, & stocker, 2015). state severance tax structures: oklahoma, texas tax structures are not easy to compare as they vary across states and at different levels of government authority, i.e. federal, state, and local jurisdictions. to address this problem, the literature often makes use of the effective tax rates, taxes divided by production value, in order to account for various form of tax incentives granted by states. for example, including severance, property, income and sale taxes, oklahoma and texas have in fy 2010-2011 effective tax rates between 7.4 and 8.4 percent (carey 2014). although their effective tax rates are similar, there are major differences in their tax structures. for example, texas does not levy a corporate income tax while oklahoma does. in addition, counties can impose property taxes on drilling companies, which are independent of the well’s economic value, but the revenue from taxation on structures and equipment are generally not as large as the revenue obtained from the severance tax (kunce & morgan, 2005). also, state and 3 u.s. energy information administration. 2015. u.s natural gas prices. wellhead price from 1922 to 2012. volume 35, number 1 53 federal corporate income taxes are levied on the firm profit and have very little effect on the firm’s decision to explore and produce. they are more likely to affect future drilling investments and output, rather than the actual number of drilling permits issued (deacon, 1993). states grant numerous exemptions and credits to oil and gas producers (kunce, 2003). for example, oklahoma and texas offer exemptions for inactive wells for at least a certain period after the date of certification of two or three years of inactivity. their tax structures also differ on other features. the oklahoma gross severance tax rate on gas is 7 percent when the price of gas exceeds $2.10 per thousand cubic feet (mcf). the state offers exemptions on severance tax for recovery projects, inactive wells (reestablished production), horizontally drilled wells, new discovery wells, and seismic exploration. since 2002, oklahoma has exempted gas production from horizontal drilling to claim only 1 percent for the first four years of production.4 it is the most generous exemption provided by the state which can be claimed by drilling companies for unlimited production for the first forty-eight months regardless of the current market price. like oklahoma, texas has taxed oil and gas production at a rate of 7.5 percent of the market value of gas produced and 4.6 percent of the market value of oil produced.5 (see appendix: table a2 for detailed information on state tax incentives for oklahoma and texas.) the state has provided natural gas tax incentives since 1989 in the form of an exemption for production of gas with higher drilling costs (“high cost gas”) and inactive wells, both for a period of ten years. the tax benefits have been extended several times and made permanent in 2003. more important to our identification, the tax code does not include production tax exemptions for horizontally drilled wells in oil and gas production.6 overall, and essential to our identification strategy, unlike oklahoma, texas does not provide tax incentives that specifically target horizontal drilling. also, texas has not enacted a major change in their tax code for other types of production. texas has not revised chapter 201, its administrative code on tax exemption for natural gas, since 1997, except for minor modifications in 2005 and 2009 (house bill 2161 and senate bill 997). there was also a myriad of minor regulatory changes, but no major statewide regulatory changes over the period (occ 2016, rrc 2016). the empirical specification will control for static differences in the regulatory and tax structure 4 oklahoma statutes. chapter 68 §1001 (e). 5 texas tax code. chapter 201 section 52 (a). 6 other exemptions comprise gas production from low producing wells on and after 2005 and gas production in association with geothermal energy production after 2009. 54 journal of business strategies between texas and oklahoma, but does not control for dynamic regulatory or tax changes occurring over the sample period in either texas or oklahoma. however, our research, indicates that there have not been major relevant regulatory or tax policy changes over the sample. while it is clear that increases in oil and gas production lead to increases in tax revenue, it is not clear that the reduction in oklahoma’s severance tax rate for horizontal wells will lead to additional oil and gas development. this paper focuses on the empirical question of whether the tax credit on horizontal drilling in oklahoma is associated with an increase in drilling permits relative to texas. data for our analysis, the number of oil and natural gas permits issued serves as our measure of oil and gas development. the steps in the development process include permitting, drilling, completion, and production. in each step after the initial drilling permit is issued, firms face additional costs and resource constraints in order to complete the well development process. for this reason, the number of permits issued provides the best measure of the influence of a tax policy on a firm’s initial oil and gas development decision without the confounding effects of subsequent changes in development costs and other constraints facing these firms. the permit provides the firm with authorization to drill in the designated location abiding by any state restrictions regarding drilling methods.7 therefore, the measure provides a complete set of oil and gas development activity; for each oil or natural gas well drilled in a state, the state’s oil and gas commission requires a permit. the drilling permit data for the analysis were collected from the relevant state oil and gas and or geologic agency; the oil and gas division of the oklahoma corporation commission and the railroad commission of texas.8 each drilling permit is categorized by the relevant agency as conventional or horizontal. in addition, permits are designated as oil, natural gas, or simply oil and gas.9 data are collected for the sample period 1995-2013 and aggregated to the month-county level for each county during the sample period. in addition to permit data, we 7 the permits typically require that drilling begin within 6 months to a year from the issue date and expire if not used. the number of permits issued and the number applied for are essentially the same. for example, in oklahoma over the sample period only 20 permits were rejected. in order to eliminate those few cases where permits were denied, we used only approved permits in the measure. 8 permits for oil and gas drilling and recompletion were considered. permits for other wells such as injection wells are excluded from the analysis. for texas, only onshore permits are analyzed. 9 for permits for oil and gas drilling that were not categorized separately as oil or natural gas, we defaulted to a joint oil and gas category. volume 35, number 1 55 also collected data on monthly oil and natural gas prices by state from the energy information association (eia).10 data on population and personal income at the county-year level were collected from the bureau of economic analysis (bea). lastly, information on whether a county is a metro or non-metro and whether the counties were consistent oil and gas producing counties were collected from the economic research service of the united states department of agriculture (ersusda). empirical specification the paper empirically examines whether the severance tax reduction in oklahoma in 2002 is associated with an increase in the amount of horizontal drilling relative to texas. the empirical analysis measures the influence of the horizontal drilling severance tax policy in oklahoma on the number of drilling permits issued. by using a difference in difference approach we can examine whether oklahoma’s state policy is associated with differences in the number of horizontal and conventional drilling permits issued in oklahoma as compared with texas. the main specification of the fixed effects model is: where i = county, j = state, t = month, and y = year (y) represents the county-month number of permits issued. (r) is an indicator of the oklahoma tax policy of interest. (t) is the time period when the oklahoma tax policy is in effect. (price) is a state-month real oil or natural gas price.11 (inc) is county-year real personal income. lastly, (pop) is the county-year population. the difference-in-difference (did) technique that is used relies on the assumption that changes in drilling permits over time would have been the same in both the treatment, oklahoma, and control state, texas, in the absence of the intervention. figure 1, shows that from 1995 through the early 2000s, the share of conventional and horizontal drilling permits approved was constant for both 10 for oil prices, we used the eia first purchase price, while for natural gas prices we used the eia citygate price; first purchase or wellhead prices for natural gas were discontinued in 2013. 11 the policy change in oklahoma was implemented in large part to promote the implementation of hydraulic fracturing technology and increase oil and gas development in oklahoma. while oil and natural gas prices vary by state, they are highly correlated across states and texas did not adopt the same tax policy. technology, which is clearly correlated with price, was the main factor in oklahoma’s decision, though some correlation between the policy and price cannot be ruled out. 56 journal of business strategies states. this is due largely to the absence of hydraulic fracturing technology prior to the mid-2000s and its rapid adoption throughout the united states thereafter. the extent to which the rise in horizontal drilling in oklahoma demonstrated in figure 1 is due to this technological advancement and the degree to which it was influenced by the tax policy in oklahoma is therefore an empirical question. by differencing out the availability of hydraulic fracturing technology, which was also available in texas we are focused on identifying the oklahoma tax policy impacts. specifically, the county and month fixed effects specification controls for all time invariant county characteristics, and the effects of seasonal and annual national economic and policy changes that influenced both oklahoma and texas. still, the possibility of endogeneity exists due to unmeasured county-level heterogeneity in resource potential, which may lead to changes in the number of permits issued and the implementation of the tax policy. in order to control for resource availability, we have used an alternative sample to focus on geologically similar regions across states as designated by the united states geologic survey (usgs).12 in addition, to address concerns over unmeasured local economic factors, we have controlled for dynamic changes in personal income and population. results for the full sample are provided below. results the findings in table 1 indicate that there is not a robust statistically significant relationship between the implementation of the oklahoma tax policy in 2002 and the number of horizontal permits issued. despite the dramatic increase in horizontal drilling demonstrated in figure 2, the results suggest that the tax break was not a determining factor, rather it was oil prices that had a significant influence.13 the rise in horizontal drilling was not limited to oklahoma. figure 2 also shows marked growth in the number of horizontal drilling permits in texas, which did not have the policy. clearly, the technological expansion of horizontal drilling crossed state lines and led to growth in permitting in both texas and oklahoma. oil prices have the expected finding, an increase in oil price is associated with an increase in both horizontal and conventional drilling permits. the coefficient of 12 the data used in the empirical specification do not allow us to entirely control for differences in the amount of increase in oil and natural gas resource by county. while the regions are designated as geologically similar by the usgs, the usgs does not indicate the entire region has the same level of oil and natural gas resources. using an alternative data set or empirical technique that controls for resource heterogeneity at the well level is left for future work. 13 in addition, natural gas prices were also considered and the statistical and economic significance of the policy intervention were consistent when the analyses were conducted using natural gas rather than oil prices. results available upon request. volume 35, number 1 57 0.0038 on oil price in table 1a column 1 combined with the standard deviation for oil price of 28.16 suggests that a one standard deviation increase in oil prices increases county month horizontal permits issued by 0.11. this is an economically significant relationship given that the mean number of horizontal permits issued over the sample period is 1.06. the finding for conventional permits is also statistically significant. the results in table 1b, column 1 indicate that a one standard deviation increase in oil prices is associated with a 0.65 increase in the county-month conventional permits issued. this is also an economically significant finding given that the mean number of conventional drilling permits issued is 3.73. the findings for both horizontal and conventional permits indicate that there is not a consistently significant relationship between either horizontal or conventional drilling and the implementation of oklahoma’s tax policy. robustness checks for the main sample are examined below. oil and gas resource availability there are several distinct geologic areas throughout the sample area. the usgs central region energy team assessed the oil and gas resources of the united states and developed geologic boundaries for the oil and gas resource assessment project from 2005 through 2012. each region, called a province, is defined by major geologic changes.14 (see figure 3) the amount of oil and natural gas resource available is a key factor in determining the amount of drilling that will take place. figure 4 shows that texas has more oil and gas resources than oklahoma and a larger increase in resources over the sample period.15 the heterogeneity in resource availability may confound the effects of the tax policy, i.e. differences in the state’s resource availability may lead to differential development behavior by firms independent of the tax policy. in order to control for resource availability, we analyzed a sample of counties which are in geologic regions that overlap the boundaries of the states.16 the assumption underlying this analysis is that counties in the same geologic region would be expected to have the same development potential before and after 2002, but for the change in oklahoma’s tax policy. the findings for horizontal permitting remain consistent with the full sample 14 see http://energy.usgs.gov/oilgas/assessmentsdata/nationaloilgasassessment.aspx#.vw3pcc-6dpj, http://certmapper. cr.usgs.gov/data/noga00/natl/spatial/geodatabase/usprov12gdb.zip 15 proved reserves can increase due to an increase in resource price, technological growth, or through an expansion in oil and gas drilling activity (eia 2017). 16 the provinces that are included in the overlapping regions sample are the anadarko basin and the bend arch-fort worth basin. 58 journal of business strategies if the analysis is completed for the overlapping geologic regions sample. table 1, column 2 indicates that the policy is not statistically significantly associated with a change in horizontal permitting. still, there may be differences in the amount of increase in oil or gas resources between texas and oklahoma counties in the overlapping regions sample due to differential changes in proved reserves. our analysis does not control for these differences, but does provide a robustness check for the previous results using a more homogeneous resource area. the finding for conventional permitting becomes insignificant and changes sign, indicating that the negative coefficient found in the main sample may have been due to the heterogeneity in resource availability in the full sample. in this sample, there is not a statistically significant effect from the policy. share of permits figure 2 shows that texas has issued considerably more permits than oklahoma. in order to determine if the findings are driven by variation in the magnitude of the number of permits issued, we have also analyzed the share of conventional and horizontal permits. table 1, columns 3 show that for the alternative dependent variable, share of permits, the results for horizontal permitting become significant while conventional drilling remains insignificant. specifically, the findings in table 1a indicate that after the implementation of the tax policy, horizontal permitting increased. importantly, however, the positive significant findings regarding horizontal permitting are limited to the construction of this alternative dependent variable and are not robust across specifications. permits – oil and gas the findings thus far have distinguished permits by type, horizontal or conventional permit, but not by fuel, oil or natural gas. in order to determine if the tax policy was differentially affecting oil and gas permits, we examined the number of permits issued for wells other than oil wells. oil and gas permits are often issued for oil and gas wells jointly, rather than specifically designating either oil or gas individually. in addition, many wells produce oil and natural gas with the ratio of oil and natural gas produced used to determine whether the well is designated oil or natural gas in a particular year. in order to analyze the permits separately, we constructed a variable that is a measure of the total number of county-month permits minus those that were designated as oil permits. the findings in table 1a, column 4 indicate that the results for horizontal permits are insignificant. the policy did have a volume 35, number 1 59 negative and statistically significant relationship with conventional permitting in this sample, but once again the magnitude and direction of influence are not consistent across specifications for the conventional permits. resource rich counties previously, we restricted the sample to overlapping geologic regions in order to analyze a more homogeneous sample in terms of the oil and gas resource availability. for this analysis, we focus on resource rich counties defined as those with continuous oil and/or gas production as reported by ers-usda.18 this specification highlights the potential differences in the relationship between the policy and counties that had marginal resource development versus counties that had continuous resource development. the analysis focuses on a more homogeneous sample in terms of resource development. the findings in table 1a, column 5 indicate that horizontal permitting declined in this sample full sample, the coefficient on the policy variable was -1.18, but for resource rich counties the decline was less -0.218. the results are not consistent with the previous results, and do not support the hypothesis that oklahoma’s tax policy increased horizontal drilling. the policy influence on conventional permitting is also negative, but there is no differential relationship between the policy in marginal and resource rich counties. the lack of a consistent magnitude and direction for the tax policy on horizontal or conventional drilling indicate that there was not a robust statistically significant finding. conclusion and discussion oklahoma’s severance tax reduction was designed to promote the adoption of what was at the time a technological advancement in drilling. resource rich states, such as oklahoma rely on tax revenue from energy production in order to meet their fiscal obligations. this reliance has proven particularly salient recently as oklahoma faces a budget shortfall. according to the oklahoma policy institute, this shortfall is due not only to declining oil and gas production due to falling prices, but to tax incentives, both income and the severance tax reduction (ok policy 2016, 2017). prior to the current environment of declining energy prices, the boom in oil and gas drilling that followed the adoption of hydraulic fracturing technology was credited with providing jobs and revenue for state and local governments. the state tax implications of increased oil and gas production seem clear, but the benefits of 18 see http://www.ers.usda.gov/data-products/county-level-oil-and-gas-production-in-the-us.aspx. the data on oil and gas production cover the period 2000-2011. 60 journal of business strategies the tax break can only be realized if the industry responds by ramping up production when the policy is implemented. industry leaders, including the three largest oil companies in oklahoma indicated that they would reduce drilling if the horizontal tax reduction was allowed to lapse, resulting in a production tax increase back to the full seven percent from the reduced one percent (veith, 2014). the results in this paper suggest, however, that the rise in hydraulic fracturing was due to resource prices, rather than a response from oil and gas producers to the tax policy. in the case of oklahoma’s policy, our findings indicate that the policy is not associated with an increase in horizontal drilling. although no significant effect was found, it is not possible to entirely control for differences in the regulatory and resource environment in texas and oklahoma over the sample period using the current specifications. in terms of the potential for omitted variable bias due to differences in the regulatory environment, we have addressed this by examining the relevant policy environment, presented in appendix a2, and have not found another significant relevant state-level regulatory change during the sample period. in order to address concerns over differences in the growth in resource endowments between oklahoma and texas we have examined the more homogeneous overlapping regions sample and have used the share of permits rather than the absolute number of permits as the dependent variable. across the specifications, the results indicate that there is not a consistent statistically significant association between the oklahoma tax policy and oil and gas development. previous empirical work examining the effect of state tax incentives on geographically mobile capital has found mixed results and this work contributes to that literature; indicating that state tax credits may not provide incentives to increase production for an immobile resource such as oil and natural gas. however, the results also indicate that additional work on the benefits of state tax credits for immobile oil and gas resources is needed in order to determine whether these tax credits are having the desired outcome of increasing oil and gas development. references api (2009). hydraulic fracturing operations, well construction and integrity guidelines. american petroleum institute. api guidance document hf1. http:// www.shalegas.energy.gov/resources/hf1.pdf, accessed september, 09 2015. arauzo-carod, j. m., liviano-solis, d., & manjón-antolín, m. (2010). empirical studies in industrial location: an assessment of their methods and results. journal of regional science, 50(3), 685-711. volume 35, number 1 61 arezki, r., & blanchard, o. (2014). seven questions about the recent oil price slump. imfdirect the imf blog, december 22, 2015. asche, f., oglend, a., & osmundsen, p. (2012). gas versus oil prices the impact of shale gas. energy policy (47), 117-124. baffes, j., kose, a. o., & stocker, m. (april 2015). the great plunge in oil prices: causes, consequences, and policy responses. working paper series. koc universtiy-tusiad economic research forum, 1-60. bartik, t. j. (1985). business location decisions in the united states: estimates of the effects of unionization, taxes, and other characteristics of states. journal of business & economic statistics, 3(1), 14-22. bartik, t. j. (1989). small business start-ups in the united states: estimates of the effects of characteristics of states. southern economic journal, 1004-1018. black, k. j., mccoy, s., & weber, j. g. (2016). when externalities are taxed: the effects and incidence of pennsylvania’s impact fee on shale gas wells. usaee working paper, no. 16-272. blair, j. p., & premus, r. (1987). major factors in industrial location: a review. economic development quarterly, 1(1), 72-85. buss, t. f. (2001). the effect of state tax incentives on economic growth and firm location decisions: an overview of the literature. economic development quarterly, 15(1), 90-105. carey, m. (2014). effective severance tax rates [memorandum], may 11, 2014. colorado legislative council. denver, co. carlton, d. w. (1983). the location and employment choices of new firms: an econometric model with discrete and continuous endogenous variables. the review of economics and statistics, 440-449. chakravorty, u., gerking, s., & leach, a. (2010). state tax policy and oil production. u.s. energy tax policy, 759-774. dabney, d. y. (1991). do enterprise zone incentives affect business location decisions? economic development quarterly, 5(4), 325-334. deacon, r., (1993). taxation, depletion, and welfare: a simulation study of the u.s. petroleum resource. journal of environmental economics and management, volume 24, pp. 159-187. eia (2011). review of emerging resources: u.s. shale gas and shale oil plays, energy information administration, doe. http://www.eia.gov/analysis/studies/ usshalegas/pdf/usshaleplays.pdf. accessed august, 05 2015. 62 journal of business strategies eia (2015). u.s. energy information administration. natural gas gross withdrawals and production. authors’ calculations. http://www.eia.gov/dnav/ng/ng_prod_ sum_a_epg0_fpd_mmcf_a.htm eia (2016). energy information administration. u.s. states: state profiles and energy estimates. https://www.eia.gov/state/ accessed (10/10/16) eia (2017). energy information administration. natural gas: definitions, sources, and explanatory notes. (https://www.eia.gov/dnav/ng/tbldefs/ng_enr_ngl_ tbldef2.asp) accessed (11/1/17) fitzgerald, t. (2012). frackonomics: some economics of hydraulic fracturing. case w. res. l. rev., 63, 1337. haughton, j., & tuerck, d. (2006). the incidence of state taxes on oil and gas. public finance review, 34(5), 527-550. headwaters economics. (2013). unconventional oil and natural gas production tax rates: how does oklahoma compare to peers? bozeman, mt. helms, l.d. (2008). horizontal drilling. north dakota department of mineral resources newsletter, 35(1), pp. 1-3. helms, l. j. (1985). the effect of state and local taxes on economic growth: a time series--cross section approach. the review of economics and statistics, 574-582. helmi-oskoui, b., narayanan, r., glover, t., lyon, k. s., & sinha, m. (1992). optimal extraction of petroleum resources: an empirical approach. resources and energy, 14(3), 267-285. holmes, t. j. (1998). the effect of state policies on the location of manufacturing: evidence from state borders. journal of political economy, 106 (4), 667-705. kaiser, m. j. (2012). modeling the horizontal well severance tax exemption in louisiana. energy, 40(1), 410-427. kfor. (2017). oklahoma faces $878 million shortfall for upcoming year, revenue failure declared. kfor news channel 4. http://kfor.com/2017/02/21/oklahomafaces-878-million-shortfall-for-upcoming-year-revenue-failure-declared/, accessed march 10, 2017. king, r. f. (1993). drilling sideways: a review of horizontal well technology and its domestic application. doe/eia/tr-0565. washington, d.c.: energy information administration. kunce, m. (2003). effectiveness of severance tax incentives in the us oil industry. international tax and public finance, 10(5), 565-587. volume 35, number 1 63 kunce, m., gerking, s., morgan, w., & maddux, r. (2003). state taxation, exploration, and production in the u.s. oil industry. journal of regional science, 43 (4), 749-770. kunce, m., & morgan, w. e. (2005). taxation of oil and gas in the united states 1970-1997. nat. resources j., 45, 77. lee, j. (2015). the regional economic impact of oil and gas extraction in texas. energy policy, 87, 60-71 lee, y. (2008). geographic redistribution of u.s. manufacturing and the role of state development policy. journal of urban economics, 64(2), 436-450. leighty, w., & lin, c. y. c. (2012). tax policy can change the production path: a model of optimal oil extraction in alaska. energy policy, 41, 759-774. maguire, karen. (2012). prices or politics? the influence of markets and political party changes on oil and gas development in the united states, energy economics 34:2013-2020. maguire, karen. (2016). drill baby drill? political influence on federal onshore oil and gas leasing in the western united states. economics of governance, 17 (2), 131-164. michaels, guy (2010). the long term consequences of resource-based specialisation. the economic journal. 121, 31-57. munasib, a., & rickman, d. (2015). regional economic impacts of the shale gas and tight oil boom: a synthetic control analysis. regional science and urban economics, 50, 1-17. newon6 (2015). oklahoma budget shortfall could be $900m in 2016. news on 6. http://www.newson6.com/story/30759089/oklahoma-budget-shortfall-couldbe-900m-in-2016, , accessed march 10, 2017. occ (2016). oklahoma corporation commission: chapter 10 oil and gas conservation (oac 165:10-3-10) in http://www.occeweb.com/rules/rulestxt. htm, accessed january 22, 2016. ok policy (2016). budget trends and outlook – 2016. oklahoma policy institute. http://okpolicy.org/budget-trends-and-outlook-january-2016, accessed january 22, 2016. ok policy (2017). budget trends and outlook — march 2017. oklahoma policy institute. http://okpolicy.org/budget-trends-outlook-march-2017/, accessed march 10, 2017. papke, l. e. (1991). interstate business tax differentials and new firm location: evidence from panel data. journal of public economics, 45(1), 47-68. 64 journal of business strategies papke, l. e. (1994). tax policy and urban development: evidence from the indiana enterprise zone program. journal of public economics, 54(1), 37-49. pindyck, r. s. (1978). the optimal exploration and production of nonrenewable resources. journal of political economy, 86(5), 841-861. plaut, t. r., & pluta, j. e. (1983). business climate, taxes and expenditures, and state industrial growth in the united states. southern economic journal, 99-119. rrc (2016). railroad commission of texas: chapter 3 – oil and gas division (tac 16:1.3) in http://www.rrc.state.tx.us/legal/rules/current-rules/, accessed january 22, 2016. schmenner, r. w. (1982). making business location decisions. prentice hall. schmenner, r. w., huber, j. c., & cook, r. l. (1987). geographic differences and the location of new manufacturing facilities. journal of urban economics, 21(1), 83-104. strauss-kahn, v., & vives, x. (2009). why and where do headquarters move? regional science and urban economics, 39(2), 168-186. tannenwald, r. (1996, january). state business tax climate: how should it be measured and how important is it? in proceedings of the annual conference on taxation held under the auspices of the national tax association-tax institute of america (pp. 225-228). national tax association-tax institute of america. tiebout, c. m. (1956). a pure theory of local expenditures. the journal of political economy, 416-424. veith, warren (2014). drilling tax debate divides industry leaders on the impact of increase. tulsa world. (may 21, 2014) wasylenko, m. (1999). taxation and economic development: the state of the economic literature. public administration and public policy, 72, 309-328. weber, jeremy (2014). a decade of natural gas development: the makings of a resource curse? resource and energy economics. 37, 168-183. weber, jeremy g. 2012. the effects of a natural gas boom on employment and income in colorado, texas, and wyoming. energy economics, 34(5), 15801588. weinstein, amanda l. 2014. unconventional oil and gas development’s impact on state and local economies. choices, 29(4), 1-7. wertz, joe (2016). in oklahoma, low energy prices drive state budget crisis. npr. http://www.npr.org/2016/01/19/463622817/in-oklahoma-low-energyprices-drive-state-budget-crisis, accessed march 20, 2017 wilson, j. d. (1986). a theory of interregional tax competition. journal of urban economics, 19(3), 296-315. volume 35, number 1 65 wilson, j. d. (1999). theories of tax competition. national tax journal, 269-304. biographical sketch of authors mary n. gade is an associate professor and graduate program advisor in the department of economics and legal studies at oklahoma state university. she received her doctorate in economics from michigan state university. her recent work is focused on state and local tax policy, including property tax incidence, tax increment financing, and oil and gas severance taxes in oklahoma. karen maguire is an assistant professor in the department of economics and legal studies at oklahoma state university. she is an active researcher and teacher in the fields of energy economics, environment and resource economics, and regional economics. her primary research and teaching focus is on analyzing energy markets, specifically how politics and policies affect energy development. francis makamu is a visiting instructor in the department of economics and legal studies at oklahoma state university. his research focus is in development economics. 66 journal of business strategies ta bl e 1 m ai n sp ec ifi ca ti on volume 35, number 1 67 figure 1 share of permits (horizontal/conventional) by state figure 2 horizontal and conventional permits by state 68 journal of business strategies figure 3 usgs oil and gas provinces for kansas, oklahoma, and texas figure 4 proved reserves volume 35, number 1 69 appendix 1 summary statistics 70 journal of business strategies appendix 2 summary of key policy changes for gas severance tax exemptions p263501coll9_10.pdf volume 32, number 1 1 does hedging reduce risk? analysis of large domestic airlines garland simmons stephen f. austin state university • nacogdoches, texas abstract in this paper two approaches are applied to understand the hedging behavior of companies which compete in the american airline industry (2007-2014) as they seek to cope with the uncertain, future costs of jet fuel. the first measures the risk that jet fuel prices will fall, a matter of concern to airlines that hedge against rising jet fuel prices, for when jet fuel prices fall, those airlines that have hedged lose money on their hedges. the second describes the risk of hedging or not by using some of the tools of game theory. two different cases are investigated. in the first case airlines compete against one another in a market structure where it is assumed that whether one airline hedges is of no immediate concern to its rivals. in this first case hedging decisions of one airline produce no effects upon other airlines. in the second case airlines compete against one another in the context of an oligopoly. hedging decisions of one airline are connected to the hedging decisions of other airlines. if some airlines hedge jet fuel costs while at the same time others do not, winners and losers are created among the competing airlines. the problem here is that while hedging can fix the price of jet fuel, it cannot guarantee that this fixed price will be lower than the price paid by a rival that did not hedge. the last part of this paper is an empirical data analysis of the differences in jet fuel costs, net of hedging results, is conducted. the null hypothesis that all airlines have equal jet fuel costs after hedge results are accounted for could not be rejected at any reasonable level of confidence. introduction the only purpose of a hedge is to reduce risk. there are different hedge strategies available. some fix the price of an input. other strategies locate the input price below an upper bound or within a range defined by upper and lower bounds. consider the case of an airline wishing to mitigate the effects of an increase in jet fuel prices. this airline may agree to purchase some portion of its future jet fuel usage at a fixed price known today by way of either a forward pricing contract or a swap contract, thus shifting the risk that jet fuel prices might increase to the speculator who 2 journal of business strategies takes the other side of the forward contract or the swap contract. (futures contracts are often used as substitutes for forward contracts.) or an airline may construct a collar around current jet fuel prices. a collar could be constructed by purchasing call options on jet fuel with the exercise price of these calls somewhat above the current level jet fuel prices and by selling put options on jet fuel with the exercise price of these puts somewhat below current jet fuel prices. the effect of this collar would be to fix jet fuel costs within a known range of jet fuel prices. there are other hedging strategies. perhaps the simplest is to buy calls with exercise prices well above the current level of jet fuel prices to insure against a large price increase in jet fuel. readers interested in the nuts and bolts of creating hedges using call options, put options, forward contracts, futures contracts, and swap contracts may consult hull (2009). there are real-world problems with every hedge. there are often problems of basis risk: in some markets jet fuel derivatives are not available, not available in sufficient quantity, or too expensive relative to contracts that are highly correlated with jet fuel price movements. a solution to these difficulties might be to use derivative contracts on heating oil instead of contracts on jet fuel. but heating oil is not the same thing as jet fuel, so the price movements of heating oil and those of jet fuel may be highly correlated, but these changes are not identical. a perfect hedge is impossible in these instances. there are also financial problems that must be addressed. creating hedges requires collateral (margin) to secure performance and/ or cash to make hedge investments. some airlines may be unable to hedge because they had insufficient collateral or not enough cash. of the six airlines studied in this paper four have sought bankruptcy protection in the last 15 years. and financial health remains a problem among large, domestic airlines. in this regard, table 1 contains bond ratings for these companies. of the largest domestic airlines, only southwest airlines is rated as an investment grade risk. the others are rated as below investment grade risks. table 1 bond ratings as of february 2014 united continental american delta southwest jetblue moody’s b1 b1 ba3 baa2 b2 standard & poor’s b b+ bb bbb b fitch b b+ bb bbb b+ source: bloomberg volume 32, number 1 3 rampini, sufi, and viswanathan (2014) find that airlines which are financially vulnerable hedge less than those airlines with stronger balance sheets. in addition to problems of raising money to buy hedge investments or finding assets that can serve as collateral for hedge investments, there is the issue of counterparty risk for those airlines who choose and who are able to afford hedging. every hedge investment is defined by a contract or a collection of contracts. if the other side of the hedge contract (or contracts) does not keep their end of the bargain, then the hedge fails. finally, and of special interest in this paper, there is a problem with hedging that result from competing against rivals within the context of an oligopoly. to see this problem, consider competing airlines within an oligopoly suppose, contrary to the present set of facts which describe the large carriers of the domestic airline industry, all but one of these rival airlines hedge away 100 percent of the jet fuel price risk associated their future jet fuel usage for the next ten years. in doing so each airline that has hedged has done so perfectly without encountering any of the hedging difficulties discussed above, fixing the price of jet fuel for the next ten years. one airline does not hedge any of the jet fuel price risk. and suppose also that after all hedge commitments have been made that will be made by those choosing to hedge, jet fuel prices drop by one-half over the space of six months. should those airlines that have hedged against an increase in jet fuel prices be concerned that jet fuel prices have declined? the answer to this question is yes. why? airlines have some control over the prices that they charge their passengers. if jet fuel prices decline, the airline that chose not to hedge can better afford to reduce the prices that it charges to its passengers because its cost structure is now less than that of its rivals. the main point is this: although hedge contracts can fix input prices so that they are constant, these same hedge contracts cannot guarantee low input prices, low relative to the rival that chose not to hedge. it makes a difference whether all firms in a given oligopoly choose to hedge. if in this oligopoly, competitors all hedge alike, then no airline that fixes the price of its jet fuel will be at a disadvantage if in the future jet fuel prices fall, even though all have locked in fuel costs at an older, higher price. the effort to gain an understanding of the risk that all rivals will not hedge alike motivates this paper. this paper is organized in the following manner. first, brief comments are made about the net present value (npv) concept of capital budgeting and whether or not this tool has been or can be found to be useful in the problem of deciding whether to hedge. as a calculation, npv seems to be of little help in the problem of hedging. this could be because npv works on expected future cash flows or 4 journal of business strategies the certainty equivalent of future cash flows, while hedging works to eliminate the risks of realizing future cash flows that had not been expected. second, a method for measuring the risk that jet fuel prices will decline is studied. hedges are most often designed to deal with the problem of higher jet fuel prices. what is the risk that jet fuel prices will fall instead? that is the problem of this section. to address this problem, a first passage time model operating under an assumption that changes in jet fuel prices follow geometric brownian motion is proposed. the assumption of geometric brownian motion is controversial. pros and cons concerning this assumption are discussed. third, a game theory approach to the problem of hedging is attempted. using ordinal preferences which rank possible outcomes in different future states of the world for each of two competitors, the consequences of the actions of rival airlines are compared. fourth, the last part of this paper is an empirical data analysis of the differences in jet fuel costs, net of hedging results, is conducted. results are inconclusive. net present value as a tool to evaluate hedging decisions the decision of whether or not to hedge can be thought of as a choice to alter the future cash flows of a capital investment. why not calculate the net present value of a hedge in order to determine whether a hedge should be undertaken? npv tools are often used to evaluate capital investment decisions. irving fisher (1930) developed the concept net present value, the quantity of shareholder wealth created by a management’s investment decision. robichek and myers (1965) extended fisher’s work so that the risk of expected future cash flows could be taken into account in the calculation of npv. some have studied the connection of npv to hedging decisions. in perfect markets it may well be the case that decisions to hedge are all zero npv decisions. aretz and bartram (2010) note that shareholders and bondholders themselves can choose to hedge risk without any assistance from corporate management. to apply this reasoning to the case of the airline industry: if southwest airlines should choose to stop hedging the risk that jet fuel prices might increase, there remains nothing to stop their shareholders and bondholders from choosing to hedge this risk in their own accounts. so, it is argued, hedging decisions on the part of managers cannot create or destroy value for owners. and if this is true, then hedging is a zero npv decision in perfect markets. however, capital markets may not be perfect. some argue that corporate managers can generate positive npv from hedging decisions in the presence of volume 32, number 1 5 capital market imperfections produced by tax law and bankruptcy costs, but empirical evidence in this regard is slight. those interested in these issues may see two articles: one written by mackay and moeller (2007), and the other by campello, lin, ma, and zou (2010), for more information about the connection of market imperfections and the ability of corporate managers to create wealth by way of hedge decision making. the works cited above consider whether or not hedging decisions can create a positive npv and if so under what conditions. there are problems in applying npv to a specific hedging problem. npv analysis is understood in terms of expected cash flows or in terms of certainty equivalents of expected cash flows, but hedging is understood in terms of realized cash flows. nevertheless, it may, in some cases, be practical to translate ex ante data about all possible cash flows that may be realized into expected cash flows so that a npv analysis of hedge decision making could be undertaken. one could then consider all possible realized cash flows with and without hedging. and too, it ought to be the case that if one takes an investment proposal and hedges away all of the risk associated with forecasting future cash flows that one has, though this hedging, defined what the certainty equivalent cash flows must be. but no one has pursued this line of reasoning, and this present paper does not study the connection of npv to hedging decisions. when jet fuel hedges lose money through hedging, an airline can choose to eliminate the risk of large increases in jet fuel prices, but the problem remains that jet fuel prices may decline after the airline puts into place these hedge contracts. if this occurs, hedge contracts lose money. plus, in periods of falling jet fuel prices, the airlines that do not hedge pay less for their jet fuel than their rivals that do hedge. this is the risk that remains after management decides to put hedges in place. recently – during the fourth quarter of 2014, jet fuel prices declined. table 2 jet fuel cost per gallon after the results of hedging: fourth quarter results 2014 vs fourth quarter 2013 2014 2013 2014 2013 2014 2013 2014 2013 2014 2013 united continental american delta southwest jetblue per gallon fuel cost (economic) $2.83 $3.08 $2.52 $3.06 $2.62 $2.83 $3.08 $2.52 $3.06 $2.62 source: various company press releases 6 journal of business strategies the cost reduction in american airlines is largest because american airlines has chosen not to hedge jet fuel prices. martin (2015) and levine-weinberg (2014) comment on american airlines’ decision not to hedge jet fuel prices, noting that it is a risky decision, but one that is responsible for increased profits in 2014. what is the probability that jet fuel prices will fall? to answer this question, an assumption must be made as to the stochastic nature of the changes in jet fuel price changes through time. carter, rogers, and simkins (2004) assume that changes in jet fuel prices can be described as geometric brownian motion. not everyone agrees. tan (2002) asserts that there is instead mean reversion in jet fuel prices. perhaps tan is right in identifying ex-post data sets of jet fuel prices in time-series as better described with mean reversion than with other stochastic assumptions of price behavior. if tan (2002) is correct in an ex ante sense, then the first passage time model application of this paper is misguided. in an ex ante sense, a mean reversion model would necessarily produce expectations on future jet fuel prices such that when jet fuel prices move above some price, then they are more likely to decline, and when jet fuel prices move below that same price then they are more likely to increase. any economic story explaining this price behavior would unfold in two parts. first, it would divide the quantity demanded and the quantity supplied of jet fuel into two categories: normal and abnormal. second, it would also fix both supply and demand curves. put these assumptions together and one can then justify mean reversion. when market conditions are normal, jet fuel prices are likely observed in the neighborhood of some mean value. when market conditions are abnormal, jet fuel prices are more likely to be observed farther away from their mean value price. for short-run problems where the opec cartel dominates the market for petroleum products, where supply and demand are fixed, the choice of a mean reversion model seems reasonable. an economic story justifying geometric brownian motion is simpler than that of mean reversion. there is no need to locate reflecting barriers above and below a mean value price and no need to measure the speed at which jet fuel prices return to their mean. and economic thinking consistent with geometric brownian motion permits both the quantity demanded and the quantity supplied to change over time along with both the supply and demand curves of jet fuel. given recent large increases in oil production in texas and north dakota oil fields, it may be argued that the opec cartel has lost the ability to control the price of oil. if this is so, then one could argue that price changes of petroleum products will no longer be mean reverting. volume 32, number 1 7 if a geometric brownian motion assumption is employed to describe the stochastic nature of jet fuel prices, parameter estimates are required to produce forecasts: a drift term µ which describes the constant, instantaneous rate of change of jet fuel prices, absent any random shocks; and a volatility term σ which describes the sensitivity of jet fuel prices to these random economic shocks. this expected drift rate may or may not be realized, for it is a random variable, which in every future time period is normally distributed with expectation equal to a constant µ and standard deviation about this expectation equal to a constant σ. if one can estimate both drift and volatility, then a first passage time model, working in the context of geometric brownian motion, can answer the question: what is probability that jet fuel prices will drop far enough to penetrate some fixed lower boundary price at least once over the next t years? σ 2 2 μ c—s( ( c—s( ( √t σ c—s( ( √t σ where: c is the lower boundary jet fuel price, s is the current jet fuel price, μ is the expected continuous rate of drift in jet fuel prices, σ is the volatility of jet fuel prices, and t is the number of years of the planning horizon. if future changes in jet fuel prices are normally distributed in cross-section, and if changes in jet fuel prices are described as a geometric brownian motion, then the probability solution given in this model above is exact. an example below is provided only to illustrate an application of this first passage model. suppose that management wanted to know the probability that jet fuel prices would fall by fifty percent at least once over the next four years. given parameter estimates for drift and volatility this question can be addressed. 8 journal of business strategies table 3 an illustration of solutions in a first passage time problem planning horizon decline in jet fuel prices as a percentage expected drift rate volatility probability of a specified decline in jet fuel prices occurs at least once 4 years 50 % 0 % 25 % 16.6 % 4 years 50 % 0 % 40 % 38.6 % 4 years 50 % 0 % 55 % 52.9 % holding drift and planning horizon constant, the probability of jet fuel prices penetrating a lower boundary price for jet fuel increases as volatility increases and vice versa. the hedging decision viewed as a game in this section the problem airlines have of choosing whether to hedge jet fuel prices is studied from the viewpoint of a game-theoretic framework. the airline industry is an example of an oligopoly. as such it may be the case that an airlines’ choice to hedge jet fuel prices is not only connected to the future price that an airline will pay for jet fuel but also connected to their rival’s profitability. two cases are considered. in the first case considered below, illustrated in table 4, two rival airlines both make hedging decisions, but these decisions cannot affect the other’s profitability. in the second case, illustrated in table 5, two rivals both make hedging decisions as before, but these decisions can affect the other’s profitability. in table 4 the decision of whether to hedge jet fuel prices is illustrated. two rival airlines make their hedge choices simultaneously and without collusion. after these hedge decisions are made, jet fuel prices change. the change in jet fuel prices is a random variable, beyond the control of either airline. a hedge will be beneficial to an airline if jet fuel prices rise. otherwise, hedging will reduce the airline’s profits. both the potential benefits and the potential losses depend upon the size of the hedge relative to the airline’s jet fuel usage, and how large the movement is in jet fuel prices. in table 4 the outcomes shown are ordinal preferences. these ordinal preferences rank outcomes over all possible future states of the world. game theorists show that knowledge of ordinal preferences, rather than knowledge of the cardinal outcomes associated with these preferences, is sufficient to reach a rational decision. for an explanation see mccain (2004) pages 68-69. volume 32, number 1 9 how are these ordinal preferences assigned? four ranks are employed. rank 4 is the most preferred. in this state jet fuel prices have declined and the airline has not hedged, so there is no cost of hedging to be subtracted from the benefits associated with the decline in jet fuel. rank 3 is assigned to a state where jet fuel prices have declined, but the airline has hedged against the possibility of an increase in jet fuel prices. the cost of this insurance will increase jet fuel costs. rank 2 is assigned to a state where jet fuel prices have increased, but the airline has hedged against higher jet fuel prices. airlines seldom or never hedge all of their jet fuel needs, and at the time that this paper was being written (february 2015), the airlines under study (american, delta, jetblue, southwest, and united continental) each hedged significantly less than half of their jet fuel requirements. so, even though in this state, where jet fuel prices have increased and the airline has hedged against these price increases, the airline would have preferred states where jet fuel prices drop. rank 1, the worst possible outcome, is a state where jet fuel prices increase, but the airline did not hedge against any price increase. table 4 hypothetical preferences (you, rival) over future states of the world for two airlines where rank 1 is least preferred: a case where no one is penalized for being outguessed by a rival or rewarded for outguessing a rival rival hedges rival does not hedge you hedge 2,2 costs rise 3,3 costs fall 2,1 costs rise 3,4 costs fall you do not hedge 1,2 costs rise 4,3 costs fall 1,1 costs rise 4,4 costs fall if airlines can make hedging decisions independently of one another, without any concern that their rival’s hedging choices will affect their profitability or that their hedging choices will affect their rival’s profitability, then preferences over all possible future states for one airline must not depend on the hedging decisions of 10 journal of business strategies any other airline, and vice versa. such independence is plausible if and only if one airline does not gain any economic advantage by outguessing its rival in regard to future jet fuel price movements and it is not subject to any penalty when it is outguessed by its rival. the preferences of table 4 above describe these circumstances. there is no dominant strategy for either airline, no nash equilibrium. but there is a minimax strategy available to both, if they are financially able. von neumann and morgenstern (1947 ), using methods of theorem and proof, justify minimax strategies for decision makers as a reasonable choice for rational decision makers on the grounds of risk aversion. adopting this strategy, both should consider hedging. doing so avoids the worst possible outcome, a state where jet fuel prices drop and this drop is unmitigated by any hedge. unlike the preceding analysis, the ordinal preferences of table 5 below assume an oligopolistic market structure where the hedging decisions of rivals are relevant to the hedging decisions that an airline must make. consistent with these ordinal preferences found below is the notion that outguessing a rival in regard to the direction of future jet fuel price movements generates economic benefits for the airline, and, to the contrary, being outguessed by rivals results in economic penalties. in periods of falling jet fuel prices, airlines that do not hedge (or that do not hedge as much as their competitors) are able to translate reduced jet fuel prices into reduced ticket prices if they want. competitors who choose to hedge jet fuel prices bear this risk unless all hedge alike. if jet fuel prices go up, then those who hedge will benefit from gains associated with their hedge investments which offset to some degree the increases in jet fuel prices. but their unhedged (less hedged) competitors suffer (or suffer more) from higher jet fuel prices. airlines who have hedged before an increase in jet fuel prices takes place are able to translate gains from hedging into lower ticket prices. airlines choosing not to hedge jet fuel prices bear this risk unless all choose not to hedge. an analysis of ordinal preferences in the case where one airline’s hedging choices can affect both its own profitability and the profitability of its rivals requires eight ranks rather than the four of the previous case. why? there is an added dimension to this new problem. as before jet fuel prices may go up or down, and as before an airline may either hedge or not hedge, but now it matters whether an airline pays the same price for jet fuel as its rival. a possible state of the world where both pay the same high price for jet fuel because jet fuel prices went up and neither airline hedged is ranked differently than a possible state of the world where your airline pays a high price for jet fuel because jet fuel prices went up and your airline did not hedge, but your unhedged rival pays less. volume 32, number 1 11 rank 8 is preferred above all others. in this state jet fuel prices have declined and your airline has not hedged (so for your airline there is no cost of hedging to be subtracted from the benefits associated with the decline in jet fuel), but your rival has hedged and thus pays more for jet fuel than your airline does. rank 7, in this state jet fuel prices have declined, your airline has not hedged, and your rival also has not hedged, so both benefit fully from lower jet fuel prices – both your airline and your rival pay the same price for jet fuel. rank 6, in this state jet fuel prices have fallen, your airline and your rival have both hedged, so both do not benefit fully in the decline of jet fuel prices, but neither your airline or your rival are put at a competitive disadvantage by hedging, because both your airline and your rival pay the same price for jet fuel. rank 5, in this state jet fuel prices have fallen, but your airline has hedged against jet fuel price increases while your rival has not hedged, so you must pay more for jet fuel than your rival. rank 4, in this state jet fuel prices have risen, but your airline has hedged against jet fuel price increases while your rival has not, so you pay less than your rival for jet fuel. rank 3, in this state jet fuel prices have increased, but both your airline and your rival have hedged against jet fuel price increases, thus both your airline and your rival pay the same price for jet fuel. rank 2, in this state jet fuel prices have increased, but neither your airline nor your rival has hedged, so your airline and your rival pay the same price for jet fuel. rank 1, in this state jet fuel prices have risen and your airline has not hedged, but your rival has hedged, so your airline pays more for jet fuel than your rival does. table 5 hypothetical preferences (you, rival) over future states of the world for two airlines where rank 1 is least preferred: a case where one is penalized for being outguessed by a rival and rewarded for outguessing a rival rival hedges rival does not hedge you hedge 3,3 costs rise 6,6 costs fall 4,1 costs rise 5,8 costs fall you do not hedge 1,4 costs rise 8,5 costs fall 2,2 costs rise 7,7 costs fall 12 journal of business strategies as in the first case above that is illustrated in table 4, a minimax solution is again available, suggesting that if both you and your rival are rational and risk averse, then both should consider hedging to avoid the worst possible outcome. if all hedge alike, then two good things happen: the risk of paying a high price for jet fuel is mitigated, and, ceteris paribus, all competitors pay the same price for jet fuel. but, what if there is a risk that your rival cannot or will not hedge? if you persist in hedging, then your hedging strategy is made more risky. in this scenario, when jet fuel prices fall your rival will pay less for jet fuel than your airline. if there is a risk that your rival will not hedge, then your airline may consider not hedging as well. if no one hedges against possible changes in jet fuel prices, then, ceteris paribus, all airlines pay the same price for jet fuel in every possible future state. depending on an airline’s ability to pass higher jet fuel costs on in the form of higher ticket prices, decision makers may look with favor upon a strategy that attempts to attain the same price for jet fuel at the expense of hedging against the possibility that jet fuel prices rise. in fact not all airlines do hedge. in table 6 below, one can see that american is unhedged. the other airlines studied: united continental, delta, southwest, and jetblue are hedged in varying degrees against a possible increase in the price of jet fuel. american airline’s decision to not hedge jet fuel prices is consistent with that of us air, which completed a merger with american airlines on december 9, 2013. levine-weinberg (2014) writes that management of this airline decided in 2008 to no longer hedge their jet fuel costs. by the third quarter of 2009 all of their hedging contracts were gone. american shows no hedge losses in the fourth quarter of 2014 because they are not hedged. their rivals all show losses in the fourth quarter of 2014 because they have hedged against the possibility of higher prices for jet fuel, but jet fuel prices fell instead. but, in times past hedging has paid well. gwynne (2012) reports that southwest is the only domestic airline that has avoided bankruptcy. american, united, delta, northwest, and us airways have sought bankruptcy protection since september 11, 2011, or, like continental, have lost their separate existence. when the price of oil began to increase dramatically in 2000, southwest was protected in large degree by jet fuel hedges, which saved the company four billion american dollars from 2000-2011. volume 32, number 1 13 table 6 a comparison of fuel expense per income statement and economic cost of jet fuel as it is reported in schedules associated with financial statements: fourth quarter results 2014 vs fourth quarter 2013 2014 2013 2014 2013 2014 united continental united continental american american delta fuel purchase cost $2,445 $2,987 $2,659 $3,214 $2,394 add: realized hedge losses (gains) 85 (22) 2,146 add: refinery segment impact loss (gain) (105) add: hedge loss (gain) or mark to market effects 151 (4) (1,966) equals: total economic (or adjusted) fuel cost $2,681 $2,961 $2,659 $3,214 $2,469 total fuel expense (gaap) $2,530 $2,965 $2,659 $3,214 $4,435 2013 2014 2013 2014 2013 delta southwest southwest jetblue jetblue fuel purchase cost $2,823 $1,150 $1,364 $410 $463 add: realized hedge losses (gains) (150) 17 3 26 3 add: refinery segment impact loss (gain) 46 add: hedge loss (gain) or mark to market effects 92 (1) (13) equals: total economic (or adjusted) fuel cost $2,811 $1,166 $1,354 total fuel expense (gaap) $2,719 $1,167 $1,367 $436 $466 source: various company press releases and, where information was not available from company sources, calculations by the author. calculations above are consistent with accounting standards: statement of financial accounting standards no. 133 defines jet fuel hedges to be cash flow hedges such that the market value of all derivative contracts are found on the balance 14 journal of business strategies sheet and, for hedges that are effective, the changes in the market value of derivative contracts are booked to other comprehensive income until the jet fuel purchase that is being hedged is used. when the jet fuel is used, the hedging results become a part of the jet fuel expense. on the other hand, ineffective hedging results in immediate income statement recognition. statement of financial accounting standards no. 161, an amendment to fasb statement no. 133, requires that firms disclose how and why they hedge, and how the gains and losses associated with derivatives affect both balance sheet and income statement accounts, and cash flows. one major airline has taken the extraordinary step of making its own jet fuel. delta air lines in 2012 purchased an oil refinery with the intention that this investment will alleviate a shortage of jet fuel supply. hargreaves (2012) reports that delta purchased the shut-down phillips 66 trainer refinery for $150 million, and that delta planned to invest another $100 million to modify the refinery so that it can produce more jet fuel. delta management (2012 form 10-k) explains that the trainer refinery, located near philadelphia, pennsylvania, was acquired in response to delta’s inability to control jet fuel costs through hedging, and that this investment is in response to both higher refining margins for jet fuel and the declining supply of jet fuel in the north-eastern united states. the trainer refinery has a capacity of 185,000 barrels per day. this refinery restarted in september 2012. figure 1 below describes the work of this refinery. delta consumes the jet fuel produced by trainer refinery and sells or swaps the by-products of refinery products to oil companies. figure 1 volume 32, number 1 15 delta, in their 2013 10-k filing, reports that their refinery operations lost money in 2013 because of u. s. environmental agency requirements. the epa requires refiners like delta that do not blend renewable fuels (ethanol) to obtain a waiver from this requirement, or to purchase renewable energy credits in a secondary market from refiners that produce more renewable fuels at their refineries than regulations require. delta chooses to purchase these credits and their cost in 2013 is high enough to cause delta’s refinery business to show a loss. delta is studying the matter and hoping for better results in the future. nevertheless, delta contends that their refinery has succeeded in increasing jet fuel supplies. analysis of variance of jet fuel costs per gallon consider the following data set contained in table 7 below. every year in annual reports airlines report their average jet fuel cost per gallon after hedge results are taken into consideration. similar data, in some instances differing by a penny or so on the gallon, is provided by the bureau of transportation statistics. it could be the case that for the airlines under study, different hedging practices result in different jet fuel costs per gallon after hedging effects are accounted for. proving this by way of hypothesis testing fails. table 7 per gallon jet fuel cost after hedging results are considered united continental american delta southwest us air jetblue 2014 $2.97 $2.91 $2.87 $2.92 n.a $2.99 2013 $3.13 $3.08 $3.07 $3.12 n.a. $3.14 2012 $3.27 $3.20 $3.26 $3.30 $3.17 $3.21 2011 $3.06 $3.00 $3.05 $3.19 $3.11 $3.17 2010 $2.39 $3.20 $2.33 $2.51 $2.24 $2.29 2009 $1.80 $2.00 $2.15 $2.12 $1.74 $2.08 2008 $3.52 $3.03 $3.13 $2.44 $3.17 $3.08 2007 $2.18 $2.13 $2.24 $1.80 $2.20 $2.18 source: company 10-k filings and bureau of transportation statistics 16 journal of business strategies consider the null hypothesis – mean per gallon fuel costs after hedging are equal for all airlines appearing in the sample for the time period indicated. take the data set contained in table 7 which is the jet fuel costs after hedging effects, airline by airline for the years 2008 through 2012. let the treatment variable be identified as the choice of airline, with six levels of that treatment variable, one for each of the six airlines studied. and let the blocking variable be the time periods in which annual per gallon jet fuel costs were measured, with six levels of that blocking variable, one for each of the six years annual per gallon jet fuel costs were recorded. table 8 below is an anova table that results: table 8 analysis of variance of per gallon jet fuel cost after hedging effects for the years 2007-2012 source of variation sum of squares degrees of freedom mean squares f ratio airline 0.155600 5 0.031120 0.55 year 8.761233 5 1.752247 30.85 error 1.419870 25 0.056795 total 10.33670 35 the f ratio calculation of 0.55 is much too low to show at any reasonable level of confidence that fuel costs, net of hedging results, are different from airline to airline. one cannot reject the null hypothesis that mean differences in jet fuel costs after hedging is accounted for are equal for all airlines studied. as expected, the inclusion of blocking variable – time period – is highly effective in making the analysis of variance more powerful than it otherwise could be. the blocking variable is statistically significant at the 99 percent level of confidence. this test is arguably powerful in a statistical sense, and yet the null hypothesis cannot be rejected. the work summarized in table 9 is similar to that of table 8. again an analysis of variance of jet fuel costs, net of results is undertaken. but, in the data set associated with table 9, an airline that has lost its separate identity in 2013 is omitted from the study. however, dropping us air, which now no longer exists as a separate entity, and including the years 2007-2014 do not change the results. again, the null hypothesis that all airlines have equal jet fuel costs after hedge results are accounted for, cannot be rejected at any reasonable level of confidence. volume 32, number 1 17 table 9 analysis of variance of per gallon jet fuel cost after hedging effects for the years 2007-2014 source of variation sum of squares degrees of freedom mean squares f ratio airline 0.092810 4 0.0232025 0.49 year 7.929997 7 1.13285679 23.99 error 1.321990 28 0.04721393 total 9.344797 39 conclusion in the airline industry, hedging may be used by management to fix the price of jet fuel, or to locate it within some predetermined range, but hedging cannot guarantee that an airline will pay a price for jet fuel as low as the price that its competitors pay, unless all competitors hedge alike or all refuse to hedge. hedging cannot guarantee an airline which hedges that its unhedged rivals will not benefit from a decline in jet fuel prices. all in airline industry may wish to hedge alike. there are benefits to the risk averse for doing so. if all do hedge alike, then all are protected against a sudden surge in jet fuel prices and, when ceteris paribus conditions are met, all will pay the same price for jet fuel. but it may be the case that not every airline can afford to hedge jet fuel costs, or hedge as much as they would like. hedge commitments may require collateral and cash beyond the means of some airlines. if this is so, then those airlines which do not hedge are put at further risk should jet fuel prices increase. however, these airlines by not hedging, put their rivals who do hedge at risk should jet fuel prices decline. those who hedge in these instances find themselves paying more for jet fuel than their unhedged rivals. therefore, knowledge that your rival may not or cannot hedge may change your own hedging strategy. you may choose not to hedge as well. if no one hedges against possible changes in jet fuel prices, then, ceteris paribus, all airlines pay the same price for jet fuel in every possible future state. depending on an airline’s ability to pass higher jet fuel costs on in the form of higher ticket prices, decision makers may look with favor upon a strategy that attempts to attain the same price for jet fuel at the expense of hedging against the possibility that jet fuel prices rise. 18 journal of business strategies references american air lines group, inc. (2015). news release: american airlines group reports fourth quarter and full year 2014 profit. january 27, 2015. fort worth, texas: american air lines group, inc. american air lines group, inc. (2015). american air lines group, inc. 10-k annual report pursuant to section 13 and 15(d) of the securities and exchange act of 1934 filed on 02/25/2015 filed period 12/31/2014. fort worth, texas: american air lines group, inc. aretz, k., & bartram, s. m. (2010). corporate hedging and shareholder value. journal of financial research 33(4), winter, 317-371. bailey, jeff. (2007). southwest airlines gains advantage by hedging on long-term oil contracts. the new york times. 2007, november, 28. 2007. retrieved from http://www.nytimes.com/2007/11/28/business/worldbusiness/ bureau of transportation statistics. (2015). airline fuel cost and consumption. retrieved from: http://www.transtats.bts.gov/fuel.asp campello, m., lin, c., ma, y., & zou, h. (2011). the real and financial implications of corporate hedging. journal of finance 66(5), 1615-1647. carter, d., dan, r., & simkins, b. (2004). fuel hedging in the airline industry: the case of southwest airlines. social science research network. abstract 578663, july. delta air lines. (2015). press release: delta airline announces december quarter results, january 20, 2015. atlanta, georgia: delta air lines. delta air lines. (2015). delta air lines, inc. 10-k annual report pursuant to section 13 and 15(d) of the securities and exchange act of 1934 filed on 02/11/2015 filed period 12/31/2014. atlanta, georgia: delta air lines. delta air lines. (2014). delta air lines, inc. 10-k annual report pursuant to section 13 and 15(d) of the securities and exchange act of 1934 filed on 02/24/2014 filed period 12/31/2013. atlanta, georgia: delta air lines. delta air lines. (2013). delta air lines, inc. 10-k annual report pursuant to section 13 and 15(d) of the securities and exchange act of 1934 filed on 02/13/2013 filed period 12/31/2012. atlanta, georgia: delta air lines. financial accounting standards board. (1998). statement of financial accounting standards no. 133 accounting for derivative instruments and hedging activities. norwalk, connecticut: financial accounting standards board of the financial accounting foundation. volume 32, number 1 19 financial accounting standards board. (2008). statement of financial accounting standards no. 161 disclosures about derivative instruments and hedging activities an amendment of fasb statement no. 133. norwalk, connecticut: financial accounting standards board of the financial accounting foundation. fisher, i. (1930). the theory of interest. new york: the macmillan co. fitzpatrick, d., & zuckerman, g. (2012). ‘whale’ tab hits $5.8 billion. wall street journaleastern edition. pp. b1-b2. gwynne, s.c. (2012). luv and war at 30,000 feet. (cover story) texas monthly, 40(3), 124-196. retrieved from http://www.texasmonthly.com/story/luv-andwar-30000-feet hargreaves, s. (2012). delta’s risky oil refinery bet. cnnmoney. may 2, 2012. retrieved from http://news/companies/delta-refinery/index hull, j. c. (2009). options, futures, and other derivatives, upper saddle river, nj: prentice hall, c2009. jetblue. (2015). press release: jetblue announces fourth quarter and full year results. january 29, 2015. new york, new york: jetblue. jetblue. (2015). jetblue air lines, inc. 10-k annual report pursuant to section 13 and 15(d) of the securities and exchange act of 1934 filed on 02/12/2015 filed period 12/31/2014. new york, new york: jetblue. jetblue. (2014). press release: jetblue announces 2013 annual profit. january 29, 2014. new york, new york: jetblue. levine-weinberg, a. (2014). should american airlines group, inc. return to fuel hedging? the motley fool, october 22, 2014, retrieved from http://www.fool. com/investing/general/2014/10/22/should-american-airlines-group-inc-returnto-fuel.aspx mackay, p., & moeller, s.b. (2007). the value of corporate risk management. journal of finance 52(3), 1379-1419. martin, h. (2015). american airlines’ fuel-buying bet pays off in record profit. los angeles times, january 28, 2015. retrieved from http://www.latimes.com/business/la-fi-airlines-fuel-hedging-20150128-story.html mccain, r. a. (2004). game theory: a nontechnical introduction to the analysis of strategy. oh: south-western. nash, j. (1951). non-cooperative games. the annals of mathematics 54(2), 286-295. rampini, a. a., sufi, a., & viswanathan, s. (2014). dynamic risk management, journal of financial economics 111(2), 271-296. robichek, a. a., & stewart, c. m. (1966). conceptual problems in the use of riskadjusted discount rates, journal of finance 21(4), 727-730. 20 journal of business strategies southwest airlines co. (2015). press release: southwest airlines reports fourth quarter and record annual profit; 42nd consecutive year of profitability. january 22, 2015. dallas, texas: southwest airline co. southwest airline co. (2015). southwest airlines, inc. 10-k annual report pursuant to section 13 and 15(d) of the securities and exchange act of 1934 filed on 02/06/2015 filed period 12/31/2014. dallas, texas: southwest airline co. tan, m. (2002). managing aviation fuel risk: emerging market’s airline companies perspective on the international arena. research papers in international business, paper 25-02 united continental holdings, inc. (2015). news release: united announces fullyear and fourth quarter profit. january 22, 2015. chicago illinois: united continental airlines. united continental holdings, inc. (2015). united continental holdings, inc. 10-k annual report pursuant to section 13 and 15(d) of the securities and exchange act of 1934 filed on 02/20/2015 filed period 12/31/2014. chicago illinois: united continental airlines. von neumann, j., & morgenstern, o. (1947). theory of games and economic behavior. princeton, n.j. ; woodstock: princeton university press, 1947. brief biographical sketch of author garland simmons is an associate professor of finance in the nelson rusche college of business at stephen f. austin state university. he teaches business statistics, financial statement analysis, and speculative markets. his recent research interests are in the methodology of financial research and in the use of options and option theory by corporate managers. fostering innovation through humble leadership and humble organizational culture maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 73 journal of business strategies doi:10.54155/jbs.38.2.73-94 fostering innovation through humble leadership and humble organizational culture tiffany maldonadoa, lila cardenb, carol bracec, marie myersd a department of management, marketing, and information systems, sam houston state university, huntsville tx 77341. tmaldonado@shsu.edu (corresponding author). b construction management department, university of houston, 312 technology building, houston tx 77204. lcarden@uh.edu. c marilyn davies college of business, uhd northwest campus at lsc university park, 20515 state hwy 249, houston tx 77077. bracec@uhd.edu. d cfo of hewlett packard, 1501 page mill road, palo alto, ca 94303. marie.myers@hp.com. key words humble leadership; organizational culture; robotic process automation abstract companies understand they need to innovate to stay competitive, but innovation is not as simple as thinking of a great idea and then implementing it. successful innovation requires supportive actions from leaders and the firm especially when the innovation is complex. in order to foster complex technological innovations, such as robotic process automation (“rpa”), we propose that firms benefit from having (1) humble leadership actions and (2) a humble organizational culture. we share what we learned about our propositions after reviewing the finance controllership division within a major multinational technology organization that develops hardware and other computer-related support items. this work is licensed under a creative commons attribution-noncommercial 4.0 international license. copyright (c) 2021 tiffany maldonado, lila carden, carol brace, marie myers. mailto:tmaldonado@shsu.edu mailto:lcarden@uh.edu mailto:bracec@uhd.edu mailto:marie.myers@hp.com https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/4.0/ https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/4.0/ 74 maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 1. introduction companies are well aware that they need to innovate to stay competitive in the ever-changing business environment, but innovation is not as simple as thinking of a great idea and then implementing it. successful innovation requires supportive actions from leaders and the firm especially when the innovation is as complex as implementing new technology (aronson et al., 2014). one type of complex technology that more firms are implementing is the use of robots to perform repetitive manual processes via robotic process automation (seasongood, 2016). in robotic process automation (“rpa”), the tools and techniques drive process automations using existing work packages, freeing up human intervention to focus more on complex analytical skills that are unable to be handled by robotics (lacity & willcocks, 2016; seasongood, 2016). in light of a radical change such as rpa, it is expected that firms would face numerous challenges as more complex innovation initiatives are conducted however, such initiatives usually yield greater value than noncomplex technological projects (torugsa & arundel, 2016). to foster such complex innovations, we propose that firms benefit from humble leadership behaviors and a humble organizational culture based on what we learned in a case study of the finance controllership division within a major multinational technology organization (called “tech inc” in this paper) that develops hardware including computers, printers, keyboards, headphones, and other computer-related support items. we define humble leaders as those leaders who are willing to learn, aware of their strengths and weaknesses, appreciative of the contributions of others, and invest in self transcendent pursuits (aziz, 2019; owens & hekman, 2012; vera & rodriguez-lopez, 2004). a humble organizational culture is a culture that nurtures the virtue of humility through six dimensions: employee development, mistake-tolerance, transparency, accurate awareness, recognition, and openness (maldonado et al., 2018). our paper details our propositions that (1) innovation is supported through leadership behaviors, in particular humble leadership behaviors, and (2) innovation is supported through a culture primed for innovation, in particular humble corporate culture. to illustrate our proposal and provide recommendations and implications to managers, we examined a large company, referred to as “tech inc”, that has won several awards due to its innovation. through this case study, we show that organizations cannot maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 75 successfully foster innovation with just humble leadership behaviors or just a humble organizational culture alone, but organizations need the combination of both humble leadership behaviors and humble organizational culture to ensure dynamic innovation. 2. review of literature of innovation, humble leadership and humble organizational culture our paper examines the impact of humble leadership and humble organizational culture on innovation. before we can begin, we must first make note that even though there is an abundance of studies that examine not only the antecedents of innovation but also the benefits, results are unclear as researchers have not agreed on a consistent definition of “innovation” nor a consistent tool or measurement of innovation (calik et al., 2020; collins et al., 1988; hage, 1999). this is not uncommon, and we expect that innovation will continue to have different interpretations. one common definition is that innovation depends mostly on competence and leadership (chapman, 2006). researchers have noted that workplace innovation flourishes in environments in which key leadership activities are conducted (chapman, 2007; moussa et al., 2018) and leaders are a critical factor in the promotion of innovation and creativity (aronson et al., 2014; montes et al., 2005; mumford et al., 2002). more specifically, innovation is supported in humble leadership environments (ye et al., 2020) that embrace personal faults and mistakes as well as recognizes contributions and positive performances as employees sometimes transition into new roles and responsibilities. through the examination of our case study on tech inc, the company has focused on robotic process automation (rpa) which is a process automation that uses software robots or artificial intelligence as a business tool (madakan et al., 2019). the vision for the use of rpa is to reduce the time of repetitive work by automation, which allows organizations such as tech inc to reimagine their strategic implementations including their financial allocations (fluss, 2018). this technology innovation is used to automate business functions that were mostly conducted by humans including integrating data from various sources such as email and enterprise systems. because rpa has this type of capability, the future of work will require innovative thoughts from the leadership teams to implement these solutions with the assistance of new hardware, software, and smart devices. these innovative thoughts will include 76 maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 opportunities to increase productivity and innovation which is fueled by the need for retooled and reskilled workers (fluss, 2018). the work environments that are conducive to automation initiatives such as rpa include environments in which company leadership is attuned to the re-imagining of work including priorities that are focused on quickly embracing the new technologies. this reimagining of work will include an assessment of the business functions that are appropriate for automation such as business functions that follow a frequent, structured process. this re-imagining also includes readying the organization for the change (uzkurt et al., 2013) and needs to include considerations related to humble leadership, humble organizational culture, and innovation. while research exists that suggests the various mechanisms in which leadership supports innovation (back & bausch, 2019; ye et al., 2020), there is still a research gap in identifying which leadership behaviors can influence the innovation of individuals and subunits (khalili et al., 2015). moussa and colleagues (2018) have identified an exhaustive list of key leadership behaviors. they also identified that one challenge of the firm is to develop systems, processes, and climates that promote and demonstrate innovation and creativity. meanwhile, chen and colleagues (2020) propose that leader humility impacts the creativity of the team through leader-leader exchange. we propose that the unique style of humble leadership combined with humble corporate culture can promote and foster technological innovation in firms. according to upper echelon theory, the characteristics of the upper echelons in the organization influence the decisions made and the performance of the firm. one such characteristic that upper echelons can have is humility. humble leaders are open to new information and ideas, willing to correct their mistakes, appreciative of the contributions of others, and eager to learn from others (aziz, 2019; owens & hekman, 2012; vera & rodriguez-lopez, 2004). humility is not a dichotomous virtue where individuals are either humble or they are not humble. instead, humility can be thought of as a continuum, where individuals possess different levels of humility ranging from low to high levels of humility. leaders who are open to new ideas tend to have a learning orientation and leaders with learning orientations often use experiences to develop new routines to change the way the organization operates, which helps the organization to function better than it did in the past. the learning orientation maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 77 innate in humble leaders also influences them to make decisions that enhance the innovation of the firm such as making small and continuous changes rather than large, infrequent changes (owens & hekman, 2012; vroom & jago, 2007). leaders of innovation are those who possess certain characteristics that influence and stimulate others to work collaboratively to achieve new and significant results (prasad & junni, 2017; vroom & jago, 2007). humble leaders have this ability by steadfastly recognizing the contribution of others and modeling how to be willing to correct mistakes (owens & hekman, 2012). research has also shown that there is a positive relationship between creativity and innovation and transformational leadership behaviors (cheung & wong, 2011; eisenbeiss & boerner, 2013; engelen et al., 2014) much like those behaviors of humble leaders (cheung, et al., 2020; ye et al., 2020). in addition to directly influencing innovation in the firm, humble leaders also influence the culture of the organization. organizational cultures are systems of shared beliefs, cognitions and values that produce norms of behavior (cheung & wong, 2011; eisenbeiß & boerner, 2013; engelen et al., 2014). if there is a strong coherence between the strategy and culture, the culture of the organization can facilitate the adoption and implementation of strategy, on the other side, the organizational culture can also serve as a barrier that hinders change (fernandez et al., 2003) and stifles innovation if it is not aligned with strategy. organizations are struggling to innovate for various reasons; thus, practitioners have the challenge to develop cultures that promote innovation and creativity (moussa et al., 2018; uzhurt et al., 2013). one culture that supports innovation is a corporate culture of humility. a culture of humility influences how individuals think and act, and how the firm performs and is built and maintained by policies, processes, routines, and practices that are nurtured by strategic leaders (cameron, 2010). a culture of humility has six dimensions (see table 1): employee development, mistaketolerance, transparency, accurate awareness, recognition, and openness (maldonado et al., 2018). the combination of these dimensions of the humble organizational culture further the company’s ability to continuously innovate in the changing environment. based on our research we propose that it is not only through humble leadership behaviors that companies are able to foster innovation, but also through humble organizational culture. we also propose that it is the humble 78 maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 table 1. impact of dimensions of humble organizational culture humble organizational culture dimension impact employee development cultivates the strengths and abilities of organizational members and the increased knowledge of the members is shared and eventually encoded in organizational routines (maldonado et al., 2018). mistake-tolerance ensures that members can make decisions without fear of negative retaliation, embarrassment or humiliation which encourages members to take more risks and creative decisions which enable the firm to continuously innovate as new discoveries are made (rego et al., 2020). transparency encourages individuals to be honest about their limitations and accept responsibility for mistakes (maldonado et al., 2018). this non-biased selfawareness of employees encourages collaboration which increases innovation. accurate awareness supports the organization in making non-biased, accurate assessments of its strengths and weaknesses and the threats and opportunities in the environment which allows the firm to make wise strategic decisions and to learn from its limitations (maldonado et al., 2018). recognition celebrates the successes of employees which encourages them to become more uninhibited in pursuing larger challenges (maldonado et al., 2018). employees remain motivated knowing that their efforts are recognized and not abused or fraudulently promoted as belonging to upper management. openness considers ideas that are new or external which gives way to new learning within the organization as the absorptive capacity of the firm is increases as the external and new knowledge is integrated and used within the company to innovate (maldonado et al., 2018). maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 79 leadership behaviors that can help facilitate and build this dynamic humble organizational culture (see figure 1). 3. the story of tech inc fostering innovation through humble leadership behaviors and humble organizational culture tech inc is a multinational technology organization with over 50,000 employees. tech inc has received many awards that recognize the firms many successful innovations, such as (award details altered to protect identity of the firm) the star award, which is one of the highest honors in the technology and services industry to recognize a firm’s commitment to outstanding innovation, leadership, and excellence and the design award for the most innovative and cutting-edge industrial, product, and graphic designs. the finance controllership division of tech inc, and the focus of this article, won the prestigious digital award which spotlights companies that are on the cutting edge of digital transformation, including smart automation, robotic process automation, cognitive computing, and advanced analytics. the division was tasked with digitalizing the experience by enabling tools and processes that accelerate their employees’ ability to imagine the future and inspire the team. the finance controllership division, led by jane doe, implemented robotic process automation (rpa), artificial intelligence, advanced analytics, and other emerging technologies to radically streamline financial tasks to improve accuracy and efficiency by 85% due to the ability of rpa to process 24/7 and reduce invoice cycle time by 87%. as a result, the team of 2000+ employees were able to use their time to work on generating new ideas and other higher value-added tasks. the innovations produced such radical change within the division that they were also adopted by other business units in tech inc. the rpa was used throughout the company to figure 1. fostering innovation through humble leadership and humble corporate culture innovation humble corporate culture humble leadership 80 maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 focus on repetitive processes and tasks to automate invoicing processes, security checks, demand expansion, and auditing details for compliance reporting to name a few tasks. through the story of tech inc, managers can learn how to foster innovation through humble leadership behaviors and humble organizational culture. 4. innovation is supported through leadership behaviors, in particular humble leadership behaviors in tech inc, the finance controllership division has been committed to building an innovative culture and developing skills of the future so much that that one award giver mentioned its “best-in-class culture creation”. the innovative culture promotes employees that are data savvy, strategic, creative, and innovative. the culture also includes developing skills for the future related to business acumen, relationship management, and agility for change orientation. the finance controllership division of tech inc has been automating processes leveraging robotic process automation (rpa), advanced analytics, and artificial intelligence in addition to other emerging technologies. tech inc’s ability to support a culture of innovation is based on its “best-inclass culture creation” and leadership. the finance controllership division of tech inc is currently focusing on digitalization as an innovative effort and the impacts to overall communication by initiating these types of efforts. this innovation approach includes starting with a strategy; connecting the dots; making the execution relevant, accessible, and mobile; and telling the story. more specifically, the message from the leaders includes “we nurture digitalization by delivering content and messaging that help employees connect the dots, stay on course and celebrate”. evident in this message are the humble leadership behaviors of recognizing the contribution of others (“celebrate”) and prioritizing employee development (“help employees connect the dots”). tech inc benefits from the humble leadership behaviors of its managers (see table 2). these behaviors demonstrate that the leaders are open to new information and ideas and eager to learn from others, willing to correct their mistakes, appreciative of the contributions of others, and have an accurate awareness of self and others (owens & hekman, 2012; vera & rodriguezlopez, 2004). the leaders of tech inc enact several activities and humble behaviors that help to support and foster technological innovation. jane doe was aware of the strengths and weaknesses of the organization and supports maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 81 innovation through annual scoping and programming of projects in addition to providing clear strategic messaging. jane doe understood that they must be open to new ideas, hence tech inc has an internship program to help generate new innovative thoughts and an innovation advocate core team. finally, these leaders understand that they are successful based on the contributions of others, so they ensure that they recognize and share employee success stories frequently. jane doe saw that new ideas needed to be generated at a greater pace, so they launched a crowd sourcing platform for the entire team of 2500 employees, where every employee was able to go in and post an idea on something that could be improved. the group then used a crowd sourcing approach where employees would vote on the idea and the ideas were reviewed by process experts with the result being that the ideas that had the most votes were included on the implementation schedule for rpa. jane doe helped change the way in which the firm sought out transformation and instead turned it into a "people's transformation" by letting the people drive where things needed to be fixed and improved. this was a dramatic change in approach as normally this was a top-down driven process without a lot of stakeholder engagement. additionally, the leaders at tech inc recognize that it is not just through humble leadership behaviors or a humble organizational culture that they are able to foster innovation, but it is through the combination of both. at tech inc, there are various coordination and integration mechanisms in place to ensure that the humble leader behaviors support the humble organizational culture and vice versa. this can be found in their dedication to building a culture of innovation program, formally supporting employees and being champions of innovation. 5. innovation is supported through a culture primed for innovation, in particular humble corporate culture the organizational culture of tech inc has the six dimensions of humble organizational culture (employee development, mistake-tolerance, transparency, accurate awareness, recognition, and openness) (maldonado et al., 2018). tech inc uses this culture to support innovations related to the collaboration of the digital and physical work environments that support their digital finance structure. this culture of humility is built and maintained by norms that are nurtured by strategic leaders (cameron, 2010) which aligns with 82 maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 table 2. key humble leadership behaviors for innovation leadership support activities leadership support applications within tech inc openness to new information and ideas from employees of all levels created a crowd sourcing platform for the entire team of 2500 employees, where every employee was able to go in and post an idea on something that could be improved eager to learn from others held monthly brown bags concerning innovation willingness to correct self-mistakes and humbly correct mistakes of others department realized that the current rewards programs was not sufficient to drive a culture of innovation, so changed the nature of rewards program department was focused on drone technology for inventory scanning, after little progress, department moved to artificial intelligence is appreciative of the contributions of employees on all levels monthly awards to teams that created new bots or ai scripts has an accurate awareness of self and others understood the lack of skills and abilities of workforce skewed toward millennials annually scopes and programs projects current thought that innovative cultures need to focus on their structure, systems, and culture (bennett & parke, 2015; mackey & deng, 2016). tech inc’s culture focuses on employee development to foster innovation in the firm. this dimension of employee development is so valued that upon winning the digital award for work done in the finance controllership division, tech inc made note that its employees had skills of the future and digital fluency and that the firm was committed to growing their people and cultivating their strengths. to increase the knowledge and strengths of employees jane doe helped to implement “lessons in leadership” training, roundtables focused on innovation and companywide brown bags that include sessions on diversity and inclusion, as well as learning paths. these activities helped to share the increased knowledge of the organizational members to the rest of the employees such that the firm’s training focused on building out maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 83 digitally native skills that was aimed at the entire organization and not just the leadership team. through accurate awareness of others, jane doe realized that with a workforce of 50% millennials, they needed to quickly increase the skills and awareness of the team. they prioritized the development of employees by quickly reskilling the entire workforce of the group through launching a training program focused on analytics and building rpa and digital skills; hosting competitions between key sites to encourage participation and awarded teams that competed and won. this training program and employee competition encoded the increased knowledge and skills of employees into organizational routines. tolerance of competent mistakes allows tech inc to support innovation. at tech inc, they have the motto of “keep reinventing with employee feedback” while continuing to “engage and communicate with experiences that amaze” to ensure that employees can make decisions without fear of embarrassment or negative retaliation. to facilitate this, employees are allowed to take bold risks as tech inc’s employees are taught to fail and fail fast. they are allowed to make many mistakes; but these mistakes never stopped the team, in fact they were constantly scanning the market looking for new technology and trying new ideas. when employees take more risks or creative decisions, such as during the employee technological competitions, the firm can continuously innovate. to encourage this, tech inc took the approach of many pharmaceutical firms, in which they planted a lot of seeds (ideas) and watched to see which might come to the top and which might grow. the firm invested people in these projects and when an investment did not pay off, they quickly cut off the program and then moved onto another. for example, tech inc was working on drones for inventory scanning for about one year, when they saw that little progress was made, they pivoted to ai instead. tech inc prides itself on its transparent communications. the finance controllership division has a dedicated team of employees whose sole focus is on supporting communications. the team has won several awards for their high-quality communications and jane doe continually monitors communications for effectiveness. accurate awareness is a vital part of the culture of tech inc that allows it to successfully support innovation. a notable example is when jane doe realized that the current rewards programs, through welcomed by employees, were not sufficient to drive innovation, so they pivoted to a new program. during strategy planning at tech inc, they evaluate 84 maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 the firm’s swot and because of the analysis, use rpa to capitalize on the opportunity to automate operations to reduce costs and reengineer roles and responsibilities. jane doe made a non-biased, accurate assessment of its weaknesses by recognizing that with a workforce of 50% millennials, the group needed to reskill rapidly based on the changing environment. this allowed the group to make wise strategic decisions and to learn from its limitations. the group is so committed to rewarding transparency and honesty that they created a 3-year strategic plan centered around this dimension. the culture of tech inc includes recognition which celebrates the successes of employees and encourages them to become more uninhibited in pursuing larger challenges. upon receiving the digital award, tech inc made a point to recognize the efforts of employees by saying that “employees [were] an integral part of [their] journey” towards the award and innovation and tech inc makes it a point to regularly share employee success stories. the company makes an effort to ensure recognition programs are effective. for example, at one point, jane doe realized that the current rewards programs were not sufficient to drive innovation and pivoted such that each month the company scanned the division to highlight new technology, such as ai or bots. this new technology was implemented by the team and used a creative approach to inspire inventors. finally, tech inc demonstrates openness in its culture through maintaining open lines of communication. part of the reason tech inc won the digital award; they were able to be so innovative was due to social media crowdsourcing and their commitment to innovating with employee feedback. openness to new ideas was so valued that the finance controllership group implemented a program in which employees could post ideas about areas of improvement before having the ideas vetted by an expert panel and implemented. this program allowed for new concepts to help guide learning and skill acclimation. 6. a culture primed for innovation, in particular humble corporate culture, must be maintained and refined this culture of humility at tech inc (see table 3) supported an environment focused on strategic planning initiatives including the environment, operations, communications, and management. the goal of the strategic planning process was to maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 85 table 3. tech inc’s humble organizational culture behavioral norms actions at tech inc accurate awareness is promoted tech inc promotes an accurate awareness of the firm’s swot through in their strategy planning. the firm uses rpa to automate operations to reduce costs and reengineer roles and responsibilities competent mistakes are tolerated tech inc encourages healthy risk taking and creativity by following a motto of “keep reinventing with employee feedback” and a mission of “engage and communicate with experiences that amaze” transparency and honesty are rewarded tech inc accepts blame, admits weakness, and actively seeks new ideas and feedback from multiple sources through their culture of innovation program and by having an innovation advocate core team openness to the ideas of others is valued and modeled employee development is prioritized tech inc focuses on employee training and encourages difficult goals through its “lessons in leadership” training; brown bag sessions which include learning paths and diversity and inclusion sessions; and its “innovation, design and automation” roundtable employee recognition is practiced regularly tech inc has effective recognition programs, is generous with kudos and spotlight the achievements of others through sharing its employee success stories execute projects that support implementations related to first adopters and design thinkers. the execution of the first adopters and design thinkers included a feedback loop stressing “keep inventing with employees” which indicated the humble leadership behaviors of remaining teachable and willing to learn from others. the environment focused on building a community of small teams that connect the dots and build a reward structure including learning and benefits for motivation which is indicative of the humble leader behaviors and humble organizational cultures that support innovation by encouraging collaboration. to measure the success of the collaborative efforts of digital and physical work environments, there needs to be a system in place to measure the success of the projects (bennett & parke, 2015). this measurement of performance 86 maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 supports the humble organizational culture of the firm in that it allows the firm to have an accurate awareness of its strengths and limitations. tech inc measured its success based on improvements in communications technology. this included automation of services to reduce human intervention and reduce costs. other measurement systems included goal and target setting with innovation metrics such as workload, cost, and return analyses. tech inc strives to achieve operational excellence both internally and externally. internally, tech inc has used an employee survey to assess operational excellence. to further engage the employees and prepare for the cultural changes associated with the innovation, tech inc conducted a survey to determine the overall perceptions of their employees about the innovative path forward for the organization. the survey was distributed to approximately 2000 employees and 179 responded to the survey which represented approximately 8%. the survey results included 89% of the employees approving the innovative path forward and 11% responded that no other path would be better for the organization. the survey respondents also noted that social media communications were not welcomed as much and that methods of communication needed to include videos, websites, email, and in-person communications. the culture of the case organization included an internal work environment predicated on relatable communications and engagement for all employees. this includes modeling the future ahead by clarifying values and setting the example that includes imaging the future by providing relatable values. the culture is also embedded in an atmosphere to inspire the team by being inclusive and defining a vision and mission for everyone. after inspiring the team, there needs to be a structure to support making it happen (ma, 2002) with a growth mindset which includes building relationships, capacity, and expertise across teams to find an avenue for promoting company values through lifestyles. this company support also includes training topics including finance and accounting tools and methods, innovation and automation tools and techniques, and technical software and hardware tools. 7. discussion our paper has several implications for theory and practice. our paper extends the field of knowledge on the implications of humility behaviors and humble organizational culture of the firm by examining how they impact innovation, maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 87 in particular a radical, complex innovation such as rpa. further theoretical implications of our study include considerations for creating environments that will encourage, cultivate, and grow innovation. specifically, the humble leadership will need to ready the organization for the innovative environment built around change. building on the work of kurt lewin (1947) and kotter (1996), a change management theoretical approach for innovation can include the 4-rs below. 1. reimage the organization’s strategy including a new way of doing business that is more efficient and effective as well cost effective. this new way of strategy and forward-thinking includes relationship management that focusses on business demand using data analytics, restructured processes and procedures, and new tools and methodologies. 2. reinforce humble leadership to communicate innovative business acumen and the applicable business factors. this innovative leadership provides resources to support strong interpersonal skills; social and emotional intelligence; and agility. 3. reignite innovative leaders to support open collaborative environments that welcome change and embrace ambiguity with shifting priorities. 4. resource a humble organizational culture with diverse humble leadership including creative ideas that are developed from curiosity and constructive criticism. our paper also provides several implications for practice by developing recommendations for managers to develop complex innovations through humble leadership behaviors and by building a humble organizational culture (see table 3). these humble leadership behaviors are noted in table 3 and applications of the leadership support activities for the finance controllership division are also included herein. these leadership support applications can be implemented in organizations that use innovative technology as an operational strategic tool. managers also need to know that successful technological innovations require employee engagement, valuation of employees, and employee development. the management activities that promote employee engagement are focused on creating environments in which employees are committed at all levels of the organization. some of the ways that managers can create a technological 88 maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 innovation environment include providing challenging work, allowing opportunities for decision-making, creating career advancement opportunities, and supporting collaborative work environments where people work well in teams and have resources to get their job done (bankar & gankar, 2013). managers need to also implement policies and practices that include valuing employees and is based on supporting personal and job resource goals as well as trust and transparency. for example, future job positions and career paths for technological innovations need to include roles that select and train employees on team building, networking, and tolerance of ambiguity due to uncertainty (bankar & gankar, 2013; neves et al., 2017). additionally, managers also need to know that technological innovation implementations include elevating the educational training levels of employees so they can engage in more analytical-type jobs (kesting & ulhoi, 2010; seasongood, 2016). this elevation would include providing employee development programs so that employees can transition into more high-end job functions. based on the mini case of tech inc and previous research, we propose that organizations need more than just a humble organizational culture that supports innovation, or leadership behaviors which support innovation. we propose that organizations need both a humble organizational culture and humble leadership behaviors in order to successfully foster innovation. studies have shown that organizations vary in their degree of humble organizational culture and degree of humble leadership behaviors, thus we offer a matrix (see figure 2) in which organizations can observe how the combination of culture and leadership impacts innovation. our matrix simplifies the degree of organizational humble organizational culture and humble leadership behaviors into high and low for feasibility in applying the model to organizations. organizations can move within the matrix, but for complex innovations to thrive, an organization needs a high level of humble corporate culture and humble leadership behaviors. at this level, organizations will enjoy the success that comes along with being the first mover and innovation leader in their industry. when organizations have high levels of humble corporate culture and low levels of humble leadership behaviors, innovations are often birthed, but rarely survive due to the lack of leadership support to the employees behind the innovation. one way that firms can increase humble leadership behaviors is by ensuring that leaders give employees a voice and increasing the trust employees have in the leader when leaders act as moral role models. maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 89 figure 2. impact of humble leadership actions and humble corporate culture on innovation when organizations have low levels of humble corporate culture and high levels of humble leadership behaviors, innovations are often birthed, but rarely survive due to the lack of processes and structure to support the innovation. firms can increase the process and structure to support innovation by increasing the quantity and quality of humble organizational culture actions (maldonado et al., 2018). finally, when organizations have low levels of humble corporate culture and low levels of humble leadership behaviors, innovations that are birthed die very quickly and eventually, innovations stop being birthed. as a result, these firms risk becoming technologically locked-out of their industry and unable to meet the latest technology standards required to compete. in the future, managers should not depend on their old batch of tricks as innovations take their organizations to new heights. to be on the forefront of the digital revolution, managers need to understand that in order to accommodate the implementation of ai and machine learning systems, such as rpa, they must employ high quality humble leadership behaviors, and a humble corporate culture through many of the actions and behaviors described in this paper. humble corporate culture high low q u a n ti ty a n d q u a li ty o f h u m b le l e a d e rs h ip a c ti o n s h ig h complex innovations thrive innovations birthed, but rarely survive and thrive due to a lack of process/structure to support the innovation(s) l o w innovations birthed, but rarely survive and thrive due to a lack of leadership support innovations rarely birthed, innovations that are birthed quickly die due to lack of support from leadership and organizational systems 90 maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 references aronson, z. h., shenhar, a. j., & wenzhou, w. (2014). the effect of vision, artifacts, and leader values on contextual performance behavior and success in technology challenging projects: qualitative evidence. international journal of innovation and technology management, 11(06). https://doi.org/10.1142/s0219877014500400 aziz, k. (2019). why is humility so relevant for leaders and can it be developed through coaching? strategic hr review, 18(1), 30-33. https://doi.org/10.1108/shr-10-2018-0088 back, p., & bausch, a. (2019). not if, but how ceos affect product innovation: a systematic review and research agenda. international journal of innovation and technology management, 16(03). https://doi.org/10.1142/s0219877019300015 bankar, s., & gankar, s. (2013). employee engagement and change management. journal of commerce and management thought, 4(2), 313-321. bennett, n., & parke, j.m. (2015). struggling to innovate? examine your structure, systems, and culture. business horizons, 58(5), 563-569. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.bushor.2015.05.009 calik, e., cetinguc, b., & calisir, f. (2020). a comprehensive validated model of innovation and performance: an empirical study of turkish companies. international journal of innovation and technology management, 17(03). https://doi.org/10.1142/s0219877020500194 cameron, k. (2010). five keys to flourishing in trying times. leader to leader, 55, 45–51. https://doi.org/10.1002/ltl.401 chapman, m. (2006). building an innovative organization: consistent business and technology integration. strategy & leadership, 34(4), 32-38. https://doi.org/10.1108/10878570610700992 chapman, w. r. (2007). how strategic innovation really gets started. strategy & leadership, 35(1), 21-29. chen, c., feng, j., liu, x., & yao, j. (2020). leader humility, team job crafting and team creativity: the moderating role of leader–leader exchange. human resource management journal. https://doi.org/10.1111/1748-8583.12306 cheung, m., & wong, c. (2011). transformational leadership, leader support, and employee creativity. leadership & organization development journal, 32(7), 656-672. https://doi.org/10.1108/01437731111169988 cheung, s. y., huang, e. g., chang, s., & wei, l. (2020). does being mindful make people more creative at work? the role of creative process engagement and perceived leader humility. organizational behavior and https://doi.org/10.1142/s0219877014500400 https://doi.org/10.1108/shr-10-2018-0088 https://doi.org/10.1142/s0219877019300015 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.bushor.2015.05.009 https://doi.org/10.1142/s0219877020500194 https://doi.org/10.1002/ltl.401 https://doi.org/10.1108/10878570610700992 https://doi.org/10.1111/1748-8583.12306 https://doi.org/10.1108/01437731111169988 maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 91 human decision processes, 159, 39-48. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.obhdp.2019.12.003 collins, p.d., hage, j., & hull, f.m. (1988). organizational and technological predictors of change in automaticity. academy of management journal, 31(3), 512-543. https://www.jstor.org/stable/256458 eisenbeiß, s., & boerner, s. (2013). a double‐edged sword: transformational leadership and individual creativity. british journal of management, 24(1), 5468. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8551.2011.00786.x engelen, a., schmidt, s., strenger, l., & brettel, m. (2014). top management’s transformational leader behaviors and innovation orientation: a cross-cultural perspective in eight countries. journal of international management, 20(2), 124-136. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.intman.2013.04.003 fernández, e., junquera, b., & ordiz, m. (2003). organizational culture and human resources in the environmental issue: a review of the literature. international journal of human resource management, 14(4), 634-656. https://doi.org/10.1080/0958519032000057628 fluss, d. (2018). smarter bots mean greater innovation, productivity, and value. scouting report. customer relationship management (malibu, calif.), 22(10), 38-39. hage, j.t. (1999). organizational innovation and organizational change. annual review of sociology, 25(1), 597-622. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.soc.25.1.597 kesting, p., & ulhoi, j. p. (2010). employee-driven innovation: extending the license to foster innovation. management decision, 48(1), 65-84. https://doi.org/10.1108/00251741011014463 khalili, a., muenjohn, n., & mcmurray, a. (2015), leadership behaviour, creativity and innovative behaviour: instrument development inquiry. iabc conference, hawaii, usa, 2015, p. 322-326. kotter, j. p. (1996). leading change. boston: harvard business school press. lacity, m., & willcocks, l. p. (2016) robotic process automation at telefonica 02. mis q. executive, 15(1), 21-35. lewin, k. (1947). frontiers in group dynamics. in cartwright, d. (ed.), field theory in social science. london: social science paperbacks. https://doi.org/10.1177/001872674700100103 ma, h. (2002). competitive advantage: what's luck got to do with it? management decision, 40(6), 525-536. https://doi.org/10.1108/00251740210433927 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.obhdp.2019.12.003 https://www.jstor.org/stable/256458 https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-8551.2011.00786.x https://doi.org/10.1016/j.intman.2013.04.003 https://doi.org/10.1080/0958519032000057628 https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.soc.25.1.597 https://doi.org/10.1108/00251741011014463 https://doi.org/10.1177/001872674700100103 https://doi.org/10.1108/00251740210433927 92 maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 mackey, j. t., & deng, f. j. (2016). examining the role of management control systems in the creation of an innovative culture. international journal of innovation and technology management, 13(03). https://doi.org/10.1142/s0219877016400022 maldonado, t., vera, d., & ramos, n. (2018). how humble is your company culture? and, why does it matter? business horizons, 61(5), 745-753. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.bushor.2018.05.005 madakam, s., holmukhe, r.m., & jaiswal, d.k. (2019). the future digital work force: robotic process automation (rpa). journal of information systems and technology management, 16. https://doi.org/10.4301/s18071775201916001 montes, f.j.l., moreno, a.r., & morales, v.g. (2005), influence of support leadership and teamwork cohesion on organizational learning, innovation and performance: an empirical examination. technovation, 25(10), 11591172. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2004.05.002 moussa, m., mcmurray, a., & muenjohn, n. (2018). a conceptual framework of the factors influencing innovation in public sector organizations. the journal of developing areas, 52(3), 231-240. http://doi.org/10.1353/jda.2018.0048 mumford, m.d., scott, g.m., gaddis, b., & strange, j.m. (2002). leading creative people: orchestrating expertise and relationships. the leadership quarterly, 13(6), 705-750. https://doi.org/10.1016/s1048-9843(02)001583 neves, p., almeida, p., & velez, m.j. (2018). reducing intentions to resist future change: combined effects of commitment-based h|r practices and ethical leadership. human resource management, 57, 249-261. https://doi.org/10.1002/hrm.21830 owens, b., & hekman, d. (2012). modeling how to grow: an inductive examination of humble leader behaviors, contingencies, and outcomes. academy of management journal, 55(4), 787-818. https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2010.0441 prasad, b., & junni, p. (2017). a contingency model of ceo characteristics and firm innovativeness: the moderating role of organizational size. management decision, 55(1), 156-177. https://doi.org/10.1108/md-022016-0071 rego, a., melo, a. i., bluhm, d. j., e cunha, m. p., & júnior, d. r. (2020). leader-expressed humility predicting team psychological safety: a personality dynamics lens. journal of business ethics, 1-18. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-020-04622-1 https://doi.org/10.1142/s0219877016400022 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.bushor.2018.05.005 https://doi.org/10.4301/s1807-1775201916001 https://doi.org/10.4301/s1807-1775201916001 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.technovation.2004.05.002 http://doi.org/10.1353/jda.2018.0048 https://doi.org/10.1016/s1048-9843(02)00158-3 https://doi.org/10.1016/s1048-9843(02)00158-3 https://doi.org/10.1002/hrm.21830 https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2010.0441 https://doi.org/10.1108/md-02-2016-0071 https://doi.org/10.1108/md-02-2016-0071 https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-020-04622-1 maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 93 seasongood, s. (2016). not just for the assembly line: a case for robotics in accounting and finance. financial executive, 32(1), 31-32. torugsa, n., & arundel, a. (2016). complexity of innovation in the public sector: a workgroup-level analysis of related factors and outcomes. public management review, 18(3), 392-416. https://doi.org/10.1080/14719037.2014.984626 uzkurt, c., kumar, r., & ensari, n. (2013). assessing organizational readiness for innovation: an exploratory study on organizational characteristics of innovativeness. international journal of innovation and technology management, 10(04). https://doi.org/10.1142/s0219877013500181 vera, d., & rodriguez-lopez, a. (2004). strategic virtues: humility as a source of competitive advantage. organizational dynamics, 33(4), 393-408. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.orgdyn.2004.09.006 vroom, v.h., & jago, a.g. (2007). the role of the situation in leadership. american psychologist, 62(1), 17-24. https://doi.org/10.1037/0003066x.62.1.17 ye, b. h., tung, v. w. s., li, j. j., & zhu, h. (2020). leader humility, team humility and employee creative performance: the moderating roles of task dependence and competitive climate. tourism management, 81. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tourman.2020.104170 https://doi.org/10.1080/14719037.2014.984626 https://doi.org/10.1142/s0219877013500181 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.orgdyn.2004.09.006 https://doi.org/10.1037/0003-066x.62.1.17 https://doi.org/10.1037/0003-066x.62.1.17 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tourman.2020.104170 94 maldonado et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 73-94 the impact of managerial discretion on firm performance anisya susan thomas florida international university miami, florida joseph peyrefitte florida atlantic university ft. lauderdale, florida abstract theoretical arguments from two distinct literatures are integrated to develop a model which attempts to shed further light on the determinants of performance in multinational corporations. it is suggested that the ambiguity of results in prior investigations could be attributed to variations in managerial discretion. building on the concept of managerial discretion, it is hypothesized that in high discretion settings, organizational and leadership factors will be associated with performance. in contrast, in low discretion settings, where environmental factors predominate, managers have limited latitude; therefore, the impact of these factors on performance will be limited. these hypotheses are tested in two different industry settings. the results largely confirm the theoretical contentions. introduction the theoretical roots of international business (ib) are reflected in a rapidly evolving discipline where alternative perspectives and paradigms are continuously introduced and evaluated. while the multiplicity of different approaches contributes to the richness of the field, the failure to synthesize theories has also led to barriers between scholars and the duplication of research across distinct functional areas. in commenting on this trend, dunning (1989) suggests that the advancement of academic excellence in ib will be best achieved by integrating relevant parts of multiple disciplines. in other words, interdisciplinary research which transcends functional borders to develop explanations for the success and failure of organizations in the global arena will contribute substantially to an enhanced understanding of the complexities of a multidimensional field. in this paper we build upon studies in international business and strategic management to explore the determinants of success in multinational corporations (mncs). by using the concept of managerial discretion, we integrate these theo22 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 1 retical platforms and develop an argument for the differential impact of environmental, organizational, and leadership factors on financial outcomes. our model is then empirically tested and directions for future research are delineated. hypotheses the determinants of performance in large mncs are an area of persistent and enduring interest to researchers in the field of international business. during the last two decades, several studies have explored the impact of various factors on the success and growth of these organizations (e.g., daniels & bracker, 1989; geringer, beamish, & dacosta, 1989; grant, 1987; haar, 1989; rugman, 1983; sullivan, 1994b). the variables hypothesized to affect mnc performance include organizational factors such as the level of international involvement (multinationality), firm nationality, product diversification, direction of international involvement, advertising expenditures, and research and development spending in addition to environmental factors such as industry differences. although there have been a wealth of studies, empirical findings from these efforts provide little consensus regarding the impact of various internal and external forces on performance outcomes. for example, daniels and bracker (1989), dunning (1981), haar (1989), and kumar (1984) failed to find a link between multinationality and mnc profitability or growth. in contrast, grant (1987), kim, hwang, and burgers (1989), and mitchell, shaver, and yeung (1993) found positive associations, while siddharthan and lan (1982) found negative relationships between the same variables. complicating the matter even further, geringer, et al. (1989) and sullivan (1994b) found curvilinear relationships between the degree of internationalization and performance. similar contradictions characterize the study of the impact of other organizational factors such as r&d spending and capital intensity on the performance of multinational enterprises (e.g. severn & laurence, 1974; siddharthan & lall, 1982; vernon, 1971). in addition, industry differences have been shown to have both significant (daniels & bracker, 1989; haar, 1989) and insignificant (grant, 1987) effects on profitability. table 1 provides a review of the empirical findings in selected studies of mnc performance (for extensive methodological reviews, see ramaswamy (1992) and sullivan (1994a». in spite of two-and-a-half decades of research of the phenomenon, there does not seem to be any consistent pattern in the relationships between various internal and external factors and the performance of mnc's. however, there is a movement away from the examination of individual, unidimensional indicators to more multidimensional conceptualizations that incorporate the combined impact of the organization and environment, through the consideration of constructs such as the role of strategy (geringer et ai., 1989). despite the dominance of the rational-economic and market power models in the literature (see table 1), and the lack of empirical evidence, there is also consid erable agreement that the leaders of multinational organizations do in fact play spring 1996 thomas & peyrefitte: managerial discretion 23 table 1 review of empirical findings in studies of mnc performance8 study sample findings vernon (1971) severn & laurence (1974) buckley, dunning, pearce (1978) 187 fortune 500 firms 48 mncs, 70 non-mncs (u.s.) 1,000 u.s. mncs from various industries mncs earned higher returns than nonmncs. advertising intensity and r&d intensity were also associated with higher returns; mncs typically reflect higher levels of advertising and r&d intensity. no association between foreign direct investment and profitability. overseas profitability was associated with level of r&d. level of overseas activity had a positive relationship with organizational growth for one period of the study. dunning (1981) 188 large u.k mncs in 1979 siddharthan & 74 largest u.s.mncs lall (1982) in 1976-79 rugman (1983) 50 largest u.s.mncs, 50 largest european mncs overseas production was insignificantly related to return on assets. overseas ratio had a negative influence on firm growth once firm size, advertising, r&d intensity, scale economies, and profitability were taken into account. european mncs were less profitable than u.s. mncs. size and risk were not significant. kumar (1984) michel & shaked (1986) grant (1987) grant, jammine, & thomas (1988) 672 u.k. quoted cos., 1972-76 58 mncs, 43 nonmncs (u.s.) 304 british mncs 304 british mncs mncs earned higher return on assets and on sales than domestic firms. overseas ratio was not significantly related to profitability and growth. risk-adjusted performance is superior for non-mncs. muftinationality was positively associated with superior profitability. destination of overseas expansion and industry effects were not significant. product diversity led to declining profitability once firms encountered limits to complexity. however, multinational diversity was strongly related to profitability. 24 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 1 table 1 review of empirical findings in studies of mnc performancea cont'd study sample findings daniels & 116 large u.s. firms bracker (1989) geringer, 100 largest u.s. mncs. beamish, & 100 largest european dacosta (1989) mncs the relationship between profit performance and dependence on foreign operations varied widely according to industry u.s. mncs were more profitable than european mncs. related diversification strategies yielded superior performance. the degree of internationalization exhibited a positive relationship with performance until a threshold level was reached. haar (1989) kim, hwang, burgers (1989) mitchell, shaver, & yeung (1993) blaine (1994) 50 largest u.s. mncs, 50 largest european mncs, 50 largest japanese mncs 62 u.s. mncs 17 u.s. firms in a "domestic" industry, 18 u.s. firms in a "transition" industry 100 large industrial companies each in germany, japan, and the u.s. past performance, industry, and nationality significantly impacted performance. size, state ownership, and multi nationality were not significant. profitability varied with the extent of internationalization. related diversifiers outperformed unrelated diversifiers. however, unrelated diversifiers that were well diversified internationally outperformed those that were not. international expansion returns superior performance in both domestic and transition industries. only minor differences were found in the financial performance of large multinational firms (each derives a substantial portion of its revenues from foreign operations) from three nations. accounting differences across countries were controlled for; thus these factors did not play a significant role in the minor differences across firms. spring 1996 thomas & peyrefitte: managerial discretion 25 table 1 review of empirical findings in studies of mnc performance8 cont'd study sample findings carpano, chrisman, & roth (1994) sullivan (1994b) 319 u.s. mncs from 33 industries 100 largest u.s. mncs, 100 largest european mncs; 75 most international u.s. manufacturing mncs geographic scope and segment differentiation were used to distinguish four international strategies in global and multidomestic industries (segmented, mass-market, segmented-focus, and focus). performance across the strategies varied with the measure of performance (roi or sales growth). however, conclusive results were found in global industries. in global industries segmented and focus strategies were more effective than segmented-focus strategies. using the foreign sales/total sales ratio, the threshold of internalization (geringer, beamish & dacosta[1989]) was confirmed; however, when internationalization was measured with an "international scale," the threshold was not confirmed; mncs of slight and high degrees of internationalization experienced both low and high degrees of profitability. • for extensive methodological reviews see ramaswamy (1992) and sullivan (1994a). an important role in designing responses to environmental challenges and marshalling organizational resources to meet them. thus, the extant knowledge about the predictors of performance in multinational organizations can be restated in an integrated form as: h1: the performance of mncs is a function of environmental, organizational, and leadership factors~ however, investigations of mnc performance continue to emphasize methodological solutions to explain the ambiguity and contradictions that characterize the literature (see sullivan, 1994a). while new methodological approaches are critical to the advancement of knowledge, we contend that in order to move towards a better understanding of mnc performance, there is a need for a broader, more holistic conceptualization which looks beyond the findings of any individual study. instead, the focus should shift to the 26 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. i search for theoretical explanations of why factors such as the extent of involvement in foreign activities contributes to performance in some situations but not in others. we suggest that a potential reason for the differential impact of environmental and organizational factors on the performance of mncs is managerial discretion, an emerging concept in the field of strategic management. managerial discretion: the missing link? the relative importance of managers and the environment to the success and failure of organizations is a source of considerable debate in the strategic management and organization theory literatures. advocates of the strategic choice paradigm (child, 1972) suggest that managers are the main arbiters of organization direction and performance. they suggest that since managers choose the domain for the firm's activities, decide on its resource allocation priorities, and design competitive maneuvers, they are directly responsible for its success or failure. in contrast, the proponents of the population ecology perspective contend that the success or failure of organizations is determined by inertial and environmental forces. in their view, organizational survival is largely dependent on environmental selection (hannan & freeman, 1977; aldrich, 1979). thus, in the framework of this theory, the role of managers and strategy becomes less important to organization performance. these opposing theoretical perspectives have each received considerable empirical support (e.g. lieberson & o'connor, 1972; gupta & govindarajan, 1984). however, their incompatibility has often resulted in mutually exclusive, yet parallel research. in other words, researchers subscribing to these alternative theoretical perspectives often investigate the same phenomena using different lenses. the mixed results of these efforts have highlighted the necessity of bringing these world views closer together. theorists in both camps (hannan & freeman, 1977; miles & snow, 1978; tushman & romanelli, 1985) seem to agree that each perspective may be more useful in some circumstances than in others. in addressing this issue hambrick and finkelstein (1987) developed the concept of managerial discretion. managerial discretion refers to the latitude of managerial action. more specifically, it pertains to the ability of a chief executive officer (ceo) to exert his or her influence in a variety of substantive and symbolic domains such as resource allocation, product-market selection, or the launching of competitive initiatives. hambrick and finkelstein (1987) argue that different ceos have different ranges of decision making options available to them, determined by a combination of environmental, organizational and personal factors. in other words, although environmental, organizational and leadership factors all have the potential to influence outcomes, the relative importance of each can vary by situational constraints. hambrick and finkelstein (1987) illustrate the impact of environmental factors on the level of managerial discretion in their argument which compares spring 1996 thomas & peyrefitte: managerial discretion 27 the latitude available to the ceo of a public utility and his or her counterpart at a medium-sized microcomputer firm. "the computer executive has legitimate options in the areas of pricing, promotion, production technology and locations, distribution, joint ventures and sales force incentives (to name but a few); and, realistically speaking, the utility executive's options in these areas are limited or even nil. viewed another way, the two executives may be said to have the same possible domains of action, but greatly different ranges of discretion in many of those domains" (1987:372). in the former instance, the top manager could make and execute decisions that change the direction and focus of the organization. for example, the decision of steve jobs to maintain the closed architecture in the machines produced by apple computer corp. set the company on an entirely different course from its competitors in the industry. however, in the latter case of the utility executive, the restrictive web of regulatory constraints imposed by environmental and governmental forces largely reduces the leadership role to that of a figurehead. in other words, identical decisions made by the ceos of the computer and utility firms will affect each organization in a different way. theoretically, because of the greater latitude available to the computer executive, the decision will have a much more immediate and significant impact on organizational performance. in contrast, the impact of the utility executive will be substantially diluted by the dominance of external environmental factors such as government regulation and environmental legislation. thus in some environments, managerial actions can alter the course of organizations. in others, environmentally determined factors predominate, limiting executive influence. this theory can be extended to the domain of mnc performance. it is reasonable to theorize that in high discretion settings where managers have the flexibility to make and execute strategic choices about whether to invest in new technologies or enter new markets, a relationship between leadership factors, such as the profile of top managers and strategic factors such as the level of r&d spending and performance outcomes can be expected. since managerial discretion encompasses choices that may be beneficial or detrimental, the relationship may be positive or negative. conversely, in low discretion settings characterized by powerful competitors, suppliers or buyers, low or negative growth rates and long-term contractual obligations, firms may be subject to strong inertial or market forces which overshadow or negate these linkages. thus we hypothesize that: h2: the relationship between organizational and leadership factors and mnc peiformance will vary with the constraints on managerial discretion. organizational and leadership factors have a greater impact on peiformance in high discretion settings in comparison to low discretion settings. 28 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. i operationalizing managerial discretion although hambrick and finkelstein (1987) defined managerial discretion to be comprised of three sets of forces, the environment, the organization and the chief executive, most studies have operationali zed this concept in terms of the environmental component, using industry as a surrogate for the environment. to quote finkelstein and hambrick (1990): "organizations function within domains defined by their products or services and by the markets they serve (levine and white, 1961). the characteristics of these domains, particularly the industry the firm competes in, greatly affect the level of managerial discretion. for example. lieberson and o'connor (1972) found that more variance in profitability could be attributed to ceos in industries with high advertising intensity and high growth rates-both of which signal discretion (hambrick and finkelstein, 1987)-than in more commodity like or low growth industries .... industries may differ along several important dimensions that affect the level of managerial discretion. one such dimension is product differentiability. industries characterized by product differentiability offer managers discretionary domains that are not available in commodity goods industries. ... other sources of environmental discretion are demand instability, low capital intensity, competitive market structures, market growth and freedom from government regulation. industries that are characterized by these factors offer greater discretion to top managers than do other industries (489)." the logic that the extent of discretion available to top managers varies by industry setting has been implicitly acknowledged in several studies of mnc performance. for example, daniels and bracker (1989) noted that the positive association between multinationality and profit varied widely by the industry environment. they revealed that in industries subject to heavy government regulation (such as aerospace), the multinationality-performance link was very weak. on the other hand, in the differentiated drugs and pharmaceutical industry, this association was much stronger. significant industry differences were also substantiated by haar. (1989) and carpano, chrisman, and roth (1994). therefore in this study, managerial discretion is assessed by industry membership. operationalizing strategic leadership the study of top managers, a field now referred to as strategic leadership, has become a central area of inquiry in strategic management. the origins of this research stream are usually attributed to hambrick and mason (1984) who built on the work of the behavioral theorists (cyert and march, 1963; march and simon, 1958) to explain the link between executive characteristics and organispring 1996 thomas & peyrefitte: managerial discretion 29 zational outcomes. in their view (a) managers have a limited field of visionthey can only scan some aspects of the organization and its environment, (b) managers selectively perceive only bits of information in their fields of vision (c) the information is then interpreted through a filter fonned by the manager's cognitive base and values (d) this individualistic interpretation is the basis of strategic choices. thus, choices made by managers on behalf of the organization reflect the characteristics of these managers, underlining the important role that managers play in determining organizational performance. the literature in strategic leadership suggests that since the cognitive bases which influence information gathering and evaluation are a product of backgrounds, experiences and training, demographic characteristics, such as age and education, can be used to assess this construct (wiersema & bantel, 1992). the efficacy of the demographic approach has been demonstrated in numerous investigations of the relationship between managerial characteristics and organizational outcomes (e.g. chaganti & sambharya, 1987; gupta & govindarajan, 1984; thomas, litschert & ramaswamy, 1991; wiersema & bantel, 1992). for example, wiersema and bantel (1992) found that attributes such as top management team youth, organizational tenure, educational level, and functional backgrounds were useful indicators of an organization's propensity for strategic change. thus, in keeping with the tradition of research in strategic leadership, the impact of managers on performance is examined by considering the relationship between the demographic profiles of the ceos and financial performance. method sample and setting our sample was restricted to u.s. based multinationals in order to control for variations in national context which inevitably influence the competitive posture and behavior of firms (porter, 1990). the initial sample consisted of all the firms in the electronics and computer industries (sic 367 and 368) and the chemical and petroleum industries (sic 281 and 291) listed in fortune magazine's 500 largest industrial organizations that (a) had international sales and (b) for which top manager data were available. these industries were specifically chosen as prior research (see for example, finkelstein and hambrick, 1990; hambrick and finkelstein, 1987) found that they represented distinct levels of managerial discretion. since comparative analysis indicated a large overlap in products and a lack of significant differences in terms of growth rates, size and profitability, the firms in the electronics and computer industries were combined to represent the high discretion setting and the firms in the chemical and petroleum industries were combined to represent the low discretion setting. the high discretion sample consisted of 28 firms that exhibited a high degree of product differentiability, low capital intensity and rapid growth (84% over five years), 30 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 1 characteristics specified by hambrick and finkelstein (1987) as being typical of settings where managers had greater latitude. the low discretion sample consisted of 32 firms that together typified an industry that was mature, had lower growth rates (5% over five years), established patterns of investment and subject to considerable government regulation, all characteristics of contexts where managerial latitude is constrained. table 2 presents the descriptive statistics for all the variables in the study. measures and data environmental factors. as discussed above, industry was used to operationalize the degree of discretion in firms' task environments. dummy variables were used to code firms in either high or low discretion environments. the electronics and computer industry represented the high discretion setting and the chemicals and petroleum refining industry represented the low discretion setting. organizational factors. organizational factors were defined in terms of variables that have been found to affect the performance of mncs in previous studies. data on organizational factors were collected for five years (19831987) from the 1989 directory of multinationals, the fortune 500 annual issues and compustat ii tapes. three distinct measures were used to operationalize this construct. these are detailed below: multinationality, an indicator of the level of a firm's involvement in overseas activity, was measured as the proportion of overseas sales to total sales, in keeping with the measurement scheme utilized by prior research (e.g. daniels and bracker, 1989; grant, 1987; haar, 1989). r&d intensity, an indicator of a firm's propensity to differentiate itself, was measured as the ratio of r&d expenses/total sales (e.g. kumar, 1984; siddharthan & lall, 1982). capital intensity, a common indicator of a firm's strategic focus on efficiency and low cost, was measured as the ratio of capital expenses per dollar of total sales. leadership factors. a large body of literature suggests that the chief executive officer (ceo) in a corporation provides the primary direction ofstrategic decision making by leading the firm's emergent social systems or dominant coalitions (e.g. lorange, 1980; pearce & robinson, 1987). further hambrick and finkelstein's (1987) theory of managerial discretion was explicitly related to the latitude of the ceo. hence the ceo was the unit used to measure the leadership construct. data on the chief executive officers were obtained from businessweek and dun and bradstreet's reference book of corporate managements. table 2 en means, standard deviations, and correlations for all variables·,b "0::1. ::s variables high discretion lowdiscretion 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 (jq --l.ros .06 .04 1.01.0 (.06) (.05) 0'\ 2.roi .06 .08 .82*** (.05) (.33) ~ 3. roe .13 .09 .71*** .78*** ~ ~ (.11) (.13) l:l.., 4. industry 0 1 -.17* -.18* -.18** ~ (.00) (.00) "l:l 5. multinationality .21 .28 -.06 -.06 -.06 .14# ~ (.14) (.17) ol~ 6. capital intensity .08 .08 .33*** .01 .01 -.02 .07 ~ (.09) (.03) '. ~7. r&d intensity .18 .02 .45*** .07 .04 -.48*** .05 .45*** ;::s (ll ) (.02) ~ 8. age 56.18 60.97 -.06 -.06 .01 .29*** .08 -.10 -.23** ~::l (6.04) (7.02) t:!'-9. company tenure 23.25 31.63 -.03 .02 -.02 .38*** .06 .04 -.35*** .51 *** '=' (10.82) (9.50) ~. n 10. position tenure 9.32 9.88 -.21 ** -.22** -.19** .05 .12# -.10 .02 .67*** .35*** ol.... (8.88) (9.22) s·;::s 11. education 17.68 16.94 -.05 -.04 -.01 -.06 -.12# -.15* -.05 .18* -.01 .15* (2.13) (1.33) 12. functional .46 .28 .06 .15* -.00 -.18** .04 .05 .17* -.25*** -.12# -.10 .11 orientation (.50) (.45) • standard deviations appear in parentheses #p <.10 *p< .05 **p < .01 ***p < .001 w b means and standard deviations are based on 5 year averages 32 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no.1 five demographic dimensions, previously found to be related to organizational outcomes, were used to operationalize this construct. these were: age. the age of the ceo has been linked to the manner in which a decision is reached and decision quality (kirchner, 1958). studies have consistently found that younger managers are associated with growth, innovation and risk taking, while older managers are more risk averse and tend to make more conservative decisions (carlsson & karlsson, 1970; stevens, beyer & trice, 1978). in this study, age was measured as the chronological age of the ceo. tenure in the company and position tenure (both in the company and in the position) has been used as a proxy for experience in the organization (kotter, 1982). previous research indicates that organizations pursuing efficiency strategies tend to be led by longer tenured executives who have been promoted from within the organizations, while market seeking organizations have a greater propensity to recruit from the outside (miles & snow, 1978; thomas et al., 1991). two separate indicators were used to assess managerial tenure, the number of years spent in the company and the number of years in the position of ceo. education the amount of formal education possessed by the leader has been found to be associated with organizational innovation (kimberly and evanisko, 1981). better educated executives are more receptive to new ideas. thus, the level of education possessed by the ceo was used as another indicator of the managerial characteristics construct. to operationalize this measure, a coding scheme was devised whereby each year of college education was added to a base score of 12 (for example, bachelor's degree;: 12 + 4 ;: 16, master's degree = 12 + 6 ;: 18, etc.). functional orientation has been related to the way in which executives approach and solve problems. for example, dearborn and simon (1958) found that when a group of executives from different functional backgrounds were presented with the same problem, they tended to define it primarily in terms of the activities of their own function. hambrick and mason (1984) built on this logic to classify various functional specializations as either "output" functions or "throughput" functions. output functions emphasize externally oriented activities such as developing products to meet market trends and searching for new domain opportunities, while throughput functions focus on the efficient transformation of inputs to outputs. following this logic, functional orientation was dummy coded as either output oriented (e.g. r&d, marketing) or throughput oriented (e.g. finance, production and manufacturing). spring 1996 thomas & peyrefitte: managerial discretion 33 performance. performance was measured using three separate financial ratios, return on sales (ros), return on investment (rol), and return on equity (roe). performance data were collected from compustat ii tapes and cross-validated with the annual survey. data analysis the data analysis was conducted using pooled ordinary least squares (ols) regressions. the cross-sectional organizational data were pooled in order to detect the average effect of the independent variables over the five year period (1983-1987). although pooling the data could violate some of the assumptions underlying ols regression, the approach is defensible because tests of autocorrelation (durbin watson's d) suggested that the errors were uncorrelated. to test hypothesis 1, each performance measure was regressed on environmental, organizational, and leadership factors. the results of this analysis are presented in table 3. to test hypotheses 2, six separate regression models were developed to assess the impact of organization and leadership factors on each performance measure under high and low discretion environments. the number of observations in the regressions varied between 140 and 160. the results of these analyses are presented in table 4. during our initial analysis we also separately regressed the performance variables on the organizational factors alone and also the leadership factors alone, yielding twelve separate regressions. however, these analyses provided only five significant f statistics, suggesting that performance cannot be explained by either organizational or leadership factors alone. results and discussion hypothesis 1 essentially reflected the findings of prior research and formed the baseline for the test of managerial discretion in multinational organizations. according to this hypothesis: the performance of mncs is a function of environmental, organizational, and leadership factors. this hypothesis was clearly supported. as indicated in table 3, the combination of environmental, organizational and leadership factors consistently explained a significant proportion of variance in each performance indicator. although the proportion of variance explained ranges from 35.3% (ros) to 15.4% (roi) and 13.7% (roe), in each case the equations are statistically significant. 34 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 1 table 3 pooled ols regression analyses8 variables ros roi roe intercept -.125* -.034 -.175 (.05) (.056) (.133) industry -.004 -.028** -.076** (.008) (.01) (.023) multinationality -.026 -.006 -.007 (.022) (.024) (.057) capital intensity .056 -.061 -.06 (.062) (.07) (.244) r&d intensity .614*** .098 .107 (.092) (.103) (.166) age .003*** .002** .006** (.001) (.001) (.002) company tenure .001* .001* .001 (.000) (.001) (.001) position tenure -.003*** -.003*** -.006*** (.001) (.001) (.001) education .000 -.002 -.001 (.002) (.002) (.006) functional orientation .002 .018* -.001 (.008) (.009) (.02) r2 .353 .154 .137 f 11.757*** 3.94*** 3.43*** • standard errors appear in parentheses *p < .05; **p < .01; ***p < .001; n = 300 hypothesis 2 stated: the relationship between organizational and leadership factors and mnc peiformance will vary with the constraints on managerial discretion. organizational and leadership factors have a greater impact on peiformance in high discretion settings in comparison to low discretion settings. to test, the firms were separated by industry and the tests were repeated. dramatic differences in the proportion of variance explained were observed. there was a significant increase in the variance explained in the high discretion environment [63.8% (ros), 27.1 % (roi) and 31.5% (roe)] and a decrease in the variance explained in the low discretion environment [11.7% ros; 11.7%. (rgi) and 11.7% (roe)]. thus the hypothesis was supported by the observation of the differential impact of organization and leadership factors across different levels of managerial discretion. spring 1996 thomas & peyrefitte: managerial discretion 35 table 4 results of pooled ols regression analyses by industry environment' ros roi roe high low high low high low variables discretion discretion discretion discretion discretion discretion intercept -.152 -.065 -.002 -.082 -.224 -.226 (.095) (.074) (.107) (.085) (.209) (.209) multinationality -.091# -.032 -.031 -.023 -.193# -.009 (.054) (.027) (.061) (.031) (.119) (.076) capital intensity .096 -.046 .079 -.166 .056 -.266 (.101) (.148) (.114) (.169) (.222) (.417) r&d intensity .604*** .697* -.109 .541 -.047 2.105* (.129) (.333) (.145) (.380) (.284) (.936) age .003# .003# .002 .003# .007* .013** (.002) (.001) (.002) (.002) (.003) (.004) company tenure .001 .000 .000 .000 .000 .000 (.001) (.000) (.000) (.000) (.002) (.002) position tenure -.004*** -.002* -.003* -.003* -.006*** -.009** (.00l) (.000) (.000) (.001) (.002) (.003) education .002 -.004 -.002 -.004 .002 -.023# (.003) (.004) (.003) (.005) (.006) (.012) functional -.006 .006 -.004 .018 .002 .062 orientation (.015) (.014) (.017) (.016) (.033) (.040) r2 .638 .117 .271 .117 .315 .117 f 11.585*** 1.832# 2.446* 1.857# 3.013** 1.849# ·standard errors appear in parentheses high discretion environment: n = 140 low discretion environment: n = 160 #p < .10; *p < . 05; **p<.oi; ***p < . 001 a consideration of the directional relationships between the individual organizational and managerial variables and firm performance in the overall sample as compared to the sample separated by level of discretion reveals an interesting picture as well. in the overall sample, there was no relationship between multi nationality and performance. when industry is taken into account, multinationality was significantly and negatively related to two of the three performance indicators in the high discretion environment but no relationship was statistically discernible in the low discretion environment. this is perhaps a result of the high start up costs that firms in the u.s. electronics and computer industries face as they attempt to diversify geographically. 36 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 1 capital intensity did not seem to have any impact either in the overall sample or when the firms were separated by industry. on the other hand r&d intensity was important to ros in the overall sample as well as in both discretionary environments. this finding may imply that investment in developing new products and technologies is one of the few variables that consistently enhances performance even in low discretion settings. among the managerial variables, the consistency across the discretionary environments was interesting and surprising. ceo age seemed to have a positive impact on performance, in the overall sample and in the high and low discretion environments as well. this suggests that older ceos were able to improve performance to a greater extent than their younger counterparts, regardless of the industry in which they operated in. position tenure, on the other hand, was negatively related to every performance indicator in both settings. this seems to imply that the ceo might be getting 'stale in the saddle,' reinforcing miller's (1991) contention that long tenured ceos may rely on their past accomplishments and resist reorienting their organizations to changes in the environment, thus negatively impacting performance. overall, the results of this study tell an interesting story that sheds new light on research investigating the determinants of mnc performance. they suggest that the ambiguity and contradictions that characterize prior findings must be interpreted with caution. instead of dismissing and accepting the results of individual studies based on theoretical or methodological merits alone, researchers must attempt to search for underlying explanations which may explain why a factor such as multinationality may be positively related to performance in some settings, and negatively related or not related at all to performance in others. we suggest that managerial discretion, conceptualized in this study as industry membership, offers one avenue worthy of pursuit. under the theoretical umbrella that is discretion, it is possible to argue that the relative strength of the impact of environmental. organizational and leadership factors on firm performance will vary. while it is entirely possible, as this study has indicated, that r&d intensity or ceo age may have a universal impact while others such as multinationality may have a contingency impact, the extent of the impact could depend on the latitude of action available to top managers or the deterministic nature of the environment. limitations the results of this study are exploratory and must be interpreted with caution. the small sample size and the restriction to two settings limit the generalizability of findings. future efforts must replicate the test in larger and more diverse sample. further investigations can also refine the methodology by using generalized least squares procedures that specifically control for autocorrelation. spring 1996 thomas & peyrefitte: managerial discretion conclusion 37 this study has atttempted to integrate the fragmented findings that characterize research about the determinants of performance in multinational organizations. by considering the research stream through the lens of strategic management, it was suggested that mnc performance is essentially a result of environmental. organizational and leadership factors. in so doing, it responds to dunning's (1989) call for more interdisciplinary research and heeds the advice of bartlett and ghoshal (1991) and buckley (1993) who advocate that international business researchers draw on the strategic management literature to explore the role of managers in international, strategic and organizational contexts. further, it was suggested that the contradictions of prior findings can be reconciled under the theory of managerial discretion which suggests that the relative importance of the environment and strategic managers (and therefore organizational factors) can vary across situations. thus it is possible that some factors may have a significant positive or negative impact on performance in some situations and a minimal or no impact on performance in others. this study has some very important implications for researchers studying mncs. it suggests that an investigation of the determinants of mnc performance should be preceded by an evaluation of the factors that enhance and constrain managerial discretion. such an evaluation will provide insight to the relative importance of environmental, organization and leadership factors. it also suggests that single industry studies or studies of firms facing relatively similar constraints are necessary to accurately identify the factors that actually influence mnc performance. since discretion can vary widely by the setting, results of studies which include samples of firms from multiple industries may be contaminated by variations in managerial latitude. practitioners who study mncs should also be cognizant of the latitude of action available to top executives before arriving at prescriptions about avenues to survival and success. although managers are important, their ability to impact performance can vary by the constraints on their discretion. thus in low discretion settings such as petroleum refining, efforts to improve performance through executive succession and recruitment may not always evoke the desired results. similarly, the impact of changed strategies and new resource allocation decisions may be slower in some industries than others. thus the criteria for measuring the success of managers and strategies should reflect the relative freedom available to top managers. 38 journal of business strategies references vol. 13, no. 1 aldrich, h.e. or~anizations and environments. englewood cliffs, nj: prentice-hall, 1979. bart~ett, c.a. and s. ghoshal. "global strategic management: impact on the new frontiers of strategy research." strate~ic mana~ement journal 12 (1991): 5-16. blaine, m. "comparing the profitability of firms in germany, japan, and the united states." manai<'ment international review 34(2) (1994): 125-148. buckley. pj. "the role of management in internalisation theory." mana~ement international review 33(3) (1993): 197-207. buckley, pj., j.h. dunning, and r.d. pearce. "the influence of firm size, industry, nationality and degree of multinationality on the growth and profitability of the world's largest firms 1962-1972." weltwirtschaftlisches archiv 2 (1978): 243-257. carlsson, g., and k. karlsson. "succession and performance among school superintendents." american sociolo~cal review 35 (1970): 710-718. carpano, c., 1.1. chrisman, and k. roth. "international strategy and environment: an assessment of the performance relationship." journal of international business studi§ 25 (1994): 639-656. chaganti, r and r. sambharya. "strategic orientation and characteristics of upper management." strate~ic mana~ement journal 8 (1987): 393-401. child, 1.. "organization structure, environment and performance: the role of strategic choice." sociolo~y 6 (1972): 2-21. cyert, r.m. and j.g. march. a behavioral theory of the firm. englewood cliffs, nj: prentice-hall, 1963. daniels, j.d. and j. bracker. "profit performance: do foreign operations make a difference?" mana~ement international review 29 (1989): 46-56. dearborn, d.c. and h.a. simon. "selective perceptions: a note on the departmental identifications of executives." socjometry 21 (1958): 140-144. dunning, j.h. international production and the multinational enterprise. london: george allen & unwin, 1981. dunning, j.h. "the study of international business: a plea for a more interdisciplinary approach." journal of international busjness studjes 20 (1989): 411-436. spring 1996 thomas & peyrefitte: managerial discretion 39 finkelstein, s., and d.c. hambrick. "top management team tenure and organizational outcomes: the moderating role of managerial discretion." administrative science ouarterly 35 (1990): 484-503. geringer, j.m., p.w beamish, and rc. dacosta. "diversification strategy and internationalization: implications for mne performance." stratekic manakement journal 10 (1989): 109-119. grant, rm. "multinationality and performance among british manufacturing companies." journal of international business studies 18 (1987): 79-89. grant, rm., a.p. jammine, and h. thomas. "diversity, diversification, and profitability among british manufacturing companies, 1972-84." academy of manakement i!rn.m.lll 31 (1988): 771-801. gupta, a.k. and v. govindarajan. "business unit strategy, managerial characteristics and business unit effectiveness at strategy implementation." academy of mana~ement journal 27 (1984): 25-41. haar, j. "a comparative analysis of the profitability performance of the largest u.s., european, and japanese multinational enterprises." management international review 29(3) (1989): 5-18. hambrick, d.c. and s. finkelstein. "managerial discretion: a bridge between polar views of organizational outcomes." in l.l. cummings and barry m. staw (eds.), research in or~anizational behavior 9 (1987): 369-406. greenwich, ct: jai press. hambrick, d.c., and p.a. mason. "upper echelons: the organization as a reflection of its top managers." academy of manae:ement review 9 (1984): 193-206. hannan, m.t. and j.h. freeman "the population ecology of organizations." a!lliti: can journal of socioloe;y 82 (1977): 929-964. kim, wc., p. hwang, and wp. burgers. "global diversification strategy and corporate profit performance." strate~ic management journal 10 (1989): 45-57. kimberly, j.r, and mj. evanisko. "organizational innovation: the influence of individual, organizational and contextual factors on hospital adoptions of technological and administrative innovations." academy of manab,ement journal 24 (1981): 689-713. kirchner, wk. "age differences in short term retention of rapidly changing information." journal of experimental psychology 55 (1958): 352-358. kotter, j.p. the general managers. new york, ny; the free press, 1982. kumar, m.s. growth. acquisition and investment. cambridge, u.k.: cambridge university press, 1984. 40 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 1 levine, s., and p.e. white. "exchange as a conceptual framework for the study of interorganizational relationships." administrative science ouarterly 5 (1961): 583-601. lieberson, s., and j.p. o'connor. "leadership and organizational performance: a study of large corporations." american sociolo~ical review 37 (1972): 117-130. lorange, p. corporate planning, prentice hall, englewood cliffs: nj, 1980. march, j.g., and h.a simon. organizations. new york: john wiley, 1958. michel, a, and i. shaked. "multinational corporations vs. domestic corporations: financial performance and characteristics." journal of international business studies 16 (1986): 89-100. miles, r.e., and c.c. snow. organizational strategy. structure. and process. new york: mcgraw-hill, 1978. miller, d. "stale in the saddle: ceo tenure and the match between organization and the environment." management science 37 (1991): 34-52. mitchell, w., j.m. shaver, and b. yeung. "performance following changes of international presence in domestic and transition industries." journal of international business studies 24 (1993): 647-669. pearce, j.a, and r.b. robinson. "a measure of social power in strategic decision making." strategic management journal 8 (1987): 297-304. porter, m.e. competitive advantage of nations. new york, ny: free press, 1990. ramaswamy, k. "multinationality and performance: a synthesis and redirection." advances in international comparative management 7 (1992): 241-267. rugman, a.m. "the comparative performance of u.s. and european multinational enterprises, 1970-79." management international review 23(2) (1983): 4-14. severn, a.k., and m.m. laurence. "direct investment, research intensity, and profitability." journal of financial and quantitative economics 29 (1974): 181-190. siddharthan, n.s. and s. lall. ''the recent growth of the largest u.s. multinationals." oxford bulletin of economics and statistics 44 (1982): 1-12. stevens, j.m., j.m. beyer, and h.m. trice. "assessing personal role and organizational predictors of managerial commitment." academy of management journal 18 (1978): 74-81. sullivan, d.. "measuring the degree of internationalization of a firm." journal of international business studies 25 (1994a): 325-342. spring 1996 thomas & peyrefitte: managerial discretion 41 sullivan, d. ''the "threshold of internationalization:" replication, extension. and reinterpretation." manalit'went international review 34(2) (l994b): 165-186. thomas, a.s., r.j. litschert, and k. ramaswamy. "the perfonnance impact of strategy manager coalignment: an empirical examination." strate~ic mana~ement jourill!! 12 (1991): 509-522. tushman, m.l., and e. romanelli. "organizational evolution: a metamorphosis of convergence and reorientation." in l.l. cummings and barry m. staw (eds.), e&. search in qre-anizational behavior 7 (1985): 171-222. greenwich, ct: jai press. vernon, r. sovereignty at bay: the multinational spread of u.s. enterprises. new york: basic books, 1971. wiersema, m.p. and k.a. bantel. ''top management team demography and corporate strategic change... academy of manae-ement journal 35 (1992): 91-121. the impact of managerial discretion on firm performance volume 34, number 2 125 strategic reorientation in failing firms: the ceo perspective sonia taneja texas a&m university – commerce • commerce, tx guclu atinc texas a&m university – commerce • commerce, tx mildred golden pryor texas a&m university – commerce • commerce, tx abstract this paper addresses new ceos in failing firms and their potential positive or negative impact in terms of strategic reorientation and organizational survival. specifically, the authors recognize the need for new ceos of failing firms to be able and willing to rapidly make strategic and tactical transformative changes through their decisions and actions. specific suggestions are made in terms of capabilities and experience needed by new ceos of failing firms in order for them to positively impact the future of their respective organizations. keywords: strategic reorientation; failing firms; ceo power; managerial discretion; introduction organizations are routinely confronted with significant changes that trigger the need for strategic reorientation. virany, tushman, and romanelli (1992) assert that change in any of the key components of a firm’s strategy – structure, controls, and power distribution – constitute strategic reorientation. lant, miliken, and batra (1992) contend that strategic reorientation is a function of past performance, ceo turnover, top management team turnover, and/or environmental changes. priem, butler & li (2013) caution that our traditional view of strategic management needs to be expanded because strategic reorientation may also be driven by the demand side as consumers seek out greater value. organizational leaders must plan for strategic reorientation in advance of it being urgently needed. since there are precursors to the need for strategic change, it would be beneficial for academicians and practitioners alike to study those precursors and their probable impacts on organizations. stacey (1995) proposed an adaptive system in response to strategic processes most commonly referred to as strategic choice and system dynamics. 126 journal of business strategies successful organizational systems (i.e., successful individual organizations) adapt to the environment based on their upper echelons’ strategic choices (hambrick & mason, 1984), a transformational process in which organizational processes are restructured to adapt to the changes in the environment (zajac & kraatz, 1993). also, organizations adapt to environmental changes based on their ecologies, which is an evolutionary process of competitive selection while it is a challenge for the whole organization to transform and adapt to the environmental change (hannan & freeman, 1977). these well-established perspectives from which the strategic process of an organization is viewed comprise the system dynamics through which organizations are driven by “negative feedback processes toward predictable states of adaptation to the environment” (stacey, 1995: 477). the three perspectives relating to the causes of changes in organizational strategies include the following issues: (1) the issue of systemic properties, characterized by how organizations transform or renew themselves based on the human systems, e.g., how organizations change with the change in the ceo (stacey, 1995; daily & dalton, 1995; dowell, shackell & stuart, 2011); (2) the intention vs. emergence issue which questions the extent to which new organizational states (caused by changing organizational strategies) are the outcome of prior shared intentions of the agents within them or the top management (ceo) changes which impact the competitiveness and potential for survivability of the organization (stacey, 1995; mintzberg & waters, 1985); and (3) the free choice vs. determinism and constraint issue which questions whether the change of organizational strategies is based on the environment in which it operates and its capability to choose strategies and their outcomes (stacey, 1995, bourgeois, 1984; mackay & chia, 2013). we propose that, by utilizing their strategic choices, which is an antecedent for managerial discretion, organizational leaders can expedite and better manage strategic change. this line of research contributes to the extant literature by explaining how organizations can use complex adaptive systems to influence the strategic change process, thereby restructuring the organizations in ways that result in strategic reorientation. gordon, stewart, sweo, & luker (2000) propose that “industry turbulence and ceo turbulence (are) necessary precursors to strategic reorientation and suggest that industry turbulence conditions managers’ external attributions for negative financial performance in influencing strategic reorientation” (911). according to dess and beard (1984), the three dimensions of organizational environment are munificence (generosity), dynamism (turbulence), and complexity (intricacy). over the years, researchers have investigated the environment’s impact on structure (burns & stalker, 1961; karaevli, 2007), strategy (gilley, mcgee & volume 34, number 2 127 rasheed, 2000; miller, 1988), and decision-making processes (baum & wally, 2003; garg, walters, & priem, 2003, priem, rasheed, & kotulic, 1995). in this paper, our focus is on ceo changes in failing firms. over the years, researchers studied the impact of governance changes and firm survival, such as executive and director turnover prior to bankruptcy (daily & dalton, 1995) and board structure on the probability of failure (dowell, shackell, & stuart, 2011). other researchers investigated the effect of power struggle between the boards and the executives on strategic change (golden & zajac, 2001) and the need for ceos to use their discretion as a way to adapt to dynamic occurrences within and outside the organizational boundaries (peteraf & reed, 2007). firms that are failing typically are unable to keep up with the external environment with their routines. once the status quo is not working, there is a definite need for change. hence, the first thing many firms do is to change their ceos. however, research shows that changing ceos does not always help (daily & dalton, 1995). adopting a configurations perspective and partially echoing what prior researchers observed (e.g., ketchen, thomas & snow, 1993), our contention is that incoming ceos should be equipped to deal with the existing instability and dynamism. we also suggest that the only way for incoming ceos to implement radical change is through the use of managerial discretion (hambrick & finkelstein, 1987) which actually provides the source of power to initiate strategic reorientation. in addition, adopting an agency perspective regarding the board, we also propose a possible strengthening effect of board power. we aim to contribute to the ongoing debate about the need for powerful ceos with experience in dynamic environments for firm survival while the board is also powerful to support strategic reorientation. literature review strategic choice/strategic change early theorists proposed that strategic change is a key element for successful organizational entrenchment (barker & duhaime, 1997; stacey, 1995; schendel, patton, & riggs, 1976; hofer & schendel, 1980). if a firm is failing, apparently the current strategy is not working. then, change is needed to get the firm back on track. since the turn of the century, we have witnessed an ever increasing interest in strategic change (mackay & chia, 2013; haynes & hillman, 2010; franken, edwards, & lambert, 2009; lohrke, bedeian & palmer, 2004; crossan & berdrow, 2003). given the important role that strategic reorientations play in turnaround in 128 journal of business strategies declining firms (lohrke, bedeian & palmer, 2004), further assessment becomes imperative. it is necessary to examine the factors that cause organizational leaders to initiate change by utilizing organization’s abilities to achieve strategic reorientation. various studies have supported the assertion that strategic change enhances performance (hambrick & schecter, 1983; zajac & kraatz, 1993) while other studies concluded that strategic change reduces performance (jauch, osborn, & glueck, 1980; singh, house, & tucker, 1986). still others, such as zhang and rajagopalan (2010), found that the relationship between strategic change and performance is not linear. in fact, the authors postulated that, “the level of strategic change in the pattern of resource allocation will have an inverted u-shaped relationship with firm performance” (zhang & rajagopalan, 2010, p.336). in other words, while low levels of change become an adaptive mechanism to align organizational goals with the environment, high levels of change strengthen the disruptive effect which in returns negatively impacts performance. when and to what extent change is needed for a failing firm is the general theme of this study. in the next section, we discuss the importance of strategic precursors that lead to change. strategic precursors our characterization of strategic reorientation follows that of lant, miliken, and batra (1992) who indicate that strategic reorientation is a result of ceo turnover, top management team turnover, and impact of the external environment. there are also other precursors of change. for instance, priem, butler and li (2003) consider consumer demand to be an impetus for strategic reorientation. while, enhancement of customer value perception is an important strategic move, in this paper our focus is on the top executive officer who initiates change as a retrenchment strategy in failing organizations. the level of strategic change reflects the organization’s capabilities to experiment and the risk–taking aspects of the firm’s strategic choices (carpenter, 2000; finkelstein & hambrick, 1990; zhang, 2006). an important organizational condition that is salient to understand the nature and magnitude of strategic change is executive leadership (virany, tushman, & romanelli, 1992). upper echelons theory states that organizational outcomes, including both strategic choices and performance levels, can be predicted by the top management characteristics (hambrick & mason, 1984). in fact, according to hambrick and mason (1984), organizations are reflections of their upper echelons. ceo career experiences, for example, have a high impact volume 34, number 2 129 potential on organizational happenings (greiner, cummings, & bhambri (2002); zhang, & rajagopalan, 2010). one concept to remember is “managerial discretion.” hambrick and finkelstein (1987) define discretion as “latitude of action” (p.369). the potential impact of an executive is determined by the amount of discretion he or she has in an organization. finkelstein, hambrick and canella (2009) propose that environmental, organizational and personal factors determine the amount of executive discretion. one personal characteristic is commitment to status quo. in the case of a failing firm, once a new ceo is brought in, he or she would be reluctant to stick to the status quo. actually, this ceo is brought in to challenge the status quo that is not working in the first place. crossland & hambrick (2011) postulate that “the concept of managerial discretion provides a theoretical fulcrum for resolving the debate about whether chief executive officers (ceos) have much influence over company outcomes (p. 797). the overall impact of the level of strategic change on an organization’s performance can be observed when a ceo moves from one industry to another. for instance, the recently retired ceo of ford motor corp. was previously the ceo of boeing inc. before he joined ford. during his reign, ford went through an entire restructuring process. commensurately, it is beneficial to note that ceo origin has a moderating effect on the impact of strategic change on firm performance (zhang & rajagopalan, 2010). as a side note, barker and mone (1998) purported that change in ceos during a turnaround may lead to mechanistic shifts as new ceos attempt to make decisions and take actions affecting their organizations. they found that “mechanistic structure shifts did restrict firms’ abilities to change their strategic orientations in response to decline” (barker & mone, 1998, p. 1227). another finding of barker and mone (1998) was that “replacing the firm’s ceo during turnaround attempts had conflicting and paradoxical effects on firms’ abilities to enact strategic reorientation” (p. 1227). new ceos are likely to attempt to directly reorient the organizational strategies. for example, ron johnson joined j.c penney’s as chief executive officer. in 2013 (17 months later), he was fired after his controversial attempts to change the retail chain led to a 25 percent plunge in sales (townsend, 2014). to further explain our contentions, we next offer our propositions. to be specific, we assess the possible impact of ceo power, ceo experience, particularly in the case of dynamic industries, and a possible moderating effect of board power on these relationships. 130 journal of business strategies propositions the effect of new ceo power on strategic change according to carpenter (2000), strategic change is comprised of two components. the first one is strategic variation, which refers to change from the existing resource allocation structure of the firm, and the second component is strategic deviation, described as the shift away from the firm’s resource commitments determined by the industry norms. these variations and deviations are managed and handled by the ‘board capital’. as a strategic management concept, hillman and dalziel (2003) described board capital as the sum of the human and social capital of the board of directors and the board’s ability to provide resources to the organization to capture strategic change. one concept is that ceo power acts as an intermediary and moderates the relationship between board capital and strategic variation and deviation (haynes & hillman, 2010). ceo power’s role in strategic decision making (finkelstein, 1992, haynes & hillman, 2010; pearce & zahra, 1991), strategic choice (mackay & chia 2013; quigley & hambrick, 2012; child, 1972), and strategic change (krause & semadeni 2013; hopkins, mallette, & hopkins 2013; haynes & hillman, 2010; hambrick & mason, 1984) to cope with internal and external sources of uncertainty are well documented in the literature. according to finkelstein (1992), for organizations, internal sources of uncertainty are top managers and boards of directors, and major external sources of uncertainty include performance and institutional environments. finkelstein’s (1992) study supports the upper-echelons theory and contends that managerial power affects the relationship between top managers and organizational outcomes. golden and zajac (2001) discussed the effect of boards on strategic change when ceos have power vis-à-vis the board. pearce and zahara’s (1991) typology relating to ceo-board power relationships is worthy of noting. in that study, the authors discuss four different types of ceo power/board power configurations. these board types differ based on composition, characteristics, processes in the organization, and decision making styles of the members of the board. proactive boards exercise more power and they are considered as true instruments of corporate governance. the board power exceeds the ceos power especially when the board consists of outside directors, and in the case of proactive boards, the board’s impact on firm performance is positive. with the participative board, in decision making, the emphasis is on reaching consensus among directors and members of the top management team. therefore, volume 34, number 2 131 negotiation and compromise are essential for effective control (haynes & hillman, 2010). according to haynes and hillman (2010), “a ceo’s preferences with respect to strategic change prevail when the ceo is powerful vis-à-vis the board” (p.1151). ceos may remain committed to the status quo because of industry’s strategic norms (carpenter, 2000) and because industrywide norms reduce competitive uncertainty (spender, 1989). thus, ceos often remain committed to past strategies (datta, guthrie, & rajagopalan, 2002) and strategic conformity to industry central tendencies (zhang & rajagopalan, 2004) because they seek stability in the competitive environment. as a result, “industry effects outweigh the importance of adopting ‘novel strategies’ often associated with the appointment of a new ceo” (haynes & hillman, 2010, p. 1151). “newly appointed ceo’s are known for their proclivity for change, (however) if the ceo is from the firm’s own focal industry, the mandate for change is overridden by the mandate to conform to industry norms” (haynes & hillman, 2010: 1151). another factor which can impact the level of strategic change is career variety of new ceos. crossland, zyung, hiller & hambrick (2014) suggest that ceos with high career variety tend to sponsor rapid change and increased strategic uniqueness so that strategic reorientation is more immediate and transformative. while ceos may tend to follow the status quo and the industry norms in the case of a powerful ceo, it depends on the strategic choices required by the organization. in such a case, the ceo’s preference for industry norms will impact the strategic change/reorientation and may decide the position of the organization in the industry. this is aligned with hambrick and finkelstein’s (1987) managerial discretion concept. the ceo is considered the personification of strategic leadership and is pivotal to the success or failure of an organization (finkelstein & hambrick, 1996). ceos from the outside are sometimes preferred over the inside ceos succession during the time of performance turnarounds because they can bring in fresh perspectives and new skills and they may be more willing to question existing practices and initiate major changes (kesner & sebora, 1994). however, various studies have found that outside ceos are generally less able to have positive effects on firm performance (greiner, cummings, & bhambri, 2002; shen & cannella, 2002; wiersema, 2002). this relates to the disruption and organizational chaos that is often created by the hiring and onboarding of an outsider as the ceo. such disruption often impedes any rapid turnaround efforts of a new outsider ceo. another problem is that “outsiders are less familiar with an organization’s particular routines and competencies and thus are more likely to either ignore or even challenge these 132 journal of business strategies competencies” (zhang & rajagopalan, 2004: 6). strategic change may be required when there is shift in the dynamics of competitive advantage for an industry as a result of technological breakthroughs that favor new rivals, global changes in labor arbitrage, change in cost structure, or new competitors entering markets from other industries. some of the changes are instigated by regulatory upheaval, such as the structural changes to the u.s. healthcare market set in motion by the affordable care act. virtually every ceo of a hospital system in the u.s. is confronting a major disruption to its business model as a result (irwin, topdjian, & ashish, 2013). quigley and hambrick (2012) posit that the retention of the former ceo as board chair restricts a successor’s discretion, thereby diminishing the new person’s ability to make changes and thereby decreasing the new ceo’s potential to greatly alter the firm’s performance. hambrick and finkelstein (1987) first used the term ‘managerial discretion’ and defined it as top management having latitude (flexibility) in their strategic choice and decisions in organizations. rajagopalan and finkelstein (1992) and finkelstein and boyd (1998) further concluded that the greater the level of discretion, the greater the amount of compensation paid to ceos. strategic orientation, environmental change, and reward systems in managerial discretion ultimately affect firm performance. the task environment, the organization, and the managerial capabilities of the ceo are the main determinants for ceo compensation and the discretion emanating from them (hambrick & finkelstein, 1987; finkelstein & boyd, 1998). the ceos who stay on as board chair are often committed to their prior decisions (hambrick, geletkanyez, & fredrickson, 1993; quigley & hambrick, 2012). researchers have studied factors that affect managerial discretion (crossland & hambrick, 2011; finkelstein & boyd, 1998). hambrick and finkelstein (1987) introduced the concept (theoretical construct) of managerial discretion to bridge the gap between two views about how top executive influence their organization so that they are either “inertial or highly adaptive” (p. 369). variation in managerial discretion could potentially be used to assess the suitability of the inertial and strategic-choice views. the polar extremes of executives are described by hambrick and finkelstein (1987) as “the titular figurehead and the unconstrained manager” (p. 369). we propose that, for new ceos in failing firms, power is a critical ingredient for ceo and firm survival. turnarounds in failing firms cannot be expected as a result of simply changing ceos. while the bases of ceo power may vary, the results of ceo power are more predictable. in a recent study, berns and klarner (2017) reported that, contender ceos, those who arrive after the current ones are forced to leave, are more likely to initiate change and likely to succeed. in addition volume 34, number 2 133 that, dowell and shackell (2011) reported increased probability of survival with greater ceo power. we consider managerial discretion as being the foundation for ceo power, and in return propose that, ceo changes in failing firms can only be successful if the new ceo is powerful as stated in the following proposition: proposition 1. ceo changes in failing firms can only increase the chances of firm survival if the new ceo is powerful. various scholars and researchers such as finkelstein (1992); nelson (2003); fischer and pollock (2004); and mackey (2008) further added to the extant literature that the strong position of the ceo in the firm improves the survival prospects of the organization. finkelstein (1992) and fisher and pollock (2004), for instance, observed that the independent position of the ceo in an organization positively affecting the survival prospects for firms facing significant financial distress. powerful ceos will have more impact in an environment that is characterized by low munificence and high uncertainty. such environments offer less with too many unknowns that requires a power source to hold the company together by initializing radical moves to cope up with such windy conditions. position of the ceo gives him/her an ability to take extreme decisions (adams, almeida, & ferreira, 2009). these extreme decisions change the firm’s strategy and in return have an impact on firm’s survival (dowell, shackell, & stuart, 2011). wielding power may not have much impact during periods of organization stability and success. however, as the organization is failing, the ceo capability to utilize power becomes more significant. when an organization faces financial problems, internal or external environmental turbulence and other issues of distress, it is advantageous to have a powerful ceo who can use that power to avoid the stigma of failure and increase the probability of success by making radical decisions. dowell, shackell, and stuart (2011) concluded that the greater the level of financial distress, the more the ceo power decreases the probability of failure. research has documented that firms experience many radical changes in systems, governance mechanisms, and business cycles due to change in ceo power (boone, field, karpoff, & raheja, 2007). firms which are not in equilibrium due to internal or external changes need new governance mechanisms; and failing firms need changes in governance mechanisms to significantly increase their prospect of survival (dowell, shackell, & stuart, 2011). for firms facing a crisis, the powerful ceos are beneficial. they respond faster to the environmental factors and enact necessary changes as required for the firm’s survival and sustenance (dowell, 134 journal of business strategies shackell, & stuart, 2011; boyd, 1995; finkelstein & d’aveni, 1994). powerful ceos have a greater incentive to maintain their reputation as a successful ceo rather than bearing the stigma as having had more responsibility for the firm’s failure (sutton & callahan, 1987). their association with the failure stigmatizes ceos of failed firms (semadeni, cannella, fraser, & lee, 2008). the actions of top management and boards have a direct and profound impact on corporate strategy (haveman, 1993). in short, the failing firm needs powerful ceos and they tend to initiate radical change to turn the company around. the above discussion leads to the below proposition: proposition 2. new powerful ceos of failing firms are more inclined to execute radical change. impact of new ceos from dynamic industries dynamism is about the stability of the environment in which the firm operates. if changes are taking place rapidly in the environment, due to uncertainty, strategic decision makers’ jobs become even more complicated (dess & beard, 1984). in such a turbulent atmosphere, the ceo is challenged to deal with constant change (galbraith, 1979; wholey & brittain, 1989). such an environment turns planning into a more complicated task (aldrich, 1979). for instance, it has been documented that managers operating in such environments are expected to implement broader ranges of strategic options (carpenter & westphal, 2001; karaevli, 2007). if a ceo is experienced to deal with turbulence, a major characteristic of environmental dynamism, he or she can carry that experience forward to manage firms in similar situations. by nature, firms that are failing deal with tremendous amount of turbulence. thinking about the internal routines in failing firms and their apparent failure to deal with the external environment, a ceo who is well equipped with how to deal with turbulence and is willing to use managerial discretion, might be a source of competitive advantage from a resource based view (barney, 1991). in other words, the ceo’s social and human capital becomes an important resource for a failing firm so the chances of survival increase. hence, we offer the following proposition: proposition 3. new ceos with experience in dynamic industries will increase the chances of survival for failing firms. volume 34, number 2 135 moderating role of board power upper-echelons theory highlights that organizational outcomes are affected by the performance of their top managers (hambrick &mason, 1984) and also posits that top management people have to have managerial discretion in strategic decision making. some top managers will have more discretion compared to others depending on the type of organization; hence, managerial characteristics may not always be predictive of organizational outcomes (finkelstein & hambrick, 1990). finkelstein and hambrick (1990) concluded that “(1) organization with long-tenure teams exhibit organizational performance that closely adheres to industry averages, while short-tenure teams are associated with deviations in performance levels; (2) top management-team tenure is more strongly related to strategies and performance in high discretion organizations (within an industry) than in low-discretion organizations” (p.489). moving on to pearce and zahra (1991) typology of board versus executive power, participative type boards, which signifies both parties to be powerful, is the best configuration for organizational outcomes. thinking about failing firms and the argument we made previously regarding the need for powerful ceos and the use of managerial discretion, the other major player of the dominant coalition, board of directors, should enhance the impact of ceos power on organizational outcomes, which in the case of failing firms refers to chances of survival. looking at prior research, several studies assessed the possible moderating effect of ceo power on the relationship between board and organizational outcomes. for instance, combs, ketchen, perryman and donahue (2007) proposed that ceo power interacts with board composition and firm performance. in a more recent study, chen (2014) proposed that board capital and r&d intensity relationship is positively moderated by ceo power. haynes, campbell and hitt (2014) on the other hand, demonstrated the need for powerful boards to minimize the effect of ceo greed while forcing the powerful ceo to work better which then translates into better organizational outcomes. to our knowledge, previous studies did not look at the possible moderating effect of board power on ceo power and firm survival relationship in the case of failing firms. if the ceo is expected to be powerful, particularly in the case of failing firms, paring him or her with a powerful board would not only result in more efficient strategic decision making process but also enhance the current corporate governance structure. we offer the following proposition to be further tested by empirical data: 136 journal of business strategies proposition 4. the relationship between powerful ceos and increased chances of survival will be moderated by board power such that the more powerful the board, the greater the chances of firm survival. conclusions and recommendations when organizations are failing, the prevailing judgment seems to be “change the ceo and do it now.” while we agree that change is needed, we propose that certain features of the ceo should be in place for successful entrenchment. first of all, contrary to the well-known contentions of popular governance theories, such as agency theory, a very powerful ceo is needed for turning around the company. this power is the source for challenging the status quo. if a firm is failing, radical change is needed and this change can only happen through dramatic moves impacting the current company structure. only a powerful ceo can do that. in other words, a ceo who is willing to exercise discretion, can make an impact as urgently needed for a failing firm. in addition, we consider ceo’s experience with dynamic industries to be a determinant factor. in dynamic environments, there is too much turbulence that requires the upper echelons to be on edge all the time. the situation of a failing firm is not very different regardless of the environment in which it operates. hence, a ceo with knowledge of how to deal with turbulence is more likely to change the picture for a failing firm. finally, we proposed a possible moderating effect of board power on the relationship between powerful ceo and chances of survival. we believe that a powerful board will complement the overall entrenchment strategy developed by a powerful ceo. besides, governance mechanisms would work better with such a pairing. all of these propositions are testable with empirical data. future researchers may consider utilizing secondary data sources to verify our propositions. also, we believe that our propositions have both practical and theoretical implications. from a theoretical perspective, we contend that ceo being highly powerful is not such a bad thing in the case of failing firms. this is a challenge to some of the fundamental theories of corporate governance. in addition the need for experience with dynamic industries is consistent with the configurations view. positive impact of the use of managerial discretion and the presence of a powerful board are also consistent with some of the seminal work in corporate governance literature. from a practical perspective, our recommendation to failing firms is to bring in a powerful ceo with experience in dynamic industries, then pair the new executive with a powerful board, and wait for him/her to implement change to save the failing firm. volume 34, number 2 137 in this paper, we offer four propositions to be considered and tested by future researchers. it is natural for firms to go down. however, in many instances some of these firms can be saved by having the right people in place. determining who might be the right person has always been an area of interest for organizational researchers. with this study, we aimed to contribute to this long-time ongoing discussion. references adams, r., almeida, h., & ferreira, d. 2009. understanding the relationship between founder–ceos and firm performance. journal of empirical finance, 16(1): 136-150. aldrich, h.e. 1979. organizations and environments. englewood cliffs, nj: prentice hall. arogyaswamy, k., barker iii, v. l., & yasai-ardekani, m. 1995. firm turnarounds: an integrative two-stage model. journal of management studies, 32: 493-525. barker iii, v. l., & duhaime, i. m. 1997. strategic change in the turnaround process: theory and empirical evidence. strategic management journal, 18(1):13-38. barker iii, v. l., & mone, m. a. 1998. the mechanistic structure shift and strategic reorientation in declining firms attempting turnarounds. human relations, 51(10):1227-1258. barney, j. 1991. firms resources and sustained competitive advantage. journal of management, 7: 99-120. berns, k., & klarner, p. 2017. a review of the ceo succession literature and a future research program. academy of management perspectives, 31: 83-108. baum, j.r., & wally, s. 2003. strategic decision speed and firm performance. strategic management journal, 24: 1107-1129. boone, a.l., field, l.c., karpoff, j.m., & raheja, c.g. 2007. the determinants of corporate board size and composition: an empirical analysis, journal of financial economics, 85(1): 66-101. bourgeois, l.j. 1984. strategic management and determinism, academy of management review, 9(4): 586-596. boyd, b. k. 1995. ceo duality and firm performance: a contingency model. strategic management journal, 16: 301–312. burns, t., & stalker, g. m. 1961. the management of innovation. london: tavistock. carpenter, m.a. 2000. the price of change: the role of ceo compensation in strategic variation and deviation from industry strategy norms. journal of management, 26: 1179–1198. 138 journal of business strategies carpenter, m.a., & westphal, j.d. 2001. the strategic context of external network ties: examining the impact of director appointments on board involvement in strategic decision making. academy of management journal. 4(4): 639-660. chen, h. l. 2014. board capital, ceo power and r&d investment in electronic firms. corporate governance: an international review. 22(5): 422-436. child, j. 1972. organizational structure, environments and performance: the role of strategic choice. sociology, 6: 1-22. combs, j. g., ketchen, d. j., perryman, a. a., & donahue, m. s. 2007. the moderating effect of ceo power on the board composition–firm performance relationship. journal of management studies, 44(8): 1299-1323. crossan, m. m., & bedrow, i. 2003. organizational learning and strategic renewal. strategic management journal, 24(11):1087-1105. crossland, c., & hambrick, d.c. 2011. differences in managerial discretion across countries: how nation-level institutions affect the degree to which ceos matter, strategic management journal, 32: 797-819. crossland, c., zyung, j., hiller, n., & hambrick, d.c. 2014. ceo career variety: effects on firm-level strategic and social novelty, academy of management journal, 57(3): 652-674. daily, c.m., & dalton, d.r. 1995. ceo and director turnover in failing firms: an illusion of change? strategic management journal, 16: 393-400. dalton, d. r., daily, c. m., ellstrand, a. e., & johnson, j. l. 1998. meta-analytic reviews of board composition, leadership structure, and financial performance. strategic management journal, 19: 269–290. dalton, d. r., hitt, m. a., certo, s. t., & dalton, c. m. 2007. the fundamental agency problem and its mitigation: independence, equity, and the market for corporate control. in j. p. walsh & a. p. brief (eds.), academy of management annals, 1: 1–64. essex, uk: routledge. datta, d.k., guthrie, j.p., & rajagopalan, n. 2002. different industries, different ceos? a study of ceo career specialization, human resource planning, 25(2): 14-25. dess, g.g. & beard, d.w. 1984. dimensions of organizational task environments, administrative science quarterly, 29(1): 52-73. dimaggio, p.j., & powell, w.w. 1983. the iron cage revisited: institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. american sociological review, 48(2): 147–160. volume 34, number 2 139 dowell, g.w.s., shackell, m.b., & stuart, n.v. 2011. boards, ceos, and surviving a financial crisis: evidence from the internet shakeout, strategic management journal, 32: 1025-1045. favaro, k. karlson, per-ola, & neilson, g. l. 2014. the lives and times of the ceo. strategy + business magazine, issue 75: 1-18. retrieved online from http://www.strategy-business.com/article/00254?pg=all#ceo_turnover. finkelstein, s. 1992. power in top management teams: dimensions, measurement, and validation. academy of management journal, 35(3): 505-538. finkelstein, s., & boyd, b.k. 1998. how much does the ceo matter? the role of managerial discretion in the setting of ceo compensation. academy of management journal, 41(2): 179–199. finkelstein, s., & d’aveni, r.a. 1994. ceo duality as a double-edged-sword: how boards of directors balance entrenchment avoidance and unity of command. academy of management journal, 37(5): 1079–1108. finkelstein, s., & hambrick, d. c. 1990. top-management team tenure and organizational outcomes: the moderating role of managerial discretion. administrative science quarterly, 35: 484–503. fischer, h.m., & pollock, t.g. 2004. effects of social capital and power on surviving transformational change: the case of initial public offerings. 47(4): 463-481. franken, a., edwards, c., & lambert, r. 2009. understanding the critical management elements that lead to success. california management review, 51(3): 49-73. fredrickson, j.w., & mitchell, t.r. 1984. strategic decision processes: comprehensiveness and performance in an industry with an unstable environment. academy of management journal. 27(2): 399-423. galbraith, j.r., & nathanson, d.a. 1979. the role of organizational structure and process in strategy implementation. little brown: boston, ma. garg, v.k., walters, b.a., & priem, r.l. 2003. chief executive scanning emphases, environmental dynamism, and manufacturing firm performance, strategic management journal, 24: 725-744. gilley, k.m., mcgee, j.e., & rasheed, a. 2004. perceived environmental dynamism and managerial risk aversion as antecedents of manufacturing outsourcing: the moderating effects of firm maturity, journal of small business management, 42(2): 227-133. gilley, k.m., & rasheed, a. 2000. making more by doing less: an analysis of outsourcing and its effects on firm performance, journal of management, 26(4): 763-790. 140 journal of business strategies golden, b.r., & zajac, e.j. 2001. when will boards influence strategy? inclination x power = strategic change, strategic management journal, 22: 1087–1111. gordon, s. s., stewart, j. h., sweo, r., & luker, w. a. 2000. convergence versus strategic reorientation: the antecedents of fast-paced organizational change. journal of management, 26(5): 911-945. greiner, l., cummings, t., & bhambri, a. 2002. when new ceos succeed and fail: 4-d theory of strategic transformation. organizational dynamics, 32(3): 1–17. hambrick, d.c., & finkelstein, s. 1987. managerial discretion: a bridge between polar views of organizational studies. in l. l. cummings & b.m. staw (eds.) research in organizational behavior, 9: 369–406, greenwich, ct: jai press. reprinted in b.m. staw, & l.l. cummings (eds.), the evolution and adaptation of organizations: 101-138, greenwich, ct: jai press, 1990. hambrick, d.c., geletkanycz, m.a., & fredrickson, j.w. 1993. top executive commitment to the status quo some tests of its determinants. strategic management journal, 14(6): 401–418. hambrick, d.c., & mason, p.a. 1984. upper echelons: the organization as a reflection of its top managers. academy of management review, 9(2): 193– 206. hambrick, d.c., & schecter, s. m. 1983. turnaround strategies for mature industrialproduct business units. academy of management journal, 26: 231–248. hannan, m., & freeman, j. 1977. the population ecology of organizations, american journal of sociology, 82: 929-964. harris, d., & helfat, c.e. 1998. ceo duality, succession, capabilities and agency theory: commentary and research agenda, strategic management journal, 19(9): 901-904. haveman, h.a. (1993). follow the leader: mimetic isomorphism and entry into new markets. administrative science quarterly, 38(4): 593-627. haynes, k.t., & hillman, a. 2010. the effect of board capital and ceo power on strategic change, strategic management journal, 31: 1145–1163. haynes, campbell, & hitt. 2014. when more is not enough: executive greed and its influence on shareholder wealth. journal of management 0149206314535444. herman, e.s. 1981. corporate control, corporate power. new york: cambridge university press. hillman, a.j., & dalziel, t. 2003. boards of directors and firm performance: integrating agency and resource dependence perspectives, academy of management review, 28(3): 383-396. hofer, c. w. (1980). turnaround strategies. journal of business strategy, 2(1): 19. volume 34, number 2 141 hofer, c., & schendel, d. 1978. strategy formulation: analytical concepts. st. paul, minnesota: west publishing. irwin, g. topdjian, j., & kaur, a. 2013. putting an i in the healthcare. business + strategy, 71: 12. retrieved online from http://www.strategy-business.com/ media/file/00167_putting-an-i-in-healthcare.pdf. jauch, l.r., osborn, r.n., & glueck, wf. 1980. short term financial success in large business organizations: the environment-strategy connection. strategic management journal, 1(1): 49–63. karaevli, a. 2007. performance consequences of new ceo ‘outsiderness’: moderating effects of preand post-succession contexts. strategic management journal, 28(7): 681-706. kesner, i.f., & sebora, t.c. 1994. executive succession: past, present & future, journal of management, 20(2): 327-372. ketchen, d., thomas, j.b., & snow, j.b. 1993. organizational configurations and performance: a comparison of theoretical approaches, academy of management journal, 36(6): 1278-1313. krause, r., & semadeni, m. (2013). apprentice, departure, and demotion: an examination of the three types of ceo-board chair separation. academy of management journal, 56(3): 805-826. lant, t. k., milliken, f. j., & batra, b. 1992. the role of managerial learning and interpretation in strategic persistence and reorientation: an empirical exploration. strategic management journal, 13: 585-608. lohrke, f.t., bedeian, a.g., & palmer, t.b. 2004. the role of top management teams in formulating and implementing turnaround strategies: a review and research agenda. international journal of management reviews. 5/6(2): 63-90. mackey, a. 2008. the effect of ceos on firm performance. strategic management journal. 29: 1357-1367. mackay, r. b., & chia, r. 2013. choice, chance, and unintended consequences in strategic change: a process understanding of the rise and fall of northco automotive. academy of management journal, 56(1): 208-230. doi:10.5465/ amj.2010.0734. miller, r. w. 1988. workers, managers, and technological change: emerging patterns of labor relations. employee responsibilities & rights journal, 1(4): 331-333. mintzberg, h. 1978. patterns in strategy formation. management science, 24: 934– 948. 142 journal of business strategies mintzberg, h., & waters, j.a. 1985. of strategies, deliberate and emergent, strategic management journal, 6: 257-272. molz, r. 1985. the role of the board of directors: typologies of interaction, journal of business strategy, 5(4): 86-93. nelson, t. 2003. the persistence of founder influence: management, ownership, and performance effects at initial public offering. strategic management journal, 24(8): 707-724. norburn, d., & birley, s. 1988. the top management team and corporate performance, strategic management journal, 9: 225-237. pearce ii, j. a., & zahra, s. a. 1991. the relative power of ceos. and boards of directors: associations with corporate performance. strategic management journal, 12(2): 135-153. peteraf, m., & reed, r. 2007. managerial discretion and internal alignment under regulatory constraints and change, strategic management journal, 28: 1089– 1112. priem, r.l., butler, j.e. & li, s. 2013. toward reimagining strategy research: retrospection and prospection on the 2011 amr decade award article, academy of management review, 38(4): 471-489. priem, r.l., rasheed, a.m.a., & kotulic, a.g. 1995. rationality in strategic decision processes, environmental dynamism and firm performance, journal of management, 21(5): 913-929. quigley, t.j., & hambrick, d.c. 2012. when the former ceo stays on as board chair: effects on successor discretion, strategic change, and performance. strategic management journal, 33: 834-859. schendel, d., patton, g., & riggs, j. 1976. corporate turnaround strategies: a study of profit decline and recovery. journal of general management, 3: 3-11. semadeni, m., cannella, a.a., fraser, d.r., & lee, d.s. 2008. fight or flight: managing stigma in executive careers, strategic management journal, 29: 557567. shen, w., & cannella, a. a. 2002. revisiting the performance consequences of ceo succession: the impact of successor type, post succession senior executive turnover, and departing ceo tenure. academy of management journal, 45: 717–733. singh, j.v., house r.j., & tucker, d. 1986. organizational change and organizational mortality. administrative science quarterly, 31: 587–611. spender, j.c. 1989. industry recipes. new york: blackwell. volume 34, number 2 143 stacey, r. d. 1995. the science of complexity: an alternative perspective for strategic change processes. strategic management journal, 16(6): 477-495. sutton, r. i., & callahan, a.l. 1987. the stigma of bankruptcy: spoiled organizational image and its management, academy of management journal, 30(3): 405-436. townsend, m. 2014. j. c. penney ex-ceo ron johnson didn’t get severance when he left. business week, p.1. retrieved online from http://www.bloomberg.com/ news/2014-03-07/j-c-penney-ex-ceo-ron-johnson-didn-t-get-severance-whenhe-left.html. virany, b., tushman, m. l., & romanelli, e. 1992. executive succession and organization outcome in turbulent environments: an organization learning approach. organization science, 3: 72-91. wholey. d. h., & brittain, j. 1989. characterizing environmental variation. academy of management journal, 32: 867-882. wiersema, m. f. 2002. holes at the top: why ceo firings backfire? harvard business review, 80(12): 70–77. zajac, e. j., & kraatz, m. s. 1993. a diametric forces model of strategic change: assessing the antecedents and consequences of restructuring in the higher education industry. strategic management journal, 14: 83-103. zhang y. 2006. the presence of a separate coo/president and its impact on strategic change and ceo dismissal. strategic management journal, 27(3): 283–300. zhang, y., & rajagopalan, n. 2010. once an outsider, always an outsider? ceo origin, strategic change, and firm performance. strategic management journal, 31(3): 334-346. zhang, y., & rajagopalan, n. 2004. when the known devil is better than an unknown god: an empirical study of the antecedents and consequences of relay ceo successions. academy of management journal, 47: 483–500. brief biograpical sketch of authors dr. sonia taneja (phd) is an associate professor of management, in the college of business at texas a&m university-commerce. dr. taneja’s primary research focus and publications are in the areas of strategic management and various other management topics from the strategic perspective such as empowerment from the gender perspective, crisis management, and management history. she has published in a number of scholarly peer-review journals including journal of management history, journal of business strategy, international journal of 144 journal of business strategies sustainable strategic management, journal of applied business and economics, and delhi business review. dr. guclu atinc is an associate professor of management at texas a&m university-commerce. his research interests include corporate governance and research methods in social sciences. he currently serves on editorial boards of several national and international journals. his work appeared in numerous outlets such as organizational research methods, journal of organizational behavior, journal of business research and management decision, among others. dr. mildred golden pryor is professor of management at texas a&m university-commerce where she has received many excellence awards for her teaching and research. she has received a number of excellence awards for her research from professional organizations. she also won top excellence awards during her 17 years in industry. dr. pryor has published many articles in a variety of scholarly journals, and she is on the editorial board for several journals. her research interests include: strategic management, quality management, leadership, and related topics. dimensions of culture in cross-border business linkages sara l. keck pace university new york, ny abstract several macroeconomic measures of linkages across numerous national borders are used to explore the impact of cultural distance on international business linkages. greater distances between hofstede's (1980) cultural dimensions are associated with lower total monetary value of several linkages, especially for power distance and individuality. the work here suggests there is cultural bias or constraint in choosing destinations of cross-border linkages. implications of that bias include costs associated with firms that venture outside established paths. introduction porter (1990) acknowledged the effect of culture on economic performance, and others have shown empirically that such a relationship exists. for example, franke, hofstede, and bond (1991) found that culture drives economic growth within the country. they found individualism and confucian dynamism to be positively associated with growth and concluded that cultural characteristics were more strongly related to economic growth than level of gnp per capita, refuting the economic convergence model (baumol, 1986). shane (1993) found that tolerance for uncertainty, individualism, and lack of distance between hierarchical ranks are all positively associated with higher national rates of innovation. the conclusion from previous work must be that factors other than simply economic ones drive economic decisions. firms and nations are not seeking solely other firms in the lowest-cost nations with which to build linkages. important historical cultural variables such as protestantism and achievement motivation (franke, et ai, 1991) and confucian values (hofstede and bond, 1988) are impacting those economic decisions as well. with the exceptions noted above (e.g., shane, 1993; tucker, jain, and failer, 1992), researchers are only beginning to examine the mechanisms through which culture affects measures of macroeconomic performance. the approach in this paper begins with the argument that the aggregate of firms' strategic decisions regarding cross-border linkages is one of the mechanisms through which culture impacts economic performance. cross-border linkages 108 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 are important because they translate cultural dimensions into firm activity across borders which, when aggregated, become linkages at the macroeconomic level for the nation involved. this is one of the first studies to demonstrate explicitly the aggregate mechanisms through which culture impacts economic performance. those mechanisms are important because the accretion of individual firm strategies impacts cross-border economic relationships among nations. there are several types of linkages among the economies of nations that reflect interorganizational linkages and entry choices. examples are the overall foreign direct investment from one country to another, the total monetary value of all royalties paid by finns in one country to firms in another country, and the total r&d investment of one country's firms in another country. these total amounts indicate the overall value of the relationships that firms are entering. it is important to understand the factors involved in the choice of the most effective international business relationships across national (often meaning economic and cullural) boundaries. there are at least three reasons for this. first, international relationships may act as coordination and control mechanisms for firms and, as such, may be mechanisms for the integration of the global economy. second, ventures abroad, such as foreign manufacturing, entail large investments even more so than in the past (egelhoff, 1988). new entrants have no previous experience from which to draw so initial experiences may be influential in organizational learning regarding linkages. third, the choice of linkages affect the form, structure, and size of the firm (garland, farmer, taylor, 1990). as a result, experiences may become institutionalized for the fiml and even for the industry and economic sector of which the firm is a part. for these reasons, international business linkages as reflected in the macroeconomic linkages has theoretical and practical relevance for transnational finns, industries and economics. other researchers (benito and gripsrud, 1992; keck, 1992; kogut and singh, 1988; tallman and shenbr, 1994) argued that the factors related to choice of interorganizational relationship include: 1) the socio-cullural factors in the country of origin and target country; 2) the organizational characteristics of the firms involved; 3) industry characteristics; and 4) the linkage itself. for example, kogut and singh (1988) empirically demonstrated that firms in countries considered to have cullures more closely aligned with american culture chose entry methods that were less dependent on partnering. further, when socio-cultural distance is great, economic factors will be overridden by cultural ones in the decision making process (benito and gripsrud, 1992; keck, 1992). cultural dimensions and macro linkages socio-cultural differences in managerial style have received systematic attention recently (e.g., adler, 1986a, 1986b; barsoux and lawrence, 1990; fall 1996 keck: cross-border business linkages 109 benito and gripsrud, 1992; calori and lawrence, 1991; hofstede, 1993; kogut and singh, 1988; lachman, nedd, and hinings, 1994; randall, 1993; shenkar and von glinow, 1994). during the decade of the 1980s, systematic evidence of management's cultural blinders has emerged (e.g., kim and naubornge, 1987; von glinow and teagarden, 1988). previous studies have typically addressed distance in a general sense rather than in specific dimensions (anderson and gatignon, 1986; kogut and singh, 1988). for example, kogut and singh (1988) investigated cultural distance as a factor in choice of entry mode and found that cultural distance does play a role in entry mode to the us market but did not specify which dimensions of culture were most important in entry choices. in other general statements of the importance of culture, some studies are beginning to include the impact of specific cultures on international operations (kobrin, 1987; tung, 1987). for example, in the study of expatriate performance, kobrin (1987) found anecdotal evidence that expatriate failures abroad are more often due, not to business conditions, but to the inability of managers to adapt to their assigned locations. more specifically, american expatriates fail more often than european or japanese expatriates because americans lack the international perspective of europeans and the cross-cultural training of the japanese. recognition of general cultural differences and international sophistication is important. but, it may be the cultural distance on specific dimensions rather than cross-cultural sensitivity, generally, that is more important in influencing location choices. this distance concept embodies not only the frequently recognized differences such as asian versus western and planned versus market economy but also more subtle features such as organizational structure and control as well. though other models of culture exist, the hofstede (1980) model provides the conceptual and empirical basis for judging cultural distances based on four dimensions: power distance, uncertainty avoidance, emphasis on individualism, and value placed on styles defined as masculine. hofstede's dimensions are widely used to explicitly recognize one-to-one differences between cultures. therefore, the model proposed here is based upon hofstede's (1980) measures of culture. for example, american firms may be more willing to invest in great britain than in india, chile, or taiwan because the difference between the cultural measures is lower between the u.s. and great britain than between the u.s. and india, chile, or taiwan. of course, the fact that most foreign direct investment into the us is from great britain and the netherlands supports this idea (e.g., us department of commerce, bureau of economic analysis, 1995). international business linkages of all kinds combine different organizational goals, strategy, structure, and personnel. some conceptual work (e.g., keck, 1992; tallman and shenkar, 1994) has recognized that some combinations are likely to be more effective, hence, repeated more often than others, but very little empirical work has documented this to-date. specific differences 110 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no.2 between originating and target cultures may play a major role in influencing which combinations end in successful long-term results that are imitated by firms from one country to another. investigation of differences is important because cultural considerations (embodying language, type of economic system, historical background of the country, and socio-cultural characteristics) may swamp the effects of economic and industrial characteristics when cultural differences are great. national culture is not a monolith. that is, not every member or firm in a culture can be characterized by the attributes of that culture in that there are subcultures and individual differences. there are many similarities or central tendencies, however, that may be observed in individuals and firms. hofstede's (1980) cultural dimensions as defined by national culture are a literature-based means for assessing culture. though there may be some weaknesses in hofstede's (1980) measures, they provide many advantages. because hofstede's (1980) work-related dimensions of culture are the basis of this theory, the relevance of each dimension is briefly described here along with its hypothesized relationship to international business linkages. the four cultural dimensions included are: power distance, uncertainty avoidance, emphasis on individualism, and value of masculinity. power distance refers to the issue of inequality of individuals in the society. in organizations power distance refers to the degree of centralization of authority or the degree of autocratic control (hofstede, 1980). this dimension raises such questions in international linkages as: who maintains control of the linkage; how is control established and maintained; at what level of the organization are decisions made; how is performance evaluated by output or by behavioral measures; and many others. as the distance between these issues increase, the less likely it is that the decision maker will choose the more distant location. therefore, fewer individual firms choose linkages in the more distant culture, and cumulatively the overall value of linkages is lower for the two countries involved. the hypothesis is: hypothesis la: greater differences in power distance between the target and originating nations are associated with lower total monetary value of each type of linkage between those nations. uncertainty avoidance refers to the degree to which a society's members are socialized to live with uncertainty brought about by the fact that the future is unknown. some societies socialize their members to accept uncertainty and not be upset by it. other societies socialize their members to attempt to "beat the future" which creates a higher level of anxiety, emotionality, and aggressiveness (hofstede, 1980). these characteristics suggest that individuals and firms that enter into linkages across national boundaries or cultures have issues to resolve, for example: what types of routine and nonroutine activities fall 1996 keck: cross-border business linkages 111 are they likely to be engaged in; how much fonnal planning must be perfonned; how progress from one step to the next is evaluated; and how decisions to proceed are made. again, as uncertainty-avoidance distance between the two cultures tends to dissuade individual decision makers from choosing the more distant culture, the overall monetary value of each type of linkage goes down for the two nations. the hypothesis is: hypothesis lb: greater differences in uncertainty avoidance between the target and originating nations are associated with lower total monetary value of each type of linkage between those nations. individualism versus collectivism is the third dimension. this is the degree to which the individual is responsible for just looking out for one's self and immediate family. individualism provides a great deal of freedom in the society. in other societies, individuals are taught to look after the interests of one's own ingroup and have limited personal interests (hofstede, 1980). when organizations link across such backgrounds there may be concerns such as: the basis upon which to measure value of the endeavor the individual's personal gain versus the finn's or the nation's; the importance of tradeoffs made between individual gain and society's gain; the degree of integration required of the individuals involved in the linkage; and others. as managers and decision makers differ more widely on these approaches, individual linkages are less likely to occur and the overall monetary value of such linkages will be lower for the two countries. the hypothesis is: hypothesis lc: greater differences in the value of individualism between the target and originating nations are associated with lower total monetary value of each type of linkage between those nations. masculinity versus femininity, the fourth and final dimension, refers to value placed on certain styles and to the division of social roles between genders in society. because social role divisions are more or less arbitrary, hofstede refers to those soci-eties with a high degree of division as masculine and societies with a low degree of division as feminine. related to this division is the value placed on the characteristics of each. that is, showing off, performing, making money, achieving something visible, etc are all valued highly in masculine societies while putting people before money, not showing off, etc are all valued in feminine societies. for organizations, this means that rewards for individuals go to those who match the dominant values. further, decision making systems will exhibit dominant values. in international linkages similar concerns arise: what will the strategic positioning be firstmover versus follower, etc; what will be the primary concerns individual 112 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 development versus profitability; and others. again, the distance between preferred styles will affect individual decisions and cumulatively result in lower overall monetary value of all linkages. the hypothesis is: hypothesis 1d: greater differences in the value of masculinity versus femininity between the target and originating nations are associated with lower total monetary value of each type of linkage between those nations. specialized strengths to enter linkages some cultures are less likely to succeed in linkages across cultural boundaries in general. for example, kobrin (1987) argued that americans fail in expatriate assignments more to difficulty in cross-cultural adjustment than to business conditions. if this is the case, american managers may be expected to have fewer and lower value cross-border linkages than managers from other countries. hofstede (1980) suggests that firms from cultures that have lower uncertainty avoidance will acquire more cross-cultural sensitivity, ceteris paribus. therefore, firms from cultures that have lower uncertainty avoidance will enter into linkages of all kinds and even vague, unstructured tasks such as research and development more frequently than firms from cultures that seek to avoid uncertainty. because the us has a relatively low uncertainty avoidance score compared to other nations, one would expect the american managers to have higher cross-cultural sensitivity, and higher-valued linkages, not lower. this extension from hofstede places hofstede's and kobrin's assessments in conflict. hofstede's suggestion is explicitly hypothesized here in the context of cross-border linkages. the hypothesis is: hypothesis 2: lower uncertainty avoidance of individual nations will be associated with greater values of all linkages, especially less-structured ones. methods sample data available in foreign direct investment in the united states and u.s. direct investment abroad used in the study are reported only at the level of national economies and only for those with linkages to the us. this may create a bias in the results in that only linkages to and from the us are included. however, there are also advantages in that the data used are consistent and comparable because they come from one data source. the economic data were combined with the work-related cultural values developed by hofstede (1980). data for which economic linkages and hofstede's measures were both available resulted in a maximum sample of 22 countries. countries included in the final sample include i3 west european fall 1996 keck: cross-border business linkages 113 countries, and australia, new zealand, japan, taiwan, canada, brazil, venezuela, israel, and the us. linkages between countries in either direction are included. measures-dependent variables though several types of linkages could be included, the following were available from the data sources: foreign direct investment, income, and return from the investment; capital inflows; royalty payments and receipts from licensing and from services other than those included in licensing; and r&d expenditures. descriptions of the dependent variables are summarized from the two sources from which the data were taken: i) foreign direct investment in the united states, 1990; and 2) u.s. direct investment abroad, 1985. these sources report values for 1987 and 1982, respectively. all values for these variables are reported in millions of dollars per capita to standardize the results by size of the economy. in keeping with commonly used methods, natural logs were taken of the standardized values and were used as the final form of the dependent variables. us foreign direct investment abroad was collected from the u.s. direct investment abroad (1990). investment abroad is us parents' equity in, and net outstanding loans to, their foreign affiliates. this is viewed as the us parents' contribution to total assets of the foreign affiliate. us foreign direct investment income is that which can be directly attributable to the us parent's contribution. us return on foreign direct investment is a return on investment (rgi) income divided by investment. foreign investment in the us, foreign direct investment income, and foreign return on investment in us are analogous to us foreign direct values. for these variables, investment abroad is investment by foreign affiliates in the us. expenditures for r&d in the us by foreign affiliates were taken from foreign direct investment in the united states (1885). the value used here is for r&d expenditures in all industries from each country included in the sample. r&d by us firms abroad and foreign r&d in us are a measure of research activity, whether it was done for themselves or for others. both measures of r&d expenditures represent the extent to which vague or indefinite tasks have been entered into by firms from each country represented. royalty payments and royalty receipts are direct investment royalties and licensing fees. payments are to us firms and receipts are from foreign affiliates (u. s. direct investment abroad, 1990). service payments and service receipts are for miscellaneous arrangements other than direct investment royalties and licensing fees. royalty and service payments are to us firms and royalty and service receipts are from foreign affiliates (u. s. direct investment abroad, 1985). these measures represent more specific, definite, and contract-oriented arrangements, and as such, contrast to the vague, more indefinite arrangements of the r&d expenditure measures. 114 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no.2 foreign capital inflow (to the us) consists of equity capital inflows, reinvested earnings, and intercompany debt inflows. equity capital inflows are net increases in foreign parents' equity in their us affiliates, whether incorporated or unincorporated. reinvested earnings of us affiliates are earnings less distributed earnings after capital gains and after us income taxes. intercompany debt inflows consist of the increase in us affiliates' net intercompany debt pay abies to their foreign parent during the year. this measure reflects change from one year to the next. us capital inflow (to other countries) is defined comparably to foreign capital inflow except that each component flows in the opposite direction from foreign capital inflow. measures-independent variables whereas kogut and singh (1988) used a composite measure of cultural distance, the measures here are individual dimensions. this allows for comparison of the effects of the distance between each cultural dimension. while, uncertainty avoidance is often pointed to as the most important dimension (e.g., anderson and gatignon, 1986; kogut and singh, 1988), this study tests whether this is the case. measures of the four work-related cultural dimensions were taken directly from hofstede (1980). these four dimensions (power distance, uncertainty avoidance, individualism, and masculinity) were discussed in the theory section and will not be individually described here. rather, a summary description of the values used will be described. the values for all the dimensions range from zero to 100 with higher values representing stronger, more apparent occurrences of the cultural trait. that is, higher scores represent more power distance among people, more uncertainty avoidance, more emphasis on the individual rather than the group, and more value on showing off or performing, etc. (or masculinity, to use hofstede's term). one set of analyses uses these actual-value scores (table 1). the distance measure on each dimension is simply the absolute value of the difference between the score for the us and the nation of the affiliate whether that nation entered the us or the us entered that nation. one set of analyses uses these distances. analyses analyses of the data included simple correlations and ordinary least squares for each of the dependent variables. both actual values of hofstede's measures and the distance values described in the measures section were used as independent variables in separate regressions. variance inflation factors were used to verify that there was no significant multicollinearity among the cultural values in any of the models. fall 1996 keck: cross-border business linkages 115 table 1 countries and culture values that are in study uncertainty masculinity vs. qlli.n!n'. power distance avoidance individualism femininty index rank index rank index rank index rank australia 36 13 51 17 90 49 61 35 austria 11 i 70 26~27 55 33 79 49 belgium 65 33 94 45-46 75 43 54 29 brazil 69 39 76 28-30 38 25 49 25 canada 39 15 48 12-13 80 46-47 52 28 denmark 18 10-12 23 3 74 42 16 4 finland 33 8 59 20-21 63 34 26 7 france 68 37-38 86 36-41 71 40-41 43 17-18 germany 35 10-12 65 23 67 36 66 41-42 great britain 35 10-12 35 6-7 89 48 66 41-42 ireland 28 5 35 6-7 70 39 68 43-44 israel 13 2 81 32 54 32 47 23 italy 50 20 75 28 76 44 70 46-47 japan 54 21 92 44 46 28-29 95 50 netherlands 38 14 53 18 80 46-47 14 3 norway 31 6-7 50 16 69 38 8 2 new zealand 22 4 49 14-15 79 45 58 34 philippines 94 47 44 10 32 21 64 39-40 spain 57 23 86 36-41 51 31 42 15-16 sweden 31 6-7 29 4-5 71 40-41 5 i switzerland 34 9 58 19 68 37 70 46~47 taiwan 58 24-25 69 25 17 10 45 20-21 united states 40 16 46 ii 91 50 62 36 venezuela 81 45-56 76 28-30 12 4 73 48 source: hofstede, g. "national cultures in four dimensions." international studies of management and organization 13(1-2) (1983):52 results table 2 presents the descriptive statistics and correlations for the independent and dependent variables. table 2 shows that the measures of both actual and distance measures of cultures are frequently correlated with the dependent measures of linkages; distance is significantly correlated slightly more often. although not all the correlations between distance and the linkage variables are significant, many of them are, and all in the predicted direction except for return on investment. return on investment may not be negatively correlated with distance values because returns can be negative. partially supporting the hypotheses, differences in power distance and individualism are negatively correlated overall with the value of the linkages. table 2 correlations with descriptive statistics 0\ 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 ii 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 us income abroad' (i) us investment abroad' (2) +.97''' foreign income in us' (3) +.78'" +.80'" foreign investment in us' (4) +.73'" +.76'" +.97''' us r&d expenditure abroad' (5) +.66'" +.72'" +.92'" +.90'" foreign expenditure in us' (6) +.84'" +.85'" +.79'" +.76'" +.76'" royalty payments to affiliates' (7) +.76"'+.71"'+.80"'+.76"'+.75'''+.78''' royalty receipts from affiliates' (8) +.63' +.60' +.56 +.53' +.53' +.42 +.47 service payments to affiliates' (9) +.86'"+.90''' +.84'" +.77'" +.77''' +.82'" +.72'" +.83'" service receipts from affiliates' (10) +.52' +.61" +.77"'+.72'''+.75'''+.74'''+.52' +.84'''+.56' us capital inflow' (lj) +.81''' +.79'" +.68" +.52' +.42 +.53' +.46' +.44 +.69" +.40 foreign capital inflow' (12) +.65" +.67'''+.93''' +.94'" +.82'" +.65" +.66" +.51 +.68" +.62" +.45 annual us returns abroad' (l3) -.02 -.25 -.23 -.24 -.32 -.18 +.11 -.19 -.29 -,45' -.15 annual foreign returns in us· (14) -.08 -.11 -.13 -.38 -.31 -.15 -.36 +.00 -.22 -.18 +.26 power distance" (is) -.72'" -.68'" -.71" -.71''' -.66'" -.66'" -.71'" -.33 -.61" -.38 -.44 uncertainty avoidance" (l6) -.35' -.34 -.27 -.20 -.25 -.10 -.22 -.49 -,45' +.17 -.28 individualism" (17) -.70'" -.69'" -.77'" -.62" -.67'" -.76'"-.81''' -.19 -.72'" -.44 -,49' masculinity" (l8) -.02 -.10 +.22 +.20 +.14 -.03 +.17 -.19 -.02 -.13 -.30 power distance" (l9) -,45' -.38 -.66" -.44' -.50' -.44' -.59" -.44 -,47' -.17 -.31 uncertainty avoidance" (20) -.29 -.27 -.35 -.25 -.26 -.13 -.30 -.45 -,45 +.14 -.21 individualism (21) -.50'" .49'" .31''' -.40" -.19 -.22 +.55'" -.56" .32 -.52" -.24 masculinity (22) -.11 -.03 -.10 -.09 -.09 -.07 -.17 -.06 -.18 +.13 +.18 n= 23 .. ' p :0; .001 .. p :0; .01 , p :0; .05 -.17 -.35 +.14 -.68'" -04 -.17 -.00 -,48' +.06 +.22 +.36 -,47 -.23 -.14 -.05 -.27 -.15 -.01 -.33 +.46 -.02 +.12 -.20 +.18 -.09 +.28 -.15 +.32 +.67'''+.32 -.23 +.00 -07 +.56" +.29 +.56" -.26 +.27 +.79'" +.39 -.23 +.41 +.65'" -,4t' +.72'" .08 -.67'" -.31 +.21 +.22 +.22 -.76"'+.22 +.38 2:;::: ~ ~..... ~ o:l ::: ""5' '"'"""""v1 ~.... '"'"i)q ~. "" ·.22 ~ -vj z ? tv fall 1996 keck: cross-border business linkages table 2 correlations with descriptive statistics (continued) 117 us income abroad" (i) us investment abroad" (2) foreign income in us" (3) foreign investment in us" (4) us r&d expenditure abroad" (5) foreign expenditure in us' (6) royalty payments to affiliates" (7) royalty receipts from affiliates' (8) service payments to affiliates" (9) service receipts from affiliates' (l0) us capital inflow' (11) foreign capital inflow' (12) annual us returns abroad" (13) annual foreign returns in us' (14) power distanceb (15) uncertainty avoidance" (16) individualism" (17) masculinity" (18) power. distance (19) uncertainty avoidance (20) individualism (21) masculinity (22) a: log of per capita values b: absolute value of distance mean +3.95 +5.76 +2.40 +5.14 +0.36 +0.93 +1.01 -2.86 +0.85 -0.16 +3.21 +3.58 -1.81 -2.92 +17.04 +20.61 +28.96 +19.17 +43.48 +61.04 +62.04 +50.91 standard deviation 1.20 1.24 2.14 1.98 2.65 1.48 1.80 1.36 1.64 202 1.46 2.13 0.29 0.59 13.34 14.56 21.09 17.52 21.66 20.48 21.09 23.72 number 23 23 16 23 23 23 23 15 21 20 19 21 23 16 23 23 23 23 23 23 23 23 actual-value models eight of the sixteen regression models using the actual values of cultural dimensions were significant (table 3). the coefficient for hofstede's uncertainty dimension was not significant in any of the actual-value models. hypothesis 2 is not supported when looking at international linkages at the level of the national economy. this conflicts with previous conclusions of significance such as in kogut and singh (1988). in the actual-value models, only individualism is typically significant with positive standardized coefficients. these results suggest that higher levels of individualism are associated with more investment abroad, more r&d expenditure abroad, and more royalty and service payments. the individualism dimension is the only consistently significant actual-value measure. this suggests that cultures more oriented toward personal gain are involved in greater values of all kinds of linkages. distance models though not all distance models are significant, the results of the regression analyses provide partial support for the hypotheses (table 3). first, the ...... table 3 ...... 00 regression results+ (standardized coefficients) us foreign royalty service annual annual us investforeign lnvestforeign us royalty receipts service receipts foreign us us foreign income ment income ment r&d r&d payments from payments from capital capital return return abroad abroad in us in us in us abroad to affil affil to affil affil inflow inflow abroad in us distance models power distance -0.48** -0.46** -0030 -0.52** -0.36* -0038* -0.23 0.13 -0.16 -0.29 -0.62** -0030 -0.02 0.80** ~ uncertainty :;;:: ~avoidance -0.08 -0.07 -0.03 0.05 0.29** 0.01 -0.10 -060 -0.21 0.39 0.03 -0.06 -0.03 -0.09 i:l individualism -0.36* -0.37* -0.28 0.42*** -0.75*** om "--0.54* -0.62*** -0.52*** -0.36 -0.07 -0.28 0.11 -0.44 ~masculinity -0.15 -0.22 0.04 0.06 -0.18 0.03 0.06 -0.18 -0.08 -0.21 0.10 -0031 0.36 0.02 n 22 22 15 22 22 22 22 14 20 19 20 18 22 15 tl::i :;;:: f 7.594*** 7.267** 5.415***10.684*** 5.198***18.579*** 0.977 5.344*** 2.107 3.631 ** 2.164 0.708 1.266 "'"5.044** -.;:s actualvalue models (\l ""power distance -0.09 -0.00 -0.19 -0.16 ""-029 -0.15 -0.08 -0.04 -0.06 0.07 -0.35 -0.09 -0.36 0.22 v:l uncertainty .... ~ avoidance -0.02 -0.05 -0.07 0.01 0.19 0.02 0.08 -0.56 -0.21 0.31 0.13 -0.07 0.13 -013 ....(\l [ndividualism 0.65*** 0.70*** 0.59* 0.55** 0.80*** 0.59** 0.81 *** -0.06 0.62*** 0.64** 0.32 0.44 -0.29 0.07 00 ~. masculinity 0.06 0.14 0.16 0.06 0.05 0.07 0.01 0.22 0.05 0.17 0.07 0.24 -0.37 -0.20 "" n 22 22 15 22 22 22 22 14 20 19 20 18 22 15 f 4.419** 4 .337** 5.275** 2.954** 7.249*** 4.155** 15.961 *** 0.809 5.128*** 1.852 1.726 1.522 1.2[3 0.272 + the author uses the term foreign because us government documents use this term to refer to all non-us sources. r2 is not reported because it is not appropriate for the panel data used here. *** p s .01 ** p s .05 * p s .10 ~ ...... w z o tv fall 1996 keck: cross-border business linkages 119 models for investment and income abroad, us r&d expenditures abroad, r&d expenditures in the us, and royalty and service payments to affiliates are all significant. between 34 and 58 percent of the variance in these models is explained by cultural distance. using the distance measures, two types of linkages do not have statistically significant models. first, return on foreign investments is not significant though the amounts of the foreign investment and income from foreign investments are significant. this may be because the measure used, roi, is a shortterm measure of return and may not be representative of relationships that take many years to become profitable. a long-term measure of return may be needed to assess the value of these linkages between countries. a second type of model that was not significant were the royalty and service payments from affiliates (while royalty and service payments to affiliates were significant). this may reflect a bias in the data in using only us data. that is, some other selection bias may be operating in those countries that seek to license and purchase services in the us. wider data collection may help resolve this possible bias in the data. with two exceptions, the significant distance coefficients are all in the predicted direction. standardized coefficients are reported for each model so that the relative importance of each cultural dimension may be assessed. each distance variable will be discussed separately. virtually the same linkage models are significant in the distance set as the ones in the actual-values set. however, the significant coefficients in the two sets of analyses are different. whereas only individualism is significant in the actual-values models, both power distance and individualism are significant in the distance models. the difference in power distance is significant in seven of the fourteen linkages. overall, the greater the differences in power distance between the two cultures, the lower is the dollar value of the linkage. indicating one of the two strongest effects of all the cultural dimensions, the differences in power distance are often the largest standardized coefficients in each model. the difference in individualism is consistently significant (in the models that are significant overall). the coefficient for distance in individualism is significant for us investment and income abroad, foreign income in the us, r&d in the us and abroad, and for royalty and service payments. the hypothesis for this cultural dimension is supported overall it was hypothesized that the greater the distance in individualism between host and home country, the less the value of the linkages. the results for distance between individualism suggest that this cultural dimension may be very important in future investigation. uncertainty avoidance was significant in only one distance model and not in the predicted direction. the lack of significance of this variable is intriguing given that uncertainty avoidance receives so much attention from cultural literature (anderson and gatignon, 1986; kedia and bhagat, 1989; kogut and singh, 1988) as well as from the decision-making literature. 120 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no.2 the hypothesis for the distance between orientation toward masculine versus feminine characteristics was not supported in any of the models. the lack of results here may result from the potential confounds of gender role and value of traits labeled as masculine. discussion the purpose of the study was to investigate the role of culture in choices of international business linkages. it was predicted that greater distances between cultures would lead to lower overall linkages across those cultures. that the distance between cultural measures are significant more often than the actual-value measures of culture partially supports the overall arguments made here. that is, cultural distance influences linkages more than either cultural sensitivity in general or the specific attributes of the culture from which the firm is operating. the results here also provide an opportunity to assess which dimensions may be more influential than others in linkage choices. the study here shows that differences in the power and the individualism dimensions are most significant and deserve the most attention in future studies. previously, authors have emphasized uncertainty avoidance but have only studied the absolute values rather than distance between cultures or have converged all the dimensions without evidence that they operate in similar patterns (e.g., kogut and singh, 1988). a possible future extension of the results is to investigate which type of linkage is chosen by specific firms from each of these national cultures. one possible question might be the extent to which cultural distance affects the type of linkage chosen or which is chosen more frequently than another. the difference in power distance had a strong, consistently negative relationship with the value of the studied linkages. given that the difference in power distance was so consistently strong and significant in this study, there may be many valuable routes to pursue in studying the types of control mechanisms firms from each national culture employs. at least for linkage decisions among nations, the way managers perceive the hierarchy, power, and control mechanisms may be a significant aspect of choosing partners and markets, or the mechanisms through which managers deal with those partners. the results for distance in power distance suggest that there are many ramifications for firms seeking to establish linkages across borders. firms that follow preexisting routes may have a history that will greet them. first, the ways in which linkages are structured may need careful analysis in that the needs of both partners must be designed and balanced with those of the other. choice of which party will maintain control of the relationship could lead to expectations of partner requests such that firms may be seen as originating from nations requiring controlling interest, equal partnership interest, and/or minority interest. if firms from more distant cultures perceive too much or too fall 1996 keck: cross-border business linkages 121 little hierarchy and/or control, negative experience may result bad publicity, avoidance of future linkages, institutionalization of suspicion toward firms from the outside country could result for the outside firm and/or nation. such cultural barriers could lead to legal or practical limitations on relationships available to other firms searching for advantageous locations. firms can develop a reputation for linkages with other firms, and may be sought out or avoided. for example, unilever and corning are known for their successful linkages (bartlett and ghoshal, 1989). when this happens across borders, not only is the firm's reputation developed, but that of the nation as well. an example of a cross-border effect on reputation might be the indonesian automobile industry's hesitance in entering collaborative arrangements with american auto makers while preferring european auto makers. the second ramification of the results relates to decisions about the level at which decision making and control reside. as those expectations vary across borders, practical limitations on relationships may again emerge. the results for the distance between individualism in the us and other nations was also very significant. the differences in orientation toward personal versus group gains in linkages could have many ramifications for managing linkages with and entries into other countries. the results suggest that potential differences in the assessment of which parties will gain in the linkage and how the gain will be distributed seem to have pervasive effects on the total monetary value of linkages across nations. given that differences in individualism has such a strong effect, it may be that the structure of decisions (how uncertainty is avoided) is less important than the differences in how gains are expected to be distributed. that is, expectations may be as important as actual economic arrangements. because, cultural characteristics may sometimes overwhelm economic ones, conditions under which the result here is obtained must be examined. the lack of significance of the difference in uncertainty avoidance was surprising. it was expected that this dimension would be particularly important in linkages because uncertainty avoidance impacts the type and amount of planning, the types of activities that individuals perform well, etc. this cultural dimension was only significant for foreign r&d in the us, and it is associated with larger values of payments. given that uncertainty reduction has played such a significant role in previous work (e.g., kogut and singh, 1988), future research could address the reasons why uncertainty is not significant at the aggregate level. the results here suggest that, holding all other cultural dimensions constant, uncertainty reduction is relatively unimportant in the economic decisions studied. this is surprising given that uncertainty is closely aligned with economic variables such as rational expectation, etc. the results for masculinity are most difficult to interpret. first, there seem to be two separate factors being measured by this dimension: 1) the distance between gender roles in the culture; and 2) the value placed on masculinelabeled characteristics. the lack of results may occur because the us seems 122 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 to be in the middle of the range of scores for this dimension (masculinity = 62), and, as a result, positive and negative distance scores wash out any results. on the other hand, the lack of any significant results may indicate that linkages built in cultures with "feminine" styles are successfully executed because the "feminine" partners are using cooperative behaviors that neutralize the distances that would otherwise be a problem. the lack of results requires further examination to suggest possible theoretical explanations. conclusion this paper addressed aggregate cross-border linkages of firms between the us and several other countries and investigates the impact of cultural distance between country of origin and target country. the paper differs from previous studies for three reasons. first, the national aggregate of strategic organizational activity across borders was the unit of analysis rather than the firm-to-firm relationships used in studies such as benito and gripsrud (1992) and kogut and singh (1988). second, cross-border linkages are considered the mechanisms that drive the impact of culture on economic activity performance. third, the study assessed specific dimensions of culture rather than an index. this study has several implications for managers and decision makers. first, cultural bias or constraint in establishing and investing in linkages was demonstrated firms from all studied countries tended to choose linkages to countries with the closest cultural dimensions. this aggregate result implies that finns may be likely to choose linkages along established paths because other firms have done so. future analysis could assess whether firms that choose to go outside the established paths experience benefits or disadvantages. for example, firms may incur higher costs and higher strategic penalties. on the other hand, they may discover culturally-based factors of strategic advantage overlooked by economic analyses. further, researchers may address whether firms who do not use established paths seize the benefits for themselves or whether followers of their strategies benefit more. although this study has begun to combine cultural bases of economic behavior with linkages across national boundaries, there are several limitations that provide further opportunity for future extensions of this research. first, no economic nor organizational factors were entered as theoretical or control variables. second, none of the variables have been measured at the level of the firm. third, more nations and other types of linkages must be included. fourth, only one model of culture has been used. while some consider hofstede's (1980) model controversial, it is also the most widely accepted. therefore, while the chosen model of culture may have weaknesses, it also has many advantages of measurability, acceptability, and availability. the limitations provide opportunities for future study. one avenue for addressing the impact of culture on organizational level linkage decisions would include both organizational culture as well as national culture in determinants fall 1996 keck: cross-border business linkages 123 of linkages. although not directly related to this study, a second organizational stream is suggested. a valuable research agenda would also include the development of dimensions of organizational culture that could be applied to nations in the same way individual responses were used to construct hofstede's cultural characteristics. this would address concerns of some researchers who believe there is a mismatch between hofstede's cultural dimensions and aggregate firm behavior. finally, effective strategic management requires more than economic analysis. recognition of culture is needed in what has traditionally been considered economic decisions. cultural knowledge can become a tool of strategic choice when cultural factors are explicitly recognized for their impact on choices among cross-border linkages. the study here has shown that, similar to economic analyses, cultural analyses can be "serious business" even when they are implicit. references adler, n. j. "a typology of management studies involving culture." journal of international business studies 14(2), (l986a): 29-48. adler, n. 1. "the cultural relativity of organizational practices and theories." journal of international business studies 14(2), (i 986b): 75-90. anderson, e. and h. gatignon. "mode of foreign entry: a transaction cost analysis and propositions." journal of international business studies 17(3), (1986): 1-26. bartlett, c. a. and s. ghoshal. managing across borders: the transnational solution. cambridge, ma: harvard business school press, 1989. barsoux, j. and p. lawrence. management in france. london: cassell educational, ltd., 1990. baumol, w. j. "productivity growth, convergence, and welfare: what the long-run data show." american economic review 76 (1986): 1072-1085. benito, g. r. g. and g. gripsrud. "the expansion of foreign direct investments: discrete rational location choices or a cultural learning process?" journal of international business studies 23(3), (1992): 461-476. calori, p. w. and p. lawrence. the business of europe: managing change. london: sage publications, 1991. egelhoff, w. g. "strategy and structure in multinational corporations: a revision of the stopford and wells model." strategic management journal, 9 (1988): 1-14. 124 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no.2 franke, r. h., hofstede, g., and m. h. bond. "cultural roots of economic performance: a research note." strategic management journal 12 (1991): 165-173. garland, j., farmer, r. n., and m. taylor. international dimensions of business policy and strategy. 2nd edition. kent international business series. boston: pws-kent publishing co, 1990. hofstede, g. "cultural constraints in management theories." academy of management executive 7 (1993): 81-94. hofstede, g. culture's consequences: international differences in work-related values. beverly hills, ca: sage publications, 1980. hofstede, g. and m. h. bond. "the confucius connection: from cultural roots to economic growth." organizational dynamics 16(4), (1988): 4-21. kedia, b. l. and r. s. bhagat. "cultural constraints on transfer of technology across nations: implications for research in international and comparative management." academy of management review 13(4), (1989): 559-571. keck, s. l. "determinants of interorganizational linkage choice: the case of entry mode choice into the ec." in proceedings of the southwest academy of international business 1992, ed. k.s. cooper, (1992): 161-170. kim, c. w. and r. a. naubornge. "cross-cultural strategies." the journal of business strategies 4 (1987): 28-36. kobrin, s. j. "expatriate reduction and strategic control in american multinational corporations." human resource management 27(1), (1987): 63-75. kogut, b. and h. singh. "the effect of national culture on the choice of entry mode." journal of international business studies 19(3), (1988): 411-432. lachman, r., nedd, a., and b. hinings. "analyzing cross-national management and organizations: a theoretical framework." management science 40(1), (1994): 40-55. porter, m. e. competitive advantage of nations. new york: free press, 1990. randall, d. m. "cross-cultural research on organizational commitment: a review and application of hofstede's value survey module." journal of business research 26 (1993): 91-110. shane. s. "cultural influences on national rates of innovation." journal of business venturing 8 (1993): 59-73. shenkar, o. and m. a. von glinow. "paradoxes of organizational theory and research: using the case of china to illustrate national contingency." management science 40(1), (1994): 56-71. fall 1996 keek: cross-border business linkages 125 tallman, s. b. and o. shenkar. "a managerial decision model of international cooperative venture formation." journal of international business studies 25(1), (1994): 91113. tucker, l. r., jain, s. c., and b. failer. "factors affecting the decision to invest in eastern europe." scandinavian international business review 1(2), (1992): 3-20. tung, r. l. "expatriate assignments: enhancing success and minimizing failure" academy of management executive (1987): 117-126. us department of commerce. bureau of economic analysis. u. s. direct investment abroad: 1982 benchmark survey data. washington: bureau, 1985. us department of commerce. bureau of economic analysis. foreign direct investment in the united states: 1987 benchmark survey, final results. washington, dc: bureau. 1990. von glinow. m. a. and m. b. teagarden. 'the transfer of human resources management technology in sino-us cooperative ventures: problems and solutions." human resource management 27(2), (1988): 201-229. sara l. keck is associate professor of management at pace university. she received her ph.d. from columbia university. her research focuses on top management teams and international mangement and appears in various scholarly journals. she is currently working on projects relating to transnational top teams and top team innovativeness. she has taught in indonesia, germany, great britain, and the czech republic. she teaches competitive business strategy and innovation management. dimensions of culture in cross-border business linkages volume 40(1) p.37-52 received: march 16, 2022 revision received: december 19, 2022 accepted: january 6, 2023 https://doi.org/10.54155/jbs.40.1.37-51 business model innovation through open innovation: empirical evidence from the automotive industry benedict seiferlein a, dominik k. kanbach b a hhl leipzig graduate school of management, leipzig, germany. benedict.seiferlein@hhl.de (corresponding author). b hhl leipzig graduate school of management, leipzig, germany. dominik.kanbach@hhl.de. abstract although open innovation (oi) has been characterized as one key driver for business model innovation (bmi), the literature lacks an in-depth understanding of how oi influences the business models (bm) of new ventures. however, such an understanding is crucial for improving the value creation and value capture for technological innovations in inbound oi settings. based upon a unique data set of 19 new ventures from 7 countries, which participated in europe’s largest oi platform, this study finds that oi leads to an expansion in the customer segment, a greater focus in the value proposition, a shorter (but deeper) value chain, and challenges to the revenue model. the paper highlights important theoretical contributions for the bmi and oi literature, and derives tangible managerial guidance for entering oi partnerships. keywords business model innovation, open innovation, automotive industry, new ventures 1. introduction business model innovation (bmi), defined by casadesus-masanell and zhu (2013, p. 464) as “the search for new logics of the firm and new ways to create and capture value,” has become increasingly decisive for commercializing technologies, gaining sustainable competitive advantages, shaping industries, and increasing firm performance (seiferlein et al., 2023). the elaboration of these new value creation and value capture logics into a consistent business model (bm), in which the customer segment, value proposition, value chain, and revenue model are coherently defined, is thereby of key strategic importance to entrepreneurs and a source for innovation in and of itself (zott & amit, 2010). however, despite two decades of research, the academic understanding of how bmi is achieved, and how this affects the elements of a bm, remains limited—particularly for new ventures (foss & saebi, 2017). one of the foremost suggestions for purposefully enabling bmi can be found in the open innovation (oi) literature, which argues that bmi is facilitated by deliberately integrating external partners into the development of new bms (foss & saebi, 2017). following this reasoning, companies this work is licensed under a creative commons attribution-noncommercial 4.0 international license. © 2023 the authors. https://doi.org/10.54155/jbs.40.1.37-51 benedict.seiferlein@hhl.de dominik.kanbach@hhl.de seiferlein & kanbach / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:37-52 38 should use oi to validate assumptions about the customer segment, value proposition, value chain, and revenue model and innovate these bm elements based on feedback from external partners (ibarra et al., 2020). however, thus far, this recommendation has been primarily derived from anecdotal evidence or purely conceptual works (e.g., chesbrough & rosenbloom, 2002; saebi & foss, 2015). accordingly, foss and saebi (2018) concluded that the impact of oi on bmi requires further academic scrutiny. we argue that the need to understand the consequences of oi on bmi is especially critical for new ventures due to the increased flexibility of their bms, smaller companies’ greater reliance on oi to overcome their liabilities of size, the fact that new ventures’ perspectives on oi are underresearched, and the collaboration between incumbents as stimuli for new ventures’ bmi needs further scholarly attention (albats et al., 2021; spithoven et al., 2013; urbaniec & żur, 2021). given thisstartingpoint, newventuresmightparticularly benefit from previously identified benefits of oi, such as increased creativity, more successful technology exploitation, and improved market access, to advance their bmi (chesbrough & appleyard, 2007; chesbrough&schwartz, 2007; marulloetal., 2018). therefore, we ask the research question: how does oi influence bmi in new ventures? we answer this by applying a qualitative research approach, based on a sample of new ventures that participated in europe’s largest oi platform between 2016—2022. building upon a rich and unique data set, including interviews with founders, ceos, and key personnel of 19 new ventures from 7 countries, we provide empirical evidence of how oi impacts bmi alongside the bm components customer segment, value proposition, value chain, and revenue model. in so doing, we provide three main contributions: first, we heighten the understanding of how bmi is fostered—which is among the most frequentlycited gaps in the bmi literature (seiferlein et al., 2023). second, by studying how oi influences bmi as a context-specificfactor, weanswertherequestsfor further research on an issue expressed in recent bmi and oi literature reviews (e.g., foss & saebi, 2017; spender et al., 2017). third, we provide valuable managerial lessons for entrepreneurs and corporate managers engaging in oi, especially since bmi and strategic management are inherently linked (casadesus-masanell & ricart, 2010). the remainder of the paper is structured as follows. section 2 provides the theoretical background on bm and bmi, oi and open bm, and the connections between them. once done, we introduce our methodological approach, before presenting our findings and integrating them into the ongoing academic and managerial discussion. 2. theoretical background business models and business model innovation bms have been defined as “management’s hypothesis about what customers want, how they want it, and how the enterprise can organize to best meet those needs, get paid for doing so, and make a profit” (teece, 2010, p. 172). hence, they serve to define the economic boundaries for converting technological inventions into viable innovations, and link the company-internal technological sphere with the market (chesbrough & rosenbloom, 2002). with this architecture of operations, bms influence the diffusion of novel technologies and speed of market penetration, for which an innovative bm itself could well be a decisive factor (urbinati et al., 2019). moreover, bmi represents an additional opportunity to differentiate from the competition (chesbrough, 2007a). however, conducting bmi is often characterized as a challenging, multifaceted, and interwoven strategic activity, for which new ventures routinely lack the requisite knowledge (garcía-gutiérrez & martínez-borreguero, 2016; kraus et al., 2022). moreover, the existing literature offers new ventures only limited empirical guidance (snihur & zott, 2020). indeed, it tends to only offer instruction on conducting experiments with bm configurations and integrating company-external feedback to reduce a bm’s technological and market seiferlein & kanbach / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:37-52 39 uncertainties (micheli et al., 2020). similarly, trimi and berbegal-mirabent (2012) and ibarra et al. (2020) have advocated for integrating customers for pursuing bmi to validate hypotheses and achieve consistency between a new venture’s offerings and customer expectations. however, hossain (2017) concluded in his bmi literature review that there is still a significant scarcity of knowledge on customer integration for bmi. among those gaps is how customers influence the outcome of bmi in detail (micheli et al., 2020). from a theoretical lens, these recommendations resonate with oi, which is frequently-mentioned in the bmi context, but rarely explicitly discussed (saebi & foss, 2015). thus, recent bmi literature reviews call for more empirical studies on the intersection of bmi and oi (e.g., foss & saebi, 2017). open innovation chesbrough and bogers (2014, p. 3) defined oi as a “distributed innovation process based on purposively managed knowledge flows across organizational boundaries, using pecuniary and non-pecuniary mechanisms in line with the organization’s bm.” the literature differentiates between inbound oi, which is concerned with creating value through integrating external inputs (e.g., ideas, know-how), and outbound oi, which uses external paths to a market for commercializing excess assets (e.g., patents). oi is thus a potential strategy with which to increase firms’ creativity, gain access to new markets, reduce costs and risks, and ultimately improve profitability (chesbrough & appleyard, 2007; chesbrough & schwartz, 2007). in a recent study of 251 european companies, teplov et al. (2019, p. 26) found that inbound oi is more prevalent than outbound oi, while highlighting that only “free revealing, scanning for external technologies, subcontracting r&d, customer co-creation in r&d projects, and idea and start-up competitions” were commonly acknowledged as oi practices by the participants. their results accorded with spieth and meissner’s (2018) observation that the academic discussion of oi is primarily concerned with advancing technological innovations from an r&d perspective. however, in environments with increasing r&d costs and shrinking product life cycles, chesbrough (2007b) proposed applying oi not only in r&d, but also following an open business models logic. open business models according to weiblen (2014, p. 57), “an open business model describes the design or architecture of the value creation and value capturing of a focal firm, in which collaborative relationships with the ecosystem are central to explaining the overall logic”. hence, the interactions between customers and suppliers in an open bm transcend straightforward selling and sourcing transactions in that they also involve a deeper integration of value creation and capture (weiblen, 2014). for instance, this is typically the case for car manufacturers, where suppliers account for approximately 75% of the created value and profoundly influence their partners (seiferlein et al., 2023). frankenberger et al. (2014) argued that inconsistencies in a bm, the pressure to find a new bm for value creation and value capture, collaboration experience, imitation of open bm patterns, and the blurring of industry boundaries are conducive for open bms. however, empirical evidence still lacks details on how this openness influences bms (holm et al., 2013). saebi and foss (2015) argued that the economic benefits of oi for bmi are determined by bm configuration, as well as the breadth and depth of the applied oi strategy. their purely conceptual work suggested that new ventures with radical innovations should design their bm through intensive collaboration with key partners, which is also in line with pynnönen et al.’s (2012, p. 11) recommendation to integrate customers into the bmi “from the very beginning”. in the same vein, marullo et al.’s (2018) crosssectional study of start-ups identified a positive correlation between the integration of external knowledge and successful technology exploitation. however, neither of these studies have provided empirical insights into exactly how firms do this, nor how this affects the bm in detail. this disparity is in line with the knowledge gap on seiferlein & kanbach / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:37-52 40 how bmi arises in new ventures, as well as which role the integration of customers or other firmexternal actors play in bmi (andreini et al., 2021; hossain, 2017; snihur & zott, 2020). consequently, spender et al.’s (2017) literature review on startups and oi concluded with a call to investigate new ventures’ bmi using qualitative research methods based upon original data. accordingly, we seek to narrow this research gap with the present study. 3. methodology research design case-based research is particularly well-suited to studying the dynamics of complex processes with limited pre-existing theoretical foundations, exploring relationships between interrelated concepts, and advancing theory building based on the examined cases (gehman et al., 2018). since all of these aspects apply to our research question, we opted to apply a qualitative research approach (andreini et al., 2021). next, we chose a research context likely to allow for replication between the studied new ventures (eisenhardt, 1989). thus, we focusedourattention on the automotive industry, which is especially appropriate for studying the effects of oi on bmi for four reasons: first, the industry is traditionally highly collaborative with long-standing experience in codeveloping innovations in a tier structure of manufacturers (jacobides et al., 2016). these structures include: tier 1, system suppliers; tier 2, parts suppliers; and tier 3, raw material suppliers. second, the industry is confronted with increasing cost pressure and shrinking product life cycles, as well as market pressure to develop more autonomous, connected, and sustainable mobility options, thereby further emphasizing the need for bmi and oi (ili et al., 2010; leemann et al., 2021; seiferlein et al., 2022). third, the industry is increasingly following chesbrough’s (2007b) recommendations to use oi to create and capture value with bmi (spieth & meissner, 2018). fourth, the automotive industry commonly utilizes startup autobahn—europe’s largest oi platform as measured by the number of partners and implemented projects (daimler ag, 2021; startup autobahn, 2020). since its inception in july 2016, the platform has grown to include 29 corporate partners, and 289 new ventures from 43 countries have developed 380 prototypes, of which every fourth has achieved commercialization following the experimentation phase (schwarze, 2021). drawing our sample from this well-established program allowed us to control for potential influencing factors, such as differences in program design, cross-check inferences between multiple participants of the same program, and benefit from a large variety of interview partners. moreover, startup autobahn is a stage-agnostic program for new ventures, thereby enabling us to gain in-depth insights into oi’s influence on bmi irrespective of the maturation of new ventures. accordingly, this served to increase the generalizability of our findings. finally, the program connects new ventures with incumbents from the automotive industry, including such car manufacturers as mercedes-benz, hyundai, and porsche, and automotive suppliers like basf, bosch, schaeffler, and zf—who can become potential customers for a commercial pilot r&d project with the new venture. as such, these collaborations between new ventures and firmlyestablished corporates fit the oi archetype from a practitioners’ perspective, thus increasing our study’s practical relevance (teplov et al., 2019). data collection following gioia et al. (2012), we collected extensive primary and secondary data through various means. first, we conducted 19 semi-structured interviews with founders and c-level representatives of emerging firms headquartered in austria, bulgaria, finland, israel, germany, slovakia, and the united states, all of whom had participated in startup autobahn since its inception. the participants were randomly selected and approached either in-person, via social media, or through the snowballing technique (biernacki & waldorf, 1981). we conducted the interviews in either gerseiferlein & kanbach / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:37-52 41 man or english, and transcribed them within 48 hours of the interview. our interviews included questions about the bm before their participation in startup autobahn, the introduction of changes during and due to the program, and the lessons they had drawn from their participation. moreover, we also asked individual follow-up questions. second, we conducted in-person field visits to startup autobahn’s oi events in stuttgart, germany, and attended virtual community meet ups to engage in an informal exchange with representatives of new ventures, such as ceos, cfos, and members of the founding team. third, we also attended iaa mobility 2021 (the world’s largest mobility fair) in munich, germany, in order to meet startup autobahn alumni in an industry-specific setting and learn more about the venture’s development. collectively, the field notes and meeting memos gathered for the primary data greatly enhanced our understanding. moreover, we extensively collected secondary data from such sources as podcasts, public interviews with the founders and collaboration partners of the new ventures, and startup autobahn’s own publications (e.g., video recordings of pitches and community events). additionally, we searched for academic and lay publications about the program with search engines, such as ebsco host, google search, and google scholar, to triangulate our findings. having completed the above steps, we collected and analyzed the data iteratively until we reached theoretical saturation, as suggested and defined by thornberg and charmaz (2014). data analysis we followed gioia et al.’s (2012) guidelines for the data analysis, which included coding the transcribed primary and secondary data in maxqda, and built a data structure to categorize our findings. hence, we formed informant-centric firstorder concepts, data-driven conceptual secondorder themes, and connected them with established aggregated dimensions in the bmi literature. consequently, we related each of our twelve second-order themes to one of the four bm components customer segment, value proposition, value chain, and revenue model as found in frankenberger et al. (2013). this final abductive aggregation enabled cross-fertilization within the bmi research domain, contributed to consolidation within the bmi literature, and allowed us to follow an approach applied in other bmi papers (e.g., daood et al., 2021). the result of the data analysis is illustrated in figure 1a and 1b, while additional supporting quotes can be found in table 2 in the appendix. 4. findings our findings indicate that oi influences every component of the bm in three distinctive aspects. we explain these results in the following section. customer segment a bm’s customer segment defines the target group for a company’s offering (frankenberger et al., 2013). our data reveals that oi is conducive for extending the customer base, regardless of whether a new venture has previously been exposed to the specific industry. as such, oi can pave the way for getting in contact with key decision-makers in potential clients and securing their commitments more rapidly than in more closed business settings, thus easing entry into a new industry. one interviewed partner put this rather succinctly: from our point of view, they [startup autobahn] opened us a network in the automotive industry that otherwise would have taken me, as a business developer, a very long time to reach the right contact. the opportunity to talk to a porsche innovation manager at startup autobahn that knows the exact relevant contact and can open that door or make that reference is really, really helpful. interestingly, many of our interview partners—who strategically used oi to enter the automotive industry—strongly discouraged other new ventures from engaging in oi as early as possible, regardless of whether they may have been accepted to an oi program. instead, they shared their experiences that being close to havingaproductready, andreachingthetippingpoint between an explorative and exploitative mode, is seiferlein & kanbach / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:37-52 42 fig ure 1a: da tas tru ctu re seiferlein & kanbach / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:37-52 43 fig ure 1b: da tas tru ctu re seiferlein & kanbach / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:37-52 44 table 1: interview list # position country of ventures’ headquarters 1 ceo & co-founder austria2 ceo & co-founder bulgaria3 sales director finland4 ceo & co-founder finland5 ceo finland6 ceo & co-founder germany7 head of business development germany8 head of marketing germany9 ceo & co-founder germany10 ceo & co-founder germany11 ceo & co-founder germany12 ceo & co-founder germany13 ceo germany14 general manager israel15 general manager israel16 vice president israel17 head of business development slovakia18 sales director united states19 head of business development united states the optimal moment to use oi. indeed, the ceo of a new venture explained: it is crazy and not recommended to participate [in oi] at the beginning of the company, but at that point when you have a product, once you have market maturity, once you want to communicate directly and everything is scalable for the oem, once you know what the customers want, and you know “we just have to make some little adjustments and then let’s go.” that’s the moment when such a program makes sense. an executive of another new venture similarly argued that detailed preparation is pivotal before oi makes sense, due to the thorough checks that even stage-agnostic programs entail for the bms of new ventures: my advice to startups coming to startup autobahn is don’t come before you don’t have all your answers ready. you really need to invest time, effort, and money in building that information brief that has all the answers that the industry is going to require. [...] you need to understand that you will be asked a lot of hard questions, and the answer cannot be, “we don’t know,” or, “we need to check.” you really need to be ready. for companies with a prior initial track record in the industry, oi influences the customer segment by significantly easing expansion within the industry. this is initiated by intentionally making the collaboration visible to the public and the collaboration partner’s organization. one interviewee explained: we produced one video for mercedes and one for porsche, wrote an article, and, of course, did several posts on linkedin. [...] this helped us get a good level of positive internal communication within the respective firms [...]. what we achieved, thanks to this, is that our product is currently rolled out to further mercedes-benz plants, and we’re in talks with porsche on further expanding there, too. this openness also smooths expansion into additional application areas. the new ventures can thus utilize their innovative achievements in one industry alongside their public exposure to venture into areas. one interviewee summarized this thusly: one could see that we were able to expand the types of customers we are able to target [with our solution] since we moved from a pure sales and seiferlein & kanbach / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:37-52 45 automotive retail solution to one that’s also suitable for automotive engineering applications. interestingly, the positive benefits of oi for advancing the customer segment are not limited to industry boundaries. instead, they inspire new ventures to seek additional potential markets, and cross-fertilize business development in adjacent and distant industries, such as aerospace, architecture, pharmaceuticals, and system and machine construction. additionally, according to our primary data, they provide a signaling effect to stakeholders beyond the initial industry. one interviewee exemplified this point: startup autobahn has been a boost for the entire company, even for customers who have nothing to do with automotives. also, the communication of our project has been a boost for investors and sales in the architecture area. it helped us unquestionably to elevate the entire company to a higher level. these extensions in the customer segment ultimately also lead to significant changes in the value proposition. value proposition the value proposition of a bm specifies which value-adding products and services are offered to the customer segment (frankenberger et al., 2013). we found empirical evidence that—thanks to oi—new ventures meticulously reflect on their value proposition, gain an increased level of focus, and ultimately calibrate their offerings to established industry requirements. an interviewee explained: from the technological solution point of view, it also gives more understanding of what kind of physical interfaces we really need to create, meaning the hardware interfaces and software interfaces, and what kind of standards and certifications we need to take care of and study in the long run. a co-ceo and co-founder added: what helped us was to get a sort of a benchmark of what other business models are out there for engineering tools [like ours and] learn from the customer first-hand: what gets billed? what are the specific collaboration modes? what are the service levels, etc.? this led to an itemization of requirements. furthermore, this mix of in-depth and informal exchanges with a variety of industry experts enables new ventures to validate the demand for their solutions, as well as to identify in which areas they have a competitive advantage that should become the focus for their future value proposition. an interview partner exemplified this by stating: eventually, we decided to focus only on providing the foil for our automotive segment by ourselves, and not the electric controller [...] we just had to realize: we cannot offer an entire system, but we have to specialize ourselves onto the core technology. finally, oi supports new ventures in transforming their value proposition into modular offerings, from which customers have higher sourcing flexibility. furthermore, oi motivates them to proactively decrease evaluation barriers from a customer perspective so as to attract additional customers in the future. one interviewee illustrated: we were confirmed through [our participation in] startup autobahn that it’s important to offer components which you can bundle easily [...] if you have industry partners, which have different business models, products, etc., they ask, “what can this startup contribute?” and therefore, i have to make it easy for them and offer a box, where i can say: “this is a working system, just try it out, you can adapt it easily to your needs.” [...] this offering approach is something which has been encouraged by startup autobahn, and which we now offer. all of these value proposition changes also impact the value chain. value chain the value chain details how organizations create and deliver the value proposition through orchestrating activities and processes (frankenberger et al., 2013). according to porter (2004, p. 46), it consists of the primary activities “inbound and outbound logistics,” “operations,” “marketing and sales,” and “service,” as well as the support activities “procurement,” “technology development,” “human resources management,” and such “firm seiferlein & kanbach / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:37-52 46 infrastructures” as finance and general management. our data reveals that new ventures capitalize upon oi to integrate their activities in the industry’s value network, which leads to a shorter and deeper value chain within the new ventures. one co-founder summarized this through stating: on the value creation side, a change occurred in the way we develop, which led us to open our ecosystem and purposefully decide to locate parts of the value chain in a partner. the increased concentration of the value chain along the specialization in key activities facilitates a standardization for all of its remaining parts. accordingly, new ventures heavily engage in the implementation of industry-specific certifications, such as iso and din-compliances, and manage the professionalization of internal workflows in suchawayastoimprovecollaborationwithclients and the manufacturability of their solution. an interviewee explained: the tricky thing is to rig up the collaboration management from a startup perspective in such a way that innovation management, product management, etc., is professionalized very quickly. however, this is challenging for firms, because within the startup autobahn [program] it’s hectic, much is done in an “on request” fashion, and all this has to be transferred into a standard operation mode. finally, new ventures take oi as a vehicle for making significant adjustments to their value chain in terms of strengthening their marketing presence. in particular, they generate brand awareness and build up reference cases so as to fuel further growth: we’re in an industry where you don’t have to ask, “is there a non-disclosure agreement?” but “how many non-disclosure agreements are there?” [...] therefore, it’s always difficult for startups to get visible, and what helps is that such open innovation projects are, by definition, made accessible to a closing panel, a community, or, in the best case, even the press. and that is always very good because then you do have a reference case. all of these changes in customer segment, value proposition, and value chain also impact the revenue model. revenue model the revenue model outlines a bm’s financial aspects, and details the cost and revenue mechanisms through which a company intends to generate profits (frankenberger et al., 2013). our data suggest that new ventures strategically employ oi to evaluate how much value their innovative solutions generate for customers—which is essential information for improving their profitability and own value capturing mechanisms. for example, one interviewee characterized this as follows: what we have learned through dxc was that we were able to quantify how much savings in terms of money we can bring the customer. [...] so we learned a bit about how we need to price one of our solutions. concerning the pricing of oi projects, multiple ventures also made the thought-provoking discovery that increasing the price for oi collaboration serves to heighten the chances of a successful collaboration, since a higher price increases the visibility of the project within the corporate and guarantees management attention. one ceo elaborated upon this in detail: we have a higher probability that the customer supports and actively works with us whenever we charge a substantial amount for such [oi] projects. indeed, the projects that performed worse were those we did for free. these projects go on and on, lack the management attention because the senior management doesn’t know what the frontline employees do, and therefore, the vice president doesn’t know what the team leader does with us, etc. it all boils down to the question of how high-level the project is anchored. and this correlates directly with the project price. that’s a question of commitment and a question of “who’s authorized to approve budgets?” and the more we charge, the higher the project goes in the hierarchy, and the more closely the project gets monitored, and the better the work that gets done at the bottom of the organization. however, according to our data, after establishing an initial oi collaboration between the new venture and a corporate partner, the latter may increase the pressure on the cost and margins of seiferlein & kanbach / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:37-52 47 the former. this is done through applying their market power and in-depth industry know-how in estimating prices through the entire value chain. therefore, corporate partners may impose their billing terms on new ventures, for instance, for extending due dates, and undertake thorough due diligence to uncover any potential for decreasing the cost of the new venture’s solution from a customer’s perspective. one interviewee described it thusly: we had to decrease our overall costs considerably and display the pricing structure for the product very, very transparently to the oem, but also to the tier-1, and as a result, our revenue per square meter shrunk substantially. based upon the shared understanding that the industry prefers lower unit prices over lasting exclusivity rights for commercializing the new venture’s solution in their end product, oi leads to increased sales volumes, which is mutually beneficial for both parties. an interviewee explained: the automotive industry is not so eager to have a kind of exclusivity because even porsche said to us, “you can talk to daimler, you can talk to other car makers,” because they understood that if [our solution] comes exclusively, then the price point will jump. and i think they have learned these kinds of lessons that it’s better to be able to scale it to the huge volumes because, at the end of the day, it comes cheaper to them as well. but obviously, they want to have a certain advantage, perhaps, let’s say, one or two years in advance so that they can be the first company to launch it to the marketplace. in conclusion, our findings underline that oi also influences the revenue model. in the following section, we summarize and discuss our findings in the light of the ongoing academic debate. 5. discussion this study examines how oi influences bmi in new ventures (figure 2). to explore this issue, we applied a qualitative research approach based upon 19 new ventures which participated in europe’s largest oi platform. through clustering our findings into customer segment, value proposition, value chain, and revenue model—as per frankenberger et al.’s (2013) bm framework—we were able to empirically underline how new ventures achieve consistency within their bms through pursuing oi with incumbents as their customers. we provide empirical evidence of how oi leads to an expansion in the customer segment and enables new ventures to enter new industries, accelerate growth in entered industries, and leverage their experience in one sector to prepare for an expansion into others. thus, we confirm previous findings that oi can enable new ventures to identify industries where their solutions can create value (e.g., chesbrough & schwartz, 2007). however, our results contradict the preeminent notion in the bmi and oi literature that a very early engagement in oi is advantageous (e.g., pynnönen et al., 2012). indeed, the experts in our sample consistently stressed the importance of thoroughly preparing the engagement in an oi platform in order to be ready to capitalize on the momentum for scaling the bm. thus, based on our data, we argue that, if new ventures wait to commence oi until they are abundantly prepared, it will increase the odds that oi becomes the tipping point for a new venture to shift from an explorative to an exploitative mode. hence, our data suggest that the managerial recommendation for bmi should not be to integrate customers “from the very beginning” (pynnönen et al., 2012, p. 11), but instead at a point where the new venture is prepared to engage in a meaningful exchange with potential partners. forthevalueproposition, weconfirmmoschneret al.’s (2019) finding that oi is conducive for developing a value proposition from a new venture’s perspective, andextendtheliteraturebydetailingoi’s impact on the value proposition. moreover, we found evidence to suggest that oi might increase the creative potential of what is offered to the customer (cf. chesbrough & appleyard, 2007). however, we have also demonstrated that the market pressure to comply with, and adjust to, established industry practices works against the creative push often associated with oi when viewed from a new ventures’ perspective. therefore, we argue that, in order to maintain the initial creative momentum, new ventures must balance their deseiferlein & kanbach / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:37-52 48 figure 2: oi influence on bm components sire to receive early market feedback with the benefits of developing a solution detached from the direct influence of conformity with the dominant design. in line with chesbrough and appleyard (2007), we have demonstrated that new venture’s value chains become complementary to those already present in the industry. given the predominance of open bms in the automotive sector, this leads to a comprehensive integration of the new ventures into a global value network. consequently, their value chain becomes both shorter and deeper due tospecializationandstandardization, thuslimiting the creative potential for applying unusual practices for value creation in a so highly-regulated and standardized domain as the automotive industry. thus, our data again underline that a prematureengagementinoimighthamperthedevelopment of unusual approaches to create value. finally, we have stressed oi’s influence on the revenue model and confirmed previous research emphasizing the cost reductions which can be realized through oi (cf. chesbrough & schwartz, 2007). however, our data also accentuates that—contrary to previous understandings in the literature—this does not improve profitability per se (e.g., ili et al., 2010). instead, new ventures’ margins are challenged in an oi partnership between new ventures and corporates, thereby reflecting the unevenly distributed market power of the partners. this flipside of oi has been underemphasized in the literature, which could possibly be correlated with the lack of research on new ventures’ perspectives. thus, in light of these findings and the persistent need to improve the academic and managerial understanding of oi’s influences on bmi, this study encourages a careful reflection on the two following aspects. first, the findings underline the importance of identifying the optimal point in time to engage in oi. as demonstrated, this is vital to offset certain disadvantages of oi, such as pressure on margins or loss of creative potential due to premature oi engagement. second, we stress that the gains for one oi partner can come at a price for the other. consequently, we argue that taking the firm’s individual perspective into consideration—for instance, concerning experience with industry requirements—is a critical managerial task before pursuing bmi through oi. 6. limitations and future research we conducted our study with high theoretical and methodological rigor. nevertheless, we acknowlseiferlein & kanbach / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:37-52 49 edge that our research is not free from limitations, which themselves may inspire future research. we studied the effects of oi on bmi in an inbound oi setting in one industry. accordingly, we here acknowledge that the effects may well differ between inbound and outbound oi, as well between industries (spender et al., 2017). however, we mitigated the potential disadvantages of this research setting by examining the most relevant form of oi from a practitioner’s perspective (teplov et al., 2019). moreover, we focused on an industry for which research calls for oi have been expressed, the need for bmi is preeminent, and which hosts europe’s largest innovation platform (ili et al., 2010; seiferlein et al., 2022; startup autobahn, 2020). moreover, our application of a qualitative research method may have limited the generalizability of our findings compared to other methods. however, we would argue that our adoption of this research method is well-justified given the sparse existing theoretical underpinnings. furthermore, by studying 19 new ventures from 7 countries which participated in startup autobahn at different points in time during the last 6 years—and by following gioia et al.’s (2012) guidelines to yield empirical results based on rigor—we believe that our findings are valuable and transferable for entrepreneurs and executives in similar settings. nonetheless, we would value additional quantitative studies to further deepen the understanding of how oi influences bmi. these studies could build upon the identified relationships, quantify the individual impact of the firstorder and second-order themes, and test our hypothesis with a larger sample size. moreover, furtherstudiescouldmeasuretheimpactofpotential mediators on the oi-bmi relationship, such as the absorptive capacity, dynamic capabilities, strategic agility or the previous oi and bmi experience of the studied new ventures, to name but a few (cf. foss & saebi, 2017; zhang et al., 2021). finally, our explicit consideration of the perspective of new ventures for examining oi’s effects on bmi was due to persistent calls in the literature. notwithstanding, we acknowledge that future studies with an inverse corporate perspective could complement our research and draw useful comparisons with our findings, as suggested recently by milei (2022). references albats, e., podmetina, d., & vanhaverbeke, w. (2021). open innovation in smes: a process view towards business model innovation. journal of small business management, 1–42. https://doi.org/10. 1080/00472778.2021.1913595 andreini, d., bettinelli, c., foss, n. j., & mismetti, m. (2021). business model innovation: a review of the process-based literature. journal of management and governance, 26(4), 1089–1121. https: //doi.org/10.1007/s10997-021-09590-w biernacki, p., & waldorf, d. (1981). snowball sampling: problems and techniques of chain referral sampling.sociologicalmethods&research,10(2),141–163.https://doi.org/10.1177/004912418101000205 casadesus-masanell, r., & ricart, j. e. (2010). from strategy to business models and onto tactics. long range planning, 43(2-3), 195–215. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.lrp.2010.01.004 casadesus-masanell, r., & zhu, f. (2013). business model innovation and competitive imitation: the case of sponsor-based business models. strategic management journal, 34(4), 464–482. https: //doi.org/10.1002/smj.2022 chesbrough, h. (2007a). business model innovation: it’s not just about technology anymore. strategy & leadership, 35(6), 12–17. https://doi.org/10.1108/10878570710833714 chesbrough, h. (2007b). why companies should have open business models. mit sloan management review, 48(2), 22–28. chesbrough, h., & appleyard, m. m. (2007). open innovation and strategy. california management review, 50(1), 57–76. https://doi.org/10.2307/41166416 https://doi.org/10.1080/00472778.2021.1913595 https://doi.org/10.1080/00472778.2021.1913595 https://doi.org/10.1007/s10997-021-09590-w https://doi.org/10.1007/s10997-021-09590-w https://doi.org/10.1177/004912418101000205 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.lrp.2010.01.004 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2022 https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2022 https://doi.org/10.1108/10878570710833714 https://doi.org/10.2307/41166416 seiferlein & kanbach / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:37-52 50 chesbrough, h., & bogers, m. (2014). explicating open innovation: clarifying an emerging paradigm for understanding innovation. new frontiers in open innovation. oxford: oxford university press, forthcoming, 3–28. chesbrough, h., & rosenbloom, r. (2002). the role of the business model in capturing value from innovation: evidence from xerox corporation’s technology spin-off companies. industrial and corporate change, 11(3), 529–555. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/11.3.529 chesbrough, h., & schwartz, k. (2007). innovating business models with co-development partnerships. research-technology management, 50(1), 55–59. https://doi .org/10.1080/08956308.2007. 11657419 daimler ag. (2021). 5th anniversary of startup autobahn: the most successful innovation platform in europe continues to grow internationally [publisher: mercedes-benz group media]. https: //group-media.mercedes-benz.com/marsmediasite/en/instance/ko/5th-anniversary-ofstartup-autobahn-the-most-successful-innovation-platform-in-europe-continues-togrow-internationally.xhtml?oid=50810034 daood, a., giustiniano, l., & gatti, m. (2021). exploring the evolution of business model innovation alliances: the case of velasca. international journal of innovation management, 25(07), 2150079. https://doi.org/10.1142/s1363919621500791 eisenhardt, k. m. (1989). building theories from case study research. the academy of management review, 14(4), 532–550. https://doi.org/10.2307/258557 foss, n. j., & saebi, t. (2017). fifteen years of research on business model innovation: how far have we come, and where should we go? journal of management, 43(1), 200–227. https://doi.org/10. 1177/0149206316675927 foss, n. j., & saebi, t. (2018). business models and business model innovation: between wicked and paradigmatic problems. long range planning, 51(1), 9–21. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.lrp.2017.07. 006 frankenberger, k., weiblen, t., csik, m., & gassmann, o. (2013). the 4i-framework of business model innovation: a structured view on process phases andchallenges. international journal of product development, 18(3/4), 249–273. https://doi.org/10.1504/ijpd.2013.055012 frankenberger, k., weiblen, t., & gassmann, o. (2014). the antecedents of open business models: an exploratory study of incumbent firms. r&d management, 44(2), 173–188. https://doi.org/10. 1111/radm.12040 garcía-gutiérrez, i., & martínez-borreguero, f. j. (2016). the innovation pivot framework: fostering business model innovation in startups: a new tool helps entrepreneurs design business models by identifying the sources of competitive advantage embedded in an innovation. researchtechnology management, 59(5), 48–56. https://doi.org/10.1080/08956308.2016.1208043 gehman, j., glaser, v. l., eisenhardt, k. m., gioia, d., langley, a., & corley, k. g. (2018). finding theory–method fit: a comparison of three qualitative approaches to theory building. journal of management inquiry, 27(3), 284–300. https://doi.org/10.1177/1056492617706029 gioia, d. a., corley, k. g., & hamilton, a. l. (2012). seeking qualitative rigor in inductive research: notes on the gioia methodology. organizational research methods, 16(1), 15–31. https://doi.org/10. 1177/1094428112452151 holm, a. b., günzel, f., & ulhøi, j. p. (2013). openness in innovation and business models: lessons from the newspaper industry. international journal of technology management, 61(3/4), 324–348. https://doi.org/10.1504/ijtm.2013.052674 hossain, m. (2017). business model innovation: past research, current debates, and future directions. journal of strategy and management, 10(3), 342–359. https://doi.org/10.1108/jsma-01-20160002 https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/11.3.529 https://doi.org/10.1080/08956308.2007.11657419 https://doi.org/10.1080/08956308.2007.11657419 https://group-media.mercedes-benz.com/marsmediasite/en/instance/ko/5th-anniversary-of-startup-autobahn-the-most-successful-innovation-platform-in-europe-continues-to-grow-internationally.xhtml?oid=50810034 https://group-media.mercedes-benz.com/marsmediasite/en/instance/ko/5th-anniversary-of-startup-autobahn-the-most-successful-innovation-platform-in-europe-continues-to-grow-internationally.xhtml?oid=50810034 https://group-media.mercedes-benz.com/marsmediasite/en/instance/ko/5th-anniversary-of-startup-autobahn-the-most-successful-innovation-platform-in-europe-continues-to-grow-internationally.xhtml?oid=50810034 https://group-media.mercedes-benz.com/marsmediasite/en/instance/ko/5th-anniversary-of-startup-autobahn-the-most-successful-innovation-platform-in-europe-continues-to-grow-internationally.xhtml?oid=50810034 https://doi.org/10.1142/s1363919621500791 https://doi.org/10.2307/258557 https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206316675927 https://doi.org/10.1177/0149206316675927 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.lrp.2017.07.006 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.lrp.2017.07.006 https://doi.org/10.1504/ijpd.2013.055012 https://doi.org/10.1111/radm.12040 https://doi.org/10.1111/radm.12040 https://doi.org/10.1080/08956308.2016.1208043 https://doi.org/10.1177/1056492617706029 https://doi.org/10.1177/1094428112452151 https://doi.org/10.1177/1094428112452151 https://doi.org/10.1504/ijtm.2013.052674 https://doi.org/10.1108/jsma-01-2016-0002 https://doi.org/10.1108/jsma-01-2016-0002 seiferlein & kanbach / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:37-52 51 ibarra, d., bigdeli, a. z., igartua, j. i., & ganzarain, j. (2020). business model innovation in established smes: a configurational approach. journal of open innovation: technology, market, and complexity, 6(3), 76. https://doi.org/10.3390/joitmc6030076 ili, s., albers, a., & miller, s. (2010). open innovation in the automotive industry. r&d management, 40(3), 246–255. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9310.2010.00595.x jacobides, m. g., macduffie, j. p., & tae, c. j. (2016). agency, structure, and the dominance of oems: change and stability in the automotive sector. strategic management journal, 37(9), 1942–1967. https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2426 kraus, s., kanbach, d. k., krysta, p. m., steinhoff, m. m., & tomini, n. (2022). facebook and the creation of the metaverse: radical business model innovation or incremental transformation? international journal of entrepreneurial behavior & research, 28(9), 52–77. https://doi.org/10.1108/ijebr12-2021-0984 leemann, n., kanbach, d., & stubner, s. (2021). breaking the paradigm of sensing, seizing, and transforming evidence from axel springer. journal of business strategies, 38(2), 95–124. https://doi. org/10.54155/jbs.38.2.95-124 marullo, c., casprini, e., di minin, a., & piccaluga, a. (2018). ‘ready for take-off’: how open innovation influences startup success. creativity and innovation management, 27(4), 476–488. https://doi. org/10.1111/caim.12272 micheli, m. r., berchicci, l., & jansen, j. p. (2020). leveraging diverse knowledge sources through proactive behaviour: how companies can use inter-organizational networks for business model innovation. creativity and innovation management, 29(2), 198–208. https://doi.org/10.1111/caim. 12359 milei, p. (2022). the nature of business model innovation in start-up companies. international journal of entrepreneurial venturing, 14(1), 1–15. https://doi.org/10.1504/ijev.2022.122014 moschner, s.-l., fink, a. a., kurpjuweit, s., wagner, s. m., & herstatt, c. (2019). toward a better understanding of corporate accelerator models. business horizons, 62(5), 637–647. https://doi.org/ 10.1016/j.bushor.2019.05.006 porter, m. e. (2004). competitive strategy: techniques for analyzing industries and competitors (first free press export ed). free press. pynnönen, m., hallikas, j., & ritala, p. (2012). managing customer-driven business model innovation. international journal of innovation management, 16(4), 1250022. https : / / doi . org / 10 . 1142 / s1363919612003836 saebi, t., & foss, n. j. (2015). business models for open innovation: matching heterogeneous open innovation strategies with business model dimensions. european management journal, 33(3), 201–213. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.emj.2014.11.002 schwarze, v. (2021). 5 years, 10 programs, countless memories [publisher: startup autobahn]. https: //startupautobahn-poweredbypnp.medium.com/5-years-10-programs-countless-memoriese8a603b3155e seiferlein, b., gernsheimer, o., & kanbach, d. k. (2022). fostering entrepreneurial competencies for business model innovation. international journal of automotive technology and management, 22(4), 401–423. https://doi.org/10.1504/ijatm.2022.10045209 seiferlein, b., kanbach, d. k., & lehmann, c. (2023). internal antecedents for systematic business model innovation: insights from the german automotive manufacturers. international journal of entrepreneurship and innovation management, 27(1/2), 19–50. snihur, y., & zott, c. (2020). the genesis and metamorphosis of novelty imprints: how business model innovation emerges in young ventures. academy of management journal, 63(2), 554–583. https: //doi.org/10.5465/amj.2017.0706 https://doi.org/10.3390/joitmc6030076 https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9310.2010.00595.x https://doi.org/10.1002/smj.2426 https://doi.org/10.1108/ijebr-12-2021-0984 https://doi.org/10.1108/ijebr-12-2021-0984 https://doi.org/10.54155/jbs.38.2.95-124 https://doi.org/10.54155/jbs.38.2.95-124 https://doi.org/10.1111/caim.12272 https://doi.org/10.1111/caim.12272 https://doi.org/10.1111/caim.12359 https://doi.org/10.1111/caim.12359 https://doi.org/10.1504/ijev.2022.122014 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.bushor.2019.05.006 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.bushor.2019.05.006 https://doi.org/10.1142/s1363919612003836 https://doi.org/10.1142/s1363919612003836 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.emj.2014.11.002 https://startupautobahn-poweredbypnp.medium.com/5-years-10-programs-countless-memories-e8a603b3155e https://startupautobahn-poweredbypnp.medium.com/5-years-10-programs-countless-memories-e8a603b3155e https://startupautobahn-poweredbypnp.medium.com/5-years-10-programs-countless-memories-e8a603b3155e https://doi.org/10.1504/ijatm.2022.10045209 https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2017.0706 https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2017.0706 seiferlein & kanbach / journal of business strategies (2023) 40:37-52 52 spender, j.-c., corvello, v., grimaldi, m., & rippa, p. (2017). startups and open innovation: a review of the literature. european journal of innovation management, 20(1), 4–30. https://doi.org/10.1108/ ejim-12-2015-0131 spieth, p., & meissner, s. (2018). business model innovation alliances: how to open business models for cooperation. international journal of innovation management, 22(4), 1850042. https://doi. org/10.1142/s1363919618500421 spithoven, a., vanhaverbeke, w., & roijakkers, n. (2013). open innovation practices in smes and large enterprises. small business economics, 41(3), 537–562. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-0129453-9 startup autobahn. (2020). europe’s largest open innovation platform startup autobahn presents 40 new pilot projects at expo day. https://startup-autobahn.com/news/press-release/europeslargest-open-innovation-platform-startup-autobahn-presents-40-new-pilot-projects-at-expoday/ teece, d. j. (2010). business models, business strategy and innovation. long range planning, 43(2-3), 172–194. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.lrp.2009.07.003 teplov, r., albats, e., & podmetina, d. (2019). what does open innovation mean? business versus academic perceptions. international journal of innovation management, 23(1), 1950002. https://doi. org/10.1142/s1363919619500026 thornberg, r., & charmaz, k. (2014). grounded theory and theoretical coding. in the sage handbook of qualitative data analysis. sage publications, inc. https://doi.org/10.4135/9781446282243 trimi, s., & berbegal-mirabent, j. (2012). business model innovation in entrepreneurship. international entrepreneurship and management journal, 8(4), 449–465. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11365-0120234-3 urbaniec, m., & żur, a. (2021). business model innovation in corporate entrepreneurship: exploratory insights from corporate accelerators. international entrepreneurship and management journal, 17(2), 865–888. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11365-020-00646-1 urbinati, a., chiaroni, d., chiesa, v., & frattini, f. (2019). the role of business model design in the diffusion of innovations: an analysis of a sample of unicorn-tech companies. international journal of innovationandtechnologymanagement,16(1),1950011.https://doi.org/10.1142/s0219877019500111 weiblen, t. (2014). the open business model: understanding an emerging concept. journal of multi business model innovation and technology, 2(1), 35–66. https://doi.org/10.13052/jmbmit2245456x.212 zhang, h., xiao, h., wang, y., shareef, m. a., akram, m. s., & goraya, m. a. s. (2021). an integration of antecedents and outcomes of business model innovation: a meta-analytic review. journal of business research, 131, 803–814. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2020.10.045 zott, c., & amit, r. (2010). business model design: an activity system perspective. long range planning, 43(2-3), 216–226. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.lrp.2009.07.004 https://doi.org/10.1108/ejim-12-2015-0131 https://doi.org/10.1108/ejim-12-2015-0131 https://doi.org/10.1142/s1363919618500421 https://doi.org/10.1142/s1363919618500421 https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-012-9453-9 https://doi.org/10.1007/s11187-012-9453-9 https://startup-autobahn.com/news/press-release/europes-largest-open-innovation-platform-startup-autobahn-presents-40-new-pilot-projects-at-expo-day/ https://startup-autobahn.com/news/press-release/europes-largest-open-innovation-platform-startup-autobahn-presents-40-new-pilot-projects-at-expo-day/ https://startup-autobahn.com/news/press-release/europes-largest-open-innovation-platform-startup-autobahn-presents-40-new-pilot-projects-at-expo-day/ https://doi.org/10.1016/j.lrp.2009.07.003 https://doi.org/10.1142/s1363919619500026 https://doi.org/10.1142/s1363919619500026 https://doi.org/10.4135/9781446282243 https://doi.org/10.1007/s11365-012-0234-3 https://doi.org/10.1007/s11365-012-0234-3 https://doi.org/10.1007/s11365-020-00646-1 https://doi.org/10.1142/s0219877019500111 https://doi.org/10.13052/jmbmit2245-456x.212 https://doi.org/10.13052/jmbmit2245-456x.212 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2020.10.045 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.lrp.2009.07.004 introduction theoretical background business models and business model innovation open innovation open business models methodology research design data collection data analysis findings customer segment value proposition value chain revenue model discussion limitations and future research volume 35, number 2 1 outperforming peers through a comprehensive climate change strategy: the case of electric utilities alexandra schmidt panasonic industry europe gmbh • ottobrunn, germany anne bergmann technische universitaet dresden • germany julia hillmann technische universitaet dresden • germany edeltraud guenther technische universitaet dresden • germany abstract firms increasingly aim to combat climate change. for corporate managers, the question whether a related strategy affects financial performance arises. since empirical research on this topic is rather sparse, this study investigates whether pursuing a corporate climate change strategy leads to better corporate financial performance. by applying paired samples t-tests, a sample of 62 companies from the electric utilities sector matched in pairs is investigated over a five-year time span. results indicate that firms with a comprehensive climate change strategy predominantly perform significantly better than their competitors without such a strategy. these findings might contribute to promoting climate change strategies in a corporate context. keywords: climate change; corporate climate change strategy; corporate financial performance; pairwise comparison; matched-pair design; paired samples t-test; electric utilities. introduction climate change is considered one of the greatest long-term challenges facing society (intergovernmental panel on climate change, 2014; steffen et al., 2015). it is a prominent and much debated ecological issue that challenges many business models, requires urgent action and, thus, is strategically relevant to organizations (busch, 2011; kolk & pinkse, 2004; whiteman, walker, & perego, 2013). impacts of climate change occur at different spatial and time levels (hoffmann, sprengel, ziegler, kolb, & abegg, 2009) and therefore resulting risks are difficult to assess 2 journal of business strategies and, in addition, may lie outside of the organization’s coping range (linnenluecke & griffiths, 2012). climate change induces complexity, uncertainty, and rapid change, which, in turn, requires organizations to respond proactively (howard-grenville, buckle, hoskins, & george, 2014). to deal with climate change, a comprehensive climate change strategy, which combines the two response strategies mitigation and adaptation, is required (intergovernmental panel on climate change, 2014) and represents the focus of this paper. until now, mitigation and adaptation has been mainly investigated as two separate response strategies (dlugolecki, 2008). mitigation takes an inside-out perspective and represents the companies’ efforts to reduce their impacts on the natural environment (winn & kirchgeorg, 2005). here, organizations mainly seek to reduce their greenhouse gas emissions (weinhofer & hoffmann, 2010) or to offset them. however, scientists have suggested that even with planned mitigation, the increase in global temperatures and other harmful impacts are irreversible (intergovernmental panel on climate change, 2014). therefore, adaptation – which takes the outside-in perspective (winn & kirchgeorg, 2005) – represents the second response strategy in dealing with the impacts of climate change (winn, kirchgeorg, griffiths, linnenluecke, & guenther, 2011). while mitigation is highly regulated by legislation (kolk & pinkse, 2004), climate change adaptation is only partially in the hands of single states and is not as regulated worldwide (gasbarro, rizzi, & frey, 2016). hence, mitigation strategies are rather clear for organizations, which is not the case for adaptation. climate change adaptation represents a relatively new field which lacks clear signals from scientific communities, leading to confusion within organizations about the urgency and high barriers for investments in adaptation strategies (gasbarro et al., 2016). the agricultural industry represents one example where rising temperatures might not only negatively impact firms, but might also lead to beneficial cases (tate, hughes, temple, boothby, & wilkinson, 2010). however, organizations need to realize that they are facing a ‘new normal’ (howard-greenville et al., 2014) and, thus, a climate change strategy that only consists of mitigation is not sufficient. risks of climate change can only be substantially reduced when mitigation and adaptation efforts are combined (intergovernmental panel on climate change, 2014). thus, organizations should strive for comprehensive response strategies that combine actions of mitigation as well as adaptation, as this will, following beermann (2011) and fankhauser, smith, and tol (1999), be crucial for organizations that aim to develop competitive advantages and reap financial benefits in spite of climate change. actions to build pro-active response strategies further strengthen the strategic ability volume 35, number 2 3 to develop necessary organizational skills to deal with a changing environment, which is fundamental for desirable organizational resilience (limnios, mazzarol, ghadouani, & schilizzi, 2014). after highlighting the importance of a climate change strategy that combines both mitigation and adaptation, it is rather astonishing that, until now, financial benefits of such a comprehensive climate change strategy have not yet been empirically investigated. in order to analyze whether companies with a comprehensive climate change strategy financially outperform companies without such a comprehensive strategy, we apply a matched pair design that follows michalisin and stinchfield (2010). the contribution of such an empirical analysis is twofold. this study is the first to investigate accountingas well as market-based financial benefits of a comprehensive climate change strategy that combines mitigation and adaptation. second, we go beyond their analysis and offer a long-term perspective with a time lag analysis of four years. hence, an analysis that shows managers that companies with a comprehensive climate change strategy outperform their peers without one might be of interest and could lead those managers to opt for a more comprehensive climate change strategy. this paper is organized as follows: we review related literature in section two and build up hypotheses in section three. section four presents results which are then discussed in section five. we provide concluding remarks and avenues for future research in the last section of the paper. literature review the link between climate change strategy and financial performance to date, only two prior studies have investigated the link between a corporate climate change strategy and corporate financial performance, each with different foci: the mitigation perspective (michalisin & stinchfield, 2010) or the adaptation perspective (stechemesser, endrikat, grasshoff, & guenther, 2015). moreover, both studies focus on accounting-based measures for corporate financial performance and do not include measures for market-based financial performance or measures for market risk. the study by michalisin and stinchfield, published in 2010, investigates the financial benefits of mitigation. findings of this study show that firms with a climate change strategy have higher financial returns for return on assets (roa), return on 4 journal of business strategies sales (ros), and total asset turnover than their competitors without a mitigation strategy (michalisin & stinchfield, 2010). they suggest that addressing climate change involves three strategic capability-based climate change strategies that achieve sustainable competitive advantage in a way that sustains natural resources and ecosystems: pollution prevention, product stewardship, and sustainable development (michalisin & stinchfield, 2010). a meaningful aspect that should be underlined is the fact that the authors implicitly equate a so-called ‘proactive climate change strategy’ with mitigation. at the time, adaptation was not as discussed as it is today, which explains its specific focus on the mitigation perspective of a corporate climate change strategy. the second, more recent study by stechemesser et al. (2015) addresses the adaptation perspective on climate change and its relationship to financial performance. they investigate three capabilities that are related to and a result of engaging in climate change adaptation and investigate their link to roa. strategic climate change integration options include new insurance products and services, financing customer improvements, and (re-)investments in climate change solutions. the authors find no significant support for this relationship. however, they find that other climate change related capabilities are positively related to roa, namely climate knowledge absorption and climate-related operational flexibility. one of the reasons for this might be the long-term characteristics of these capabilities as some time may be needed before the integration of climate change pays off. the authors further assume that a relationship is likely to be observed in the future due to the growing importance of climate change adaptation (stechemesser et al., 2015). since literature on that specific link is sparse, we broadened the search to studies that deal with the more general topic of environmental strategies and their relation to financial performance since climate change strategies can be seen as a sub-category of environmental strategies. findings from this literature show that a significant number of studies predominantly state a positive link (e.g. aragóncorrea, hurtado-torres, sharma, & garcía-morales, 2008; chan, 2010; chan, 2005; fergusson & langford, 2006; sánchez-ollero, garcía-pozo, & marchantelara, 2012). some publications find a negative (cainelli, mazzanti, & zoboli, 2011; cordeiro & sarkis, 1997) or simply no significant relationship at all (carmonamoreno, céspedes-lorente, & de burgos-jiménez, 2004; zaman mir & shiraz rahaman, 2011; zhang, wang, yin, & su, 2012). overall, findings on the influence of an environmental strategy on financial performance are inconclusive. a more recent review of mellahi, frynas, sun, and siegel (2016) has proposed that all of these strategies can be subsumed under a more general strand called volume 35, number 2 5 nonmarket strategies. they emphasize that all different variations of nonmarket strategies share similar mechanisms that explain the influence on organizational performance (mellahi et al., 2016). however, even at this more collective level, the paper does not provide a clear conclusion on the link of nonmarket strategies to financial performance, which confirms the findings are inconclusive at best. as an explanation, it could be argued that the implementation of an environmental strategy and its outcomes are generally difficult to measure and the strategy may reveal its effects rather in the long run than in the short run (stechemesser et al., 2015). friedman (1962) argued that social activities require financial and other, e.g. human, resources that are drained from value creating investments. while this argument might be valid in the short run, “in the long term, social and environmental issues become financial issues.” (sørenson, 2015, n.p.). as winner of the 2015 harvard business review competition for ‘the best-performing ceos in the world’, sørenson (2015, n.p.) argued “corporate social responsibility is nothing but maximizing the value of your company over a long period.” thus, trade-offs between short-term negative financial performance and long-term positive financial performance might occur. moreover, financial performance of a company is also subject to many other influences related to the whole value chain and the availability of slack resources (bergmann, rotzek, wetzel, & guenther, 2017). this means that firms with a high corporate financial performance in the preceding years are more likely to invest in improved environmental performance in the following years as they have enough resources to do so (modi & mishra, 2011). due to the inconclusiveness of the results, more future research is needed, especially on the topic of climate change strategies, where a significant research gap still exists (boiral, henri, & talbot, 2012; michalisin & stinchfield, 2010). a comprehensive climate change strategy combines mitigation with adaptation while the value and necessity of climate change mitigation for companies has been studied extensively (see, for example, the review on climate change mitigation research of glienke & guenther, 2016), there is only a small body of literature that addresses the adaptation perspective (stechemesser et al., 2015). the adaptation debate started much later and gained momentum only after the publication of rockström et al. (2009) on the planetary boundaries that suggested that mitigation efforts might be ineffective in addressing climate change risks (e.g., buob & stephan, 2011; nordhaus, 2006). although climate change adaptation has become a central 6 journal of business strategies part of scientific debate (e.g., berkhout, hertin, & gann, 2006; busch & hoffmann, 2009; dlugolecki, 2008; linnenluecke, griffiths, & winn, 2012; stechemesser et al., 2015), both strategies have been mostly discussed separately. only recently have researchers started to examine the necessity to combine both strategies as this can create synergies (e.g., bosello, carraro, & de cian, 2013; buob & stephan, 2011; shalizi & lecocq, 2009). although most of those studies explain these benefits on the policy level, their findings can provide fruitful insights and explanations for why combining mitigation with adaptation at the company level is needed as well. since mitigation concerns the reduction of emissions with the aim of minimizing the impact of climate change, the success of mitigation will determine the need for adaptation actions (shalizi & lecocq, 2009). studies repeatedly emphasized that individual countries have only limited control over total world emissions (shalizi & lecocq, 2009) and, thus, the success of mitigation. consequently, a single company has even less control, increasing the relevance of adaptation even more so. having said this, however, does not render mitigation fruitless, as it depends on the ability to adapt (shalizi & lecocq, 2009). clement and rivera (2017) show that companies, especially those from sectors that heavily rely on ecosystem services for adaptation, face adaptation limits if ecosystems shift and collapse. therefore, mitigation is still suggested as the key to avoiding potentially catastrophic shifts. besides this, there are further reasons for companies to extend their climate change strategy to include adaptation. while mitigation is highly regulated by legislation (kolk & pinkse, 2004), climate change adaptation is only partially in the hands of the state and is not as regulated worldwide as mitigation (gasbarro et al., 2016), thus it is within the organizations’ realm of control. although there might be local policies and regulations that concern climate change adaptation, which is especially the case for firms acting in highly regulated sectors, it is the responsibility of the company to identify their exposure and vulnerability to climate change and to adapt accordingly. therefore, a company’s long-term success and sustained competitive advantage are as dependent on adaptation as they are on mitigation (beermann, 2011; fankhauser et al., 1999). as expected, resources that are invested in mitigation cannot be invested in adaptation, but investing resources in mitigation on a global scale implies fewer resources for adaptation as it reduces the damage to which adaptation is needed (barrett, 2008; bosello et al., 2013; tol, 2005). a successful response to climate change can only be materialized if mitigation efforts are combined with adaptation (beerman, 2011; linnenluecke & griffiths, 2012; winn et al., 2011), volume 35, number 2 7 which strengthens the strategic ability to develop necessary organizational skills to deal with a changing environment, a fundamental element for achieving desirable organizational resilience (limnios et al., 2014). resilience is a “measure of the persistence of systems and their ability to absorb change and disturbance and still maintain the same relationships between populations or state variables” (holling, 1973, p. 14). in the context of organizations, it has been translated into the ability of an organization to persist and absorb disturbances resulting from climate change (impact resistance) and the ability and time to recover from those disturbances (recovery) (linnenluecke & griffiths, 2010; linnenluecke et al., 2012). organizations can apply different strategies to build impact resistance and recovery, i.e. resilience (clement & rivera, 2017; linnenluecke & griffiths, 2010). in the long term, companies that integrate climate change in their strategy can create resilience in terms of an increase in competitiveness through cost reduction, e.g. costs induced by new regulatory requirements, and thus gain independence from governmental agenda setting. moreover, a differentiation strategy, e.g. offering green energy options to customers, can reduce the dependence on existing technologies. risks can thereby be reduced and resilience of the companies enhanced. both strategies – mitigation and adaptation – create organizational resilience, albeit through different mechanisms. hypotheses development since research on the linkage of corporate climate change strategy and corporate financial performance is sparse, we draw from existing research on the relationship between corporate environmental and corporate financial performance. within this research stream, there have been various theoretical explanations for this relationship (guenther & hoppe, 2014). for the relationship where corporate environmental performance predicts corporate financial performance, there are two theoretical explanations: value creation and trade-off theory (guenther & hoppe, 2014). considering the latter, friedman (1962) was one of the first who argued that social activities require financial or human resources that, contemporaneously, cannot be used for other value creating businesses. within the trade-off theory, scholars further claim that investments, such as in pollution control, negatively affect cash positions and, therefore, also lower profits. following mahapatra (1984), this further leads to an increased risk for the original investment. a contrasting viewpoint for this line of reasoning is provided by several studies and meta studies in the field. one of the most recent meta studies includes more 8 journal of business strategies than 2,200 single analyses and its findings indicate an overall positive link between environmental, social, and governance criteria and corporate financial performance (friede, busch, & bassen, 2015). hence, from an empirical point of view, the second perspective, also known as the value creation perspective, seems to better explain the link to financial performance. in addition to its empirical support, there are some other theoretical explanations for the value creation perspective. following the argumentation of guenther and hoppe (2014), the ‘it pays’-link is possible because a reduction in the usage of resources, emissions, or waste can be directly translated to a reduction of related costs (e.g. judge & douglas, 1998; nishitani, kaneko, fujii, & komatsu, 2011). besides costs advantages, benefits might also stem from increased competitiveness through differentiation advantages on the product as well as on the firm level (mcwilliams & siegel, 2000). hence, customers might be willing to pay more as the offered product is environmentally friendly or the company can offer an enhanced environmental management system. when it comes to climate change, the dichotomy of friedman’s argument and the anti-friedman crowd might wane. at first glance, social responsibility can indeed be seen as a contradiction to a mere economic focus. when taking a broader view, however, it is quite rational for entrepreneurs to be socially responsible towards all stakeholders that might affect their financial performance, e.g. employees, the state, or suppliers. thus, the ecological environment as a stakeholder in terms of decent climatic conditions might threaten or foster their financial performance and can be actively integrated into the business model. considering the study’s focus on corporate climate change strategy, michalisin and stinchfield (2010) also favor the value creation perspective and draw on the natural resource based view by hart (1995) to explain the positive mechanisms behind a climate change strategy. these mechanisms can be seen in the development of three strategic capabilities (pollution prevention, product stewardship, and sustainable development). for the strategic capability of pollution prevention, they argue that reduced greenhouse gas emissions and a continuous improvement lead to lower costs which represent the basis for a sustainable competitive advantage. second, competitors can be preempted by product stewardship through renewable energy sources and stakeholder participation. the third strategic capability of sustainable development requires a shared vision and leads the company to face global climate change problems (michalisin & stinchfield, 2010). the reason why corporate decision makers might not see those resulting benefits from proactive environmental business in general and comprehensive climate change strategies in particular might be due to insufficient information volume 35, number 2 9 regarding possible profit opportunities (king & lenox, 2002). to sum up, the value creation perspective provides fruitful grounds for developing related hypotheses. we follow the above-presented considerations and argue that firms can generate value through a comprehensive climate change strategy combining mitigation and adaptation strategies. value generation occurs in terms of financial benefits that are internal (e.g. improved accounting-based financial performance) as well as external (e.g. improved market-based financial performance and reduced market risk). accounting-based measures represent backward looking measures of a firm’s ability to use their assets efficiently and to generate value (peloza, 2009). for instance, climate change mitigation strives to reduce fossil fuel utilization and carbon dioxide emissions, which redirects the energy sector towards low-carbon energy technologies (international energy agency, 2015a). electric utilities, for example, can influence the supply side and increase water efficiency, reduce water use, or utilize municipal effluent for cooling (ebinger & vergara, 2011; international energy agency, 2015b). a major aspect of this redirection is the idea that pollution prevention is related to value maximization (lanoie, laplante, & roy, 1998; porter & van der linde, 1995). as several scholars, such as michalisin and stinchfield (2010), have already highlighted, pollution prevention leads to a reduced usage of additional resources. this potential is at the same time an indicator for the inefficient usage of resources (hart & ahuja, 1996) because reduced consumption of resources includes resources that can be invested elsewhere and, ideally, create value. furthermore, reduced resource usage and lower emissions help to avoid fines or liability costs. product stewardship allows cost advantages to appear on the product level; thus, firms can sell green products for which customers are willing to pay a higher price, ultimately influencing sales outcomes such as ros. on the firm level, environmental leadership, for instance, leads to learning curve advantages (michalisin & stinchfield, 2010), which again leads to using assets more efficiently. adaptation measures can include investments in assets such as transmission and distribution systems (e.g., hardening and reinforcement) or specific asset design to improve impact resistance, ensuring functionality or fast recovery in the face of natural disasters (ebinger & vergara, 2011; international energy agency, 2015b). although costly, those measures can significantly reduce costs of restoration or outage-induced income losses. it can be expected that companies that are aware of this have planned accordingly and have applied related measures and, therefore, experience some stability in their accounting-based measures, even if the value 10 journal of business strategies creation hypothesis might not be the proper theory to explain benefits of adaptation measures. another possibility to adapt to climate change can be achieved at the supply side by building redundancy and flexibility in the supply chain (e.g., jüttner & maklan, 2011; sheffi & rice, 2005). this further supports impact resistance and recovery and, in turn, can ensure stability in terms of sales and income. for example, companies that can ensure functionality or at least faster recovery avoid or reduce the need to purchase energy from competitors as they can ensure their own production. thus, those companies still outperform their peers, although through a different mechanism. moreover, self-reinforcing effects when combining adaptation and mitigation might occur (hallegatte, 2009; international energy agency, 2015b). this selfreinforcing effect in the case of companies can be seen in the stability created for the accounting-based measures in combination with potential changes in accountingbased measures through the positive effects of pollution prevention, product stewardship, and sustainable development. this allows companies to build more slack resources, which again can be reinvested and create a small advantage that over time accumulates and becomes an even stronger competitive advantage. we therefore expect that companies with a comprehensive climate change strategy experience positive effects for accounting-based financial performance. hypothesis 1: companies pursuing a comprehensive climate change strategy financially outperform their competitors without such a strategy in terms of improved accounting-based financial performance. market-based financial performance measures reflect assumptions of investors about a firm’s future developments (balabanis, phillips, & lyall, 1998; endrikat, guenther, & hoppe, 2014; peloza, 2009) and also include intangible assets and reputational effects (surroca, tribó, & waddock, 2010). we hypothesize that the market and investors already perceive and value a comprehensive climate change strategy today for the following reasons: firms with a comprehensive climate change strategy take into account climate risks, prepare accordingly, and reduce their vulnerability. they reduce vulnerability in so far as they continuously anticipate and develop plans to detect further changes and act accordingly by building resilience. as companies cannot avoid all vulnerabilities, they develop strategies to deal with remaining vulnerabilities (e.g., burnard & bhamra, 2011; mcmanus, seville, brunsdon, & vargo, 2007). they are also able to deal with unexpected events and to adjust to external changes volume 35, number 2 11 without experiencing trauma (burnard & bhamra, 2011; hamel & välikangas, 2003; linnenluecke et al., 2012). these activities contribute to stability in terms of less scrutiny and less unsystematic market risk (ortiz-de-mandojana & bansal, 2016). this represents a clear signal to market participants as they assess firms with a comprehensive climate change strategy as being less risky and better managed. thus, we expect further benefits in terms of an improved market-based financial performance and a reduced market risk. hypothesis 2: companies pursuing a comprehensive climate change strategy financially outperform their competitors without such a strategy in terms of improved market-based financial performance. hypothesis 3: companies pursuing a comprehensive climate change strategy financially outperform their competitors without such a strategy in terms of reduced market risk. method and material our chosen sample focuses on the electric utilities industry as it represents a sector with high climate vulnerability since facilities are often located in climate sensitive areas (busch, 2011; gasbarro et al., 2016). moreover, utilities need to rely on long-term assets and infrastructure resulting in high and long-term investments (ebinger & vergara, 2011). hence, as utilities cannot react in the short term regarding their assets, they have to carefully consider building climate change strategies and related resilience. this makes them a meaningful sample for this study. we rely on one distinct industry sector, as this is preferred when studying causality or change (bono & mcnamara, 2011). in addition, we thereby enhance the comparability of the gained results and do not have to control for industry effects (klassen & whybark, 1999). an appropriate test design to compare companies pursuing a comprehensive climate change strategy with their competitors without such a strategy is represented by the method of pairwise comparison (matched-pair design). michalisin and stinchfield (2010) also decided to apply this method as it is preferable when attempting to determine if financial returns of so-called ‘proactive’ firms are significantly greater than those not considered ‘proactive’. first, electric utilities that report to the cdp were added to the sample. cdp provides the largest globally recognized database for information on climate 12 journal of business strategies change and companies (cdp, 2016; kolk & pinkse, 2004). furthermore, it offers important data for climate change related strategy analysis (lewis, walls, & dowell, 2014), which is, for instance, not the case for the kinder, lyndenberg, domini & co. (kld) index. we, thus, select all electric utilities that reported to the cdp in 2012 (reported data refers to the year 2011) in order to expand the investigated time frame as suggested by michalisin and stinchfield (2010). analyzing several years of data (2011-2015) reduces the impact exceptional events may have on a firm’s financial performance, such as buying or selling power plants. it also allows for the consideration of the time lag between an action taken and its measured effect. in 2012, 52 electric utilities were listed in cdp and, out of those, 49 provided reports in english. checking those 49 companies on whether they confirmed the integration of climate change into their business strategy reduced the sample size to 44 companies. second, we manually searched the thomson reuters datastream database for electric utilities from the same country without an externally identifiable climate change strategy in order to match them with the cdp companies. we searched for company information on if and how they address climate change by applying a keyword search in the company’s annual report, the corporate social responsibility report (if existent), and on the company’s website. besides the comparison of the country to minimize country-specific influences, for example legislation, the company size presents a decisive matching criterion. following bansal and hunter (2003) and michalisin and stinchfield (2010), assets were chosen as a company size indicator. since the ownership of power plants is a decisive feature of electric utility businesses, assets are a reasonable indicator for that industry sector. a comparable company, as defined by country and size, could not be identified for each of the 44 companies, which ultimately reduced the sample size to 31 pairs. these 31 pairs, i.e. 62 companies, stem from europe (n=16), north america (n=26), south america (n=12), and asia (n=8). following michalisin and stinchfield (2010), we then conducted a pairedsamples t-test to investigate the differences between the two pairs in terms of corporate financial performance. in contrast to the t-test for a single sample, the paired sample t-test uses difference scores and assumes that the population mean of the difference scores is 0. a difference score entails the difference between the paired values from the two datasets. all difference scores are then treated as a single sample of scores during the hypothesis testing by calculating the mean and standard deviation of the difference scores in order to calculate the t-statistic (aron, coups, & aron, 2011; boslaugh, 2012). therefore, the paired sample t-test can be seen as volume 35, number 2 13 a single sample t-test on the difference scores (weinberg & abramowitz, 2008) that basically tests for a statistical significant difference between matched pairs. measures of corporate financial performance stem from the thomson reuters datastream. we rely on accounting-based as well as on market-based corporate financial performance measures. for accounting-based measures, we investigate the two profitability measures roa and ros as well as asset turnover as a measure for efficiency. for market-based financial performance measures, we rely on market value. market risk is covered by the measures volatility and beta. results the final dataset derived from the matching process described in the previous section is verified by calculating the pearson correlation coefficient in order to check for the correlation of the matched pairs regarding firm size (total assets values from 2011) (michalisin & stinchfield, 2010). the results of this pre-test indicate that the matching process was effective since r = 0.989 (p < 0.001), which inevitably suggests a significant and very strong positive relationship. table 1 and table 2 present statistics for the paired samples, including the means of each dataset, the number of companies in the dataset (n), the standard deviation, and the standard error means. 14 journal of business strategies table 1 paired samples statistics for accounting-based measures volume 35, number 2 15 table 2 paired samples statistics for market-based measures table 3 provides the detailed paired sample t-test results. they are interpreted as follows: for example, the mean of the difference scores that is calculated from the 2011 roa values of the cdp companies minus the 2011 roa values of the matching pair (mp) companies is 0.036. this difference is presumed to be not attributable to chance since p < 0.01 indicates that the roa of cdp companies is significantly better (higher) than the roa of mp companies, thus rejecting h0. the same applies for the roa values of 2012 (p < 0.05), 2013 (p < 0.1), and 2015 (p < 0.05). 16 journal of business strategies table 3 results of paired samples t-tests as the paired samples statistics in table 1 show, the means of the cdp companies are better for roa and ros over the entire investigated five-year timeframe. however, as shown in table 3, the results are only statistically significant for four years of roa and two years of ros. therefore the findings of michalisin and stinchfield (2010) can be confirmed for roa and ros. however, no evidence for higher asset turnover is found since the results do not suggest significant differences between the two investigated groups at all (see table 3). the means themselves are better (higher) for two years each (see table 1). volume 35, number 2 17 considering the analyzed measures for market-based financial performance and market risk, namely market value, volatility, and beta, the conducted paired samples t-tests indicate significant results for all investigated years (see table 3). these results further suggest that a comprehensive climate change strategy leads to better corporate financial performance, particularly in terms of market value and market risk. to sum up, the results of the paired samples t-test show that electric utilities pursuing a comprehensive climate change strategy usually perform significantly better than their peers. discussion since no empirical study that assesses the influence of comprehensive climate change strategies on the corporate market-based performance is known, this study presents unique findings. in comparison to michalisin and stinchfield (2010), who published a static analysis (two-year average, 2005 2006), the results of this study are more comprehensive and meaningful due to the larger dataset investigated. in summary, the results of the hypotheses testing indicate that electric utility companies pursuing a comprehensive climate change strategy predominantly outperform their comparable competitors without such a strategy in terms of corporate financial performance. thus, the presented results not only confirm our underlying theoretical explanation, the value creation perspective, in several ways, but they also refine it: the results regarding accounting performance measures confirm michalisin and stinchfield’s (2010) findings of significantly higher mean values for roa and ros. however, results are not as clear for asset turnover. asset turnover is a measure for the company’s efficiency in terms of how well it uses its assets. companies with a climate change strategy build resilience which is associated with building redundancies, thus being contradictory to efficiency. therefore, a comprehensive climate change strategy might affect this particular financial ratio differently. however, as mentioned in the hypothesis section, companies that build resilience are able to provide some kind of stability by, for example, avoiding long lasting outages in the case of a disturbance due to faster recovery. thus, there are mixed arguments for the influence of a climate change strategy on asset turnover. on the contrary, the results for market-based measures are clearer. our results indicate a stronger relationship between climate change strategy and marketbased measures. one of the reasons could be the long-term characteristic of climate strategies that find expression in the more long-term oriented market-based measures. 18 journal of business strategies in contrast, accounting-based measures represent a short-term orientation. this is in line with other publications that rely on the long-term positive influence of climate strategies (e.g., cainelli et al., 2011; cordeiro & sarkis, 1997; stechemesser et al., 2015; zhang et al., 2012). another explanation for the strong positive relationship of climate change strategy and market-based measures is the reputational benefit proactive managers can trigger with deliberations on how to position the company with regard to future challenges (surroca et al., 2010). as climate change is perceived to be an important risk factor (kreft, eckstein, & melchior, 2017), companies that integrate the expected risks in their company policy are perceived to be more resilient when facing future challenges like climate change. investors seeking possibilities to assess a company’s comprehensive climate change activity might be particularly interested in this possible positive relationship to market value and market risk and might be encouraged to consider cdp as an indicator for a better performance of companies (guenther, guenther, schiemann, & weber, 2016). in addition, two other explanations for the differing results for marketand accounting-based measures are possible: the electric utility sector is highly regulated in many countries and the companies might have the possibility to transfer the costs for adaptation measures to customers or the state, which is, for example, the case in germany with the german renewable energy law. for instance, costs for more resilient grids can directly be incorporated in the pricing policy; thus, the firms’ profitability is not affected. as electricity demand is usually considered to be rather inelastic, net sales of electric utility companies may not vary much in general and may therefore not be influenced by a climate change strategy. finally, if we delve deeper into the observed relationships, we could seek out for drivers behind the applied measures. a comprehensive climate change strategy can be an indicator for good corporate governance in general, increased accountingbased performance can be achieved due to increased efficiency, and increased market-based performance can be attributed to an increased awareness of the general public concerning climate change (kock, santaló, & diestre, 2012). however, it is important to keep in mind that we cannot judge what executives really think based on the analysis of cdp data. thus, our results and their interpretation are based on the assumption that cdp data reflects the real intention of the companies and that they actually ‘walk the talk’. it could be argued that cdp disclosure might also be used for greenwashing (delmas & burbano, 2011). in this case, the result that firms with a comprehensive climate change strategy outperform their competitors without such a strategy would mean that companies with a higher level of greenwashing perform better. for market-based measures this result could volume 35, number 2 19 be explained by investors who have been misled, but for accounting-based measures this conclusion does not hold. thus, we interpret the accounting-based measures as robustness indicators for honest response behavior. conclusion results of this empirical research provide evidence that electric utilities with a comprehensive climate change strategy outperform their matched peers, particularly in terms of market value and market risk. having analyzed financial impacts of climate change strategies within a climate sensitive industry, this conclusion will, first of all, elaborate possible questions for future research. results of this paper provide evidence that, indeed, strategy matters and, thus, empirical analyses on the link of climate change and financial performance should include variables for strategic performance. in other words, future research should not only rely on mere operational data such as co2 emissions. moreover, since time matters for empirical analyses, we therefore encourage future research to avoid using concurrent measures. considering the measures for financial performance, both accounting and market-based measures should be considered within future studies. a final conclusion for future research can be drawn on a meta-level concerning the type of analysis: in contrast to medical research, where matched-pair tests represent a state-of-the-art method, they remain rare in economic analyses. as the comparison of two similar firms allows for a specific focus on the differentiating item to be analyzed (in our case, climate change strategy), more studies based on this design could contribute to a better understanding of success factors. for scholars, the mere process of matching the pairs provides deep insights into corporate practices and can even be superior to only considering confounding variables by accounting for moderators. besides the presented ideas for future research, this conclusion also provides possible implications for investors, top managers, and politicians. investors gain the knowledge that cdp is a good indicator and easy to grasp. moreover, investors learn that, considering the long-term perspective, climate change strategy is not a tradeoff for performance. top managers can use the results to learn that a comprehensive climate change strategy is a means for improving performance and reducing risk – as is also the case for the highly regulated electric utilities sector. hence, the value creation perspective should receive more attention from top management. instead of asking the question of whether a comprehensive climate change strategy pays off, they should try to influence climate change drivers for financial success. finally, this 20 journal of business strategies research can inspire and encourage politicians to cope with climate change, either by mitigation or by adaptation, as opposed to being afraid that such measures could endanger economic growth. references aragón-correa, j. a., hurtado-torres, n., sharma, s., & garcía-morales, v. j. (2008). environmental strategy and performance in small firms: a resourcebased perspective. journal of environmental management, 86(1), 88–103. doi:10.1016/j.jenvman.2006.11.022 aron, a., coups, e. j., & aron, e. 2011. statistics for the behavioral and social sciences: a brief course (5. ed). boston: prentice hall. balabanis, g., phillips, h. c., & lyall, j. (1998). corporate social responsibility and economic performance in the top british companies: are they linked? european business review, 98(1), 25–44. bansal, p., & hunter, t. (2003). strategic explanations for the early adoption of iso 14001. journal of business ethics, 46(3), 289–299. barrett, s. (2008). dikes vs. windmills: climate treatise and adaptation. discussion paper, johns hopkins university, baltimore, md. beermann, m. (2011). linking corporate climate adaptation strategies with resilience thinking. journal of cleaner production, 19(8), 836–842. doi:10.1016/j. jclepro.2010.10.017 bergmann, a., rotzek, j. n., wetzel, m., & guenther, e. (2017). hang the lowhanging fruit even lower evidence that energy efficiency matters for corporate financial performance. journal of cleaner production, 147, 66–74. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2017.01.074 berkhout, f., hertin, j., & gann, d. (2006). learning to adapt: organisational adaptation to climate change impacts. climatic change, 78(1), 135–156. boiral, o., henri, j.-f., & talbot, d. (2012). modeling the impacts of corporate commitment on climate change. business strategy and the environment, 21(8), 495–516. doi:10.1002/bse.723 bono, j. e., & mcnamara, g. (2011). publishing in amj part 2: research design. academy of management journal, 54(4), 657–660. doi:10.5465/ amj.2011.64869103 bosello, f., carraro, c., & de cian, e. (2013). adaptation can help mitigation: an integrated approach to post-2012 climate policy. environment and development economics, 18(3), 270-290. doi:10.1017/s1355770x13000132 volume 35, number 2 21 boslaugh, s. 2012. statistics in a nutshell (2nd ed). farnham, surrey, england: o’reilly. buob, s., & stephan, g. (2011). to mitigate or to adapt: how to confront global climate change. european journal of political economy, 27(1), 1–16. doi:10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2010.05.001 burnard, k., & bhamra, r. (2011). organisational resilience: development of a conceptual framework for organisational responses. international journal of production research, 49(18), 5581–5599. doi:10.1080/00207543.2011.563827 busch, t. (2011). organizational adaptation to disruptions in the natural environment: the case of climate change. scandinavian journal of management, 27(4), 389– 404. busch, t., & hoffmann, v. h. (2009). ecology-driven real options: an investment framework for incorporating uncertainties in the context of the natural environment. journal of business ethics, 90(2), 295–310. doi:10.1007/s10551009-0043-y cainelli, g., mazzanti, m., & zoboli, r. (2011). environmentally oriented innovative strategies and firm performance in services. micro-evidence from italy. international review of applied economics, 25(1), 61–85. doi:10.1080/02692170903426146 carmona-moreno, e., céspedes-lorente, j., & burgos-jiménez, j. de. (2004). environmental strategies in spanish hotels: contextual factors and performance. the service industries journal, 24(3), 101–130. doi:10.1080/0264206042000247786 cdp. (2016). catalyzing business and government action. retrieved from https:// www.cdp.net/en-us/pages/about-us.aspx chan, r. y. k. (2005). does the natural-resource-based view of the firm apply in an emerging economy? a survey of foreign invested enterprises in china. journal of management studies, 42(3), 625–672. chan, r. y. (2010). corporate environmentalism pursuit by foreign firms competing in china. journal of world business, 45(1), 80–92. doi:10.1016/j.jwb.2009.04.010 clement, v. & rivera, j. (2017). from adaptation to transformation: an extended research agenda for organizational resilience to adversity in the natural environment. organization & environment, 30(4), 346–365. doi:10.1177/1086026616658333 22 journal of business strategies cordeiro, j. j., & sarkis, j. (1997). environmental proactivism and firm performance: evidence from security analyst earnings forecasts. business strategy and the environment, 6(2), 104–114. doi:10.1002/(sici)10990836(199705)6:2<104::aid-bse102>3.0.co;2-t delmas, m.a. & cuerel burbano, c. (2011). the drivers of greenwashing. california management review, 54(1), 64–87. doi: 10.1525/cmr.2011.54.1.64 dlugolecki, a. (2008). climate change and the insurance sector. the geneva papers on risk and insurance issues and practice. 33(1), 71–90. doi: 10.1057/ palgrave.gpp.2510152 ebinger, j. o., & vergara, w. (2011). climate impacts on energy systems: key issues for energy sector adaptation. a world bank study. washington, d.c: world bank. endrikat, j., guenther, e., & hoppe, h. (2014). making sense of conflicting empirical findings: a meta-analytic review of the relationship between corporate environmental and financial performance. european management journal, 32(5), 735–751. doi:10.1016/j.emj.2013.12.004 fankhauser, s., smith, j. b., & tol, r. s. (1999). weathering climate change: some simple rules to guide adaptation decisions. ecological economics, 30(1), 67–78. doi:10.1016/s0921-8009(98)00117-7 fergusson, h., & langford, d. (2006). strategies for managing environmental issues in construction organizations. engineering, construction and architectural management, 13(2), 171–185. doi:10.1108/09699980610659625 friede, g., busch, t., & bassen, a. (2015). esg and financial performance: aggregated evidence from more than 2000 empirical studies. journal of sustainable finance & investment, 5(4), 210–233. doi:10.1080/20430795.201 5.1118917 friedman, m. (1962). capitalism and freedom. chicago: university of chicago press. gasbarro, f., rizzi, f., & frey, m. (2016). adaptation measures of energy and utility companies to cope with water scarcity induced by climate change. business strategy & the environment, 25(1), 54–72. doi:10.1002/bse.1857 glienke, n., & guenther, e. (2016). corporate climate change mitigation: a systematic review of the existing empirical evidence. management research review, 39(1), 2-34. doi:10.1108/mrr-10-2013-0243 guenther, e., guenther, t., schiemann, f., & weber, g. (2016). stakeholder relevance for reporting: explanatory factors of carbon disclosure. business & society, 55(3), 361–397. doi:10.1177/0007650315575119 volume 35, number 2 23 guenther, e. m., & hoppe, h. (2014). merging limited perspectives. journal of industrial ecology, 18(5), 689–707. doi:10.1111/jiec.12125 hallegatte, s. (2009). strategies to adapt to an uncertain climate change. global environmental change, 19(2), 240–247. doi:10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2008.12.003 hamel, g., & välikangas, l. (2003). the quest for resilience. harvard business review, 81(9), 52–63. hart, s. l. (1995). a natural-resource-based view of the firm. academy of management review, 20(4), 986–1014. doi:10.5465/amr.1995.9512280033 hart, s. l., & ahuja, g. (1996). does it pay to be green? an empirical examination of the relationship between emission reduction and firm performance. business strategy and the environment, 5(1), 30–37. hoffmann, v. h., sprengel, d. c., ziegler, a., kolb, m., & abegg, b. (2009). determinants of corporate adaptation to climate change in winter tourism: an econometric analysis. global environmental change, 19(2), 256–264. doi:10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2008.12.002 holling, c. s. (1973). resilience and stability of ecological systems. annual review of ecology and systematics, 4, 1–23. howard-grenville, j., buckle, s., hoskins, b., & george, g. (2014). from the editors: climate change and management. academy of management journal, 57(3), 615–623. doi:10.5464/amj.2014.4003 intergovernmental panel on climate change. (2014). climate change 2014: synthesis report. contribution of working groups i, ii and iii to the fifth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. geneva. international energy agency. (2015a). energy and climate change. world energy outlook special report. retrieved from https://www.iea.org/publications/free publications/publication/weo2015specialreportonenergyandclimatechange.pdf international energy agency. (2015b). making the energy sector more resilient to climate change. retrieved from https://www.iea.org/publications/ freepublications/publication/cop21_resilience_brochure.pdf judge, w., & douglas, t. (2009). organizational change capacity: the systematic development of a scale. journal of organizational change management, 22(6), 635–649. doi:10.1108/09534810910997041 jüttner, u., & maklan, s. (2011). supply chain resilience in the global financial crisis: an empirical study. supply chain management: an international journal, 16(4), 246–259. doi:10.1108/13598541111139062 24 journal of business strategies king, a. a., & lenox, m. j. (2000). industry self-regulation without sanctions: the chemical industry’s responsible care program. academy of management journal, 43(4), 698–716. doi:10.2307/1556362 klassen, r. d., & whybark, d. c. (1999). the impact of environmental technologies on manufacturing performance. academy of management journal, 42(6), 599– 615. doi:10.2307/256982 kock, c. j., santaló, j., & diestre, l. (2012). corporate governance and the environment: what type of governance creates greener companies? journal of management studies, 49(3), 492–514. doi:10.1111/j.1467-6486.2010.00993.x kolk, a., & pinkse, j. (2004). market strategies for climate change. european management journal, 22(3), 304–314. doi:10.1016/j.emj.2004.04.011 kreft, s., eckstein, d., & melchior, i. global climate risk index 2017: who suffers most from extreme weather events? weather-related loss events in 2015 and 1996 to 2015. lanoie, p., laplante, b., & roy, m. (1998). can capital markets create incentives for pollution control? ecological economics, 26(1), 31–41. doi:10.1016/s09218009(97)00057-8 lewis, b. w., walls, j. l., & dowell, g. w. s. (2014). difference in degrees: ceo characteristics and firm environmental disclosure. strategic management journal, 35(5), 712–722. doi:10.1002/smj.2127 limnios, e. a. m., mazzarol, t., ghadouani, a., & schilizzi, s. g. m. (2014). the resilience architecture framework: four organizational archetypes. european management journal, 32(1), 104–116. doi:10.1016/j.emj.2012.11.007 linnenluecke, m. k., & griffiths, a. (2012). assessing organizational resilience to climate and weather extremes: complexities and methodological pathways. climatic change, 113(3-4), 933–947. doi:10.1007/s10584-011-0380-6 linnenluecke, m., & griffiths, a. (2010). beyond adaptation: resilience for business in light of climate change and weather extremes. business & society, 49(3), 477–511. doi:10.1177/0007650310368814 linnenluecke, m. k., griffiths, a., & winn, m. (2012). extreme weather events and the critical importance of anticipatory adaptation and organizational resilience in responding to impacts. business strategy & the environment, 21(1), 17–32. doi:10.1002/bse.708 mahapatra, s. (1984). investor reaction to a corporate social accounting. journal of business finance & accounting, 11(1), 29–40. doi:10.1111/j.1468-5957.1984. tb00054.x volume 35, number 2 25 mcmanus, s., seville, e., brunsdon, d., & vargo, j. (2007). resilience management: a framework for assessing and improving the resilience of organisations. retrieved from http://www.resorgs.org.nz mcwilliams, a., & siegel, d. (2000). corporate social responsibility and financial performance: correlation or misspecification? strategic management journal, 21(5), 603–609. doi:10.1002/(sici)1097-0266(200005)21:5<603::aidsmj101>3.0.co;2-3 mellahi, k., frynas, j.g., sun, p & siegel, d. (2016). a review of the nonmarket strategy literature: toward a multi-theoretical integration. journal of management 42(1), 143–173. doi:10.1177/0149206315617241 michalisin, m. d., & stinchfield, b. t. (2010). climate change strategies and firm performance: an empirical investigation of the natural resourcebased view of the firm. journal of business strategies, 27(2), 123–149. modi, s.b., mishra, s., 2011. what drives financial performance resource efficiency or resource slack? journal of operations management, 29(3), 254– 273. doi:10.1016/j.jom.2011.01.002 nishitani, k., kaneko, s., fujii, h., & komatsu, s. (2011). effects of the reduction of pollution emissions on the economic performance of firms: an empirical analysis focusing on demand and productivity. journal of cleaner production, 19(17-18), 1956–1964. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2011.06.021 nordhaus, w. d. (2006). after kyoto: alternative mechanisms to control global warming. american economic review, 96(2), 31–34. doi:10.1257/000282806777211964 ortiz-de-mandojana, n., & bansal, p. (2016). the long-term benefits of organizational resilience through sustainable business practices. strategic management journal, 37(8), 1615–1631. doi:10.1002/smj.2410 peloza, j. (2009). the challenge of measuring financial impacts from investments in corporate social performance. journal of management, 35(6), 1518–1541. doi:10.1177/0149206309335188 porter, m. e., & van der linde, c. (1995). toward a new conception of the environment-competitiveness relationship. journal of economic perspectives, 9(4), 97–118. doi:10.1257/jep.9.4.97 rockström, j., steffen, w., noone, k., persson, a., chapin iii, f. s., lambin, e. f., & et al. (2009). a safe operating space for humanity. nature, 461(7263), 472–475. doi:10.1038/461472a 26 journal of business strategies sánchez-ollero, j. l., garcía-pozo, a., & marchante-lara, m. (2012). environment and strategic behaviour: the case of hotels in andalusia (spain). international journal of environmental research, 6(4), 1067–1076. doi:10.22059/ ijer.2012.577 shalizi, z., & lecocq, f. (2010). to mitigate or to adapt: is that the question? observations on an appropriate response to the climate change challenge to development strategies. the world bank research observer, 25(2), 295–321. doi:10.1093/wbro/lkp012 sheffi, y., & rice, j. b. (2005). a supply chain view of the resilient enterprise. mit sloan management review, 47(1), 41–48 sørenson, l. r. (2015). the best-performing ceos in the world. retrieved from https://hbr.org/2015/11/the-best-performing-ceos-in-the-world%20lars%20 s%c3%b8rensen%20(novo%20nordisk)%e2%80%9d stechemesser, k., endrikat, j., grasshoff, n., & guenther, e. (2015). insurance companies’ responses to climate change: adaptation, dynamic capabilities and competitive advantage. the geneva papers on risk and insurance issues and practice, 40(4), 557–584. doi:10.1057/gpp.2015.1 steffen, w., richardson, k., rockstrom, j., cornell, s. e., fetzer, i., bennett, e. m. et al. (2015). planetary boundaries: guiding human development on a changing planet. science, 347(6223). 1259855-1–1259855-10. doi:10.1126/ science.1259855 surroca, j., tribó, j. a., & waddock, s. (2010). corporate responsibility and financial performance: the role of intangible resources. strategic management journal, 31(5), 463–490. doi:10.1002/smj.820 tate, g., hughes, g., temple, m., boothby, d., & wilkinson, m. (2010). changes to farm business management under extreme weather events: likelihood of effects and opportunities in the uk. journal of farm management, 14(1), 67–86. tol, r.s.j. (2005). adaptation and mitigation: trade-offs in substance and methods. environmental science and policy, 8(6), 572–578. weinberg, s. l., & abramowitz, s. k. (2008). statistics using spss: an integrative approach (2nd ed). cambridge, new york: cambridge university press. weinhofer, g., & hoffmann, v. h. (2010). mitigating climate change – how do corporate strategies differ?. business strategy and the environment. 19(2), 77– 89. doi:10.1002/bse.618 whiteman, g., walker, b., & perego, p. (2013). planetary boundaries: ecological foundations for corporate sustainability. journal of management studies, 50(2), 307–336. doi:10.1111/j.1467-6486.2012.01073.x volume 35, number 2 27 winn, m. i., & kirchgeorg, m. (2005). the siesta is over: a rude awakening from sustainability myopia. in s. sharma & j. aragón-correa (eds.), corporate environmental strategy and competitive advantage. edward elgar publishing. winn, m., kirchgeorg, m., griffiths, a., linnenluecke, m. k., & günther, e. (2011). impacts from climate change on organizations: a conceptual foundation. business strategy & the environment, 20(3), 157–173. zaman mir, m., & shiraz rahaman, a. (2011). in pursuit of environmental excellence. accounting, auditing & accountability journal, 24(7), 848–878. doi:10.1108/09513571111161620 zhang, b., wang, z., yin, j., & su, l. (2012). co2 emission reduction within chinese iron & steel industry: practices, determinants and performance. journal of cleaner production, 33, 167–178. doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2012.04.012 biographical sketch of authors alexandra schmidt studied at technische universitaet dresden and esc rennes school of business. she received a b.sc. in business and economics and a m.sc. in business management. her main focus was on environmental management, sustainability and energy economics. currently she is working in the electronic industry at panasonic industry europe gmbh as environment & csr officer specializing on recycling, environmental product compliance and corporate social responsibility. dr. anne bergmann studied industrial engineering and management at the technische universitaet dresden and esc rennes school of business. from 2012 to 2016, she worked as a research associate at the chair of environmental management and accounting, technische universitaet dresden and the university of new south wales in sydney. in 2017, she defended her dissertation focusing on the impacts of the natural environment, particularly climate change and resource scarcity, on corporate financial performance and on corporate responses to those impacts. julia hillmann is a doctoral candidate at the chair of environmental management and accounting. she studied business administration at the technische universitaet dresden. she is researching organizational resilience and was part of and held a scholarship of an interdisciplinary graduate school from the leibniz institute of ecological urban and regional development that consisted of doctoral candidates dealing with the concept of resilience from different perspectives. she was also part of the research project on regional climate change adaptation (regklam). 28 journal of business strategies prof. dr. edeltraud guenther received her doctorate in environmental management control from the universitaet augsburg and holds the chair in environmental management and accounting at the technische universitaet dresden since 1996. she has been visiting professor at the university of virginia’s mcintire school of commerce. most recently, prof. guenther has initiated prisma, the centre for sustainability assessment and policy www.tu-dresden.de/prisma. a cross-cultural comparison of expatriates’ shopping behaviour geri j. wijnen development manager • wereldhave, the netherlands astrid d. a. m. kemperman eindhoven university of technology • eindhoven, the netherlands ingrid i. janssen tias nimbas business school • tilburg, the netherlands abstract explored is how shopping centre attributes can be adapted to culture-related shopping behaviour of expatriates. while awareness of consumer ethnicity and effectiveness of culture-based market segmentation are on-going and relevant topics in retailing, there is only limited information available on consumer behaviour of expats, as well as on the translation of market segmentation strategies to shopping environment. an online survey among british, japanese, and american expatriates in the amstelveen/amsterdam region (the netherlands) points out the importance of both lifestyle and ethnicity for the shopping behaviour. managerial implications for retailers, shopping centre developers, and operators are also discussed. introduction globalisation causes consumers to develop more homogeneous needs, tastes, and lifestyles. however, at the same time, it might also lead to greater heterogeneity, as it opens doors for consumers to belong to and identify themselves with several groups simultaneously (de mooij & hofstede, 2002). expatriates are a typical example of such a heterogeneous group. expatriates are in fact all persons who have moved outside their country-of-origin for the purpose of work or study (amsterdam municipality, 2007). however the term is commonly used for professionals employed outside of their host-country (farquhar, 2009). in this study, the term expatriate is used to refer to both the working expat as well as the partner of the working expat. expatriates are usually highly educated and receive an above average income-including various (tax) benefits and remunerations (farquhar, 2009; amstelveen municipality, 2008). because of their affluence they form an interesting target group. expatriates are often regarded as cosmopolitan consumers (hannerz, 1990; caldwell, et al., 2006), but they also stay attached to their cultural or ‘ethnic’ background (thompson & tambyah, 1999), and acculturate to a certain extent to the 126 journal of business strategies host-country’s culture (koubaa, 2011). their adjustment to a host-country has been widely studied (black et al., 1991; van vianen et al., 2004; grinstein & wathieu, 2009). it is clear that non-work or general lifestyle adjustment practices in the host country takes a central position in the life of expats and their well-being (black, 1988; black & stephens, 1989; andreason, 2008). gilly (1995) and koubaa (2011) explored some aspects of expatriate consumer behaviour. however, only limited market information is available about their shopping behaviour. in this study we are interested in the culture-related aspect of expatriates’ shopping behaviour. the cultural aspect of shopping behaviour has been studied extensively world-wide, varying from direct cross-cultural comparisons of shoppers in different countries (sood & nasu, 1995; brunsø & grünert, 1998; nicholls et al., 2000; seock, 2011) or within countries (shim & eastlick, 1998; ackerman & tellis, 2001; michon & chebat, 2004; chebat & morrin; 2007) to relating shopping behaviour to cultural values and dimensions (homer & kahle, 1988; kahle, 2000; hofstede, 2001; kacen & lee, 2002; de mooij, 2004; rubio-sanchez, 2007; zhang & mittal, 2008). however, these ideas have never been applied to a multi-faceted segment like expatriates. the translation from culture to shopping environment has received limited attention in research literature while the retailing industry is continuously being confronted with the importance of local sensitivity in their marketing strategies. in recent years for example, both wal-mart and ikea realised that adaptation of their standardized products and strategy to local consumer preferences is necessary to be successful (holstein 2007; halepete et al., 2009; strategic direction, 2009). international real estate operators and developers also know that there are cultural aspects to location, accessibility, retail mix, leisure, architecture, climate, and routing. in the us, one is familiar with so-called ‘ethnic malls’ that fully target a specific ethnic market such as hispanics, afro-americans or asians (lavin, 1996; hazel, 2005; shearin, 2006; the economist, 2009). cross-border shopping tourism is another field in which such cultural aspects are discernible (timothy, 2005; yüksel, 2007). awareness of the effect of culture on consumer behaviour and the effectiveness of culture-based market segmentation are therefore on-going relevant topics. thus, although the translation from cultural marketing segmentation strategies to the shopping environment is made in practice, research in this area has been sporadic. the relation between items such as shopping behaviour, shopping value, quality perception, and emotions on one hand and the shopping environment (babin & attaway, 2000; stoel et al., 2002; allard et al., 2009; jackson et al., 2011; masicotte et al., 2011) as well as retail atmospherics (turley & milliman, 2000; michon volume 29, number 2 127 et al., 2005; chebat & morrin, 2007) on the other, only recently received more attention. the relation between culture and the shopping environment has thus remained largely under-analysed. chebat and morrin (2007) found in a field-study that french-canadians have a higher perception of product quality while shopping in a warm coloured mall décor, while anglo-canadians experience this perception with a cool colour décor. in contrast, shim and eastlick (1998) found that ethnic identification has a greater influence on personal values and attitudes towards shopping centre attributes and shopping behaviour than ethnicity itself. michon and chebat (2004) suggested that both the shopping environment and ethnic diversity should receive more attention from researchers and mall managers. likewise, the international council of shopping centers (2009) stresses the necessity of understanding the cultural context of developments to retain a local sense of place in shopping centres. therefore, the aim of this study is to examine how shopping centre attributes can be adapted to culture-related shopping behaviour of expatriates. in this study, a ‘shopping centre’ is considered to be a planned retail development comprising at least three shops, under the freehold, managed and marketed as a unit with a minimum gross retail area of 5000 m2 (dennis, 2005). specifically, the cultural values and shopping behaviour of expatriates living in the amstelveen/amsterdam area in the netherlands are investigated through a literature review and data collection, with in-depth interviews and an online survey. the survey results are also compared to existing data on dutch consumers from market research specialist strabo. the outcomes provide shopping centre developers, managers, and retailers with information about how to adapt shopping centre attributes to optimize the shopping experience of expatriates. culture and values the relation of culture and shopping behaviour is the focal point of this study. however, the concept of culture is rather complex and cannot be quantified directly. over the years, numerous attempts have been undertaken to describe the concept (e.g., tylor, 1881; geertz, 1973; mcracken, 1988; hofstede, 1980; rice, 1993). according to rice, culture is “the values, attitudes, beliefs, artefacts and other meaningful symbols that help people interpret, evaluate and communicate as members of society.” values can be regarded as the most important manifestations of culture, next to rituals, heroes, and symbols (hofstede, 2001). the term ‘value’ was defined by rokeach in 1973 as “an enduring belief that one mode of conduct or end-state of existence is preferred over an opposing mode of conduct or end-state of existence.” 128 journal of business strategies values are more or less stable over time and can be determined through research techniques such as interviewing and observation, making them crucial for cross-cultural research (de mooij, 2004; hofstede, 2001). values therefore make the concept of culture measurable and comparable. note, that there is a fundamental and paradoxical problem in trying to compare cultures, since the distinctive “idiosyncratic cognitive categories and dimensions” (brunsø and grünert, 1998, p. 149) that define a culture are exactly those elements that are discarded when trying to catch the concept in a cross-culturally valid value system. moreover, the main value theories have all been developed in a western context, creating another cultural bias. the value-attitude-behaviour hierarchy values owe their importance to their central role in consumer behaviour and decision-making. several theories have been applied to explain consumer behaviour. the theory of planned behaviour (tpb) asserts that specific salient beliefs influence behavioural perceptions and subsequent actual behaviour (ajzen, 1985; 1991). there are three types of beliefs in the tpb that affect three perceptual constructs: behavioural beliefs influence attitudes, normative beliefs affect subjective norms, and control beliefs shape perceived behavioural control. in turn, these three perceptual constructs determine behavioural intentions and actual behaviour. tpb has been recently applied in studies that have examined multi-channel consumer behaviour (keen et al., 2004; kim & park, 2005). one study specifically takes in consideration cross-cultural effects while studying e-commerce activities (pavlou & chai, 2002). this study applied hofstede’s cultural dimensions (hofstede, 2001) to the tpb conceptual framework. theories on individual choice behaviour may also be valuable to explain consumer behaviour (louviere & hensher, 1981; sands, oppewal, & beverland, 2009; timmermans, 1982). these theories assume that consumers perceive shopping centres as bundles of features, called attributes. while selecting the most preferred shopping centre consumers evaluate these attributes. it is assumed that the consumer will choose the shopping centre with the highest perceived value of all attributes. both theories (tpb and theories on individual decision making) count for value systems as being an important determinant for behaviour. however, for this study we have chosen to apply the value-attitude-behaviour hierarchy that was first distinguished by homer and kahle (1988). this theoretical framework has also been applied in shopping research (shim & eastlick, 1998; swinyard, 1998) and is closely related to the personal value system of vinson et al. (1977) (see figure 1). the influence of values on behaviour is regarded as indirect, flowing from abstract volume 29, number 2 129 values (global values) via mid-range attitudes (domain-specific values and evaluations of product attributes) to specific behaviours. figure 1 value-attitude-behaviour hierarchy based on the personal value system of vinson et al. (1977) global values global values reflect more general values or desired end-states such as those defined by rokeach (1973). several methods for measuring such values have been applied in cross-cultural consumer research over the years such as hofstede’s cultural dimensions (2001) and the list of values (lov) (kahle, 2000). relations between cross-cultural shopping behaviour and hofstede’s individualism-collectivism, uncertainty avoidance, and power distance have been identified (kacen & lee, 2002; de mooij, 2004; zhang & mittal, 2008). the lov was used by shim and eastlick (1998) to explain shopping behaviour and attitude towards mall attributes among hispanics and anglo-americans, and recently by kuruvilla and joshi (2010) to develop a shopper typology for indian consumers. as for the rest, the role of personal values in a cross-cultural shopping context has been largely neglected so far. domain-specific values domain-specific values are kinds of attitudes towards certain social or economic activities. in a shopping context, this can be recognized as the attitude towards a shopping experience, or perceived shopping value (babin et al., 1994). shopping value can be assessed along two dimensions, namely, a utilitarian dimension related to task orientation and a hedonic dimension reflecting personal gratification and selfexpression found in the shopping experience itself. utilitarian and hedonic shopping value have turned out to be valuable constructs in shopper research (griffin et al., 2000; michon & chebat, 2004; seo & lee, 2008; allard et al., 2009) and in relation to the shopping environment (babin & attaway, 2000; stoel et al., 2003; eroglu et al., 2005; jackson et al., 2011). however, the idea of hedonic and utilitarian shopping value has only been applied in a few cross-cultural studies. for example, shim and gehrt (1996) found differences in shopping value orientation between hispanic evaluations of product attributes domain-specific values global values behaviour 130 journal of business strategies and native americans, while nicholls et al. (2000) compared chileans and americans, and griffin et al. (2000) compared us and russian shoppers. michon and chebat (2004) found that french-canadian mall shoppers exhibit more hedonistic shopping value than anglo-canadians. rubio-sanchez (2007) studied the relation between cultural dimensions and shopping value. product attribute evaluation the evaluation of product attributes is equivalent to the evaluation of (a set of) shopping centre attributes oppewal (1995) described as part of the shopping decision-making process. that the perception and evaluation of shopping centre attributes by consumers differs cross-culturally seems evident, however it has not been researched extensively. in 1966, hall argued that human perceptions of space such as privacy, personal distance, involvement, and boundaries differ across cultures. kliment (2004) pointed out differences in ethnic preferences with regard to colour brightness, lighting levels and product presentation in stores. in a field study, chebat and morrin (2007) found differences in product quality perception, in relation to mall colour décor, between frenchand anglo-canadians. brunsø and grünert (1998) compared the importance of aspects of ways of shopping for food among danish, british, french, and german consumers, discovering differences in the importance of product information, attitudes to advertising, enjoyment from shopping, specialty stores, price criteria, and shopping lists. with regard to price criteria, ackerman and tellis (2001) suggested that cultural value differences are an explanation for remarkable price differences between chinese and american supermarkets in the usa, indicating towards how deeply rooted cultural influences might be. expatriates as mentioned, expatriates form the focus of this study since they are an under-analysed but interesting consumer segment. when applying the value-attitudebehaviour model, in relation to expat’s shopping behaviour, we can formulate the following research questions: 1. what are the (cultural) values and shopping values of expatriates? 2. how do expatriates perceive and evaluate shopping centre attributes? 3. what is the shopping behaviour of expatriates? 4. how can shopping centre attributes be adapted to culture-related shopping behaviour of expatriates? volume 29, number 2 131 in this section we discuss the value-attitude-behaviour model in relation to expats’ shopping behaviour based on a literature review. values information on the lifestyles of expatriates is available through the international surveys commissioned by hsbc (farquhar, 2008; hsbc, 2008) and some academic research on cosmopolitanism (thompson & thambyah, 1999; cannon & yaprak, 2002; caldwell et al., 2006) as this is often linked to “being an expatriate” (hannerz, 1990). the hsbc study shows that the biggest benefits of being an expat are financial benefits, cultural opportunities, and the increased quality of lifemainly in terms of lifestyle, freedom, and adventure. cosmopolitanism is not without reason commonly associated with an elite and worldly attitude, sophistication, and selfenhancement through travelling (thompson & thampyah, 1999). on the downside of the expat life are social aspects such as missing relatives, language and communication barriers, difficulty making new friends, adapting to the local culture, and facing identity issues (black & stephens, 1989; caldwell et al., 2006; hsbc, 2008; andreason, 2008). consequently, there is an ambiguous tension between being a world-citizen, adapting to local culture and staying close to one’s cultural background. hence, the value orientation and consumer behaviour of expatriates seems under influence of ethnicity as well as lifestyle, displaying both local and global components. shopping behaviour and evaluation of the shopping environment from literature on expatriate consumer behaviour follows that food, ideas about health care, hygiene, and beauty play a role in the expatriate consumer experience and behaviour (gilly, 1995; usunier, 1999; koubaa, 2011). gilly (1995) specifically explored expatriates consumer learning and the meaning of possessions. she found that unfamiliarity with consumer customs frustrates them and that they were keen on obtaining certain products (especially food) from their country-of-origin that symbolize home. they used their networks to obtain those products. usunier (1999) confirmed the importance of food. koubaa (2011) studied the influence of country-of-origin values versus host country values on the consumer attitude regarding buying skin care products. further detailed information on shopping behaviour of expats is basically unavailable. regarding shopping and leisure, expats generally assess the netherlands relatively low in terms of quality of food, entertainment, and clothing (hsbc, 2008). in the regional dutch context of amstelveen, expats indi132 journal of business strategies cated they missed restaurants, cafes, clubs, cultural facilities, and stores with longer opening hours at night and on weekends (amstelveen municipality, 2008). to learn more about shopping behaviour and perception of shopping centre attributes from a cultural perspective, we will discuss some examples of cultural market segmentation from the retailing practice and the cultural reference frame of consumers in the next section. retailing industry in practice there are several examples (mainly in the us) of how shopping centres are successfully marketed to attract a cultural target group. examples are the legaspi group centres (his panic community), the mitsuwa marketplace chain (japanese community), the south dekalb mall in atlanta, ga (afro-american community) and the diamond jambo ree mall in irvine, ca (asian community), and the japan centre in london. extreme examples like this are non-existent in the netherlands, but there is ethnic retailing on a smaller scale by individual retailers in district shopping streets in ethnic neighbourhoods or in shopping venues such as the bazar in the hague, the shoperade on osdorpplein in amsterdam, and the shopperhal in amsterdamse poort, also in amsterdam. from these examples, we can learn about the shopping centre attributes that are significant from a cultural perspective (lavin, 1996; hazel, 2005; shearin, 2006; icsc, 2009; “segregation and shopping,” 2009). most importantly are retail mix, brand mix, and the product assortment. the formulas are often international or contain large amounts of imported products or brands. typical product categories are foods, books, cd’s, dvd’s, clothing, home ware, cosmetics, health products, and gift items. the food assortment can differ in proportions of fresh, instantly prepared, semi-prepared, canned, and dried foods ac cording to the customary food culture. also, aspects like ripeness of fruits and vegetables can vary. regarding fashion, the colours, fabrics, and sizes can be different. in terms of leisure and gastronomy there can be an enhanced focus on entertainment for children, the size and type of food court or on specific concepts such as a tea bar, karaoke bar, or photo sticker store. services on offer often require intensive communication or are subject to cultural customs and societal norms. bilingual staff as well as bilingual signage and information is very important in such mall and stores. the atmosphere, design, sizes of isles (to cater to large families), layout, and lighting level of the centre may be adjusted as well to match certain cultural preferences. volume 29, number 2 133 consumers’ reference frame culture influences behaviour through its manifestations, namely values, heroes, rituals, and symbols (hofstede, 2001). those are intangible, as well as material expressions of culture linked by communication systems (craig & douglas, 2006) that are commonly accepted in a society and form a consumer’s reference frame for approaching the world. with regard to shopping behaviour, those can be norms or standards concerning cuisine, beauty ideal, fashion style, health care, hygiene, gift-giving, and dining-out. for example kacen and lee (2002) stressed the importance of societal norms such as the accepted level of showing emotions and achievement of instant gratification for impulse buying behaviour. apart from being directly related to consumption behaviour, values also indirectly influence shopping behaviour through family or group relations, (male-female) role patterns, school, work, politics, and religion (hofstede, 2001). besides material manifestations such as food culture, also standards regarding housing and transportation can be perceived as a cultural phenomenon influencing shopping behaviour. an example is the small size of houses in japan, and consequently the limited storage space that people have available. another example is the common use of the car as a transportation mode in many countries, resulting in a habit of buying a lot in one time, as opposed to the netherlands where many people also utilize their bicycle for shopping (gilly, 1995; kooijman, 1999; krafft & mantrala, 2006). differences in opening hours and shopping centre locations (e.g., in-town versus out-oftown) can also lead to differences in shopping behaviour and assessment of attributes. data collection to gain further insight into the value orientation and shopping behaviour of expatriates, data was collected using in-depth interviews, online surveys, and then the outcomes were compared to existing data of dutch consumers. in-depth interviews prior to the main data collection, through an online survey, a total of 12 in-depth interviews were held with japanese, british and american expatriates. the outcomes provided insights into the shopping behaviour of expats. due to difficulties in reaching the expat community and obtaining information on their addresses the snowball technique was used to find respondents. the snowball technique is a sampling method where respondents are asked to recruit new respondents within their social network. it is typically used among ‘hidden populations’ such as expatriates. starting point were expat associations, social media, and the researchers’ own network. 134 journal of business strategies first, respondents were asked about their shopping behaviour in the netherlands as compared to their home-country. the main finding from the interviews was that all respondents noticed alterations in their shopping pattern and shopping motivations after they moved to the netherlands. this corresponds with gilly’s findings (1995). the most important reasons for this were opening hours and decreased car mobility. the british and american respondents mentioned that they shopped more often for daily products in the netherlands, but less often (as a leisure activity) for non-daily products. the japanese respondents also no ticed shopping less during leisure time. one japanese respondent noted that: “i have become more cautious about quality and less about price, since i have less opportunity to shop here,” illustrating that a changed shopping pattern can even influence shopping attitude. second, respondents were asked about their attitude towards shopping and the shopping environment in the netherlands in comparison to their home-country. the biggest issues mentioned are the restricted opening hours of stores and restaurants at nights and on weekends, and the service level of personnel. the wide-spread knowledge of english among store personnel is perceived as positive. another main issue are products from home that are missed such as food, personal care products, and clothing due to differences in size and style. expats therefore shop in expat stores, their home-country, elsewhere abroad or online. other items that were mentioned as being different were retail mix, store size and lay out, personal space, level of lighting, pricing, product range, offer of gastronomy, and modes of transportation. three additional interviews with experts on expats’ consumer behaviour confirmed these findings. online survey to enhance insight into the values, shopping behaviour and perception of the shopping environment of expatriates, data was collected with a structured and self-administered online survey in both english and japanese. to cope with issues of linguistic and conceptual equivalence (de mooij, 2004), the english version was checked by three native speakers, after which it was translated into japanese and reviewed by four other native speakers. some minor adaptations were incorporated into the survey based on the outcome of the in-depth interviews. in the japanese version some translations of concepts were adjusted. the scope of the study is limited to american, british, and japanese expats that live in amstelveen and amsterdam. because no sample frame is available, people were notified about the survey via international schools, expat associations, expat networks, expat websites, and a volume 29, number 2 135 number of expat stores. the survey was online from april to june 2010. note that it was not the objective of this study to test specific scales. therefore, we have made a pragmatic decision to use scales that have been used in a variety of studies, and have proven to be reliable, in measuring the various aspects of interest. measurements to measure values, the list of values (homer & kahle, 1988) was utilized since it offers the best prospects in terms of high reliability versus ease of use (grünert & scherhorn, 1990; shim & eastlick, 1998; de mooij, 2004). the nine items of the lov are displayed in table 3. respondents were asked to indicate which three values are most important to them in their personal life. shopping values are operationalised by using a recently developed extended classification of shopping values by seo and lee (2008) with which they investigated differences in perceived shopping value across social class. apart from the utilitarian shopping dimension (efficiency), they distinguished multiple hedonic shopping motives, namely experiential, diversional, reliable, and self-expressive shopping value. efficiency shopping value is related to time-awareness and time-efficiency, experiential shopping value to enjoyment of the shopping experience itself, diversional shopping value to feelings of escapism and problem diversion, reliable shopping value to the perception of product and brand reliability, and self-expressive shopping to self-conscious ness and identification with the shopping environment. the ten statements as defined by seo and lee (2008) are slightly adapted so they reflect a general shopping attitude. see table 4 for an overview of these statements. respondents were asked to indicate to what extent they agree with those statements using a 5-point likert-type scale. shopping behaviour is explored by measuring choices of respondents, i.e. the shopping patronage, favourite brands, main points of purchase for different product categories, and products that are unavailable in regular dutch stores. the perception of the shopping environment was measured by asking respondents to indicate the importance of and satisfaction with 14 shopping centres attributes using a 5-point likert-type scale. the list of attributes is displayed in table 6. it is based on existing lists by oppewal (1995), shim and eastlick (1998), and dennis (2005), and the outcomes of the literature review and in-depth interviews. the overall satisfaction regarding the centre is measured using a 10-point scale. the questions on shopping value and perception of shopping centre attributes each consist of a set of statements; therefore factor analysis was conducted to 136 journal of business strategies determine any underlying dimensions (factors). for each factor analysis, the kaisermeyer-olkin (kmo) measure has to be higher than .5 and bartlett’s test of sphericity should be significantly small, indicating that the sample size is adequate and the correlations between the variables are large enough to perform this type of analysis. the factors with an eigenvalue of >1 are extracted, and they are rotated orthogonally by varimax. to test for significant differences in mean factor scores between the cultural groups, anova and a standard f-test was used. in addition, expats were requested to provide some general information regarding their gender, age, nationality, household structure, occupation, level of education, income, zip code, time of residence in the region, and level of cultural identification (shim & eastlick, 1998). the latter was examined by asking respondents how strongly they relate to their cultural background using a 5-point likert-type scale. comparison in order to gain insight into the dutch context a comparison was made between the collected data and existing data on dutch consumers with a similar age profile in the same area, which was obtained from market research specialist strabo (2008a; 2008b; 2009; 2010).1 results using the research questions that were posed in the introduction, the cultural values of expatriates will be discussed in this paragraph, followed by the findings regarding their shopping behaviour and perception, and evaluation of shopping centre attributes. first however, a description of the sample is given. sample a total of 133 expats completed the questionnaire, of which 24 were american, 27 british, 32 japanese and 50 were distributed among 21 other nationalities (see table 1). the sample consisted of 87% females and 13% males. 71% of the sample was between the age of 35 and 54. as expected, almost all respondents (96%) were high-educated and the majority (59%) has an above average income. note that a quarter did not want to indicate their level of income. around 71% indicated to have been living less than 5 years in the area, which corresponds with the hsbc survey (2008) in which 68% indicated to have been staying 5 years or less in the host-country. due to the distribution of questionnaires via schools the number of women and households with children is overrepresented in the sample. approximately 57% of the respondents were employed and 34% indicated volume 29, number 2 137 they were housewives. table 2 and figure 2 display the level of cultural identification among expatriates. on average expats maintain a moderate to strong connection with their cultural background. interestingly, there is no correlation between the level of cultural identification and the time of residence in the area. based on an f-test though, british expats held a significantly weaker connection to their cultural background than the americans and japanese (f = 7.282, p = 0.001). table 1 sample descriptive total (n = 133) american british japanese variable # % # # # ethnicity american 24 18% british 27 20% japanese 32 24% other nationalities 50 38% gender male 17 13% 1 7 2 female 116 87% 23 20 30 age < 35 years 36 27% 5 2 10 35-54 years 94 71% 18 25 22 > 55 years 3 2% 1 0 0 household one person 18 14% 4 5 5 type two person 32 24% 4 7 9 family with kids 74 56% 16 15 13 other 6 5% 0 0 2 education secondary education 4 3% 0 3 0 professional education 16 12% 1 4 2 university education or higher 111 83% 23 20 30 do not want to say 2 2% 0 0 0 occupation full time job 41 31% 6 12 3 part time job 23 17% 5 6 3 autonomous / freelance 12 9% 1 3 3 house wife / man 45 34% 9 3 20 other 12 9% 3 3 3 income < €2.600 a month 20 15% 5 3 7 > €2.600 a month 79 59% 13 16 17 do not want to say 34 26% 6 8 8 138 journal of business strategies table 2 level of cultural identification mean total american british japanese f p cultural identification level 3.56 3.83 3.07 3.84 7.282 < .001 figure 2 cultural identification across cultures personal values expats were asked to indicate which three values out of the nine-item list of values were most important to them in their personal lives (see table 3). the findings indicate that expats clearly regard fun and enjoyment in life (23%) and warm relationships with others (23%) most frequently as one of their top-3 values in life. other frequently named values are sense of accomplishment (12%) and security (12%). being well-respected, excitement, and a sense of belonging have a rather low total score. although the scores of americans, british and japanese expats are rather comparable, as is shown in figure 3, some significant differences were still identified with chi-square tests (see table 3). fun and enjoyment in life appears to be a much less important value for the americans compared to the british and the japanese. security was more important for the japanese than it was for the british. if compared to the outcomes of rose and shoham (2000) who explored the personal volume 29, number 2 139 values of us and japanese mothers, the relatively high score for the americans on self-respect and the japanese on security and fun and enjoyment is not surprising. table 3 personal values frequency with which value was mentioned in top-3 american british japanese list of values # % # # # c2 p sense of belonging 20 5% 7% 11% 0% excitement 14 4% 3% 1% 9% fun and enjoyment in life 90 23% 18% 28% 28% 7.3961/5.8883 p < .01/p < .05 warm relationship with others 91 23% 24% 26% 27% self-fulfilment 33 8% 11% 6% 6% being well-respected 12 3% 1% 0% 0% sense of accomplishment 49 12% 14% 12% 10% security 48 12% 14% 7% 18% 5.2952 p < .05 self-respect 32 8% 8% 7% 1% total 389 97% 100% 100% 100% 1 significant differences exist between american and japanese expats 2 significant differences exist between british and japanese expats 3 significant differences exist between american and british expats 140 journal of business strategies sense of belonging self-respect security sense of accomplishment being wellrespected self-fulfillment warm relationships with others fun and enjoyment in life excitement 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 0% american british japanese figure 3 personal values across cultures shopping value to learn about the domain-specific values of expats regarding shopping, they were asked about their general attitude towards shopping, i.e. shopping value (see table 4). explanatory factor analysis was conducted on the variables describing shopping value. the kmo measure was 0.771 and the bartlett’s test of sphericity was significant, indicating adequacy of the sample and data for factor analysis. specifically, two factors were extracted as shown in table 4. subsequently, standard f-tests were carried out to determine differences between groups. the first factor seems to be associated with (1) hedonic shopping motives and leisure, since it comprehends experiential and diversional shopping values on the positive scale and a negative factor loading for “a store visit is good when it is over very quickly.” factor 2 covers values related to efficiency, self-expression and brand-reliability, pointing towards a (2) utilitarian dimension. product-reliability takes a distinct position, since it is not associated with any other components but receives a high score in general from the entire group of expats. these results correspond with general findings on shopping value dimensions, but contrast with the findings by seo and lee (2008). according to them the utilitarian dimension comprehends solely efficiency shopping values. in our findings, this volume 29, number 2 141 dimension includes values regarding efficiency, self-expression, and brand-reliability. the relation of efficiency and reliability might be a manifestation of functionality and saving time. the link with self-expressive shopping values could be explained by a kind of (uncomfortable) self-awareness that is associated with shopping for a purpose and not with shopping as a leisure activity. table 4 shopping attitude mean total total group 1. 2. of expatriates hedonic utilitarian the time required for shopping has a big influence on my shopping experience 3.86 .542 a store visit is good when it is over very quickly 3.04 -.620 .503 shopping trips are truly a joy 3.04 .841 i enjoy shopping trips for its own sake, not just for the items i may purchase 3.10 .864 shopping trips truly feel like an escape 2.56 .762 while shopping, i am able to forget my problems 2.39 .683 .402 i prefer to visit stores that have high reliability for product 4.11 a store is good because it has many well-known brands 2.98 .682 while shopping i feel self-conscious 2.29 .710 i identify myself with the store that i am shopping in 2.45 .656 eigenvalues 3.22 2.45 % of variance 32.22 56.70 american -.233 .331 mean british -.357 -.147 japanese .641 -.554 f 13.391 6.600 p .000 .002 the standard f-test used to test for differences in mean factor scores, between cultural groups, lead to some interesting results. they indicate that on the hedonic dimension the japanese score highly positive whereas the american and british score negative, resulting in a significant difference between the japanese on the one hand 142 journal of business strategies and the american and british on the other. the hedonic value of shopping is very important for the japanese compared to both the british and american respondents. almost the opposite applies to the utilitarian dimension. here, the americans score positive, the japanese score highly negative, and the british score slightly negative. for the american group, the utilitarian shopping value is very important, while this is not the case for the other cultural groups — specifically for the japanese. it was also tested whether the shopping attitudes differ significantly per age, gender, and occupation. whether people work or not and gender showed no differences for shopping attitude. however, for various age groups a significant effect was found (f = 4.266, p = 0.017); the younger the respondents the more important the hedonic shopping value. shopping behaviour shopping patronage the main indicator that was used to define shopping behaviour was the frequency of visits. on average, expatriates make more shopping trips than dutch consumers (see table 5), namely 3.3 per week for daily goods (such as food and personal care products) and 1.5 per week for non-daily goods (e.g. apparel), compared to a total of only 3.0 per week for dutch consumers. regarding other aspects of shopping behaviour such as the patronage of other shopping venues in the area, moment of visit, and customer motivations, there were no clear differences between expats and dutch consumers. the visit frequency of expats does not vary significantly across cultures either. whether shopping frequency differ for various age groups, gender, and occupation was tested and no significant differences were found. table 5 visit frequency per week mean total american british japanese dutch* f(p) number of shopping trips for daily goods per week 3.30 3.27 3.70 2.99 1.553 (.218) number of shopping trips for non-daily goods per week 1.52 1.74 1.44 1.44 .198 (.821) total 4.82 5.01 5.14 4.43 3.06 * based on strabo purchase flow survey 2008 volume 29, number 2 143 missed products and brand preferences expats were asked about products from their home-country that were unavailable in regular dutch stores (see figure 4). the majority indicated that there are indeed specific products that they miss: mainly foods, clothing, books and media, and personal care products. likewise, gilly (1995) and usunier (1999) already stressed the importance of foods from home for expats. in the case of food (29%), personal care (47%) and clothing (45%) those are from specific brands. in general, expats have a greater preference for well-known international brands, while dutch consumers are more oriented on national chains. expats also miss stores with petite or larger clothing sizes, underwear, and designer clothes. those items are related to cultural norms regarding body proportions, beauty ideal, style, and quality perception. some of these products could also symbolize home, just as gilly (1995) found. the results do not indicate that there are differences between cultures regarding this topic or that people with a stronger cultural identification miss more products. figure 4 missed products from home-country figure 5 shows where expats eventually bought the products that they missed. buying online (32%), in expat/ethnic specialty stores (26%) or bringing products from ‘home’ themselves or via family or friends (29%) are popular ways of attaining these products. some expats bought products elsewhere abroad (6%). food was mainly bought in expat stores or brought from their home-country. books and media were generally bought online. clothing and personal care products were brought from their home-country but were also ordered online. japanese expats visited expat stores in order to obtain specific ingredients needed in japanese cuisine. shopping centres with such japanese stores exert a real pull factor on japanese expats since 144 journal of business strategies those are visited more often by them than one would expect based on their place of residence. figure 5 points of attainment for missed products evaluation of shopping centre attributes the evaluation of shopping centre attributes was investigated as part of the value-attitude-behaviour hierarchy. expats were asked to indicate the importance of shopping centre attributes in their decision on where to shop (see table 6), as well as their satisfaction with those attributes in the main shopping venue of amstelveen, stadshart amstelveen (see table 7). in comparison to dutch consumers, expatriates found location and accessibility, opening hours, a fashionable and trend sensitive (international) brand mix, choice in clothing sizes, and the possibility of covered shopping relatively important. expatriates with kids attach importance to stores, facilities and services for children. the service level is evaluated as low in general. factor analysis was conducted on the variables describing the importance of the shopping centre attributes and resulted in four factors (see table 6). the kmo measure was 0.725 and bartlett’s test of sphericity was significant. the four factors are labelled shopping centre functionality, shopping centre identity, essentials, and parking. subsequently, mean scores were generated per respondent for each of the factors and tested whether they significantly differ per cultural group. the results show a significant difference for the factor ‘parking’ for the japanese group, who have a higher mean score on this dimension in contrast to both the americans and the british (p < .001), and find the parking aspect of a shopping centre more important than the other cultural groups. volume 29, number 2 145 table 6 evaluation of importance of shopping centre attributes mean total total 1. 2. 3. 4. group shopping shopping of centre centre expatriates functionality identity essentials parking location/accessibility of the centre 4.59 .575 parking facilities 3.28 .895 retail mix 4.14 .658 opening hours of store 3.98 .562 .482 catering facilities 2.36 .584 facilities and services 2.67 .601 .440 attributes service by personnel 3.29 .428 .483 fashion and trend sensitivity 3.14 .638 promotions and events 2.64 .770 atmosphere of the centre 3.62 .747 design of the centre and public space 3.15 .728 covered shopping 3.33 .663 personal space and privacy 2.80 .782 orientation and way-finding 3.02 .653 eigenvalues 4.03 1.61 1.22 1.12 % of variance 28.77 11.51 8.68 7.96 american -.153 .029 .056 -.311 mean british -.052 .199 .109 -.342 japanese -.194 -.293 -.127 .593 f .182 1.788 .406 10.240 p .834 .174 .668 .000 it was also tested whether other socio-demographic variables show significant differences for the importance of shopping centre attributes. women (f = 8.705, p = 0.004), and respondents without a job (f = 5.417, p = 0.022) find parking more important than men and respondents with a job. because the group of japanese is significantly overrepresented by females and housewives these results should be interpreted with care. 146 journal of business strategies table 7 evaluation of satisfaction with shopping centre attributes mean total total 1. 2. 3. 4. group shopping shopping of centre space centre expatriates identity perception functionality essentials location/accessibility of the centre 4.18 .775 parking facilities 3.50 .668 retail mix 3.36 .466 .405 .506 opening hours of store 3.13 .738 catering facilities 3.00 .766 facilities and services 2.86 .420 .676 attributes service by personnel 2.87 .425 .412 442 fashion and trend sensitivity 3.15 .770 promotions and events 3.17 .635 atmosphere of the centre 3.58 .803 design of the centre and public space 3.50 .612 .444 covered shopping 3.87 .804 personal space and privacy 3.26 .438 .612 orientation and way-finding 3.42 .655 eigenvalues 5.81 1.38 1.12 1.01 % of variance 41.50 9.88 7.98 7.21 american .081 -.509 -.160 -.122 mean british -.398 .097 .473 .308 japanese -.203 .171 -.240 -.228 f 1.360 2.676 3.108 1.754 p .264 .077 .052 .182 exploratory factor analysis was also conducted on variables describing the satisfaction with shopping centre attributes in the main shopping venue in amstelveen (see table 7). the kmo measure was 0.868 and bartlett’s test of sphericity was significant. four factors were found: shopping centre identity, space perception, shopping centre functionality, and essentials. a clear difference was found with the factor analysis of importance. the attributes related to space percep tion form a separate factor with regard to satisfaction, while they are associated with functional attributes when it concerns importance. volume 29, number 2 147 the mean factor sores of the cultural groups were compared by a one-way anova. significant differences were found for the factors space perception and shopping centre functionality. the means show that japanese are most satisfied with space perception, including orientation, way finding, and covered shopping. the british group was slightly positive while the americans were quite negative with regard to this factor. shopping centre functionality, including availability of facilities, services, and opening hours, was positively evaluated by the british. the other two groups were slightly negative with respect to this factor. also tested was whether different age groups, gender, and occupation show significant different means for the factors. the only significant finding was that people with a job (f = 4.308, p = 0.042) are in general more satisfied with the shopping centre functionality factor. conclusion and discussion this study aimed at examining how shopping centre attributes can be adapted to culture-related shopping behaviour of expatriates. the guiding research questions handled cultural and shopping values, shopping behaviour, and perception and evaluation of shopping centre attributes by expats. the answers were established through a literature review, in-depth interviews, an online survey among expats living in the amstelveen/amsterdam area in the netherlands, and a comparison of the results with existing data on dutch shoppers. the results of this study lead towards a somewhat mixed image on the shopping behaviour of expats. although expatriates seem to hold a rather comparable value framework as a group, there are still clear significant differences between cultures regarding personal values and shopping value. japanese expats for example perceive shopping more often as a joyful activity, while americans expats perceive it as more related to time and efficiency. british expats’ shopping values cannot be characterized as typically hedonic, neither as typically utilitarian. this corresponds with earlier findings of rubio-sanchez (2007), who also found that cultural dimensions influence shopping values. shopping values could not be explained by sociodemographic variables like gender and occupations. however, shopping values differ for various age groups. for younger respondents the hedonic shopping values are more important. the actual shopping behaviour, such as visit frequency, does not differ so much between cultures. however, compared to dutch consumers, expatriates make more shopping trips per week. 148 journal of business strategies the evaluation of importance of shopping centre attributes by expatriates turned out to be rather similar across cultures. based on factor analysis four factors could be identified, labelled shopping centre functionality, shopping centre identity, essentials, and parking. only one significant cross-cultural difference exists regarding the ‘parking’ factor for the japanese group. since japanese expats showed strong hedonic shopping values, and parking can be regarded as a factor representing utilitarian attributes, this finding is rather unexpected. an explanation could be the fact that females that do not have a job are over-represented in the japanese sample. a larger and more balanced sample size would have allowed us to be more specific about this issue. variables describing the satisfaction with shopping centre attributes in the shopping venue in amstelveen could be grouped in two (out of four) significant factors: space perception and shopping centre functionality. american expats were quite negative with regard to the factor “space perception” including the attributes “facilities and services” and “services by personnel.” this finding could be related to differences in societal norms regarding service levels between the american and dutch culture. british expatriates were the only group that was positive with regard to “shopping centre functionality” including attributes like “opening hours,” “facilities” and “retail mix.” this could be explained by similarities between the dutch and british culture; they share the same european shopping values. overall, facilities and services (by personnel) received the lowest evaluation by the total group of expats while the location, accessibility and the fact that a shopping centre is covered received the highest evaluation scores. on one hand the results consequently reflect a universal lifestyle among expats, while at the same time they also emphasize cultural differences. cultural sensitivity is therefore definitely important in the marketing of a shopping centre towards a heterogenic group like expats, but should not be exaggerated either since expatriates have some clear common grounds in their value orientation, shopping behaviour and perception of the shopping environment. a certain cognitive proximity among expatriates could be an explanation for these common grounds. from a broader perspective one could say that the adjustment of a shopping centre to a cultural consumer segment can take place on the level of the shopping centre, store and product assortment, and demands a marketing strategy incorporating both lifestyle and ethnicity. insight in the cultural component and potential of such consumers in a catchment area is therefore important, but adjustments should take place without jeopardising the other (dutch) consumers. apart from extended opening hours, which are a continuous subject of debate in the netherlands, the most effective soluvolume 29, number 2 149 tions for shopping centre developers, management, and retailers are therefore in the retail and brand mix, product assortment, (bilingual) service, signing and promotion. as was concluded in the literature review, only a very limited number of studies has explored the consumption and shopping behaviour of expatriates. therefore, further research is needed, preferably based on actual buying behaviour of expats and including data on exact expenditure and share of turnover. the limited sample sizes of the cultural groups in this study also make the results hard to generalise. future studies should therefore be conducted among expatriates from and on different continents in order to improve general applicability and to offer insight into the influence of lifestyle, ethnicity, ethnic identification, and other characteristics. native consumers should also be included in the study too to increase validity. in addition, it might be of interest to apply more advanced modelling techniques, such as structural equation models, to examine more complex relations between the variables and constructs included in the study. we hope to report on these results in the near future. the relation between shopping value and culture and the corresponding measurement scales might be interesting to examine more thoroughly as well. finally, due to the nature of cross-cultural research it would be preferable to have command over a culturally diverse research team and sufficient resources to allow translation/backtranslation of a survey. nevertheless, this study provides further important insights into the relation between consumers’ values, shopping behaviour and the physical shopping environment while emphasizing the complexity of this theme in relation to culture and ethnicity. acknowledgements the authors gratefully acknowledge the support of the market research specialist strabo. end notes 1. (a) visitors’ survey 2008 was held among 871 visitors of stadshart amstelveen; (b) pur chase flow survey 2008 was a phone based survey held among 400 households from amstelveen and 700 in amsterdam zuid, aalsmeer, uithoorn, hoofddorp, badhoevedorp and ouder-amstel; untapped market analysis 2009 was a written survey among 1.800 consumers in diemen, amsterdam-zuid, amsterdam-sloten and badhoevedorp; market analysis 2010 was a phone-based survey among 1.200 households, 400 in each 10-minute catchment area of stadshart amstelveen. 150 journal of business strategies references ackermann, d., & tellis, g. (2001). can culture affect prices? a cross-cultural study of shopping and retail prices. journal of retailing, 77, 57-82. ajzen, i. (1985). from intentions to actions: a theory of planned behavior. in j. kuhl & j. beckmann (eds.). action control: from conition to behavior, 11-39. new york: springer verlag. ajzen, i. (1991). the theory of planned behaviour. organisational behaviours and human decision processes, 50, 179-211. allard, t., babin, b. j., & chebat, j. c. (2009). when income matters: customers evaluation of shopping mall’s hedonic and utilitarian orientations. journal of retailing and consumer services, 16, 40-49. andreason, a. w., (2008). expatriate adjustment of spouses and expatriate managers: an integrative research review. international journal of management, 25(2), 382-395. amstelveen municipality (2008). the international dimension of amstelveen [de internationale dimensie van amstelveen]. retrieved january 21, 2010 from www.amstelveen.nl/web/show?id=199074&langid=43 amsterdam municipality (2007). the expatriates: inventarisation document development physical expat office window [the expatriates: inventarisatiedocument ontwikkeling fysiek expat loket]. retrieved january 21, 2010 from biodata.asp4all.nl/andreas/2008/09012f97803ff698/09012f97803ff698.pdf babin, b. j., darden, w. r., & griffin, m. (1994). work and/or fun: measuring hedonic and utilitarian shopping value. journal of consumer marketing, 20(4), 644-656. babin, b. j., & attaway, j. s. (2000). atmospheric affect as a tool for creating value and gaining share of customer. journal of business research, 49(2), 91-100. black, j. s. (1988). workrole transitions: a study of american expatriate managers in japan. journal of international business studies, 19, 277-294. black, j. s., & stephens, g. k. (1989). the influence of the spouse on american expatriate adjustment and intent to stay in pacific rim overseas assignments. journal of management, 15(4), 277-294. black, j., mendenhall, m., & ouddou, g. (1991). toward a comprehensive model of international adjustment: an integration of multiple theoretical perspectives. academy of management review, 16(2), 291-317. brunsø, k., & grünert, k. g. (1998). cross-cultural similarities and differences in shopping for food. journal of business research, 42, 145-150. volume 29, number 2 151 caldwell, m., blackwell, k., & tulloch, k. (2006). cosmopolitanism as a consumer orientation: replicating and extending research. qualitative marketing research: an international journal, 9(2), 126-139. cannon, h. m., & yaprak, a. (2002). will the real-world citizen please stand up! the many faces of cosmopolitan consumer behaviour. journal of international marketing, 10(4), 30-52. chebat, j. c., & morrin, m. (2007). colors and cultures: exploring the effects of mall décor on consumer perceptions. journal of business research, 60, 189-196. craig, c. s., & douglas, s. p. (2006). beyond national culture: implications of cultural dynamics for consumer research. international marketing review, 23(3), 332-342. dennis, c. (2005). objects of desire: consumer behaviour in shopping centre choices. london: palgrave macmillan. eroglu, s. a., machleit, k., & barr, t. f. (2005). perceived retail crowding: the role of shopping values. journal of business research, 58, 1146-1153. farquhar, j. d. (2009). international explorer expat survey, international journal of bank marketing, 27(3), 242-246. geertz, c. (1973). the interpretation of cultures. new york: basic books. retrieved january 21, 2010 from books.google.com. gilly, m. c. (1995). the consumer acculturation of expatriate americans. in f. r. kardes & m. sujan (eds.). advances in consumer research, 22, 506-510. provo, ut: association for consumer research. griffin, m., babin, b. j., & modianos, d. (2000). shopping values of russian consumers: the impact of habituation in a developing economy. journal of retailing, 76(1), 33-52. grinstein, a., & wathieu, l. (2008). cosmopolitanism, assignment duration, and expatriate adjustment: the trade-off between well-being and performance. esmt working paper, 08-011. retrieved february 20, 2012 from papers.ssrn.com/ sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1353128 grünert, s. c., & scherhorn, g. (1994). consumer values in west-germany: underlying dimensions and cross-cultural comparison with north america. journal of business research, 20, 97-107. halepete, j., seshadri iyer, k. v., & park, s. c. (2008). wal-mart in india: a success or failure? international journal of retail & distribution manage ment, 36(9), 701-713. hall, e. t. (1996). the hidden dimension. new york: anchor books. hannerz, u. (1990). cosmopolitans and locals in a world culture. theory, culture & society, 7, 237-251. 152 journal of business strategies hazel, d. (2005, may), local flavors: forest city’s hispanic retail group targets strong latino markets. shopping centers today. retrieved january 21, 2010 from www.icsc.org/srch/sct/sct0505/manage_market_4.php. hofstede, g. (1980). culture’s consequences: international differences in work-related values. london: sage. hofstede, g. (2001). culture’s consequences: comparing values, behaviors, institutions, and organisations across nations. london: sage. holstein, w. j. (2007, july 27). why wal-mart can’t find happiness in japan. fortune magazine. retrieved january 21, 2010 from money.cnn.com/magazines/ fortune/fortune_archive/2007/08/06/100141311/index.htm homer, p. m., & kahle, l. r. (1988). a structural equation test of the value-attitudebehavior hierarchy. journal of personality and social psychology, 54, 638-646. hsbc bank international (2009). expat explorer survey 2009: expat experience. retrieved january 21, 2010 from www.offshore.hsbc.com/1/2/international/expat/expat-survey/results-2009. icsc (2009). 21st century retail centers: context, culture and community, author. jackson, v., stoel, l., & brantley, a. (2011). mall attributes and shopping value: differences by gender and generational cohort. journal of retailing and consumer services, 18, 1-9. kacen, j. j., & lee, j. a. (2002). the influence of culture on consumer impulsive buying behaviour. journal of consumer psychology, 12, 163-176. kahle, l. r. (2000). cross-cultural consumer psychographics. new york: haworth press. keen, c., wetzels, m., ruyter, k., feinberg, r. (2004). e-tailers versus retailers. which factors determine consumers preferences. journal of business research, 57(7), 685-695. kim, j., park, j. (2005). a consumer shopping channel extension model: attitude shift toward the online store. journal of fashion marketing and management, 9(1), 106-121. kliment, s. a. (2004). building type basics for retail and mixed-used facilities. new jersey: john wiley & sons. kooijman, d. (1999). machine and theatre: design concepts of shopping venues [machine en theater: ontwerpconcepten van winkelgebouwen]. rotterdam: 010 publishers. koubaa, y. (2011), the dual impact of traditional and national cultural values on expatriate ethnic groups’ attitude and willingness to buy. asia pacific journal of marketing and logistics, 23(5), 626-640. volume 29, number 2 153 krafft, m., & mantrala, m. k. (2006). retailing in the 21st century. berlin: springer. kuruvilla, s. j., & joshi, n. (2010). influence of demographics, psychographics, shopping orientation, mall shopping attitude and purchase patterns on mall patronage in india. journal of retailing and consumer services, 17, 259-269. lavin, m. (1996). ethnic/racial segmentation: insights from theory and practice. journal of retailing and consumer services, 3(2), 99-105. louviere, j. j., levin, i. p., meyer, r. j., henley, d. h., stoner, j. w., curry, d. j., anderson, d. a., & woodworth, g. (1981). the development and test of mathematical models of travelers’ perceptions and decisions, final report 27, institute of urban and regional research, university of iowa, iowa city. masicotte, m., michon, r., chebat, j. c., sirgy, m. j., & borges, a. (2011). effects of mall atmosphere on mall evaluation: teenage versus adult shoppers. journal of retailing and consumer services, 18, 74-80. mccracken, g. (1988). culture and consumption: new approaches to the symbolic character of consumer goods and activities. bloomington: indiana university press. retrieved january 21, 2010 from books.google.com michon, r., & chebat, j.c. (2004). cross-cultural mall shopping values and habits: a comparison between englishand french-speaking cana dians. journal of business research, 57, 883-892. michon, r., chebat, j. c., & turley, l. w. (2005). mall atmospherics: the interaction effects of the mall environment on shopping behaviour. journal of business research, 58(5), 576–583. mooij de, m., & hofstede, g. (2002). convergence and divergence in consumer behavior: implications for international retailing. journal of retail ing, 78, 61-69. mooij, de m. (2004). consumer behaviour and culture: consequences for global marketing and advertising. thousand oaks, ca: sage. nicholls, j. a. f., li, f., mandokovic, t., roslow, s., & kranendonk, c. j. (2000). us-chilean mirrors: shoppers in two countries. journal of consumer marketing, 17(2), 106-119. oppewal, h. (1995). conjoint experiments and retail planning: modelling consumer choice of shopping centre and retailer reactive behaviour. eindhoven, the netherlands: eindhoven university of technology. retrieved january 21, 2010 from alexandria.tue.nl/extra3/proefschrift/prf10b/9404520.pdf pavlou, p. a., & chai, l. (2002). what drives electronic commerce across cultures? a cross-cultural empirical investigation of the theory of planned behaviour, journal of electronic commerce research, 3(4), 240-253. rice, c. (1993). consumer behaviour: behavioural aspects of marketing. oxford: butterworth-heinemann. 154 journal of business strategies rose, g. m., & shoham, a. (2000). the values of american and japanese mothers: an application of lov in the us and japan. in l. r. kahle (ed.). cross-cultural consumer psychographics, 45-62. new york: haworth press. rokeach, m. (1973). the nature of human values, new york: free press. rubio-sanchez, a. (2007). cultural dimensions and their influence on shopping value. ann arbor, mi: proquest. sands, s., oppewal, h., & beverland, m. (2009). the effects of in-store themed events on consumer store choice decisions. journal of retailing and consumer services, 16, 386-395. seo, s., & lee, y. (2008). shopping values of clothing retailers perceived by consumers of different social classes. journal of retailing and consumer services, 15, 491-499. seock, y-k. (2011). cultural influence on loyalty tendency and evaluation of retail store attributes: an analysis of taiwanese and american consumers. international journal of retail & distribution management, 39(2), 94-113. shearin, r. (2006, january). seeking cultural dna, shopping centre business. retrieved january 21, 2010 from www.shoppingcenter business.com/articles/ jan06/story3.shtml shim, s., & gehrt, k. (1996). hispanic and native american adolescents: an exploratory study of their approach to shopping. journal of retailing, 72(3), 307-324. shim, s., & eastlick, m. a. (1998). the hierarchical influence of personal values on shopping attitude and behaviour. journal of retailing, 74(1), 139-160. sood, j., & nasu, y. (1995). religiosity and nationality: an exploratory study of their effect on behaviour in japan and the united states. journal of business research, 34, 1-9. stoel, l., wickliffe, v., & lee, k. h. (2003). attribute beliefs and spending as antecedents to shopping value. journal of business research, 57, 1067-1073. strabo (2008a). purchase flow study stadshart amstelveen. amsterdam: author. strabo (2008b). visitors survey stadshart amstelveen. amsterdam: author. strabo (2009). ‘untapped market’ stadshart amstelveen. amsterdam: author. strabo (2010). market analysis stadshart amstelveen. amsterdam: author. strategic direction (2009). china teaches ikea limits of homogeneity: not yet part of the eastern furniture. strategic direction, 25(11), 43-45. swinyard, w. r. (1998). shopping mall customer values: the national mall shopper and the list of values. journal of retailing and consumer services, 5(3), 167172. volume 29, number 2 155 the economist (2009, january 22). segregation and shopping: the call of the mall. retrieved january 21, 2010 from www.economist.com/world/unitedstates/ displaystory.cfm?story_id=e1_tnjrsvvg&source=login_ paybarrier thompson c. j., & tambyah s. k. (1999). trying to be cosmopolitan. journal of consumer research, 26(3), 214-41. timmermans, h. (1982), consumer choice of shopping centre: an information integration approach. regional studies, 3, 171-182. timothy, d. j. (2005). shopping tourism, retailing and leisure. clevedon, uk: channel view publications. retrieved january 21, 201 from books.google.com turley, l. w., & milliman, r. e. (2000). atmosphere effects on shopping behavior: a review of the experimental evidence. journal of business research, 49, 193211. tylor, e. b. (1920) [1871]. primitive culture: researches into the development of mythology, philosophy, religion, language, art and custom, volume 1. (6th ed.). new york: john murray. forgotton books. retrieved january 21, 2020 from books.google.com usunier, j. c. (1999). food consumption and the expatriation experience: a study of american expatriates in france. in b. dubois, t. m. lowrey, l. j. shrum, & m. vanhuele (eds.). european advances in consumer research, 4, 352-360. provo, ut: association for consumer research. van vianen, a. e. m., de pater, i. e., kristof-brown, a. l., & johnson, e. c. (2004). fitting in: surfaceand deep-level cultural differences and expatriates’ adjustment. the academy of management journal, 47(5), 697-709. vinson, d. e, scott, j. e., & lamont, l. m. (1977). the role of personal values in marketing and consumer behaviour. journal of marketing, 41(2), 44-50. yüksel, a. (2007). tourist shopping habit: effects on emotions, shopping value and behaviour. tourism management, 28, 58-69. zhang, y., winterich, k. p, & mittal, v. (2010). power distance belief and impulsive buying. journal of marketing research, 47(5), 945-954 biographical sketch of authors geri wijnen is a development manager at wereldhave, a listed internationally operating investment company with a focus on retail. here she is responsible for redevelopment of two shopping centers in the netherlands. she holds an academic master in real estate management and development and an academic bachelor in architecture building and planning from the eindhoven university of technology. her master thesis focused on the shopping behavior of expatriates. 156 journal of business strategies astrid kemperman is an assistant professor of urban planning at the eindhoven university of technology. her research focuses on the impacts of urban environments on human behavior. she has specific interest in the areas of physical activity and health, leisure activities of different groups in society (e.g., the elderly), and shopping behavior. she also has investigated dynamics of tourist choice behavior, including modeling variety seeking, seasonality and diversification to support planning decision making. ingrid janssen is associate professor at tias nimbas business school and lecturer at the real estate management group at eindhoven university of technology. her research focuses on retail real estate, real estate asset and property management and decision making in real estate. her ph.d. involved decision-making politics in retail property development. a cross-cultural comparison of expatriates’ shopping behaviour a simple export country-market screening technique for small us businesses: a packaged good illustration jose f. medina joel saegert john merrifield university of texas at san antonio san antonio, tx abstract us small businesses are in need of processes and techniques that help them alleviate the difficult experience of choosing foreign markets. using a generic screening process, this paper explains the stages, the screening criteria, and the ranking techniques for selecting country-markets. the paper illustrates the application of shift-share analysis (ssa) as a simple technique to rank country-market potentials. results from an analysis of a packaged good show that ssa is an adequate ranking technique to identify preliminary country prospects. implications for small businesses and future research are given. introduction efforts to export to other countries usually encounter barriers less frequently faced in the domestic marketplace, such as differences in cultural, legal, political, and economic environments. at the same time, many of the sales barriers encountered in export marketing are similar to those of domestic marketing, e.g., ineffectiveness of dealers and distributors, changing customer preferences, lack of customer knowledge of the product, etc. despite the level of similarity (or dissimilarity) of the barriers between domestic and export marketing, small us businesses in growing numbers are eager to step into the international business arena. reports from the government (prosak, 1993) and the general business media (businessweek, 1995) indicate that small us firms, with reasonably priced consumer products and with a proven record of acceptability in the domestic market, have strong export potential. although assessing a product's export potential is a critical step in export marketing, determining where that potential is the greatest is just as important. which countries to export to first and how many is always a vexing question that has challenged many small and medium-sized exporters (mcniven, fall 1996 medina, saegert & merrifield: screening technique 127 1991; ramaswami & yang, 1990). research has found that perceived trade barriers are traced back to managers' difficulties in locating foreign markets (alexandrides, 1971; tesar & tarleton, 1982). unfortunately, there is not a simple, appropriate, and reliable technique to help identify attractive world markets. this is a troublesome circumstance for the many small businesses with simple decision structures (miller & friesen, 1980). the export marketing literature is sparse at best in evaluating processes and techniques on how to select country markets. existing treatments vary from the sophisticated, such as comparative cluster analysis (sheti, 1971), to the much simpler, such as multiple factor analysis (samli, 1977) and shift-share analysis (green & allaway, 1985). one problem with the more sophisticated techniques is that they require large amounts of data manipulation to screen candidate countries. another limitation is that these approaches require good knowledge and understanding of complex statistical techniques. on the other hand, a simpler and more parsimonious technique such as shift-share analysis (ssa) appears to possess characteristics for wider application. shift-share analysis has been around in the economic literature for a long time (fuchs, 1959). it has been traditionally used in studies of regional economics to assess the differences between regional and national trends of economic phenomena (merrifield, 1983). it has been successfully applied in measuring market growth by eliminating many of the limitations inherent in the use of absolute and relative measures (huff & sherr, 1967). some studies have extended its use to international trade, for example, to determine the composition of trade flows for the us and its trading partners (green, 1985; green & allaway, 1985; green & larsen, 1991a; green & larsen, 1991b). to be sure, ssa has three important limitations regarding its use in international trade. first, it involves only two points in time; choosing different points in time might render different ranking results. second, it only ranks one product category at a time. and, finally, the technique's predictive validity has not been tested for ranking exports markets. one result of applying ssa to an export screening process would be that it produces a smaller set of export country-markets that would warrant a more in-depth and focused investigation. in addition, the greater accessibility to export statistics through the internet and similar media renders ssa a more valuable and useful research technique to be applied by small businesses. the purpose of this paper is to examine the effectiveness of applying the ssa ranking technique to readily available us export statistics to measure country-market market potentials. the literature is briefly reviewed regarding the importance to small businesses of exporting as a competitive country-market entry strategy; generic methods for the export country-market screening process; and the convenience and availability of trade data and the shift-share analysis technique. a methodology for a simple export country-market screening method is described using the ssa ranking technique, following which results are described and tested against independent sources for convergent 128 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 validity. this version of ssa is intended to be one that can be easily understood and used by small us export businesses. thus, the last two sections discuss implications for such companies and make recommendations for research. exporting as a competitive country-market entry strategy exporting should be seen as only one of several possible country-market competitive entry strategies e.g., licensing, joint ventures, collaborative alliances, and direct investment (agarwal & ramaswami, 1992; cavusgil & zou, 1994). an entry strategy is a comprehensive plan that sets forth the objectives, goals, resources, and policies that will guide a company's international business operation. specifically, country-market entry strategies require decisions about the choice of a target country and the choice of an entry mode to penetrate that target (root, 1987). additionally, a competitive strategy requires decisions concerning the level of expansion concentration versus diversification and competitive posture defensive versus offensive (ayal & zif, 1978). a strategy of country-market concentration would focus available resources among a small number of country-markets. conversely, diversification allocates limited resources over a larger number of country-markets. small firms stepping into the international arena would benefit from a concentration approach, where high market growth rate and sales stability allow firms to gradually capture a few "neutral markets." experience has demonstrated that many small us companies become committed to international markets only when they no longer believe that they can attain their strategic objectives by remaining at home (root, 1987). because of their limited international experience and resources, and a "typically" defensive stance relative to their larger competitors, small firms tend to opt for foreign markets that have similar demand structures as those in the us (davidson, 1983). consequently, ayal & zif (1978) would argue that small firms should launch concentrated efforts to capture a few "neutral" countrymarkets to expand their domestic base, and thus defend themselves from a larger competitor's attack at home. many small companies in the united states seem to have now reached the point at which they need to actively seek export opportunities (businessweek, 1995). conventional wisdom and recent empirical research suggest that most small us businesses do not have the capabilities to undertake any entry strategy planning beyond exports (baird, lyles & orris, 1993; baird, lyles & orris, 1994), partly because of their unpreparedness to deal with foreign business practices and foreign government regulations (czinkota, 1994). at the same time, many potential foreign markets do not seem to offer a large enough opportunity to justify more elaborate entry strategies beyond exports. thus, exporting may be seen as the preferred choice of entry mode for most smallsized companies in the us. the continuing expansion of the global economy fall 1996 medina, saegert & merrifield: screening technique 129 will almost certainly bring many more companies to that point in the future, and identifying suitable markets is generally a first step. the export country-market screening process the sometimes complex realties of many foreign environments and the allure of high profit potentials require that export country-markets be sought objectively, systematically, and continuously (cavusgil, 1985). understanding the characteristics of available screening processes is of the utmost importance for small businesses, as they do not have the financial wherewithal to test potentially ineffective procedures (bilkey, 1978; ogram, 1982). export market screening processes were originally conceived to help companies understand information requirements as they studied the possibility of exporting to a potential pool of country-markets (cavusgil, 1985; kale & sudharshan, 1987; root, 1982; walvoord, 1980). the main goal of any screening process is, therefore, to reduce the number of prospective country-markets to a manageable set that can be further explored by the firm. the typical structure of a screening processes would include screening stages, screening criteria, and ranking techniques. most small firms would prefer to produce standardized offerings rather than to make major adjustments (or modifications) to their existing product line. this is in part due to the many potential up-front costs for such modifications, including gathering new information, laboratory testing, and patent protection, just to name a few (terpstra, 1983; walters, 1986). therefore, for small firms, identifying barriers-to-exports may be more important than identifying opportunities. a screening process designed for small firms should be able to eliminate systematically those country-markets with the least likelihood of having customers who would purchase the firm's offerings as they were originally conceived for the domestic market. product offering selection would depend on gathering country-market information guided by company operating strategies and marketplace realities. before undertaking any preliminary screening, managers of small businesses should have a well-rounded understanding of the firm's production expertise and capabilities (fennell & saegert, 1990; kerr & kirkconnell, 1989). additionally, a firm's ability to develop cost-effective product/market research methods such as data-gathering techniques, relevant information requirements and data sources, rests on maintaining a constant vigil on what is happening in the global marketplace (davidson, 1983). after choosing the candidate offering, managers should review the target market profile for the product category of interest the characteristics of the individuals (and/or organizations) that are actual or prospective customers based on their domestic marketplace experience (davidson, 1983; root, 1987; terpstra, 1988). this exercise should help the company identify screening criteria based on demand-generating conditions (or circumstances) for the candi130 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 date product. the next two sections discuss in more detail the screening stages and criteria, and the ranking technique characteristics. screening stages and screening criteria figure 1 shows an adapted model of the screening process in export country-market selection, and screening criteria and ranking techniques in export country-market selection. the adapted model includes four screening stages: (1) country-market identification, (2) country-market market potential, (3) country-market sales potential, and (4) segment identification in the targeted country market. the screening process is very specific about the research objectives pursued at every stage. for example, the research objective of the first stage is to reduce the pool to prospective country-markets; the second stage is to reduce the pool to country-markets with higher market potential; the third stage is to select a country-market with the highest sales potential; and the fourth is to select an optimal mix of segments in the targeted country-market. in this sequential-screening approach, countries are rejected (or screened) on each new stage, (with the exception of stage 4 where segments are rejected), thus reducing the pool of countries analyzed, and consequently, the total amount of information required. however, the model assumes that, as each new stage is reached, the availability of secondary data screening criteria decreases and the need for primary data screening criteria increases, thereby increasing the quality and cost of the information required. in the first stage, general information about countries and generic product barriers is applied to all countries. the general recommendation in this identification stage is that firms should first eliminate all country-markets that have legal, political, economic, financial, cultural and product-related barriers to exports. general country barriers include trade sanctions imposed by either the domestic or foreign governments, regulations under general or bilateral trade agreements, political risks, erratic economic behavior, cultural dissimilarities, etc. for example, until recently, the us had a total trade embargo placed on vietnam. therefore, vietnam was an unlikely candidate for export activities. no us firm or subsidiary could trade with vietnam without facing economic and/or legal sanctions (rogers, 1994). generic product barriers include country regulations or physical environment characteristics that might interfere with physical attributes of the product such as size, color, dimensions, and packaging. for example, ansell edmont, us producer of work gloves, found that japanese workers have smaller hands and shorter fingers than their us counterparts and therefore require different gloves (jeannet & hennessey, 1995, p. 337). the advantage of this type of data is that they are readily available or observable and can be used to quickly eliminate countries. the problem with some of these indicators, however, is that they systematically vary across product categories (green & kohli, 1991; linder, 1961). in other words, the screening effectiveness of these indicators depends on the attributes possessed by the ...... vj figure 1 'tl2 the screening process, screening criteria, and ranking techniques in export country-market selection --\0 \0 all countries i secondary screening criteria ranking techniques 0'1 data stage i. country-market identification i i economic size and social development: ~ a. general country barriers (cavusgil 1982; douglas et al. 1982; none l1:> ~ b. generic product barriers goodnow and james 1972; green and s· kobli 1991; pezeshkpur 1979; f:l root 1987; sethi 1977). ~ l1:> oq l1:> stage 2. country-market market potential international trade statistics: multiple factor analysis: ~ a. national industry barriers (ayal 1982; green and allaway samli (1977). r'> b. product category barriers 1985; rao 1979; root 1987). shift-share analysis: ~ industry related production green and allaway (1985). l1:>..... country-markets with i i facton: (samli 1977). ..... '5i highest market potential l1:> ~ stage 3. country-market sales potential v:l ~ a. competitors barriers root (1987) none ;;; b. consumer barriers l1:>:::! s· oq country-market with i i ;:;3highest sales potential ~ ~ :::! stage 4. segment identification in the ! kale and sudharshan (1987); none ..e' :::: targeted count-market saeger! and medina (1995). l1:> optimal segment mix in primary targeted country-market data source: screening process adapted from cavusgil ([ 985); kale and sudharsan (1987); and walvoord (1980). 132 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 country and not on the type of product category being considered. realistically, at this stage, countries are selected for their socioeconomic and cultural similarity to the home markets (linder, 1961; terpstra, 1983). second, to reduce the obtained pool of prospective country-markets to a set of high market potential country-markets, the national industry and product category barriers need to be analyzed. key factors include commodity-specific trade barriers, industry entry barriers such as extent of local production, availability of local procurement, imports from third countries, negative perceptions by local consumers of the product category, and availability of product substitutes. some of the screening criteria required at this stage are difficult to obtain for many candidate countries and products. thus, the literature has focused on trade statistics such as flows of exports, imports and the composition of trade between countries as convenient surrogates for market potential. these indicators are becoming more important in their use because their increasing availability and reliability of measurement; and, unlike the first stage's screening criteria, they have the added advantage that they are largely a function of the product category under consideration (green & kohli, 1991). another advantage of this type of criterion over socioeconomic and political indicators such as those in stage 1 is that they account for the dynamics and the changing nature of the trade environment between economies. one possible disadvantage for small firms is that these trade statistics are usually highly aggregated. thus they are of little help to small firms with very specific narrow product categories. in the third stage, competitor and consumer barriers must be assessed. the strengths of direct competitors (i.e., those who sell similar brands) and their likely reaction to the small firm's entry into the industry must be assessed at this point; as well as potentially unrealistic expectations of local distributors in regards to gross margins, promotional allowances, pricing, etc. customers' familiarity with company brand(s) and their willingness to buy them are also considered here. potential consumers (or their representatives) of the firm's brand(s) must compare these brands with similar local brands to assess their relative advantage, their ease to use, and their compatibility with the user, just to name a few. smaller firms are usually unaware of potential competitor's and consumer's barriers. consequently, they are generally less confident about their knowledge regarding competitor's strengths, channels of distribution, payment conditions, etc. (alexandrides, 1971; ogram, 1982; tesar & tarleton, 1982). however, government-sponsored export-promotion programs help small firms "test the waters" regarding brand recognition and acceptance, and comparability with local as well as international brands, by representing them in international trade fairs and shows (czinkota & ricks, 1981; barrett & wilkinson, 1990). the fourth and final stage identifies segments within the country-market with the highest sales potential. only recently has the literature addressed the importance of adding within-country-market segmentation to the screening fall 1996 medina, saeger! & merrifield: screening technique 133 process; by either following a conventional segmentation approach such as demographics, lifestyles, benefits, etc. (kale & sudharshan, 1987) or by emphasizing the discovery, perhaps through focus groups, of demand-generatingcircumstance segments (fennell & saegert, 1990; saegert & medina, 1995). in both of these approaches, both qualitative and quantitative demand research in the candidate country-market may be required. this information, usually, can only be obtained directly from consumers in the candidate country-market and at great expense to the company. small businesses can get some help at this stage from the us department of commerce's (usdoc) country-desk officers and the us foreign commercial service's (usfcs) offices located in each country. these offices can direct the small company to local inexpensive private sector consultants, or they can prepare specific country market plans and comparison shopping surveys for moderate charges (miller, 1993). ranking technique studies the ranking technique is the third characteristic of the screening process. it is important not to confuse techniques used to classify country-groups on a screening criteria (goodnow & hansz, 1972; sethi, 1971) or used to define screeriing criteria (green & kohli, 1991) with techniques used to rank country-markets on these criteria. for example, sethi (1971) used comparative cluster analysis to agglomerate 91 countries into seven clusters along four criteria, production and transportation, personal consumption, trade, health and education. cluster membership ranged from two to twenty eight members. similarly, green & kohli (1991) applied a multiple regression model to a data set of 102 different manufactured products to estimate the best criteria (le., gop, socioeconomic development, debt burden and fuel imports) to predict imports by countries at different levels of development. these approaches only show that countries are dissimilar (or similar) on the analyzed criteria; they are not based on some specific scale or ranking method. as far as we can tell, there are only two techniques in the literature exclusively used to rank country-markets, those of samli (1977) and green & allaway (1985). samli's (1977) process of preliminary market selection is a multiple factor analysis technique based on the relative size and quality of potential markets. the size component is indicated by the size of the population and the quality component is indicated by the degree of economic development (as indicated by surrogate measures such as steel consumption, kilowatt hours produced, etc.) and the quality of life (as indicated by the surrogate measures such as motor vehicle registration, telephones in use, etc.) all of these variables are expressed as a percentage of the us market, which is assumed to be 100 per cent market potential. in other words, market potential for a given country is expressed in terms of the us's population, economic development, and quality of life. country-markets are ranked based on an averaged percentage figure that present the country's potential (or market size) 134 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no.2 relative to other countries and compared to market size in the us. alternatively, green & allaway's (1985) study demonstrated the way in which ssa can aid in the generation of product/market sets having high export potential. after identifying products with high export potential using ssa, they again applied ssa to identify country-markets for the selected products. next, they identified growth and a normalizing procedure to bring shifts of net share of import values to a common base. this in turn allowed them to rank countrymarkets in a scale of ±100. trade data and shift share analysis trade data as screening criteria for market potential as indicated above, trade statistics are suggested by several authors and government reports as being good indicators of country-market market potentials (ayal, 1982; green & allaway, 1985; plant, 1992; rao, 1979; root, 1987). imports, along with market access (i.e., trade barriers, industry standards), local production, local distribution, and product category acceptability, determine market potential by prospective country-markets. because managers are not likely to have access to all of these statistics for every prospective country, imports could be used as a representative surrogate for them all. the validity of import statistics as a surrogate lies in the fact that information from the other complementary factors is embedded in them. in other words, once trade has been consummated over a period of time, other market potential assessment criteria (i.e., industry specification standards, industry trade barriers, availability of adequate media and channels of distribution, consumers familiarity with the product category, etc.) are sufficiently reflected in import statistics. for example, if there are indications of important import activity by a country, in all probability trade barriers are manageable, there are distribution channels developed for that product category, and consumers are familiar with the product category. the use of import statistics is even more compelling when the product category studied is in the novelty, introductory stage of its life cycle in foreign countries. in such cases, the foreign country's apparent consumption in the short run (local production plus imports minus exports) is reduced to knowing imports alone. l import data are, in most cases, collected and made available by the respective importing and exporting countries. obtaining import statistics from every prospective country could be a daunting task. therefore, us export sale statistics to the rest of the world have become a convenient and adequate substitute. information from the us importjexport of merchandise reports includes data on domestic commodities (i.e., product categories) grown, produced or manufactured in the us, and commodities of foreign origin that have been changed in the us from the form in which they were imported, or that have been enhanced in value by further manufacture in the us (tradex 1994). fall 1996 medina, saegert & merrifield: screening technique 135 these data are readily available on a monthly basis from the us department of commerce's national trade data bank (ntdb). shift share analysis as a ranking technique for market potential the main idea of shift-share analysis is to identify growth differentials (i.e., net shifts in relative share) among members of a group (e.g., countries) on a growth variable (e.g., export sales) over a period of time beginning and end years (huff & sherr, 1967). the net shift, which is calculated in several steps (refer to table 1 and appendix for illustration), will be positive for products gaining market share and negative for products losing market share. thus, group members are ranked from highest to lowest according to whether their shares have increased or decreased (green & allaway, 1985; huff & sherr, 1967). for example, a country that increasingly gains us-export-sales share of a product category over the years (versus other importing countries) represents a potential market for entry. this is so because the product category is clearly in the introductory or growth stage of its life cycle, and the product may be catching on and riding the crest of this cycle at a fast pace. in general, the advantages of ssa are that it requires little and simple information; it is better than either absolute or percentage growth measures; and it measures the size of share gains and losses relative to an estimated growth nonn (huff & sherr, 1967; green & allaway, 1985). from a country-market screening perspective, this approach, as used in the past, is subject to three important limitations. since the traditional shift-share calculations involve only two points in time, a base year and an end year, choosing different base and end years may result in different rankings (barff & knight, 1988). as most export markets do not show stability over the years, one would find it difficult to choose two "representative" points in time (green & allaway, 1985). this drawback has been somewhat attenuated by the dynamic fonn of shift-share suggested by barff & knight, (1988). in their study, these researchers calculated shift-share annually and then summed up the results over the studied period. this modification of ssa eliminates the problem of having to choose the "correct" base-year for analysis. the second limitation of ssa to detennine market potential is that it usually involves only one product category (green & allaway, 1985). it does not account for the possible interactive influence of shifts in net shares of related (or complementary) product categories. for instance, there is a functional complementarity operating between the demand for printers and computers, and between the demand for golf clubs and golf balls (solomon & englis, 1994). finally, the validity of ssa as an adequate ranking technique to select countries with high market potential has not been detennined. understandably, the problem is to find alternative measures of export potential, and these are not easy to come by. an "improved" ssa technique used for export country-market potential screening would overcome these limitations. moreover, if the results using the 136 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 improved technique can be supported by independent evidence, then, the identification stage (first stage in the screening model, refer to figure 1) can be eliminated from the process, thereby adding parsimony to the overall export country-market screening process. the following section discusses the methodology used for testing an improved ssa technique. methodology mexican sauce is the novel product category selected for this study. many new competitors are entering the mexican sauce market in the us attracted by its incredible growth rate. of all the producers of mexican sauce in the us, the great majority are small or medium-sized firms with statewide or regional distribution. only a handful of competitors are major multinational players with national and even international distribution (packaged facts, 1992). although mexican sauce and its uses are still unknown by most world consumers, there is a growing trade activity of this product between the us and other countries. ssa can help rank and identify country-markets with higher export market potential for the mexican sauce product category. because mexico and canada are considered by many industry producers as natural extensions of the us market, these two countries are omitted from the present analysis. the tested methodology for the screening of country-markets into high market potential country-markets consisted of four steps: (l) selection of complementary products as indicators of market potential, (2) selection of time period to analyze, (3) selection of independent screening measures, and (4) shift-share analysis procedure. selection of complementary products as indicators of market potential. the domestic profile for mexican sauce consumers guided the selection of complementary product categories that might be useful indicators of market potentiaj.2 after carefully analyzing the information available for the domestic and foreign markets, it was discerned that the common factor on which both of these markets agreed was in the usage/circumstance. potential foreign consumers associated mexican sauce with snacks and dipping just as americans do (e.g., susta, 1992a & susta, 1992b). consequently, potato and corn chips were selected as complementary products as they are related with a particular usage (i.e., dipping) and circumstance (i.e., socials) within the american context (lawrence, 1993). the selection of these two complementary products was also based on their availability in the export trade statistics of the us. selection of time period to analyze. a five-year (1989-1993) period of us export sales statistics on mexican sauce, potato chips and corn chips was examined. 1989 was chosen as the beginning year because that is the last time a commodity reclassification occurred table 1 "tj ~ d1ustration of traditional ssa technique applied to us exports of mexican sauces top 10, middle 5, and bottom 10 countries --\0 export data (in 000 of ibs.) calculation of shift-share analysis \0 0'. countries 1989 1993 actual change market growth rate expected value expected change net shift shift-share (%) (i) (2) (3)=(2)-(1) (4 )=(2a)/( 1a) (5)=(i)x(4) (6)=(5)-(1 ) (7)=(3)-(6) (8)=(7)/(7a) ~ ~ i. netherjand 83 1,857 1774 1.72 142.76 59.76 1714.24 17~86% l::l..s· 2. venezuela 81 628 547 1.72 139.32 58.32 488.68 5.09% ~ 3. south korea 46 466 420 1.72 79.12 33.12 386.88 4.03% ~ 4. new zealand 94 531 437 1.72 161.68 67.68 369.32 3.85% ~ 5. united kingdom 295 833 538 1.72 507.40 212.40 325.60 3.39% ~ ~ 6. france 15 201 186 1.72 25.80 10.80 175.20 1.82% ;:,. 7. germany 63 248 185 1.72 108.36 45.36 139.64 1.45% l«> 8. neth antilles 85 284 199 1.72 146.20 61.20 137.80 1.44% ~ 9. belgium 4 112 108 1.72 6.88 2.88 105.12 1.09% ""! ""! 10. australia 200 435 235 1.72 344.do 144.00 91.00 0.95% si 42. slovenia 0 0 0 1.72 0.00 0.00 0.00 o.do% ~ 5: 43. haiti 0 0 0 1.72 o.do o.do 0.00 0.00% '. 44. paraguay 0 0 0 1.72 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00% v:i n 45. dominica 0 0 0 1.72 0.00 0.00 0.00 o.do% ~ ~ 46. gabon 0 0 0 1.72 o.do 0.00 0.00 0.00% ;::s-. 79. united arab e. 135 38 232.20 97.20 -194.20 -2.02% ;::s -97 1.72 ~ 80. japan 269 253 -16 1.72 462.68 193.68 -209.68 -2.18% ~ 81. singapore 464 579 115 1.72 798.08 334.08 -219.08 -2.28% n ~ 82. honduras 267 225 -42 1.72 459.24 192.24 -234.24 -2.44% ;::s-. 83. spain 165 27 -138 1.72 283.80 118.80 -256.80 -2.67% ..t:;, :::: 84. bahamas 203 0 1.72 349.16 146.16 -349.16 -3.64% ~ -203 85. costa rica 256 57 -199 1.72 440.32 184.32 -383.32 -3.99% 86. taiwan 962 1,247 285 1.72 1654.64 692.64 -407.64 -4.25% 87. ei salvador 316 100 -216 1.72 543.52 227.52 -443.52 -4.62% 88. bermuda 295 3 -292 1.72 507.40 212.40 -504.40 -5.25% yj all total 7,293 (1 a) 12,522 (2a) 5,229 1.72 12,522.00 5,229.00 9600.47 (7a) -..l 138 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no.2 for mexican sauce. it has been through two previous reclassifications, going from broader to narrower commodity descriptions (i.e., from "tomato sauces other than ketchup," through "other sauces and preparations," to "sauces and preparations, mixed condiments and mixed seasonings.") the ending year 1993 was the latest available year for which data were available for all three products. time series data were obtained from the united states department of commerce (usdoq export trade statistics. analyzing export statistics in unit quantity rather than dollar values is important because it eliminates possible distortions regarding changes in product prices (gillespie & alden, t 989) and differences in price-quoting practices between the us and other countries. 3 independent validating measures. independent measures of country-market market potential would validate the predicted ranking of countries as estimated by ssa approaches (see table 2). the top ten ranked country-markets having positive shift shares were matched to a composite index constituted by the combination of two ad hoc independent measures of market potential (l) unsolicited product inquires to a southwest producer of mexican sauce from potential foreign clients and (2) international expansion strategies of large competitors in the us mexican sauce industry. first, unsolicited inquires collected over a period of four years (1990-1994) by a southwest producer of mexican sauce were tabulated by date and by country. then, countries were ranked by their number of inquires, and the top 10 were selected. the second measure was developed based on the assumption that large domestic competitors would be actively looking for foreign expansion opportunities. an analysis of their international expansion and investment patterns would indicate where they believed to be the greatest market potential opportunities. country-markets were ranked based on the number and type of entry strategies. 4 these two validating measures of market potential were subsumed into a composite index. countries in this index were ranked based on their number of appearances and position in the two independently obtained validating rankings. shift·share analysis procedure. first, traditional ssa for the years 1989 and 1993 was applied to a data set of only mexkan sauce export statistics. then, dynamic ssa for the years \989-1990, 1990-199\, 1991-1992, and 1992-1993 was applied to the same data set. here ssa is calculated based on data from each year within the stated period, rather than on just "two points in time" beginning and end years. this will help overcome the original limitation of selecting an appropriate time period and it will also increase the sensitivity of country-rankings to trade fluctuations. ssa estimates obtained for each year arc arithmetically averaged giving a mean estimate. finally, a "modified" ssa was applied to a data set of a composite statistic of mexican sauce, potato chips and corn chips. these three sets of top 10 ranked countries were individually compared to each of the intable 2 top-ten countries from shift share analysis (ssa) ranking approaches and validating measures, and similarity coeffecients between ssa ranking approaches and validating index ssa ranking approaches validating measures traditional ssa dynamic ssa modified ssa unsolicited competitive composite inquiries analysis index* i. netherlands i. netherlands i. taiwan i. japan 1. australia i. japan 2. venezuela 2. south korea 2. venezuela 2. united kingdom 2. netherlands 2. united kingdom 3. south korea 3. new zealand 3. united kingdom 3. venezuela 3. japan 3. australia 4. new zealand 4. venezuela 4. australia 4. south korea 4. united kingdom 4. venezuela 5. united kingdom 5. united kingdom 5. argentina 5. australia 5. venezuela 5. netherlands 6. france 6. neth antilles 6. japan 6. netherlands 6. sweden 6. south korea 7. germany 7. germany 7. south korea 7. czechoslovakia 7. new zealand 7. sweden 8. neth antilles 8. france 8. peru 8. egypt 8. saudi arabia 8. new zealand 9. belgium 9. belgium 9. germany 9. ghana 9. kuwait 9. czechoslovakia 10. australia 10. egypt 10. thailand 10. argentina 10. south korea 10. saudi arabia similarity coeffecients:** 0.20 0.13 0.81 *composite of unsolicited inquires and competitive analysis. **spearman pairwise rank order correlation coefficient between the respective ssa ranking approaches and the validating composite index. 'tl 2-'-0 '-0 0\ ~ ~ s· .f:l ~ ~ ~ ;:;. r<> ~ "'"': "'"': s; ~ f; v:l r") ~ ~ ;:: ~. ~ r") ;::.. ;:: .ts. ;;::: (':l vj '-0 140 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 dependently obtained validating measures using spearman's pairwise rank-order correlation coefficient. (this coefficient helps us measure the level of similarity betwccn thesc sets of data.) findings thc findings are presented in two sections. first, we discuss results concerning the county-market selection model in figure i. then, we discuss results of applying the methodology and the ssa technique explained above. country-market selection model looking over figure i, it appears that the selection criteria need to have at least two characteristics. first, they must include a variable that is relevant in assessing the potential barriers of one country-market relative to others. second, data on the relevant screening criterion must be available for most country-markets. otherwise, a comprehensive and realistic comparison across countries cannot be made. the literature has emphasized studying screening criteria to identify countries in stagcs i and 2 of the model, but there is little research on screening criteria for stages 3 and 4 (see figure 1). also, from our review of ranking techniques, both multiple factor analysis and ssa are potentially useful techniques for small firms as these reflect analyses from a "reference base" with a home-market framework they can understand. this reference base has commonly been the us's population, economic development, and quality of life (samli, 1977), and the us's total exports to the rest of the world on a given product category (green s& allaway, 1985). moreover, these two techniques may actually be combined to strengthen their prediction power. finally, information from the adapted model in figure i and from studies in the literature raise the question about the wisdom of using country-market identification techniques. the information reviewed suggests that the countrymarket identification stage can, in effect, be completely eliminated from the process for products for which information requirements at latter stages are readily available from public sources (e.g., export statistics for the market potential stage, thereby adding parsimony to the overall export country-market screening process.) ssa technique table 2 outlines the top ten ranked export country-markets from a pool of 88 countries (see table 1) for the three tested ssa ranking techniques traditional ssa (tssa), dynamic ssa (dssa), and modified ssa (mssa) for the two validating rankings unsolicited inquires and competitor's analysis and for their composite index. the table also shows the spearman's pairwise rank order correlation coefficients for the three different types of ranking approaches and the composite index. we first discuss the fall 1996 medina, saeger! & merrifield: screening technique 141 ranking approaches and then their degree of similarity with the composite index. the traditional and the dynamic ssa ranking approaches show "similar" country-ranking compositions as opposed to the modified ssa. this is expected as these two rankings are based on only one product category (i.e., mexican sauce), whereas the modified ssa is based on three combined product categories (i.e., mexican sauce, potato chips and corn chips). also, only four countries venezuela, south korea, united kingdom, and germany out of ten appear in all three ranking lists. moreover, the netherlands, venezuela, united kingdom, germany, and belgium share the same ranking in at least two of the three lists. although the above information alone is important, as it confounds some underlying factors that influence country rankings, it does not accurately tell us anything about how good these rankings are relative to each other. by comparing visually the three ranking approaches against the validating composite index, we observe that at least half of the countries in the composite index appear on each of the three ssa estimated rankings. the traditional ssa seems to capture the most countries with a total of six, and the modified ssa seems to best capture countries with higher rankings in the composite index (i.e., japan and australia). spearman's similarity coefficients between the composite index and the three ssa ranking approaches are shown at the bottom of table 2. these show that the modified ssa has the strongest correlation with the composite index, 0.81. the second strongest correlation is with the traditional ssa, 0.20, showing a slightly better association with the composite index than the dynamic ssa (0.13). this result does not support the alleged theoretical benefits obtained when in-between years are analyzed using the dynamic ssa (barff & knight, 1988). these results show that the modified ssa technique is an adequate ranking method for export country-market selection when analyzing a novel consumer packaged good. they also show that using complementary product categories does increase the power of prediction and ranking accuracy of the ssa technique. discussion and implications small us companies selling products that are perceived as novelties in most other countries, may rely on their own domestic marketplace experience and on us-government produced export statistics to identify countries with market potential because the choice of foreign markets is an investment decision many small businesses are now facing, we tested the validity of a simple and inexpensive ranking method known as shift share analysis (ssa) for selecting country-markets. ssa proved to be an efficient technique to rank country markets as 50% of the top-ten ranked countries were found to correspond to a composite index of two alternate validating measures. moreover, adding 142 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 information from complementary products to the growth variable (i.e., export sales) improves ssa predictive power significantly, suggesting that studying the small firm's own domestic market to determine possible complementary products is a worthwhile endeavor. general assessment of market potential in a country involves an analysis of local production, local consumption, and imports and exports of the product country in question. but, information on local production, consumption and imports, and exports are usually not available when a novel product is used. in such cases, we have suggested that export sales data can be used as adequate proxy for estimating market potential. this paper demonstrates that applying us export statistics on a simple ranking technique help select countries with the highest market potential for novel packaged goods. although we have demonstrated empirically that us export statistics can be an adequate criterion for the screening of country-markets for a novel packaged-good product category, there are three additional theoretical reasons why us export statistics are adequate as a preliminary screen for packaged goods. first, the us is the largest exporter in the world of packaged goods (us dc, 1995). it exports most known packaged-good product categories to most countries in the world. second, us government reports show that a significant and increasing proportion of the us's packaged goods are sought after and accepted all over the world (e.g., susta, 1992a). the third reason is more practical in nature, that is, that export statistics in general are more easily available from the us government than from foreign governments. as more trade statistics from different countries become available, small firms can benefit by applying the methodology demonstrated in this study in two ways. first, firms could lump us and foreign countries export statistics together and apply ssa. countries with higher shares of imports, regardless of country of origin, would become prime targets for entry. second, firms could investigate the share of us exports to importing countries relative to other exporting countries. for example, if a country has a higher share of imports from the us than it does from another country, the market potential for us products in that country will be greater. in addition, a weighting system reflecting the importance of the relative market share of exporting countries on each import market can be developed before the final country ranking exercise is done. a combination of these two approaches would perhaps be more representative of the actual level of export activity in the prospective country-markets. a final implication from this study is that stage 1, market identification, can be omitted from our adapted country-market selection model (figure 1), when a novel product category is analyzed. specifically, the methodology discussed in this paper can help small firms expedite the "identification of targeted areas" an important component of any export marketing plan (kerr & kirkconnell, 1989) for further in-depth analysis. fall 1996 medina, saegert & merrifield: screening technique 143 future research and study limitations it is important to remember that this study's results are primarily applicable to novel us packaged goods whose characteristics are similar to those of the mexican sauce; namely the product must be perceived as new in most foreign markets and that there is a recent but consistent export trade history from major industry competitors in the us. however, as the product category becomes more widely distributed and produced worldwide, us export trade statistics become less attractive as a single proxy measure of market potential assessment. also, our analysis is pertinent only to the selection of country-markets with the highest market potential (stage 2 of the model in figure 1). however, in considering a country-market's sales potential, a small firm will need to invest in the acquisition of knowledge about the specific aspects of marketing the product in each selected country. this involves obtaining data on the information requirements described in stages 3 and 4 of the model. one limitation of using usdoc export statistics is that novel products are initially assigned to highly aggregated "catch-all' product categories, or may even be missclassified as a result of their novel nature. this in turn can affect the ranking efficacy of the ssa. one alternative to circumvent this problem, is the use of more disaggregated, and perhaps accurate, trade data from independent sources such as piers port import export reporting servicea service by the journal of commerce. because piers reporting is based on product description and not codes, it avoids potential misc1assification pitfalls that are common with newly traded products. future studies should consider using data from this piers's database to test the ranking techniques developed for this study and their efficacy in selecting countries with highest market potential. as information requirements for higher screening stages (e.g., media availability, middlemen accessibility, typical pricing policies, product packaging, etc.) become increasingly available from public sources, small businesses would benefit from empirical work that emphasizes less the determination of socioeconomic and political country criteria and more the examination of industry and product category criteria. most export country-market selection studies found in the literature tend to group countries on socioeconomic and political barriers. there is now a growing need to go beyond this pattern of inquiry into one where we relate trade and industry barriers to specific product categories. finally, in regards to the ranking techniques, there is not enough breadth of options available to the small business in the literature. the only two available techniques, as described in this study, multiple factor analysis and shiftshare analysis, only apply to stage 2 in the model. future studies should emphasize the creation of new ranking techniques applicable to this and latter stages, and the testing of their predictive validity in measuring the stage's objective (e.g., countries' market potential). 144 journal of business strategies notes vol. 13, no.2 1 there is always the exceptional possibility that imports are re-exported to other countries, as is the case for many product categories in hong kong. 2 kotler's (1988, p. 174-175) eight o's is a simple practical guide that profiles target markets based on eight key factors. this tool can help exporters in determining what aspects of the domestic target market resemble its foreign counterparts. 3 for example, it is common for us exporters to quote cif (cost, insurance and freight at port of destination) or c&f (cost and freight at port of destination) to provide additional service to customers of certain countries. however, u.s. customs requires merchandise export sales to be estimated on a ea.s. (free alongside ship at u.s. port of export) basis. because individual exporters or their representatives are required to estimate this adjusted value, there is always a potential for inaccuracies in reporting that may bias export sales values for or against some countries. 4 this information was obtained from articles in various food and business periodicals, general media, company annual statements, and from an interview with a marketing manager of a major manufacturer of mexican sauce products. references agarwal, sanjjeev and sridhar n. ramaswami. "choice of country market entry mode: impact of ownership, location, and internationalization factors." journal of international business studies (first quarter, 1992): 1-27. alexandrides, e.g. "how the major obstacles to expansion can be overcome." atlanta economic review 21 (1971): 12-15. ayal, igal and jehie1 zif. "competitive market choice strategies in multinational marketing." columbia journal of world business (fall, 1978): 72-81. ayal, igal. "industry export performance: assessment and prediction." journal of marketing (fall, 1982): 72-81. baird, inga s., marjorie a. lyles, and j. b. orris. "alliances and networks: cooperative strategies for small businesses." mid-american journal of business 8 (1993): 1724. ------. "the choice of international strategies by small businesses." journal of small business management 32 (1994): 48-59. barff, richard a. and prentice l. knight iii. "dynamic shift-share analysis." growth & change 19 (1988): 1-10. barrett, niegel and ian f. wilkinson, "australian policies for trade promotion and assistance: review and evaluation." in international perspectives on trade promotion and assistance, eds. s. tamer cavusgil and michael r. czinkota. new york: quorum books, 1990. fall 1996 medina, saegert & merrifield: screening technique 145 bilkey, warren j. "an attempted integration of the literature on the export behavior of firms." journal of international business studies (spring/summer, 1978): 39-55. businessweek. "it's a small (business) world." businessweek (april 17, 1995), 96101. cavusgil, s. tamer. "guidelines for export market research." business horizons (november/december, 1985): 27-33. cavusgil, s. tamer and shaoming zou. "marketing strategy-performance relationship: an investigation of the empirical link in export market ventures." journal of marketing 58 (1994): 1-21. czinkota, michael r. "a national export development policy for new and growing businesses." journal of international marketing 2 (1994): 91-101. czinkota, michael r. and david ricks. "export assistance: are we supporting the best programs?" columbia journal of international business (summer, 1981): 73-78. davidson, william h. "market similarity and market selection: implications for international marketing strategy." journal of business research 11 (1983): 439-456. fennell, geraldine and joel saegert. "activity v. apriori groups in defining a market." in proceedings of the society for consumer psychology, american psychological association annual conference. boston, 1990. fuchs, victor r. "changes in the location of us. manufacturing since 1929." journal of regional science i (1959): 1-17. gillespie, kate and dana alden. "consumer product export opportunities to liberalizing ldcs: a life-cycle approach." journal of international business studies 20 (1989): 93-112. goodnow, james d. and james e. hansz. "environmental determinants of overseas market entry strategies." journal of international business studies 3 (1972): 33-50. green, robert t. "internationalization and diversification of us trade: 1970 to 1981." international marketing review (summer, 1985): 53-62. -----and arthur w. allaway. "identification of export opportunities: a shift-share approach." journal of marketing 49 (1985): 83-88. -----and ajay k. kohli. "export market identification: the role of economic size and socioeconomic development." management international review 31 (1991): 37-50. -----and trina l. larsen. "changing patterns of u.s. trade: 1985-1989." business horizons 34 (1991): 7-13. 146 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no.2 -----and trina l. larsen. "japanese trade in international perspective." international marketing review 8 (1991b): 13-27. huff, david l. and lawrence a. sherr. "measure for determining differential growth rates of markets." journal of marketing research 4 (1967): 391-395. jeannet, jean-pierre and h. david hennessey. global marketing strategies. boston: houghton mifflin company, 1995. kale, sudhir h. and d. sudharshan. "a strategic approach to international segmentation." international market review (summer, 1987): 60-70. kerr, jean and paul kirkconnell. "export strategies." small business reports 14 (1989): 20-27. kotler, philip. marketing management: analysis. planning. and control. englewood cliffs, nj: prentice-hall, 1988. lawrence, jennifer. 'taco bell calls on supermarkets." advertising age (february 8, 1993): 3, 47. linder, staffan b. an essay on trade and transformation. new york: wiley, 1961. mcniven, james d. "challenge and response: the rise of state export development policies in the u.s.a." in export development and promotion: the role of public organizations, eds. f. h. rolf seringhaus and philip 1. rosson. new york: klumer academic publishers, 1991. merrifield, john. 'the role of shift-share in regional analysis." regional science perspectives 12 (1983): 48-53. miller, d. and peter h. friesen. "monumentum and revolution in organizational adaptation." academy of management journal 23 (1980): 591-614. miller, myron m. "executive insights: the 10-step road map to success in foreign markets." journal of international marketing 1 (1993): 89-106. ogram, ernest w. "exporters and non-exporters: a profile of small manufacturing firms in georgia." in export management: an international context, eds. m. r. czinkota and george tesa. new york: praeger, 1982. packaged facts. 'the mexican sauce market." unpublished consultant's report on the mexican sauce industry (june, 1992): 31. plant, mark w. "the national trade data bank: the exporter's valuable resource." business america 13 (april, 1992): 16-17. fall 1996 medina, saegert & merrifield: screening technique 147 prosak, sylvia lino, "small businesses are exporting," business america 114 (november, 1993): 2-8, ramaswami, sridhar n. and yoo yang, "perceived barriers to exporting and export assistance requirements," in international perspectives on trade promotion and assistance, eds. s, tamer cavusgil and michael r czinkota. new york: quorum books, 1990. rao, c. p. "a multilevel approach to researching international markets." in international marketing: managerial perspectives , eds, subash c. jain and levis r. trucker, jr. boston: cbi publishing, 1979. rogers, john. "firms in place have advantage; newcomers face uphill climb." the journal of commerce (february 7, 1994): 6a, root, franklin r. entry strategies for international markets. lexington, ma: d.c. heath and company, 1987. ------. foreign market entry strategies. new york: amacom, 1982. saegert, joel and jose f. medina. "conceptualizing market segmentation for the option of going global." in proceedings of the society for consumer psychology. eds. scott b. mackenzie and douglas m. stay man. la jolla, ca: american psychological association, 1995. samli, a. coskun. "an approach for estimating market potential in east europe." journal of international business studies 8 (1977): 49-53. sethi, s. prakash. "comparative cluster analysis for world markets." journal of marketilll: research 8 (1971): 348-354. solomon, michael r and basil g. englis. "observations: the big picture: product complementarity and integrated communications." journal of advertising research (januarylfebruary, 1994): 57-63. susta southern united states trade association. "country profile hong kong & south korea: two of asia's tigers." insight global news. perspectives and updates for the international agribusiness trade (spring, 1992a): 3. ------. "product profile snack food: tempting global taste buds." insight global news. perspectives and updates for the international agribusiness trade (spring, i 992b): 7. terpstra, vern. "critical mass and international marketing strategy." journal of the academy of marketing science 11 (1983): 269-282. 148 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 ------. international dimensions of marketing. second edition. boston, ma: plus-kent publishing company, 1988. tesar, george and jesse s. tarleton. "comparison of wisconsin and virginia smalland medium-sized exporters: aggressive and passive exporters." in export management: an international context, eds. m. r. czinkota and george tesar. new york: praeger, 1982. tradex. us merchandise export trade by commodity. united states department of commerce bureau of the census, 1994. usdc united states department of commerce. "statistical abstract of the united states." the national trade data book. bureau of the census, 1995. walters, peters g. p. "international marketing policy: a discussion of the standardization construct and its relevance for corporate policy." journal of international business studies 17 (1986): 55-69. walvoord, wayne r. "export market research." global trade magazine (may, 1980): 83. appendix the shift share analysis (ssa) method has been devised to measure the relative size of the gains and losses (i.e., shift-share percentage) of market areas compared with a general market growth rate (or norm). in the present study, the market areas are individual country-markets and the norm derives from the aggregated total of these individual country-markets. the following paragraphs explain the meaning of each column and the steps to calculating shift-share percentages in table 1. the numbers of the formulas below, indicated in parenthesis, correspond to the same numbers in table i. countries these are the names of the countries that constitute the individual country-markets. they are ranked from the highest to the lowest market potential. export data this is the export sales data for the beginning and end years. let vi.1 represent the value of the export sales for country i at the end of time period t. thus, (i) vu-1 and (2) \ii., the total value of export sales for all the export markets from the us is equal to the sum of the values for each of the individual country markets. thus, (i a) m a vi.,.] i=l where ill is the number of all country-markets analyzed fall 1996 medina, saegert & merrifield: screening technique 149 similarly, the total value of export sales for all country-markets at the end of the terminal time period is, (2a) m a. vi,t i=j actual change (avj this is the actual change of export sales in a given country, which is simply the difference in values from one time period to another. thus, (3) avj = vi,l vi,i-j market growth rate (k) this is the growth rate for all country-markets. which is equal to the ratio of the total value in the terminal time period to the corresponding value in the initial time period. thus, m a. vi,l i=j (4) k=-----m a vi,t-j i=1 expected value [ewull this is the expected export sales value at the end of the terminal time period, had the country-market grown at the rate achieved for all the country-markets combined. thus, (5) e(vu) = kvj,i_j expected change [h(a vjl this is the difference between the expected value and the actual value for a given country-market at the initial time period. thus, (6) e(avi) = e(vi,t) vi.t -j net shift (nil. this is the difference between the actual change and the expected change for a given country-market. thus, (7) ni = avj e(avi) absolute net shift (s) the sum of the positive (or negative) net shifts. that is, (7a) p s = a nj i=1 where p is the total absolute number of the positive net shifts. 150 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no.2 shift-share percental!e (pi} this is the relative gain or loss in the value of the export sales for a particular country-market during a given time period. thus, nj (8) pi =--(100%) s jose f. medina is assistant professor of international marketing at the university of texas at san antonio. he has published papers in the journal of international consumer marketing, the journal of consumer affairs and the journal of marketing theory and practice, among others. his research interests include cross-cultural, export marketing and ethnic minorities research. joel saegert is professor of marketing at the university of texas at san antonio. he has published papers in psychology and marketing. the journal of consumer research, the journal of consumer affairs, the journal of marketing. the american journal of psychology. the journal of experimental psychology. among others. he is past-president of the society for consumer psychology, division 23 of the american psychological association. john merrifield is an associate professor of economics at the university of texas at san antonio, a position he has held since 1987. his primary teaching and research fields include international trade, the environment, natural resource management, urban and regional economics, and public choice, especially k-12 school reform. he received a b.s. in natural resource management from cal poly san luis obispo in 1977, a m.a. in economic geography from the university of i11inois in 1979, and a ph.d. in economics form the university of wyoming in 1984. a simple export country-market screening technique for small us businesses: a packaged good illustration journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 https://doi.org/10.54155/jbs.39.1.1-32 received: november 2021 / revision received: february 2022 / accepted: february 2022 should corporations care about negative brand publicity? understanding the impact of negative brand publicity on employees’ corporate brand pride fabian abeda, marion büttgenb a corresponding author. department for corporate management, university of hohenheim, schloss osthof/ost, 70593 stuttgart, germany. f abed@uni-hohenheim.de b department for corporate management, university of hohenheim, schloss osthof/ost, 70593 stuttgart, germany. m.buettgen@uni-hohenheim.de keywords abstract negative brand publicity; corporate brand pride; affective-eventstheory; internal branding; brand experience; brand supporting behavior this article examines the effects of perceived negative brand publicity on employee emotions, attitudes and brand supporting behaviors. drawing on affectiveevents-theory (aet) it attempts to identify underlying affective and cognitive processes leading to behavioral change. using data gathered from a largescale survey of employees in germany, our results show that perceived negative brand publicity affects emotional and attitudinal corporate brand pride of employees. in addition, higher levels of perceived negative brand publicity were negatively associated with brand-supporting behavior, such as employee referrals and word-of-mouth (wom). we show that corporate brand experience through internal communications can be an effective tool in mitigating harmful effects of perceived negative brand publicity. this work is licensed under a creative commons attribution-noncommercial 4.0 international license. copyright (c) 2022 fabian abed, marion büttgen. https://doi.org/10.54155/jbs.39.1.1-32 f_abed@uni-hohenheim.de m.buettgen@uni-hohenheim.de 2 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 1. introduction publicity relating to corporate (brand) behavior is on the rise in recent years (hock & raithel, 2019). corporate brand publicity can be defined as any information about a corporate brand, its products, services or behavior “communicated through editorial media that is not paid for” by the corporation (collins & stevens, 2002, p.1123). it typically involves non-personal mass communication such as tv news items, radio broadcasts or newspaper articles (lee et al., 2013; van hoye & lievens, 2005). corporate brands that have recently been the subject of negative brand publicity in germany include, for example, deutsche bank and volkswagen. the latter is receiving bad press around the world due to its manipulation of emissions. deutsche bank is in the media as a result of planning mass lay-offs and because of continuous misbehavior. in general, poor work conditions, poor management decision making, or quality issues are often matters of media coverage (monga & john, 2008; woo et al., 2020). negative (brand) publicity can have detrimental effects on multiple corporate or brand aspects. the literature provides evidence that sales (e.g. berger et al., 2010), image (e.g. zhu & chang, 2013), consumer purchase intention (e.g. osei-frimpong et al., 2019), consumer trust and consumer affective identification (e.g. lin et al., 2011), brand equity (e.g. woo et al., 2020), share price as well as firm net value (e.g. hock & raithel, 2019) can be adversely affected. moreover, negative press can lead to a lower perceived organizational attractiveness and reduced job pursuit intentions of job applicants (jaidi et al., 2011). previous research on (brand) publicity focused mainly on attitudes and behaviors of consumers and job applicants. to the best of our knowledge, no research has focused on how publicity regarding corporate brands affects employees. more precisely, a deeper understanding of how corporate brand publicity might influence work-related attitudes and behavior of employees is missing from the literature. this is surprising as employees represent a crucial part of brands’ success and competitive advantage (e.g. boukis et al., 2014; löhndorf & diamantopoulos, 2014). this paper answers the following research questions. first, does negative corporate brand publicity affect employees’ corporate brand pride and subsequent brand supporting behavior? second, can corporations mitigate the potentially devastating effect of perceived negative corporate brand publicity abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 3 on employees through corporate brand experience, i.e. internal or external communications? 2. theoretical background affective-events-theory (aet) described by weiss and cropanzano (1996) provides us with a macrostructure to understand how brand publicity affects emotional corporate brand pride (emotion), attitudinal corporate brand pride (attitude), and brand supporting behavior such as word-of-mouth (wom) and employee referrals (judgement-driven behavior). corporate brand pride has been chosen because research shows that pride affects employee behavior (e.g. turnover intention) much stronger than other workrelated attitudes (e.g. commitment), making it necessary to further investigate this construct in a brand-employee context (gouthier & rhein, 2011). moreover, several brands already include (brand) pride as central drivers for success, for example “i’m proud to be ritz-carlton” (appleberg, 2005, p.3). in general, aet helps to explain the interplay of work events, work environment features, emotions, attitudes and behaviors. specifically, the theory “explains the structure, causes, and consequences of employees’ affective experiences at work” (matta et al., 2014, p.922). according to aet, certain work-events (e. g. negative corporate brand publicity) are proximal causes of employees’ emotional reactions (e.g. emotional corporate brand pride) which in turn influence work-related attitudes (e.g. attitudinal corporate brand pride) and behavior (e.g. brand supporting behavior) (herrbach et al., 2004; weiss & cropanzano, 1996). following weiss and cropanzano (1996) we define a work-event as something that occurs in a work-related setting during a particular period, like corporate brand publicity. linking perceived negative corporate brand publicity and emotional corporate brand pride following aet, we propose that perceived negative corporate brand publicity is linked to a number of actual and perceived events that cause intense emotional responses (rosen et al., 2009). negative brand publicity is likely to evoke affective responses regarding employees due to various reasons. first, negative corporate brand publicity has usually a surprising character (cleeren et al., 2013). brands have, in contrast to other forms of communication, no direct control over publicity (collins & stevens, 2002). so, publicity exhibits a sort of an unexpected event with regard to the corporate brand 4 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 and its members. for example, employees working for volkswagen have been shocked when they read the embarrassing headlines about the emission scandal without any advance warning. in line with findings of weiss and cropanzano (1996), who state that workevents are sudden changes in circumstances eliciting emotions, we argue that the surprising occurrence of negative brand publicity should influence employees’ affective reactions (e.g. emotional corporate brand pride). second, negative publicity adversely affects the status of a corporate brand, highlighting for instance quality issues or misbehavior. previous research showed that feelings of pride are directly linked to the organization’s reflected glory or achievements (salerno et al., 2015). boons et al. (2015) stated that media, communicating organization level status information elicit feelings of pride. similarly, appleberg (2005) concluded that various aspects of organizational image can instill pride. hence, we argue that employees working for a corporate brand with a poor reputation (reflected in negative stories in the media) should exhibit diminished feelings of emotional corporate brand pride (helm, 2013). these reflections result in the following hypothesis: hypothesis 1. perceived negative corporate brand publicity is negatively associated with emotional corporate brand pride experienced by employees. linking perceived negative corporate brand publicity, wom and employee referrals previous research on negative (brand) publicity revealed detrimental effects on various attitudes (e.g. braxton et al., 2019; zhou & whitla, 2013), behavioral intentions (e.g. müller & gaus, 2015; osei-frimpong et al., 2019) and actual behavior (jaidi et al., 2011, e.g.). specifically, perceived negative publicity adversely affects consumer trust and affective identification (lin et al., 2011; müller & gaus, 2015). as trust and identification are antecedents of wom and (employee) referrals, we suppose that negative corporate brand publicity influences employee wom and referrals, too (bloemer, 2010; de matos & rossi, 2008). hence, we propose: hypothesis 2a. perceived negative corporate brand publicity has a negative influence on employee wom. hypothesis 2b. perceived negative corporate brand publicity has a negative influence on employee referrals. abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 5 even though the proposed direct effects are not explicitly specified in weiss and cropanzano (1996), we found support for this approach. zhao et al. (2007) showed, drawing on aet, that work events can have a direct impact on employee behavior. similarly, müller and gaus (2015) revealed that negative media information directly affected behavioral intentions of consumers. linking emotional corporate brand pride and attitudinal corporate brand pride corporate brand pride emotions are, as all emotions, short-lived mental experiences (fisher & ashkanasy, 2000). therefore, pride emotions have downstream consequences with regard to attitudes and behaviors (elfenbein, 2007). this assumption is in line with aet’s suggestion of causality between emotions and work-related attitudes. moreover, we argue that employees who remain in the same corporation for a certain period can experience corporate brand pride emotions repeatedly, which should lead to a more durable state, namely attitudinal corporate brand pride (gouthier & rhein, 2011). therefore, we hypothesize the following: hypothesis 3. corporate brand pride emotions have a positive influence on attitudinal corporate brand pride linking attitudinal corporate brand pride and wom/employee referrals previous research on brand supporting behavior such as wom and (employee) referrals identified multiple antecedents, such as brand passion (albert et al., 2013), positive emotions (lovett et al., 2013), satisfaction (hagenbuch et al., 2008; wangenheim & baón, 2007), brand commitment (albert et al., 2013), product (wangenheim & baón, 2007; wolny & mueller, 2013) or brand involvement (wolny & mueller, 2013). wom can be defined as “informal, person-to-person communication between a perceived non-commercial communicator and a receiver regarding a brand, a product, an organization, or a service” (harrison, 2001, p.63). in contrast to these more general forms, employee referrals represent an internal recruitment method whereby an actual employee of the corporate brand proactively identifies and provides specific information about vacancies to persons he or she knows (breaugh & starke, 2000). based on earlier findings of kraemer et al. (2020) and lythreatis et al. (2019), we assume that corporate brand pride is a strong intrinsic motivator leading to wom and employee referrals due to various reasons. first, 6 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 proud employees have a strong bond with the corporate brand leading to extraordinary intrinsic motivation (kraemer et al., 2020; lythreatis et al., 2019). this is in line with findings of verbeke et al. (2004) who stated that pride (emotion) leads to greater effort of salespeople. similarly, baer et al. (2015) revealed that high levels of pride are positively related to reputation maintenance concerns of employees (e.g. wom). second, (organizational) pride is found to be negatively related to turnover intention of employees (kraemer & gouthier, 2014). as turnover intention is in general known as a form of loyalty, similar to wom and employee referrals, we expect employees with higher levels of corporate brand pride to show stronger brand supporting behavior: hypothesis 4a. attitudinal corporate brand pride has a positive influence on wom hypothesis 4b. attitudinal corporate brand pride has a positive influence on employee referrals. linking corporate brand experience through internal/external communications and perceived negative corporate brand publicity marketing literature often emphasize synergy effects of advertising and publicity, although both aspects need to exhibit the same valence (e. g. stammerjohan et al., 2005; wang, 2006). research analyzing a situation where the two sources of information differ in their valence is scarce, especially with regard to an employee context. to date only few studies show how negative publicity can be mitigated. for example, van hoye and lievens (2005) showed that performance-based negative publicity can be compensated through recruitment advertising, and stammerjohan et al. (2005) found that effects of negative news stories can be mitigated through radio and print advertising in a consumer context. as nowadays many corporate brands extensively use new technologies in order to create an appealing internet and intranet appearance, we assume that employees’ corporate brand experience through internal and external communications can reduce perceptions of negative brand publicity. an indepth analysis of the existing literature provide support for this assumption. first, communication of brand values guides employee behavior (harris & de chernatony, 2001). this, in turn, may lead to reduced misbehavior of employees, which is one potential cause of negative brand publicity. second, abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 7 drawing on findings of eisingerich et al. (2011) we state that the extent to which employees experience the corporate brand through internal and external communications as a great place to work (e.g. corporate brand values) can induce resistance to negative information. this case relates to the goodwill of employees. thereby, individuals are less likely to blame the corporate brand for misbehavior, wrongdoings or product failures, because the corporate brand signals its good intentions through both communication channels, which in turn helps the brand to insulate itself from scrutiny when negative publicity occurs (peloza, 2006; yoon et al., 2006). theoretical support for this assumption provides the information integration theory, which states that inconsistent information will receive a decreased weight compared to consistent information. these reflections result in the following hypotheses: hypothesis 5a. corporate brand experience through external communications has a negative influence on perceived negative corporate brand publicity hypothesis 5b. corporate brand experience through internal communications has a negative influence on perceived negative corporate brand publicity linking corporate brand experience through internal/external communications and emotional corporate brand pride employees can experience corporate brand in various ways. obviously, in their daily work environment dealing with colleagues or management (morhart et al., 2009). it is also possible to experience the corporate brand through internal and external communications (aurand et al., 2005; burmann et al., 2009; harris & de chernatony, 2001; king & grace, 2010). as (emotional) corporate brand pride refers to a positive evaluation of status, reputation, or achievements of the corporate brand, we suggest that a corporations who make stories about the corporate brand accessible to their employees (e.g. testimonials, brand values, etc.) instill corporate brand pride in their workforce. this assumption is in line with aet, which posits that work environment features (e.g. internal communication) can directly affect employee emotions (e.g. corporate brand pride). research from boons et al. (2015) supports this assumption, stating that the communication of status-related information positively affects pride in a consumer context. therefore, we propose: 8 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 hypothesis 6a. corporate brand experience through external communications has a positive influence on emotional corporate brand pride hypothesis 6b. corporate brand experience through internal communications has a positive influence on emotional corporate brand pride the theoretical framework and associated hypotheses developed in this section are depicted in figure 1. 3. method sample and procedure data reported in this article were drawn from a large-scale online survey distributed in the largest business network of germany (xing). the survey investigated employees’ responses to various brand and human resources practices in germany. participants were informed about the purpose of the study and its confidentiality, and were encouraged to participate in the survey. in total, 2,870 employees opened the link and 763 completed the online survey (response rate = 26.59%). deletion of missing values and careless responses (i.e. eliminating cases with a response time less than twenty-five percent of the average response time) resulted in a usable sample of 608 employees. fifty-one percent of the respondents were female (n = 310) and forty-nine percent were male (n = 298). the majority of the participants hold a university degree (n = 472, 77.6%) and worked in a company with more than five-hundred employees (n = 375, 61.7%), without managerial responsibility (n = 435, 71.55%). they were employed in a variety of occupational fields, including: human resources (n = 97, 16.0%), sales (n = 82, 13.5%), marketing (n = 66, 10.9%), consulting (n = 64, 10.5%), other (n = 58, 9.5%), research and development (n = 49, 8.1%), information technology (n = 40, 6.6%), finance and accounting (n = 36, 5.9%), manufacturing (n = 23, 3.8%), services (n = 20, 3.3%), administration (n = 20, 3.3%), purchasing (n = 17, 2.8%), management (n = 12, 2.0%), logistics (n = 10, 1.6%), legal (n = 10, 1.6%) and design (n = 4, 0.7%). in terms of corporate tenure, 12.5 percent of employees (n = 76) joined the corporate brand less than a year ago, 21.7 percent of employees (n = 132) joined the brand one to two years ago, 31.9 percent of employees (n = 194) joined the corporate brand three to five years ago, 17.9 percent of employees (n = 109) belonged to the corporate brand between six and ten years, and abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 9 f ig u re 1 : t h eo re ti ca l f ra m ew o rk 10 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 16.0 percent of employees (n = 97) joined the corporate brand more than ten years ago. measures the response scale for each survey item ranged from 1 (‘strongly disagree’) to 5 (‘strongly agree’), unless otherwise noted. because the study was conducted in a german-speaking environment, all measures previously developed in english have been translated into german, using the commonly translation-back translation procedure (brislin, 1980). moreover, we intensively pre-tested all used measures regarding reliability, validity and mutual understanding. we measured perceived negative brand publicity with three items on a bipolar response scale ranging from 1 (very negative) to 5 (very positive). the item development was inspired by jaidi et al. (2011) as well as (collins & stevens, 2002). items are: ‘news coverage in the media regarding [corporate brand name] is mostly. . . ’, ‘when [corporate brand name] is mentioned in press, it is mostly. . . ’ and ‘the presentation of [corporate brand name] in television, radio, printor online media is. . . ’. cronbach’s alpha for this scale is 0.93. to assess the level of emotional corporate brand pride, the four-item scale by gouthier and rhein (2011) was used. a sample item is: ‘in these moments i am proud of what the [corporate brand name] has achieved’. cronbach’s alpha for this scale was 0.93. we measured attitudinal corporate brand pride using gouthier and rhein (2011)’s three-item measure. a sample item is: ‘i feel proud to work for my [corporate brand name]. due to its central role in our theoretical framework, we added one item to the existing scale to ensure reliability (‘i’m proud to be part of [corporate brand name]’). the reliability of this scale was 0.94. to measure word-of-mouth, the three-item scale by morhart et al. (2009) was used. a sample item is: ‘i talk up [corporate brand name] to people i know’. cronbach’s alpha for this scale was 0.93. we measured employee referrals with five items. we used two already validated and reliable items developed by bloemer (2010) and inspired by zeithaml et al. (1996). in addition, three items were included to ensure the specific nature of referrals and to distinguish this measure from related constructs such as word-of-mouth. the added items are: ‘i approach friends, when i have the feeling that my employer offers an interesting job, which abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 11 suits them.’, ‘i forward job postings to friends, which seek employment.’ and ‘i approach friends, when i have the feeling that my employer offers an interesting job in a similar domain, in which they are currently working.’ the cronbach’s alpha coefficient was 0.94. to assess the level of employees’ brand experience through internal communications, we used a three-item scale developed by egeler et al. (2022) and inspired by aurand et al. (2005). items are: ‘through information in our internal communications, i experience what our corporate brand stands for.’, ‘i experience the corporate brand through editorial content in our internal communications.’, ‘i come in contact with the corporate brand through available media in our internal communications.’ the reliability of this scale was 0.94. brand experience through external communications. to assess the level of employees’ brand experience through external communications we used a three-item scale developed by egeler et al. (2022) and also inspired by aurand et al. (2005). items are: ‘i experience the corporate brand through editorial content in external communications (e. g. television, radio, etc.),’ ‘i experience our corporate brand in a private setting through external communication activities,’ ‘i come in contact with the corporate brand in a private context, through actions of the external communication.’ the cronbach’s alpha for this scale was 0.93. consistent with past research, we controlled for several socio-demographic variables, including gender (1 = female 2 = male), corporate tenure (0-1 years, 1-2 years, 3-5 years, 6-10 years and more than 10 years), corporate size (0-19 employees, 20-99 employees, 100-499 employees and more than 500 employees), employee status (1 = management board 2 = executive employee 3 = employee 4 = freelancer 5 = trainee 6 = intern/working student/temporary staff), functional area (1 = consulting 2 = design 3 = purchasing 4 = finance and accounting 5 = research and development 6 = it 7= services 8 = logistics 9 = marketing 10 = administration 11 = hr 12 = manufacturing 13 = legal 14 = management 15 = sales 16 = other) and education (1 = doctoral and postdoctoral 2 = academic studies 3 = foreman/technician 4 = apprenticeship 5 = university-entrance diploma 6 = general certificate of secondary education 7 = certificate of secondary education 8 = none). 12 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 4. analysis we analysed data following anderson and gerbing (1991) two step approach. in a first step we evaluate the psychometric properties of the scales. moreover, we test for common method bias using established statistical techniques. in a second step, we test the hypothesized relationships using amos 25 (arbuckle, 2003). to assess the quality of the measurement model, we ran a confirmatory factor analysis (cfa). we followed common recommendations from gracia et al. (2013) and stumpp et al. (2009) and used the following fit indices: goodness of fit index (gfi), adjusted goodness of fit index (agfi), comparative fit index (cfi), normed fit index (nfi), tucker lewis index (tli), root mean square error of approximation (rmsea), and standardized root mean square error of approximation (srmr). for gfi, agfi, cfi, nfi and tli values higher than .90 indicate good fit (arbuckle, 2003; bryne, 2001; b. hair et al., 2006; homburg & giering, 1996; hu & bentler, 1998). srmr values lower than .05 indicate good fit respectively (j. hair et al., 1998; hu & bentler, 1998). cfa showed a good model fit: cmin/df = 1.753, srmr = .02, rmsea = .035, gfi = .94, agfi = .92, nfi = .97, tli = .98, cfi = .98. in addition, we compared the hypothesized model with three nested models (table 1). the original model shows a significant better fit than the alternative nested models, providing support for the distinctiveness of the constructs. besides a satisfactory model fit, scales included in this study should exhibit convergent validity, reliability, and discriminant validity (bagozzi & yi, 1988; fornell & larcker, 1981). since the lowest factor loading in our model was 0.75, there is support for convergent validity. for the reliabilities, see table 2. composite reliability (cr) and average variance extracted (ave) were calculated based on the procedure of fornell and larcker (1981). cr and ave for all constructs were above 0.92 and 0.72 respectively. these values fulfill the recommended cut-off values of cr > 0.70 and av e > 0.50 (bagozzi & yi, 1988; fornell & larcker, 1981). similarly, all ave values are greater than the squared correlation between that factor and another factor, suggesting discriminant validity is given. data were collected at a single point of time from a single source, which can represent a potential risk regarding to the problem of common method variance (podsakoff & organ, 1986). to minimize this bias, we referred to survey design guidelines proposed by podsakoff et al. (2003) guaranteeing abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 13 t a b le 1 : r es u lt s o f th e c o n fi rm a to ry f a ct o r a n a ly si s m o d el χ 2 d f c f i n f i r m s e a g f i s ev en -f a ct o r m o d el 4 3 6 .4 5 5 2 4 9 0 .9 8 9 0 .9 7 4 0 .0 3 5 0 .9 4 6 s ix -f a ct o r m o d el 1 : 9 3 9 .8 3 0 2 5 5 0 .9 5 8 0 .9 4 3 0 .0 6 7 0 .8 9 8 w o m a n d em p lo y ee re fe rr a ls co m b in ed s ix -f a ct o r m o d el 2 : 1 0 6 7 .4 2 3 2 5 5 0 .9 5 0 0 .9 3 0 0 .0 7 2 0 .8 6 3 e m o ti o n a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p ri d e a n d a tt it u d in a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p ri d e co m b in ed o n efa ct o r m o d el 6 9 3 3 .1 5 9 2 7 0 0 .5 9 1 0 .5 8 3 0 .2 0 2 0 .5 2 7 n o te : c f i co m p a ra ti v e fi t in d ex ; n f i n o rm ed fi t in d ex ; r m s e a ro o t m ea n sq u a re ro o t er ro r o f a p p ro x im a ti o n ; g f i g o o d n es s o f fi t in d ex 14 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 confidentiality, using clear response guidelines, designing focused and specific items, and using different scale endpoints at one of the variables. moreover, we counterbalanced the question order to disrupt the logical flow. to test statistically for potential common method bias, we conducted a harman onefactor test (podsakoff & organ, 1986). results suggested the presence of 5 factors, indicating that common method effects are no serious problem in the data. in addition, we controlled for common method variance using a marker variable test (lindell & whitney, 2001). we selected felfe’s ‘transactional leadership’ as a marker variable, as it was theoretically uncorrelated to most of the constructs. analysis showed that none of the significant correlations of the model became nonsignificant or changed their sign. thus, we assume that cmv is not likely to affect the validity of this study (doty & glick, 1998). 5. results means, standard deviations, correlations and reliabilities are shown in table 2. the results are illustrated in figure 2 and reveal that only one out of ten hypotheses need to be rejected. perceived negative corporate brand publicity adversely affect emotional corporate brand pride, supporting h1 (β = .19, p < .001). similarly, perceived negative brand publicity directly affect brand supporting behavior of employees, namely wom (h2a, β = −.15, p < .001) and employee referrals (h2b, β = −.08, p < .002). moreover, we can confirm h3 stating that emotional corporate brand pride leads to attitudinal corporate brand pride (β = .79, p < .001). in accordance with h4a and h4b, we show that attitudinal corporate brand pride significantly influences wom (h4a, β = .74, p < .001) and employee referrals (h4b, β = .67, p < .001). in contrast to our expectations corporate brand experience through internal communications and corporate brand experience through external communications did not act in the same way in compensating perceived negative corporate brand publicity. corporate brand experience through internal communications mitigates the perception of negative brand publicity (h5b, β = -.22, p < .001), supporting h5b. however, the path between corporate brand experience through external communications and perceived negative brand publicity wasn’t significant, leading to a rejection of h5a (β = −.03, n.s.). to test whether emotional corporate brand pride can be triggered by the corporation through specific corporate brand experience, we test h6a abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 15 t a b le 2 : d es cr ip ti v e s ta ti st ic s a n d c o rr el a ti o n s v a ri a b le m ea n s d 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 . p er ce iv ed n eg a ti v e b ra n d p u b li ci ty 2 .3 1 0 .8 8 (0 .9 3 ) 2 . e m o ti o n a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p ri d e 3 .8 6 1 .0 1 -0 .2 7 (0 .9 3 ) 3 . a tt it u d in a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p ri d e 3 .7 4 1 .1 1 -0 .2 9 0 .8 4 (0 .9 4 ) 4 . w o m 3 .6 2 1 .1 2 -0 .3 6 0 .6 8 0 .7 8 (0 .9 3 ) 5 . e m p lo y ee r ef er ra ls 3 .3 7 1 .2 3 -0 .2 6 0 .5 8 0 .6 8 0 .6 8 (0 .9 4 ) 6 . b ra n d ex p er ie n ce th ro u g h in te rn a l co m m u n ic a ti o n s 3 .4 4 1 .1 5 -0 .2 4 0 .4 1 0 .4 4 0 .3 9 0 .4 2 (0 .9 4 ) 7 . b ra n d ex p er ie n ce th ro u g h ex te rn a l co m m u n ic a ti o n s 2 .5 7 1 .3 0 -0 .1 3 0 .3 0 0 .3 5 0 .3 4 0 .3 4 0 .4 5 (0 .9 3 ) n o te : a ll c o rr e la ti o n s a re si g n ifi c a n t a t p < .0 1 . c o e ffi c ie n t a lp h a s a p p e a r o n d ia g o n a l 16 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 f ig u re 2 : s tru ctu ra l m o d el abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 17 and h6b. in line with expectations corporate brand experience through external communications positively affect emotional corporate brand pride (h6a, β = .14, p < .002). similarly, corporate brand experience through internal communications influences emotional corporate brand pride (h6b, β = .31, p < .001). in addition, we tested for moderators that were not hypothesized. we conducted multi-group analysis as our possible moderators are discrete variables (eberl, 2010). we applied the procedure that bryne (2010) proposes to test the difference in our groups. since gouthier and rhein (2011) suggest that women show more (organizational) pride than men, we tested for gender effects. we also tested whether tenure influence the proposed paths as helm (2013) state that employees with a longer tenure might show higher levels of pride. analysis showed that, in terms of the relationship between perceived negative corporate brand publicity and employee referrals, gender has a significant effect. results suggest that men are less likely to recommend job offers. furthermore, the relationship between corporate brand experience through external communications and emotional corporate brand pride, gender has a significant effect. however, group difference is marginal. regarding tenure analysis showed that almost all paths did not differ, except for the relationship attitudinal corporate brand pride and employee referrals. here, employees with a short tenure tend to show higher employee referrals behavior. finally, multi-group analysis revealed that management and nonmanagement employees slightly differ in referral behavior (β = .04, p < .04). results of the multi-group analysis are presented in tables 3-5. 6. discussion although there are several studies providing empirical evidence that negative (brand) publicity has adverse effects on a number of consumer and applicant attitudes and behavioral intentions, it is unclear to what extent perceived negative corporate brand publicity affects employees. the present study reveals that perceived negative corporate brand publicity directly affects employee emotion, namely emotional corporate brand pride. moreover, perceived negative corporate brand publicity has a direct effect on employees’ brand supporting behavior like wom and employee referrals. as the latter finding is in contrast to prior studies müller and gaus (e.g. 2015) who did not find significant effects of negative media on actual consumer behavior, we argue that a person’s employer (i.e. brand) represent an important 18 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 t a b le 3 : m u lti-g ro u p a n a ly sis, b y g en d er s ta n d a rd co effi cen t g ro u p p a th m a le f em a le d iff eren ce b e in tern a l co m m u n ica tio n → p erceiv ed n eg a tiv e b ra n d p u b licity − 0 .2 3 − 0 .2 2 0 .0 1 b e ex tern a l co m m u n ica tio n → p erceiv ed n eg a tiv e b ra n d p u b licity − 0 .0 2 − 0 .0 2 0 .0 0 p erceiv ed n eg a tiv e b ra n d p u b licity → e m o tio n a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p rid e − 0 .1 8 − 0 .1 9 0 .0 2 e m o tio n a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p rid e → a ttitu d in a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p rid e 0 .8 1 0 .7 7 0 .0 4 a ttitu d in a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p rid e → e m p lo y ee referra ls 0 .6 7 0 .6 7 0 .0 0 a ttitu d in a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p irid e → w o m 0 .7 6 0 .7 2 0 .0 4 p erceiv ed n eg a tiv e b ra n d p u b licity → e m p lo y ee referra ls − 0 .0 9 − 0 .0 7 0 .0 2 ∗ p erceiv ed n eg a tiv e b ra n d p u b licity → w o m − 0 .1 7 − 0 .1 5 0 .0 2 b e in tern a l co m m u n ica tio n → e m o tio n a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p rid e 0 .2 8 0 .3 0 0 .0 2 b e ex tern a l co m m u n ica tio n → e m o tio n a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p rid e 0 .1 3 0 .1 4 0 .0 1 ∗∗∗ n o te : s ig n ifi c a n t a t * * * p < .0 1 ; * * p < 0 .5 ; * p < .1 0 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 19 t a b le 4 : m u lt ig ro u p a n a ly si s, b y t en u re s ta n d a rd co effi ce n t l o n g s h o rt g ro u p p a th t en u re t en u re d iff er en ce b e in te rn a l co m m u n ic a ti o n → p er ce iv ed n eg a ti v e b ra n d p u b li ci ty − 0 .2 4 − 0 .2 7 0 .0 3 b e ex te rn a l co m m u n ic a ti o n → p er ce iv ed n eg a ti v e b ra n d p u b li ci ty − 0 .0 4 − 0 .0 4 0 .0 0 p er ce iv ed n eg a ti v e b ra n d p u b li ci ty → e m o ti o n a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p ri d e − 0 .1 5 − 0 .1 5 0 .0 0 e m o ti o n a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p ri d e → a tt it u d in a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p ri d e 0 .8 1 0 .8 0 0 .0 1 a tt it u d in a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p ri d e → e m p lo y ee re fe rr a ls 0 .6 3 0 .6 7 0 .0 4 ∗ a tt it u d in a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p ir id e → w o m 0 .7 2 0 .7 1 0 .0 1 p er ce iv ed n eg a ti v e b ra n d p u b li ci ty → e m p lo y ee re fe rr a ls − 0 .1 1 − 0 .0 9 0 .0 2 p er ce iv ed n eg a ti v e b ra n d p u b li ci ty → w o m − 0 .1 6 − 0 .1 4 0 .0 2 b e in te rn a l co m m u n ic a ti o n → e m o ti o n a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p ri d e 0 .3 1 0 .3 1 0 .0 1 b e ex te rn a l co m m u n ic a ti o n → e m o ti o n a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p ri d e 0 .1 2 0 .1 3 0 .0 1 ∗∗ ∗ n o te : s ig n ifi c a n t a t * * * p < .0 1 ; * * p < 0 .5 ; * p < .1 0 20 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 t a b le 5 : m u lti-g ro u p a n a ly sis, b y m a n a g em en t r o le s ta n d a rd co effi cen t n o n g ro u p p a th m a n a g em en t m a n a g em en t d iff eren ce b e in tern a l co m m u n ica tio n → p erceiv ed n eg a tiv e b ra n d p u b licity − 0 .2 3 − 0 .2 3 0 .0 0 b e ex tern a l co m m u n ica tio n → p erceiv ed n eg a tiv e b ra n d p u b licity − 0 .0 3 − 0 .0 3 0 .0 0 p erceiv ed n eg a tiv e b ra n d p u b licity → e m o tio n a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p rid e − 0 .2 0 − 0 .1 8 0 .0 2 e m o tio n a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p rid e → a ttitu d in a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p rid e 0 .7 7 0 .7 9 0 .0 2 a ttitu d in a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p rid e → e m p lo y ee referra ls 0 .6 5 0 .6 9 0 .0 4 ∗∗ a ttitu d in a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p irid e → w o m 0 .7 4 0 .7 4 0 .0 0 p erceiv ed n eg a tiv e b ra n d p u b licity → e m p lo y ee referra ls − 0 .0 9 − 0 .0 7 0 .0 2 p erceiv ed n eg a tiv e b ra n d p u b licity → w o m − 0 .1 5 − 0 .1 5 0 .0 0 b e in tern a l co m m u n ica tio n → e m o tio n a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p rid e 0 .2 9 0 .3 0 0 .0 2 ∗ b e ex tern a l co m m u n ica tio n → e m o tio n a l co rp o ra te b ra n d p rid e 0 .1 7 0 .1 5 0 .0 2 n o te : s ig n ifi c a n t a t * * * p < .0 1 ; * * p < 0 .5 ; * p < .1 0 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 21 part of the individual’s self-concept leading to a change in employee behavior (cable & turban, 2003). in line with aet weiss and cropanzano (1996) and earlier findings of gouthier and rhein (2011), our results reveal that emotional corporate brand pride has downstream consequences regarding attitudinal corporate brand pride. similarly, the results demonstrate that attitudinal corporate brand pride strongly influences wom and employee referrals (brand supporting behavior). here, the study helps to broaden the current view on internal branding, which mainly focuses on brand commitment as a central construct, highlighting the importance of (attitudinal) corporate brand pride in an (internal) branding context. contrary to what we expected, corporate brand experience through external communications did not mitigate the perception of negative brand publicity in the same way brand experience through internal communication does. this finding is noteworthy, because it illustrates that employees of a corporate brand seem to be more prone to brand experience through internal communications. in doing so, the results establish an understanding that in an employee context both communication channels are not equally effective in compensating negative corporate brand publicity. from a theoretical point of view, this circumstance might relate to the accessibility of information amongst others, suggesting that the likelihood that information is used as the basis of an evaluation is determined by the accessibility of that information (feldman & lynch, 1988; herr et al., 1991). in the context of our study, employees might use the internal communications more often as accessibility via the intranet is easier and often more detailed compared to external communications. hence, the information is more present and therefore more effective. in addition, de roeck et al. (2014) and gond et al. (2010) showed that employees exhibited stronger feelings from internal csr actions than from csr actions towards other stakeholders, which could support our assumption that employees are more amenable to internal forms of communications. finally, this paper adds value to the existing research by showing how (emotional) corporate brand pride can be stimulated, responding to calls for further research (kraemer et al., 2020). likewise, corporate brand experience through internal communications trigger (emotional) corporate brand pride more strongly. 22 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 the analysis of control variables (multi-group analysis) revealed only minor differences regarding gender, tenure and employee status. here, we did not find strong gender effects. in contrast to expectations employees with a short tenure are more likely to recommend specific jobs of the corporation. it is also interesting that non-management employees are more likely to refer specific jobs to persons he or she knows. as management employees usually have a broad social capital and are usually well informed about vacancies, this result is surprising. limitations and implications for further research despite the new findings noted here, several limitations should be addressed. first, the sample comprise of german employees, implying that the results cannot be generalized. second, this research used a cross-sectional design. however, it may be interesting how the influence of perceived brand publicity varies over time, calling for further research using a longitudinal design. in addition, further studies might use semi-structured interviews to gain insights answering the question what employees of a corporate brand expect in a situation of negative publicity from top management, their supervisors or in general regarding the brand they work for. third, to provide a holistic view on effects of brand publicity the study used a more general measure, capturing various forms of negative brand publicity. in doing so, we disregard previous research showing that various forms of publicity exist, for example performance-related (lee et al., 2013; lin et al., 2011) and value-related publicity (kanar et al., 2010; thwaites et al., 2012). to provide further insights, future studies should include differentiated measures to capture specific forms of (brand) publicity. fourth, this research neglected effects of dispositions. affective-events-theory postulates the importance of dispositions on the relationship of work-events and emotions. for these reasons, future research should include dispositions. fifth, nowadays various communication channels exist (e.g. social media) and future studies should try to answer the question if negative brand publicity is similarly harmful in all channels. 7. practical implications the findings of this research have several implications for management and marketing practitioners. as employees represent a crucial part of brands’ success and competitive advantage, it is important to understand how the abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 23 detrimental effects of perceived negative brand publicity on employees’ corporate brand pride and brand supporting behavior can be mitigated. the results show that corporation can effectively mitigate effects of perceived negative corporate brand publicity by creating a corporate brand experience. here, marketing managers may be well advised to highlight corporate brand values through internal communications, which in turn negatively affect the employees’ perception of negative brand publicity. moreover, this study indicates the importance of corporate brand pride as a central driver of brand supporting behavior, namely employee referrals and employee wom. as many branding initiatives base upon brand commitment, practitioners might think of including brand pride in their marketing concepts. this research shows how corporate brand pride can be fostered through specific marketing or branding activities, for example highlighting corporate brand values via internal communications. at the same time, we show that employees with a long tenure are less likely to recommend jobs to friends, compared to employees with a short tenure. as referrals are nowadays an important recruiting source (e.g. pieper, 2015; van hoye, 2013), management and hr practitioners might stimulate employee referrals through incentives targeted at this particular group (e.g. differentiated referral bonuses). similarly, managers are less likely to recommend jobs of their corporate brand to friends, compared to non-management employees. so, managers who usually have a large (business) network and know about various job opportunities within the corporation need to be encouraged to act as facilitators. references albert, n., merunka, d., & valette-florence, p. (2013). brand passion: antecedents and consequences. journal of business research, 66(7), 904–909. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2011.12.009 anderson, j. c., & gerbing, d. w. (1991). predicting the performance of measures in a confirmatory factor analysis with a pretest assessment of their substantive validities. journal of applied psychology, 76(5), 732–740. https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.76.5.732 appleberg, k. a. (2005). the construction of a nomological network for organizational pride. benedictine university. arbuckle, j. (2003). amos 5.0 update to the amos user’s guide. marketing department, spss incorporated. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbusres.2011.12.009 https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.76.5.732 24 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 aurand, t. w., gorchels, l., & bishop, t. r. (2005). human resource management’s role in internal branding: an opportunity for crossfunctional brand message synergy. journal of product & brand management. https://doi.org/10.1108/10610420510601030 baer, m. d., dhensa-kahlon, r. k., colquitt, j. a., rodell, j. b., outlaw, r., & long, d. m. (2015). uneasy lies the head that bears the trust: the effects of feeling trusted on emotional exhaustion. academy of management journal, 58(6), 1637–1657. https://doi.org/10.5465 /amj.2014.0246 bagozzi, r. p., & yi, y. (1988). on the evaluation of structural equation models. journal of the academy of marketing science, 16(1), 74–94. berger, j., sorensen, a. t., & rasmussen, s. j. (2010). positive effects of negative publicity: when negative reviews increase sales. marketing science, 29(5). https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1090.0557 bloemer, j. (2010). the psychological antecedents of employee referrals. the international journal of human resource management, 21(10), 1769–1791. https://doi.org/10.1080/09585192.2010.500494 boons, m., stam, d., & barkema, h. g. (2015). feelings of pride and respect as drivers of ongoing member activity on crowdsourcing platforms. journal of management studies, 52(6), 717–741. https://doi.org/10 .1111/joms.12140 boukis, a., kostopoulos, g., & katsaridou, i. (2014). imo and different fit types as key enablers of employee brand-supporting behaviour. journal of strategic marketing, 22(2), 117–134. https://doi.org/10 .1080/0965254x.2013.876066 braxton, d. f., muehling, d. d., & joireman, j. (2019). the effects of processing mode and brand scandals on copycat product evaluations. journal of marketing communications, 25(3), 247–267. https://doi. org/10.1080/13527266.2016.1236284 breaugh, j. a., & starke, m. (2000). research on employee recruitment: so many studies, so many remaining questions. journal of management, 26(3), 405–434. https://doi.org/10.1177/014920630002600303 brislin, r. w. (1980). translation and content analysis of oral and written materials. methodology, 389–444. bryne, b. (2001). structural equation modeling with amos: basic concepts, applications, and programming (1st ed.) erlbaum. https://doi.org/10.1108/10610420510601030 https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2014.0246 https://doi.org/10.5465/amj.2014.0246 https://doi.org/10.1287/mksc.1090.0557 https://doi.org/10.1080/09585192.2010.500494 https://doi.org/10.1111/joms.12140 https://doi.org/10.1111/joms.12140 https://doi.org/10.1080/0965254x.2013.876066 https://doi.org/10.1080/0965254x.2013.876066 https://doi.org/10.1080/13527266.2016.1236284 https://doi.org/10.1080/13527266.2016.1236284 https://doi.org/10.1177/014920630002600303 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 25 bryne, b. (2010). structural equation modeling with amos: basic concepts, applications, and programming (2nd ed.) routledge. burmann, c., zeplin, s., & riley, n. (2009). key determinants of internal brand management success: an exploratory empirical analysis. journal of brand management, 16(4), 264–284. https://doi.org/10.1057 /bm.2008.6 cable, d. m., & turban, d. b. (2003). the value of organizational reputation in the recruitment context: a brand-equity perspective. journal of applied social psychology, 33(11), 2244–2266. https://doi.org/10.1 111/j.1559-1816.2003.tb01883.x cleeren, k., van heerde, h. j., & dekimpe, m. g. (2013). rising from the ashes: how brands and categories can overcome product-harm crises. journal of marketing, 77(2), 58–77. https://doi.org/10.1509/jm.10 .0414 collins, c. j., & stevens, c. k. (2002). the relationship between early recruitment-related activities and the application decisions of new labor-market entrants: a brand equity approach to recruitment. journal of applied psychology, 87(6), 1121–1133. https://doi.org/10.103 7/0021-9010.87.6.1121 de matos, c. a., & rossi, c. a. v. (2008). word-of-mouth communications in marketing: a meta-analytic review of the antecedents and moderators. journal of the academy of marketing science, 36(4), 578–596. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-008-0121-1 de roeck, k., marique, g., stinglhamber, f., & swaen, v. (2014). understanding employees’ responses to corporate social responsibility: mediating roles of overall justice and organisational identification. the international journal of human resource management, 25(1), 91–112. https://doi.org/10.1080/09585192.2013.781528 doty, d. h., & glick, w. h. (1998). common methods bias: does common methods variance really bias results? organizational research method, 1(4), 374–406. https://doi.org/10.1177/109442819814002 eberl, m. (2010). an application of pls in multi-group analysis: the need for differentiated corporate-level marketing in the mobile communications industry. in handbook of partial least squares (pp. 487–514). springer. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-32827-8 22 https://doi.org/10.1057/bm.2008.6 https://doi.org/10.1057/bm.2008.6 https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1559-1816.2003.tb01883.x https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1559-1816.2003.tb01883.x https://doi.org/10.1509/jm.10.0414 https://doi.org/10.1509/jm.10.0414 https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.87.6.1121 https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.87.6.1121 https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-008-0121-1 https://doi.org/10.1080/09585192.2013.781528 https://doi.org/10.1177/109442819814002 https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-32827-8_22 26 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 egeler, p., abed, f., & büttgen, m. (2022). corporate brand experience as a new construct and its effects on employees’ corporate brand pride and brand-supporting behaviours. international journal of business and management, 17(3). https://doi.org/10.5539/ijbm.v17n3p39 eisingerich, a. b., rubera, g., seifert, m., & bhardwaj, g. (2011). doing good and doing better despite negative information?: the role of corporate social responsibility in consumer resistance to negative information. journal of service research, 14(1), 60–75. https://doi.org/1 0.1177/1094670510389164 elfenbein, h. a. (2007). 7 emotion in organizations: a review and theoretical integration. academy of management annals, 1(1), 315–386. https: //doi.org/10.1080/078559812 feldman, j. m., & lynch, j. g. (1988). self-generated validity and other effects of measurement on belief, attitude, intention, and behavior. journal of applied psychology, 73(3), 421. https://doi.org/10.1037 /0021-9010.73.3.421 fisher, c. d., & ashkanasy, n. m. (2000). the emerging role of emotions in work life: an introduction. https://doi.org/10.1002/(sici)1099-137 9(200003)21:2⟨3c123::aid-job33⟩3e3.0.co;2-8 fornell, c., & larcker, d. f. (1981). evaluating structural equation models with unobservable variables and measurement error. journal of marketing research, 18(1), 39–50. https://doi.org/10.1177/0022243 78101800104 gond, j.-p., el-akremi, a., igalens, j., & swaen, v. (2010). corporate social responsibility influence on employees. international center for corporate social responsibility, 54. gouthier, m. h., & rhein, m. (2011). organizational pride and its positive effects on employee behavior. journal of service management. https: //doi.org/10.1108/09564231111174988 gracia, e., salanova, m., grau, r., & cifre, e. (2013). how to enhance service quality through organizational facilitators, collective work engagement, and relational service competence. european journal of work and organizational psychology, 22(1), 42–55. https://doi.org/ 10.1080/1359432x.2011.628793 hagenbuch, d. j., wiese, m. d., dose, j. j., & bruce, m. l. (2008). understanding satisfied and affectively committed clients’ lack of referral https://doi.org/10.5539/ijbm.v17n3p39 https://doi.org/10.1177/1094670510389164 https://doi.org/10.1177/1094670510389164 https://doi.org/10.1080/078559812 https://doi.org/10.1080/078559812 https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.73.3.421 https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.73.3.421 https://doi.org/10.1002/(sici)1099-1379(200003)21:2<3c123::aid-job33>3e3.0.co;2-8 https://doi.org/10.1002/(sici)1099-1379(200003)21:2<3c123::aid-job33>3e3.0.co;2-8 https://doi.org/10.1177/002224378101800104 https://doi.org/10.1177/002224378101800104 https://doi.org/10.1108/09564231111174988 https://doi.org/10.1108/09564231111174988 https://doi.org/10.1080/1359432x.2011.628793 https://doi.org/10.1080/1359432x.2011.628793 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 27 intent. services marketing quarterly, 29(3), 24–74. https://doi.org/1 0.1080/15332960802125932 hair, b., j.f.and babin, black, w., anderson, r., & tatham, r. (2006). multivariate data analysis (6th edition). pearson. hair, j., anderson, r., tatham, r., & black, w. (1998). multivariate data analysis (5th edition). pearson. harris, f., & de chernatony, l. (2001). corporate branding and corporate brand performance. european journal of marketing. https://doi.org/ 10.1108/03090560110382101 harrison, w. l. (2001). the measurement of word-of-mouth communication and an investigation of service quality and customer commitment as potential antecedents. journal of service research, 4(1), 60–75. https://doi.org/10.1177/109467050141006 helm, s. (2013). a matter of reputation and pride: associations between perceived external reputation, pride in membership, job satisfaction and turnover intentions. british journal of management, 24(4), 542– 556. https://doi.org/10..1111/j.1467-8551.2012.00827.x herr, p. m., kardes, f. r., & kim, j. (1991). effects of word-of-mouth and product-attribute information on persuasion: an accessibilitydiagnosticity perspective. journal of consumer research, 17(4), 454– 462. https://doi.org/10.1086/208570 herrbach, o., mignonac, k., & gatignon, a.-l. (2004). exploring the role of perceived external prestige in managers’ turnover intentions. the international journal of human resource management, 15(8), 1390– 1407. https://doi.org/10.1080/0958519042000257995 hock, s. j., & raithel, s. (2019). managing negative celebrity endorser publicity: how announcements of firm (non) responses affect stock returns. management science, 66(3), 1473–1495. https://doi.org/10.1 287/mnsc.2018.3243 homburg, c., & giering, a. (1996). konzeptualisierung und operationalisierung komplexer konstrukte: ein leitfaden für die marketingforschung. marketing: zeitschrift für forschung und praxis, 18(1), 5–24. https://doi.org/10.15358/3044-1369-1996-1-5 hu, l.-t., & bentler, p. m. (1998). fit indices in covariance structure modeling: sensitivity to underparameterized model misspecification. psyhttps://doi.org/10.1080/15332960802125932 https://doi.org/10.1080/15332960802125932 https://doi.org/10.1108/03090560110382101 https://doi.org/10.1108/03090560110382101 https://doi.org/10.1177/109467050141006 https://doi.org/10..1111/j.1467-8551.2012.00827.x https://doi.org/10.1086/208570 https://doi.org/10.1080/0958519042000257995 https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2018.3243 https://doi.org/10.1287/mnsc.2018.3243 https://doi.org/10.15358/3044-1369-1996-1-5 28 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 chological methods, 3(4), 424–453. https://doi.org/10.1037/1082-98 9x.3.4.424 jaidi, y., van hooft, e. a., & arends, l. r. (2011). recruiting highly educated graduates: a study on the relationship between recruitment information sources, the theory of planned behavior, and actual job pursuit. human performance, 24(2), 135–157. https://doi.org/10.1 080/08959285.2011.554468 kanar, a. m., collins, c. j., & bell, b. s. (2010). a comparison of the effects of positive and negative information on job seekers’ organizational attraction and attribute recall. human performance, 23(3), 193–212. https://doi.org/10.1080/08959285.2010.487842 king, c., & grace, d. (2010). building and measuring employee-based brand equity. european journal of marketing. https://doi.org/10.1108/03 090561011047472 kraemer, t., & gouthier, m. h. (2014). how organizational pride and emotional exhaustion explain turnover intentions in call centers: a multigroup analysis with gender and organizational tenure. journal of service management. https://doi.org/10.1108/josm-07-2013-0173 kraemer, t., weiger, w. h., gouthier, m. h., & hammerschmidt, m. (2020). toward a theory of spirals: the dynamic relationship between organizational pride and customer-oriented behavior. journal of the academy of marketing science, 48(6), 1095–1115. https://doi.org/1 0.1007/s11747-019-00715-0 lee, c.-h., hwang, f.-m., & yeh, y.-c. (2013). the impact of publicity and subsequent intervention in recruitment advertising on job searching freshmen’s attraction to an organization and job pursuit intention. journal of applied social psychology, 43(1), 1–13. https://doi.org/1 0.1111/j.1559-1816.2012.00975.x lin, c.-p., chen, s.-c., chiu, c.-k., & lee, w.-y. (2011). understanding purchase intention during product-harm crises: moderating effects of perceived corporate ability and corporate social responsibility. journal of business ethics, 102(3), 455–471. https://doi.org/10.1007/s1 0551-011-0824-y lindell, m., & whitney, d. (2001). accounting for common method variance in cross-selectional research designs. journal of applied psychology, 86(1), 114–121. https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.86.1.114 https://doi.org/10.1037/1082-989x.3.4.424 https://doi.org/10.1037/1082-989x.3.4.424 https://doi.org/10.1080/08959285.2011.554468 https://doi.org/10.1080/08959285.2011.554468 https://doi.org/10.1080/08959285.2010.487842 https://doi.org/10.1108/03090561011047472 https://doi.org/10.1108/03090561011047472 https://doi.org/10.1108/josm-07-2013-0173 https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-019-00715-0 https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-019-00715-0 https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1559-1816.2012.00975.x https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1559-1816.2012.00975.x https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-011-0824-y https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-011-0824-y https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.86.1.114 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 29 löhndorf, b., & diamantopoulos, a. (2014). internal branding: social identity and social exchange perspectives on turning employees into brand champions. journal of service research, 17(3), 310–325. https://doi. org/10.1177/1094670514522098 lovett, m. j., peres, r., & shachar, r. (2013). on brands and word of mouth. journal of marketing research, 50(4), 427–444. https://doi.org/10 .1509/jmr.11.0458 lythreatis, s., mostafa, a. m. s., & wang, x. (2019). participative leadership and organizational identification in smes in the mena region: testing the roles of csr perceptions and pride in membership. journal of business ethics, 156(3), 635–650. https://doi.org/10.1007/s1055 1-017-3557-8 matta, f. k., erol-korkmaz, h. t., johnson, r. e., & biçaksiz, p. (2014). significant work events and counterproductive work behavior: the role of fairness, emotions, and emotion regulation. journal of organizational behavior, 35(7), 920–944. https://doi.org/10.1002/job.19 34 monga, a. b., & john, d. r. (2008). when does negative brand publicity hurt? the moderating influence of analytic versus holistic thinking. journal of consumer psychology, 18(4), 320–332. https://doi.org/1 0.1016/j.jcps.2008.09.009 morhart, f. m., herzog, w., & tomczak, t. (2009). brand-specific leadership: turning employees into brand champions. journal of marketing, 73(5), 122–142. https://doi.org/10.1509/jmkg.73.5.112 müller, c. e., & gaus, h. (2015). consumer response to negative media information about certified organic food products. journal of consumer policy, 38(4), 387–409. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10603-0159299-z osei-frimpong, k., donkor, g., & owusu-frimpong, n. (2019). the impact of celebrity endorsement on consumer purchase intention: an emerging market perspective. journal of marketing theory and practice, 27(1), 103–121. https://doi.org/10.1080/10696679.2018.1534070 peloza, j. (2006). using corporate social responsibility as insurance for financial performance. california management review, 48(2), 52–72. https://doi.org/10.2307/41166338 https://doi.org/10.1177/1094670514522098 https://doi.org/10.1177/1094670514522098 https://doi.org/10.1509/jmr.11.0458 https://doi.org/10.1509/jmr.11.0458 https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-017-3557-8 https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-017-3557-8 https://doi.org/10.1002/job.1934 https://doi.org/10.1002/job.1934 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcps.2008.09.009 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jcps.2008.09.009 https://doi.org/10.1509/jmkg.73.5.112 https://doi.org/10.1007/s10603-015-9299-z https://doi.org/10.1007/s10603-015-9299-z https://doi.org/10.1080/10696679.2018.1534070 https://doi.org/10.2307/41166338 30 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 pieper, j. r. (2015). uncovering the nuances of referral hiring: how referrer characteristics affect referral hires’ performance and likelihood of voluntary turnover. personnel psychology, 68(4), 811–858. https: //doi.org/10.1111/peps.12097 podsakoff, p. m., mackenzie, s. b., lee, j.-y., & podsakoff, n. p. (2003). common method biases in behavioral research: a critical review of the literature and recommended remedies. journal of applied psychology, 88(5), 879. https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.88.5.879 podsakoff, p. m., & organ, d. w. (1986). self-reports in organizational research: problems and prospects. journal of management, 12(4), 531–544. https://doi.org/10.1177/014920638601200408 rosen, c. c., harris, k. j., & kacmar, k. m. (2009). the emotional implications of organizational politics: a process model. human relations, 62(1), 27–57. https://doi.org/10.1177/0018726708099836 salerno, a., laran, j., & janiszewski, c. (2015). pride and regulatory behavior: the influence of appraisal information and self-regulatory goals. journal of consumer research, 42(3), 499–514. https://doi.org/10 .1093/jcr/ucv037 stammerjohan, c., wood, c. m., chang, y., & thorson, e. (2005). an empirical investigation of the interaction between publicity, advertising, and previous brand attitudes and knowledge. journal of advertising, 34(4), 55–67. https://doi.org/10.1080/00913367.2005.10639209 stumpp, t., hülsheger, u. r., muck, p. m., & maier, g. w. (2009). expanding the link between core self-evaluations and affective job attitudes. european journal of work and organizational psychology, 18(2), 148–166. https://doi.org/10.1080/13594320802281110 thwaites, d., lowe, b., monkhouse, l. l., & barnes, b. r. (2012). the impact of negative publicity on celebrity ad endorsements. psychology & marketing, 29(9), 663–673. https://doi.org/10.1002/mar.20552 van hoye, g., & lievens, f. (2005). recruitment-related information sources and organizational attractiveness: can something be done about negative publicity? international journal of selection and assessment, 13(3), 179–187. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-2389.2005.00313.x van hoye, g. (2013). recruiting through employee referrals: an examination of employees’ motives. human performance, 26(5), 451–464. https: //doi.org/10.1080/08959285.2013.836199 https://doi.org/10.1111/peps.12097 https://doi.org/10.1111/peps.12097 https://doi.org/10.1037/0021-9010.88.5.879 https://doi.org/10.1177/014920638601200408 https://doi.org/10.1177/0018726708099836 https://doi.org/10.1093/jcr/ucv037 https://doi.org/10.1093/jcr/ucv037 https://doi.org/10.1080/00913367.2005.10639209 https://doi.org/10.1080/13594320802281110 https://doi.org/10.1002/mar.20552 https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-2389.2005.00313.x https://doi.org/10.1080/08959285.2013.836199 https://doi.org/10.1080/08959285.2013.836199 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 31 verbeke, w., belschak, f., & bagozzi, r. p. (2004). the adaptive consequences of pride in personal selling. journal of the academy of marketing science, 32(4), 386–402. https://doi.org/10.1177/0092010304 267105 wang, a. (2006). when synergy in marketing communication online enhances audience response: the effects of varying advertising and product publicity messages. journal of advertising research, 46(2), 160–170. https://doi.org/10.2501/s0021849906060181 wangenheim, f. v., & baón, t. (2007). the chain from customer satisfaction via word-of-mouth referrals to new customer acquisition. journal of the academy of marketing science, 35(2), 233–249. https://doi.org/1 0.1007/s11747-007-0037-1 weiss, h. m., & cropanzano, r. (1996). affective events theory. research in organizational behavior, 18(1), 1–74. wolny, j., & mueller, c. (2013). analysis of fashion consumers’ motives to engage in electronic word-of-mouth communication through social media platforms. journal of marketing management, 29(5-6), 562– 583. https://doi.org/10.1080/0267257x.2013.778324 woo, h., jung, s., & jin, b. e. (2020). how far can brands go to defend themselves? the extent of negative publicity impact on proactive consumer behaviors and brand equity. business ethics: a european review, 29(1), 193–211. https://doi.org/10.1111/beer.12246 yoon, y., gürhan-canli, z., & schwarz, n. (2006). the effect of corporate social responsibility (csr) activities on companies with bad reputations. journal of consumer psychology, 16(4), 377–390. https://doi.org/1 0.1207/s15327663jcp1604 9 zeithaml, v. a., berry, l. l., & parasuraman, a. (1996). the behavioral consequences of service quality. journal of marketing, 60(2), 31–46. https://doi.org/1251929 zhao, h., wayne, s., glibkowski, b., & bravo, j. (2007). the impact of psychological contract breach on work-related outcomes: a metaanalysis. personnel psychology, 60(3), 647–680. https://doi.org/10 .1111/j.1744-6570.2007.00087.x zhou, l., & whitla, p. (2013). how negative celebrity publicity influences consumer attitudes: the mediating role of moral reputation. journal https://doi.org/10.1177/0092010304267105 https://doi.org/10.1177/0092010304267105 https://doi.org/10.2501/s0021849906060181 https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-007-0037-1 https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-007-0037-1 https://doi.org/10.1080/0267257x.2013.778324 https://doi.org/10.1111/beer.12246 https://doi.org/10.1207/s15327663jcp1604_9 https://doi.org/10.1207/s15327663jcp1604_9 https://doi.org/1251929 https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1744-6570.2007.00087.x https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1744-6570.2007.00087.x 32 abed and büttgen / journal of business strategies (2022) 39:1-32 of business research, 66(8), 1013–1020. https://doi.org/10.10146 /j.jbusres.2011.12.025 zhu, d.-h., & chang, y.-p. (2013). negative publicity effect of the business founder’s unethical behavior on corporate image: evidence from china. journal of business ethics, 117(1), 111–121. https://doi.org/ 10.1007/s10551-012-1512-2 https://doi.org/10.10146/j.jbusres.2011.12.025 https://doi.org/10.10146/j.jbusres.2011.12.025 https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-012-1512-2 https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-012-1512-2 introduction theoretical background linking perceived negative corporate brand publicity and emotional corporate brand pride linking perceived negative corporate brand publicity, wom and employee referrals linking emotional corporate brand pride and attitudinal corporate brand pride linking attitudinal corporate brand pride and wom/employee referrals linking corporate brand experience through internal/external communications and perceived negative corporate brand publicity linking corporate brand experience through internal/external communications and emotional corporate brand pride method sample and procedure measures analysis results discussion limitations and implications for further research practical implications 110 journal of business strategies response of the cost of equity to leverage: an alternative perspective glenn n. pettengill grand valley state university • allendale, mi diane m. lander saint michael’s college • colchester, vt abstract in this paper we examine the change in a corporation’s cost of equity as the corporation increases leverage. standard textbook treatments present the wellknown modigliani-miller hypothesis that the cost of leverage increases linearly with increases in the debt-to-equity ratio in keeping with a constant cost of capital for the firm. less frequently, textbooks present the modigliani-miller argument that, if the cost of debt rises with high levels of leverage, the cost of equity will increase at a decreasing rate or even decline in order to keep the overall cost of capital constant. standard textbook presentations continue with additional discussions concerning tax effects and bankruptcy costs but without mention of the cost of equity. these presentations leave the impression that the cost of equity remains as presented in the modigliani-miller framework. in this paper we present theoretical and empirical arguments in support of our claim that the cost of equity increases slowly with moderate increases in debt but increases dramatically as leverage increases sufficiently to cause equity investors to fear bankruptcy. introduction what should students know about the cost of equity? two fundamental relationships form the core knowledge base that students should possess about the cost of equity, both from a corporate finance perspective and an investment perspective. first, because debt has a senior payment claim both in the case of normal business operations and in the case of bankruptcy, equity has more risk and the cost of equity is greater than the cost of debt. this holds regardless if the firm uses very little leverage or a great deal of leverage. second, because debt is cheaper than equity, increasing leverage may increase per unit payments to equity, but at the cost of increasing variability in these payments. this increase in financial risk causes equity owners to demand a higher percentage return. it is the path of volume 32, number 2 111 this increased required return to equity that we argue is inadequately addressed by textbooks and provides the focus of this paper. because textbook discussions of the relationship between the cost of equity and leverage typically depend on the theory developed by modigliani and miller, we continue with a discussion of their arguments. modigliani-miller model modigliani and miller’s (1958) nobel prize winning paper on capital structure still underpins textbook discussions of capital structure. at the core of their argument is the proposal that a firm’s value is determined solely by the cash flow and the risk of the cash flow created by the firm’s assets. thus, under perfect market conditions, the value of the firm, and hence its overall cost of capital, is not influenced by the decision to finance the firm by debt or by equity. this result is referred to as the irrelevance proposal, or as modigliani-miller proposition i (mm i), and is supported by the argument that investors can achieve whatever level of leverage they desire in their investment in a firm by borrowing on their own to supplement their personal equity investment (the “homemade leverage” argument). because using debt financing replaces the higher cost of equity with lower costing debt, in order for the cost of capital to remain constant, the cost of equity must increase with leverage and must do so at a prescribed rate as shown in equation (1) below. this relationship is referred to as modigliani-miller proposition ii (mm ii). rrequity = unlevered required return of equity + d/e * (roa – cost of debt) (1) where: rrequity is the required return on equity for a given level of leverage, d/e is the debt-to-equity ratio (measures leverage), and roa is the expected return on assets. the cost of debt is assumed to be constant across levels of leverage. thus, the required return to equity is a constantly increasing linear function of leverage as measured by the d/e ratio. a constantly increasing cost of equity is consistent with constantly increasing financial risk borne by equity holders as the total amount of fixed payments to debt holders increases with leverage. the rationale that this increase in cost can be measured by equation (1) above results because 112 journal of business strategies only this increase will maintain a constant overall cost of capital. to support the validity of mm ii, it is argued that, if the markets incorrectly price equity at any level inconsistent with the cost of equity as determined by equation (1), arbitrage profits will be available and market transactions will move the stock price to the correct level. modigliani and miller consider the relaxation of several key perfect market assumptions, including a constant cost of debt with increasing leverage and the absence of corporate taxes. they find their results robust to the relaxation of these assumptions.1 these results, although widely accepted in the academic community, conflict with the observed behavior of financial managers who clearly believe that the financing decision and the level of leverage used matters. furthermore, keeping the overall cost of capital constant in the face of a rising cost of debt required modigliani and miller to argue that the rate of increase in the cost of equity slowed, or even reversed, as leverage grew high, a seemingly illogical behavior on the part of equity investors. modigliani and miller (1963) revisit the tax issue and their revised results lead to the equally untenable position that the optimum capital structure is 100% debt. textbook treatment textbook discussions of the cost of equity, as included in descriptions of capital structure, provide a fairly standard representation of the effect of leverage on the cost of equity. we find this standard representation lacking in two important aspects. we next discuss the standard presentations and then identify the two aspects of these presentations that we suggest are inconsistent with rational investor behavior, short changing the student. textbook presentations generally begin with the modiglianimiller assumptions that capital markets are efficient and there is no tax on corporate earnings. they emphasize that the value of the firm is determined by the income produced by the firm’s assets and that this asset value does not change with the method of financing. thus, the total value of debt and equity remains constant across levels of leverage. these presentations generally identify this relationship as the modigliani-miller irrelevance proposition, or mm i. discussion of the cost of equity follows from this proposition. textbook presentations may or may not emphasize that the cost of equity is higher than the cost of debt due to lower risk for debt, but do indicate a higher cost of equity relative to the cost of debt. these presentations continue with a discussion of the impact of leverage on the cost of equity. the discussion shows that leverage creates a higher volume 32, number 2 113 eps for the stockholder, but at the cost of higher financial risk. the precise increase in the cost of equity is shown as a mathematical identity whereby the value of the firm is held constant in accordance with the basic proposition that the value of the firm is solely determined by the value of the firm’s assets. in this case, the cost of equity is determined by mm ii (equation (1)) and the overall cost of capital is determined by the cost of debt and cost of equity weighted by their respective book values.2 a graphic presentation of the cost of equity, cost of debt and cost of capital as leverage increases is normally provided. generally, the graphic presentation is made in debt-to-equity space revealing a linear relationship between leverage and the cost of equity.3 most textbooks explicitly recognize that the cost of debt does increase with increasing levels of leverage due to the fear of default. however, an explicit connection between the increasing cost of debt and the optimum capital structure is often absent. indeed, in some cases, the argument made is that an increase in the cost of debt is consistent with a constant overall cost of capital. for example in their undergraduate textbook, fundamentals of corporate finance, brealey, myers and marcus (2013)4 state that the overall cost of capital remains constant despite an increasing cost of debt: “essentially because holders of risky debt begin to bear part of the firm’s operating risk. as the firm borrows more, more of the risk is transferred from stockholders to bondholders” (p. 454). implicit in the statement is the assumption that stockholders remain essentially unscathed by bankruptcy. as did modigliani and miller, textbook discussions then relax the no corporate tax assumption resulting in the conclusion that an optimum capital structure consists of 100% debt. this result relies on the implicit assumption that the cost of equity remains the same as given by mm ii. thus, the increasing cost of equity that was just sufficient to offset the use of cheaper debt when debt offered no tax advantage is now insufficient to keep the overall cost of capital constant, resulting instead in an ever decreasing cost of capital with each incremental addition of a unit of debt to that capital structure. this unrealistic result begs for resolution, which is then presented by bankruptcy costs. textbooks generally present a resolution to the 100% debt dilemma by identifying a tradeoff between the upside of the tax reduction and the downside of increased bankruptcy cost. when interest expense is taxable5, as leverage increases, the higher total interest payments result in more tax deductions and lower taxes. the amount by which the higher interest payments lower taxes is commonly referred to as the interest expense tax shield. as leverage increases, however, the possibility of default also increases. bankruptcy results in a firm having to pay a number of, 114 journal of business strategies what can be significant, direct costs (e.g., legal, accounting, and administration fees) as well as indirect costs (e.g., loss of reputation and ability to purchase supplies/inventory on credit). the tradeoff theory suggests that an optimum capital structure exists when the present value of the tax shield equals the present value of bankruptcy costs. significantly, textbook discussions of bankruptcy costs do not include a discussion of the cost of equity. rather, bankruptcy costs appear to affect the debt holder. for example, brealey, myers and marcus (2013) state that, in the case of bankruptcy involving highly marketable assets such as hotel properties, “the direct bankruptcy costs are restricted to items such as legal and court fees, real estate commissions, and the time the lender spends sorting things out” (p. 461). notice, the cost is borne by the “lender.” of course, in this situation, the stockholder bears no additional cost because this investor has lost everything. but no mention is made of the stockholder’s loss. the student is left to assume the cost of equity must remain as provided by the mm ii equation, unaffected by fears of bankruptcy. textbooks frequently discuss indirect costs of bankruptcy as well. one indirect cost often discussed is the games shareholders are assumed to play at the expense of the bondholder (an example of agency). it may seem to the student that the stockholder actually relishes the prospect of bankruptcy. in many textbooks, the presentation of the tradeoff theory is supplemented with a further discussion of the financing decision. for example, textbooks frequently present the pecking order theory, in part to explain the lack of the utilization of the tax shield by highly profitable companies. yet these additional discussions remain silent about the cost of equity. again, the student is left to assume the cost of equity must remain as determined by the mm ii equation. in this paper, we argue that standard textbook explanations of capital structure are remiss for two reasons. first, we maintain that increases in the probability of bankruptcy do affect the cost of equity and find textbook presentations remiss because no consideration is given to this relationship. we argue this point in greater detail in section ii. second, we maintain that the issue for the corporation is its market value weighted cost of equity and again find textbook presentations remiss because book values are used to determine the cost of equity. modigliani and miller assume the value of the corporation is derived only from income produced by its assets and all earnings are paid out as dividends. textbook presentations emphasize the former and implicitly assume the latter, thus ignoring the possibility that market forces may price income streams differently depending on the division of the income stream. brealey, myers and marcus (2013, p. 446) provide an example relying on the wisdom of yogi berra to make the point to students that value is unchanged by volume 32, number 2 115 selecting different financing options. the story proceeds as follows: yogi is brought an after-game pizza. when asked by the delivery person whether he should slice the pizza, as usual, into four slices, yogi asks for the pizza to be sliced into eight pieces because he is especially hungry on this night.6 the moral is clear. slicing the pizza does not increase the total size of the pizza, thus implying that slicing the value of the corporation between debt and equity does not increase total asset value. we argue that the illustration misses the point that the market value of the corporation depends on the market value of the debt and equity issued by the corporation. we suggest that, just as a pizza vendor may be able to sell eight slices of a given pizza for more than four slices of the same pizza, even if the total size of the pizza remains the same, how the firm slices claims to its cash flow may make a difference as to the total value of the slices. we also argue this point in greater detail in section ii. in section iii we provide empirical evidence for our arguments. a conclusion is found in section iv. theoretical considerations implications of the modigliani-miller model we argue that rational investor response to moderate increases in leverage is inconsistent with key implications of modigliani-miller proposition ii. careful analysis of mm ii reveals several important implications of which we find no direct mention in extant literature. it is these key implications that we suggest are inconsistent with rational investor behavior. 116 journal of business strategies table 1: implications of modigliani-miller proposition ii for the prototype firm % debt 0.00% 10.00% 20.00% 30.00% 40.00% 50.00% 60.00% 70.00% 80.00% 90.00% d/e 0.00 0.11 0.25 0.43 0.67 1.00 1.50 2.33 4.00 9.00 shares out 2.00 1.80 1.60 1.40 1.20 1.00 0.80 0.60 0.40 0.20 earnings $10.00 $10.00 $10.00 $10.00 $10.00 $10.00 $10.00 $10.00 $10.00 $10.00 eas $10.00 $9.50 $9.00 $8.50 $8.00 $7.50 $7.00 $6.50 $6.00 $5.50 eps $5.00 $5.28 $5.63 $6.07 $6.67 $7.50 $8.75 $10.83 $15.00 $27.50 book equity $100 $90 $80 $70 $60 $50 $40 $30 $20 $10 robe 10.00% 10.56% 11.25% 12.14% 13.33% 15.00% 17.50% 21.67% 30.00% 55.00% mm ii rr 10.00% 10.56% 11.25% 12.14% 13.33% 15.00% 17.50% 21.67% 30.00% 55.00% share price $50 $50 $50 $50 $50 $50 $50 $50 $50 $50 st. dev. robe 5.00% 5.56% 6.25% 7.14% 8.33% 10.00% 12.50% 16.67% 25.00% 50.00% p/e 10.00 9.47 8.89 8.24 7.50 6.67 5.71 4.62 3.33 1.82 “earnings” and “eas” are in $millions. “eas” is earnings available to shareholders. “robe” is return to book equity. “st. dev. robe” is the standard deviation of return on book equity. the calculation of “st. dev. robe” value is described in end note 10. we report these key results in table 1 above for a “prototype firm” under various levels of leverage. based on assumed structural characteristics for the firm, we allow leverage to vary and identify required market results given that mm ii holds. we assume that the firm has assets of $100,000,000 with shares outstanding of 2,000,000, resulting in a market price of $50 per share for the unlevered firm. assuming market efficiency, the average annual return on investment, roi, is 10%. thus, on average, the firm has operating income of $10,000,000 (0.10 * $100,000,000). consistent with modigliani’s and miller’s analysis, we assume that all earnings are paid out as dividends. given the number of shares outstanding and market price per share, the firm has unlevered earnings per share (eps) of $5 ($10,000,000/2,000,000) and a price to earnings (p/e) ratio of 10 ($50/$5). finally, we assume the level of business risk for the “prototype firm” corresponds to a volume 32, number 2 117 required annual return of 10% for an unlevered equity investment and a standard deviation in annual returns of 5%. the first column in table 1 represents results, as described above, for the unlevered firm given assumptions about the firm’s operating characteristics and assuming mm ii holds. in each successive column, we increase the debt financing by 10%. in keeping with mm ii, we assume the cost of debt remains constant, which we set on an ex cathedra basis at 5%. we assume the additional debt is used to retire shares of equity. thus, in column 2 of table 1, 10% of the firm’s assets are financed by debt and 90% are financed by equity. as shown in the second row, the debt-toequity ratio (d/e) is 0.11 (0.10/0.90). the third row, labeled “shares out,” reports the number of shares outstanding in millions of shares. the unlevered firm, as described above, has 2,000,000 shares outstanding. as reported in table 1, when the firm is financed with 10% leverage, there now are 1,800,000 shares outstanding. financing 10% of the firm with debt requires issuing $10,000,000 in debt, which is used to buy back outstanding shares. at $50 a share, a total of 200,000 ($10,000,000/$50) shares are repurchased, leaving 1,800,000 (2,000,000 – 200,000) remaining shares outstanding. each subsequent 10% increase in debt financing results in the same number of shares being repurchased. thus, at 20% there are 1,600,000 shares outstanding, and so on. the fourth, fifth and sixth rows report earnings. row four, labeled “earnings,” reports the total earnings for the firm. we report average annual earnings in $millions which, according to assumptions made above, is 10% of the assets invested, or $10,000,000. the next row, labeled “eas,” reports the earnings available to shareholders in $millions, which is the $10,000,000 earned by the firm minus the debt payment given the debt outstanding and the 5% interest paid on debt. as shown in table 1, when the firm’s assets are financed 10% by debt, eas is $9,500,000 ($10,000,000 – (0.05 * $10,000,000)). increasing debt financing from 0% to 10% results in a $500,000 decrease in eas, and the eas continues to decrease by $500,000 for each additional 10% increase in debt financing given the fixed 5% interest charge. the sixth row reports earnings per share (eps). this value is calculated by dividing eas by the number of shares outstanding. as reported in table 1, eps is $5.28 ($9,500,000/1,800,000) when the firm’s assets are financed 10% by debt and $6.07 (48,500,000/1,400,000) when the firm’s assets are financed 30% by debt. eps increases monotonically with an increase in debt as the average roi of 10% is greater than the constant cost of debt of 5%. the next row reports “book equity” in $millions. given that the value of the firm’s assets does not change and, consistent with modigliani-miller proposition ii, 118 journal of business strategies the value of the firm does not change with leverage, book equity plus the amount of debt issued must always equal $100,000,000. therefore, book equity for the unlevered firm is $100,000,000 and with each debt issue of 10% of firm value, book equity declines by $10,000,000. because we have calculated both earnings available to shareholders and book equity, it is an easy matter to calculate return on book equity, robe.7 for the unlevered firm robe = roi = 10%. as with eps, robe increases monotonically with increases in leverage as the average roi of 10% is greater than the constant cost of debt of 5%; meaning the equity holders pocket the excess of roi over the constant cost of debt. when 10% of the firm is financed by debt, the average robe is 10.56% ($9.5/$90) and, when 30% of the firm is financed by debt, the average robe is 12.14% ($8.5/$70). in the next row we report the required return to equity as determined by mm ii using the well-known modigliani-miller equation (equation (1)). for example, this relationship provides a required return for equity of 10.56% when the firm’s assets are financed by 10% debt and 12.14% when the firm’s assets are financed by 30% debt as shown by equations (2) and (3) below. rrequity10% leverage = 10% + .111 * (10%– 5%) = 10.56% (2) rrequity30% leverage = 10% + .429 * (10%– 5%) = 12.14% (3) thus, the required return to equity, according to mm ii, is equal to the average robe. indeed, if this were not the case, mm i would not hold either. the equality, however, emphasizes the mechanical nature of mm ii and the lack of market behavior content in the hypothesis. mm ii is intended to indicate the required return for investors and, as such, the goal of mm ii should be to calculate rome, return on market equity. there is no analysis to indicate why investors would demand exactly the return that is being observed for book equity under various levels of leverage. the equality between robe and rome, as required by mm ii, results in a constant market price for equity shares regardless of the level of leverage. as shown in row 10 of table 1, the market share price, p, is a constant $50 across all levels of leverage. we know of no documentation of this unusual result, but it is easily illustrated from the data in table 1. recall that all earnings are paid out as dividends, so the rome is simply eps divided by the share price, p. thus rome= eps/p; and volume 32, number 2 119 p = eps/rome. as shown below in equation (4) for each level of leverage the share price is $50. eps/rome = $50 (4) = $5/0.10 = $5.28/0.1056 = $5.63/0.1125 = $6.07/0.1214 = $6.67/0.1333 = $7.50/0.15 = $8.75/0.1750 = $10.83/0.2167 = $15/0.30 = $27.50/0.55 the constant share price accompanied by the ever increasing eps across leverage levels leads to a monotonically decreasing price-to-earnings (p/e). and this ratio decreases dramatically. we find both the constant share price and the dramatic decrease in the p/e ratio to be suspect. in the next section we develop our arguments relative to this position. why mm ii should not hold across moderate levels of leverage as argued below, we find the supposition that the share price for a firm, with a given level of business risk, is constant across all levels of leverage to be untenable. because a constant share price across levels of leverage is required by mm ii, our position argues that mm ii does not hold. results presented in table 1 are based on assumptions about the firm size, number of shares outstanding for the unlevered firm and the level of business risk that associates with the given roi (10%) and cost of debt (5%) for our “prototype firm.” these assumptions imply a share price of $50, but mm ii requires a constant share price across all levels of leverage regardless of the exact price indicated by basic assumptions.8 thus, the mm ii result requires that investors are indifferent between the risk-return tradeoff existing at each level of leverage.9 to present the risk-return tradeoffs, we may compare expected return and standard deviation of return at every level of leverage. as reported in table 1, for each level of leverage, we calculated a return to book equity that is identical to the market return required by mm ii. we assumed a standard deviation of return of 5% for the unlevered firm, which we use to calculate standard deviation for every level of leverage.10 financial risk11 is clearly evident from our calculations. each increase in leverage results in an increase in variability of return and a dramatic increase in return for higher levels of leverage. note that the constant share price of mm ii still allows investors to be risk averse. at the various levels of leverage, investors are paying the same for one share. this share does have higher risk, as measured by the standard deviation of returns, 120 journal of business strategies for every level of risk, but the investor is being awarded higher payments. so investors are adhering to the risk-return tradeoff maxim. our argument with mm ii is not that the risk-return tradeoff is ignored, but that the risk-return tradeoff is forced to adhere to a particular indifference curve that does not have theoretical support and one which we find unreasonable. in the rest of this section, we present arguments suggesting that the cost of equity increases more moderately with leverage than dictated by mm i and mm ii. the data presented in table 1 is annual data. we present the expected annual returns and the standard deviation in annual returns consistent with mm ii. these calculations show that mm ii requires that investors are indifferent between accepting an expected annual return of 10% with a standard deviation of 5% for the unlevered firm or accepting an expected annual return of 15% with a standard deviation of 10% for the levered firm with 50% debt or accepting an expected annual return of 55% with a standard deviation of 50% for the levered firm with 90% debt. without a theoretical basis for this relationship we are suspect that it would actually hold. certainly the reward to risk ratio varies greatly across the options ranging from 2.00 for the unlevered position to 1.10 for the 90% debt position. one may argue that the constant share price implication is supported in that it requires book equity and market equity values to be the same. however, casual empiricism shows that book equity and market equity values are seldom the same. so, indeed, the required equality between book and market values argues against the validity of mm ii. thus, the modigliani-miller arbitrage process must be relied upon to support investors’ indifference across the observed risk-return tradeoffs, but, as noted above, this process is suspect. we next address the question of investor indifference and submit that investor reaction to changes in the risk-return tradeoff caused by the use of leverage is open to question. so, how should we describe the graphic presentation of the firm’s cost of equity to our students? we postulate that the cost of equity increases more slowly with moderate levels of leverage than envisioned by mm ii. we do not, of course, argue against the proposition that stockholders are risk averse. nor do we argue against the proposition that the use of leverage increases financial risk. instead, what we argue is that stockholder reaction to an increase in financial risk is exaggerated by mm ii for at least two reasons. first, casual observations of market behavior suggest a focus on earnings rather than variability in earnings. second, conventional means of measuring return and risk tend to exaggerate the impact of leverage. according to mm ii and as stated above, investors in our “prototype firm” are indifferent between the firm being unlevered, receiving an average annual return volume 32, number 2 121 of 10% with a standard deviation of 5%, or the firm being financed with 50% debt that would provide an average annual return of 15% with a standard deviation of 10%. it is our experience that, when we show students these choices, the students are not indifferent; they choose the higher return. of course, what is important is how actual market investors act. observation of market behavior and investment analyst pronouncements suggests to us that the students are in tune with market behavior. we posit that investors, although typically risk averse, are usually much more attuned to the return portion of the risk-return tradeoff than the risk portion. we posit that investors are more concerned about eps than the variability of eps. we argue that observable market behavior supports our position. a widely used tool by investment analysts is the p/e ratio. application of this tool encourages investors to increase the price that they pay for a stock when eps increases. indeed, there are numerous studies that indicate that following such a strategy “beats the market.” (see, for example, basu (1983)) there is no strategy that encourages investors to buy a stock when the return variability falls. further, the p/e strategy is not modified by a metric measuring variability in earnings. investors eagerly await earnings announcements. market pundits look for the “earnings season” to indicate market direction. these announcements are awaited to see if earnings are changing, not if the associated earnings variability is changing. such announcements move the market, and often the announcements are made after market close to dampen their impact. we do not rely here on casual observance alone, although the uniformity of market reaction may make such observations sufficient. numerous empirical studies show the long-term impact of positive and negative earnings announcements. studies of standardized unexpected earnings (sue) announcements show that unexpectedly high (low) earnings announcements lead to positive (negative) price drifts following the announcements. (see, for example, rendleman, et. al. (1982)) the variable sue is standardized by variability in earnings, not because investors are focused on variability in earnings, but rather to determine if the change in earnings is truly unusual. there is no measure that seeks to explain price changes by a change in the variability of earnings. under sue, if a firm announces a remarkably high quarterly eps, a signal would be given to buy. if variability were the focus, this unusual eps would be a sell signal as variability in earnings would be increased. empirical evidence shows that it is the buy signal that is followed! this general focus on earnings is further illustrated by what is reported in the financial press and on financial internet sites. investors know these outlets report firms’ epss and highlight their p/e ratios. yet these outlets do not typically report 122 journal of business strategies variability in earnings, which is the measure of financial risk. investors may find reports of debt ratios, which indicate leverage and financial risk, but these ratios are not routinely responsible for investment decisions. changes in earnings are. because investors focus on earnings, especially eps, the result of a moderate increase in leverage will tend to be positive, thus increasing the value of the firm. the required payment to equity is not enough to keep the value of the firm constant as suggested by mm ii and the cost of equity rises more slowly than suggested by mm ii. our second rationale supporting the hypothesis that stockholder reaction to an increase in financial risk is exaggerated by mm ii is that conventional means of measuring return and risk tend to exaggerate the impact of leverage. textbook examples showing the creation of financial risk using leverage invariably illustrate the risk with a one-year time horizon. this is common and generally accepted practice, but, in this case as in others, the choice of this time horizon may distort reality. we illustrate our concern first with an example that instructors frequently use to advise students as young investors. the instructor could present students with a risk-return tradeoff, comparing u. s. government debt, say, for example, treasury bills, with large-firm stocks. to illustrate, according to ibbotson (2014), from 1926 through 2013, the arithmetic average annual return to treasury bills is 3.5% and the standard deviation in annual returns is 3.1%. in contrast, for large-firm equities, the 1926 through 2013 arithmetic average annual return is 12.1% and the standard deviation in annual returns is 20.2%. the instructor could use this data to illustrate the tradeoff between risk and return and may find students who prefer the treasury bill over large-firm stocks when using a one-year investment horizon. and such a choice may be reasonable for an investment with a one-year horizon. but surely an instructor would council students against such a choice for retirement investment. a typical student would have 40 plus years until retirement. regardless of the extent of the student’s risk aversion, the student should not select treasury bills. there is no historic 40-year period where large-firm equities have a lower return than treasury bills. over this time horizon, large-firm equities are no longer riskier than treasury bills.12 using a one-year comparison provides a bias against the correct long-term investment choice. a similar, if less extreme, bias exists when comparing equity investment between firms with similar business risk but different levels of leverage. to illustrate the impact of time horizon in this case, we compare returns and risk for our hypothetical firm between the unlevered position and the same firm with moderate leverage levels of 10%, 30% and 50%. data in table 1 indicates the following riskvolume 32, number 2 123 return tradeoffs: the unlevered firm has an average return of 10.00% and a standard deviation of 5.00%; the firm financed with 10% debt has an average return of 10.56% and a standard deviation of 5.56%; the firm financed with 30% debt has an average return of 12.14% and a standard deviation of 7.14%; the firm financed with 50% debt has an average return of 15.00% and a standard deviation of 10.00%. mm ii requires that investors as a whole are indifferent between these four choices. certainly individual investors might prefer any one of the four choices for a one-year investment. but what would the impact of a longer term time horizon have on an investor’s choice between these four levels of leverage? to gain insight into this choice, we simulate 1,000 annual revenue flows13 to the firm with an average annual return of 10% and a 5% standard deviation. then we calculate the annual returns to the unlevered firm and the percentage return for the four levels of leverage listed above. we then use this data to calculate overlapping three-year returns and overlapping ten-year returns for each of the four leverage levels. we calculate the average one-year, three-year and ten-year return and the standard deviations for these return series. we report these results in table 2. table 2: average returns and return standard deviations--various time horizons and various levels of leverage time horizon/ leverage unlevered 10% debt 30% debt 50% debt one-year 10.03%(5.10%) 10.59% (5.65%) 12.19% (7.27%) 15.06% (10.19%) three-year 33.25%(10.70%) 35.30% (12.04%) 41.26% (15.86%) 52.44% (23.28%) ten-year 160.58%(38.02%) 173.91% (44.53%) 216.28% (65.12%) 307.68% (114.90%) each cell reports the average return and the standard deviation (shown in parentheses) for a given level of leverage and a given time horizon. the values result from the same simulation of 1,000 annual returns. the returns for the levered positions are based on a constant 5% cost of debt, consistent with our earlier examples. we report these key results in table 1 above for a “prototype firm” under various levels of leverage. based on assumed structural characteristics for the firm, we allow leverage to vary and identify required market results given that mm ii holds. we assume that the firm has assets of $100,000,000 with shares outstanding of 2,000,000 resulting in a market price of $50 per share, assuming market efficiency, for the unlevered firm. finally, we assume the level of business 124 journal of business strategies risk for the “prototype firm” corresponds to a required annual return of 10% for an unlevered equity investment of $10,000,000 (0.10 * $100,000,000). consistent with modigliani’s and miller’s analysis, we assume that all earnings are paid out as dividends. given the number of shares outstanding and market price per share, the firm has unlevered earnings per share (eps) of $5 ($10,000,000/2,000,000) and a price to earnings (p/e) ratio of 10 ($50/$5). to provide this different perspective, we use the same simulated 1,000 annual returns to assets and the corresponding one-year, three-year and ten-year returns for the unlevered position and each of the three levered positions, the average of which we reported in table 2, but this time compare the levered and unlevered positions across each observation of overlapping 3-year and 10-year returns. on a period by period basis, we compare the returns and identify the percent of the periods when the unlevered position outperformed each of the three levered positions. the results are presented in table 3. table 3: percent of periods when the unlevered positions outperformed the unlevered position time horizon/ leverage 10% debt 30% debt 50% debt one-year 14.90% 14.90% 14.90% three-year 3.91% 4.01% 4.31% ten-year 1.01% 1.01% 1.01% in our example, consistent with modigliani’s and miller’s analysis, the firm pays a constant 5% for debt. thus, any year in which roi is less than 5% all levered positions will underperform the unlevered position. in our simulation, this occurs for 14.90% of the years. an investor with a one-year time horizon faces a reasonable probability that the unlevered position would outperform a levered position. but, as the time horizon for holding the investment increases, the likelihood that the investor would ever be better off with the unlevered position diminishes. for investors with a three-year holding period, the number of periods in which the unlevered position provides a better return is around 4% with the probability increasing as leverage increases. finally, if the investor holds the position for 10 years, there is only a 1%14 chance that the unlevered position outperforms any of the levered positions. for volume 32, number 2 125 an investor with a ten-year investment horizon, financial risk virtually disappears. if we assume two firms with the exact same return on assets and the exact same business risk, and further assume that one firm has no debt while the other has a moderate level of debt, an investor with a ten-year time horizon should pay more for the levered firm. the additional financial risk from leverage will impact an investor with a one-year time horizon, but not this investor. in summary, we maintain that moderate levels of leverage increase the value of the firm because equity investors are less concerned with financial risk than assumed by mm ii. we argued this on the basis that investors in general focus more on returns than risk. we also argued that financial risk resulting from leverage causes little increases in risk for the long-term investor and that this investor will pay more for shares of a levered firm than for shares of an unlevered firm identical in all other characteristics. but will this investor influence market price? some market participants do not care at all about financial risk. for example, high-frequency traders, who account for a significant percent of market volume, are not concerned about financial risk caused by leverage. instead, high frequency traders care about the immediate direction of the market. likewise, momentum traders are completely unconcerned about financial risk; they buy and sell stocks assuming that recent price trends will continue. indeed, all market timers including technicians are blithely unaware of any impact from financial risk. mm ii only holds if investors are fundamentalists who weigh risk against return. and, for these investors, as we have argued, their time horizons must be short enough so that financial risk provides a sufficiently large probability that leverage will reduce return so that the investors are unwilling to pay for an increase in eps. we submit that these conditions are so restrictive as to make mm ii improbable and that the increase in eps created by leverage will increase firm value. why mm ii should not hold at extreme levels of leverage how do equity holders react to extreme levels of leverage? we suggest above that equity holders should react by demanding payment for bankruptcy risk in addition to payment for financial risk. it is accepted that, at high levels of leverage, debtors react by demanding higher payments because of bankruptcy risk. in other words, lenders demand higher interest payments because they fear they will not receive full payment. modigliani and miller (1958) recognize this possibility yet suggest that, at high levels of leverage, equity investors might react by decreasing their required return below that suggested by mm ii. this reduction in the expected 126 journal of business strategies cost of equity is required in order to offset the increasing cost of debt so that the overall cost of capital remains constant. but why should equity holders be willing to accept a less than “fair” payment for financial risk in the face of increasing default risk? do equity holders somehow benefit from increasing risk of bankruptcy? or why is it that equity holders do not fear a high increased bankruptcy risk associated with high levels of debt? the finance discipline has not responded in a constructive manner to this dilemma! textbook presentations recognize a tradeoff between the present value of the tax benefits of debt and the present value of bankruptcy costs that occur with increasing levels of debt. these bankruptcy costs are direct costs, such as legal fees, and indirect costs, such as the ability to purchase supplies/inventory on credit, both of which are very different from “fear of bankruptcy” additional payments demanded by bond holders and lenders. what a paradox that bond holders receive payment for bankruptcy risk but not stock holders! moreover, bond holders receive payment before equity holders, and, when bankruptcy occurs, equity holders may lose their entire investment before bond holders suffer any loss. indeed, this difference in priority alone justifies the higher payment to equity relative to debt at any level of leverage. is it not logical then, that when the probability of bankruptcy is high, because of a combination of business risk and leverage, that equity holders will demand a very high return? this should be observed in the market by investors lowering equity prices when bankruptcy looms in order to receive a very high return if, somehow, the firm overcomes the business risk from operations and the financial risk from leverage. empirical evidence moderate increases in leverage we have argued that, with moderate increases in leverage, the cost of equity grows more slowly than required by mm ii and that, for very highly levered firms, the cost of equity rises precipitously. our arguments, of course, run counter to widely held dogma and will likely be received with some reservation. we point out, however, that there are implications of mm ii, such as the constant share price across leverage, which seem quite suspect. still it behooves us to look for empirical evidence in support of mm ii. possible sources of empirical evidence to support mm ii could consist of: 1) evidence of arbitrage activity to establish mm ii equilibrium; 2) evidence of increases volume 32, number 2 127 in the cost of equity as leverage increases among similar firms; 3) evidence of equal share price, scaled for asset size and shares outstanding, as leverage increases among similar firms; 4) evidence of constantly decreasing p/e ratios as leverage increases among similar firms. the last three possibilities are consistent with relationships reported in table 1. with regard to possibility 1, we simply note that we know of no report of arbitrage activity to support mm ii equilibrium. possibility 2 presents timing difficulties and measurement issues as it is not obvious how the reported changes in debt ratios match reported returns to equity associated with changing debt ratios. possibility 3 reduces the timing issues but presents the difficulty of scaling as price will depend on decisions concerning the number of shares outstanding relative to a given value of book equity. possibility 4 also reduces the timing issue and has the advantage of removing the difficult scaling problem. so, we conduct an empirical test of possibility 4. our sample first consists of the firms comprising the dow jones industrial average (djia) as of january 1, 2009. we then eliminate the four financial firms (american express company; bank of america; jpmorgan chase & co.; the travelers companies, inc.) because the nature of their financial structure has the potential to bias our results. finally, we further adjust our sample by adding nike, inc., which was added to the djia on september 20, 2013. thus our final sample includes twenty-seven firms from the djia. we gather data for these firms for a five-year period: 2009 through 2013. this sample should provide a general similarity in firm business risk allowing an opportunity to measure the impact of changes in the debt ratio. we then calculate the debt ratio at the end of each fiscal year. (a description of the procedure used to determine the debt ratios is found in appendix 1.) there is a considerable range of debt ratios across our twenty-seven sample firms, but in all cases the ratios may be considered to represent moderate to low levels of leverage. table 4 reports the firms with the two highest and the two lowest debt ratios among the twenty-seven firms for each of the five sample years and reports the value of the debt ratios. debt ratios for all twenty-seven firms for each year are available from the authors. 128 journal of business strategies table 4: extreme sample observations of debt ratios by years 2009 highest next highest next lowest lowest ratio 35.00% 28.90% 4.18% 4.12% firm mcdonald’s dupont intel exxon 2010 highest next highest next lowest lowest ratio 35.98% 32.11% 4.11% 3.35% firm mcdonald’s coca-cola nike intel 2011 highest next highest next lowest lowest ratio 37.89% 35.72% 4.85% 4.42% firm mcdonald’s coca-cola chevron nike 2012 highest next highest next lowest lowest ratio 38.52% 37.80% 3.47% 2.49% firm mcdonald’s coca-cola exxon nike 2013 highest next highest next lowest lowest ratio 41.17% 38.58% 6.55% 5.78% firm coca-cola mcdonald’s exxon general electric we also gather the p/e ratio for each firm in our sample for each of the five years in our sample period. (a description of the procedure used to determine the p/e ratios is also found in appendix 1.) we conduct ordinary least square regressions of the debt ratio against the p/e ratio. we conduct separate regressions for each of the five sample years. as described above, according to mm ii, increases in financial risk should increase the required cost of equity in a prescribed manner, leaving share price unchanged but constantly decreasing the p/e ratio. support for mm ii would be found if the changes in the debt ratio explain a significant part of the variation in the p/e ratios and if the slope coefficient for the debt ratio is significantly negative showing a decrease in the p/e ratio across firms as leverage increases. our results, shown in table 5, provide no evidence to support the mm ii position. as shown in table 2, according to mm ii, the p/e ratio should show a constant decrease with increases in the debt ratio. our results indicate that there is no relationship between the debt ratio and the p/e ratio for our sample firms. in four of the five years, the adjusted r-squared is less than zero. in three of the five volume 32, number 2 129 years the slope coefficient, inconsistent with mm ii, is positive. in no case is the relationship with the debt ratio and the p/e ratio significant at the 0.10 level. the relationship is strongest for 2011, but in this year the relationship is contrary to the mm ii hypothesis. thus, comparing the debt and p/e ratios of our sample djia firms provides no evidence in support of mm ii. rather, the evidence is consistent with the view that with moderate levels of leverage the cost of equity rises slowly.15 table 5: annual regressions of p/e ratios against debt ratios for sample dija firms year 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 adjusted r-squared -4.13% -3.36% 5.31% -2.20% -4.15% y-intercept 14.79 15.24 9.71 13.42 16.56 slope coefficient -0.013 0.198 0.285 0.361 -0.064 t-statistic -0.09 0.39 1.57 0.68 -0.05 we conduct ordinary least square regressions for each of the five sample years, regressing debt ratios against p/e ratios. we omit any observation with a negative p/e ratio resulting in a sample size of 26 for years 2009, 2012, and 2013. there are no omissions for 2010 and 2011 resulting in a sample size of 27. extreme leverage we have argued that, when extreme levels of leverage cause bondholders to demand higher returns because of bankruptcy fears, equity holders must also be increasing the required return in excess of what otherwise would be demanded as payment for financial risk. as equity holders will lose before bondholders, they must logically demand payment for bankruptcy risk if bondholders are demanding payment for bankruptcy risk. providing empirical evidence of this relationship is fraught with difficulties in separating the price impact of bankruptcy fears from other factors. and, we would not expect to find evidence of new equity issues when bankruptcy risk is high because of the expected high cost of such an issue. we, therefore, seek to find anecdotal evidence of the behavior of equity holders when bankruptcy fear has been high. one may argue that, in recent market experience, the 2008 financial crisis would provide a time when bankruptcy fear was high for selected firms in financial distress. we use a year-end financial article, kiviat (2008), to identify firms with 130 journal of business strategies big loses during 2008. these were firms where stockholders feared bankruptcy. according to modigliani and miller (1958) and brealey, myers and marcus (2013), when lenders begin to worry about bankruptcy because of high leverage, they demand a higher return, but stockholders reduce the rate at which their required return would normally increase to compensate for financial risk. we have argued that stockholders should fear bankruptcy more than bondholders. when bankruptcy looms, therefore, stockholders should demand a higher return than otherwise required to compensate for financial risk. although this higher required return will not be observable from new stock issues, the higher return will be observed when new stockholders purchase outstanding shares at prices sufficiently low so as to guarantee high returns if the firm survives. to see if our expectations are met, we determine the return to the firms identified in kiviat (2008) from their low point in 2008 through the end of our sample period december 2013. (we add ford motor company to our sample because of the publicity surrounding ford’s possible bankruptcy during the fall of 2008.) if our argument is correct, the shares of firms that suffered large loses in 2008 would be sold at distress prices reflecting the new investors’ high required returns. if the firms survived, the new investors should enjoy high actual returns reflecting their high required return engendered by the fear of bankruptcy. on the other hand, for some of the firms the investors’ fears should be realized. these firms should experience bankruptcy and a return of -100%. to determine actual returns, from the 2008 nadir to the end of 2013, we search yahoo finance for the lowest adjusted close in 2008 and compare that return to the adjusted close reported on yahoo finance for december 31, 2013. results reported in table 6 indicate that this was exactly what happened. surviving firms experienced very high returns indeed and some firms experienced a return of -100%. we submit this result as anecdotal evidence that when high levels of leverage engender fear of bankruptcy, the cost of equity climbs steeply in opposition to the supposition of modigliani and miller. volume 32, number 2 131 table 6: returns to extreme losers of 2008 company 2008 lowest adjusted close dec 31 2013 adjusted close 2008 to 2013 gain aig $22.10 $50.58 129% ambac $0.76 $24.56 3,132% borders $0.37 $0.00 -100% crocs $0.94 $15.92 1,594% fannie mae $0.30 $3.01 3,078% ford $1.17 $14.95 1,178% freddie mac $0.23 $7.31 3,078% mf global $1.73 $0.00 -100% pier 1 imports $0.31 $22.73 7,232% ruby tuesday $1.08 $6.93 542% conclusions we have argued that textbook presentations of the response of stockholder required return to equity is deficit in two important aspects. in both cases, we argue, these deficits associate with an uncritical acceptance of the modigliani and miller (1958) propositions. specifically, we argue that: 1) at moderate levels of leverage, the required return to equity rises less than postulated by modigliani and miller because equity investors’ reaction to leverage emphasizes the higher expected eps rather than the additional financial risk; and 2) at high levels of leverage, when debt holders demand compensation for bankruptcy risk, stockholders will also demand compensation for bankruptcy risk. the latter argument is in contrast to the modigliani-miller argument that, when bankruptcy risk is high, stockholders will reduce the payment required for financial risk. if one accepts our arguments, then the modigliani-miller irrelevance proposition does not hold. we support our theoretical arguments by two empirical studies. examination of the relationship between debt and p/e ratios among sample djia securities over a five-year period fails to find an inverse relationship between these ratios as required by the modigliani-miller propositions. further, we show that during the 2008 market crisis for firms that appeared to be in danger of bankruptcy, new stockholders demanded a very high 132 journal of business strategies expected return as evidenced by the low prices they paid for the stocks and the subsequent high actual returns if the firms avoided bankruptcy. given these results, instructors could discuss optimum capital structure using the sketch below (figure 1). the instructor can explain that the cost of equity, ke, is more than the after-tax cost of debt, kd, at every level of leverage for two reasons. first, payment to debt holders is more certain. the instructor can emphasize the certain payment to the bondholder required by the bond indenture relative to the uncertain payment to the shareholder. second, the payment to debt is tax deductible. to illustrate this point, the instructor may wish to provide a simple income statement example. the instructor can show how both of these benefits result in a higher expected eps for the stock holder. the instructor could then use a simple wacc example to show how the overall cost of capital would fall using debt. the instructor would need to take care, however, to emphasize the downside of using more debt to the stockholders. a careful example showing multi-year returns or multiple scenarios for a single year could introduce the topic of financial risk. this provides the instructor with another chance to emphasize the risk-reward tradeoff showing an increase in ke. as we have argued, however, we feel that the instructor should show a declining overall cost of capital, because of both the tax effect and the relatively slow increase in ke at moderate levels of leverage. finally, the instructor can emphasize, the increase in both ke and kd as both the bond holders and stockholders begin to fear bankruptcy. we feel that this discussion should emphasize the loss of invested wealth rather than the emphasis on legal costs of bankruptcy that textbooks tend to emphasize. volume 32, number 2 133 figure 1: sketch of cost of capital versus leverage f in a n ci n g c o st percentage of debt financing0% 100% kd ke wacc of course, these are not the only topics that an instructor may wish to cover when discussing a corporation’s decision between issuing debt or equity. among other possible topics an instructor could include are indirect costs of bankruptcy, effect of a debt issue on financial control, need to preserve financial slack, pecking order considerations in issuing debt versus equity. on a purely theoretical level, the instructor may wish to discuss the topics of homemade leverage and the modiglianimiller arbitrage action in support of mm ii. appendix 1 procedure for determining debt ratios a. fiscal year end (fye) financial statements are obtained from annual reports, 10ks, or both. all dollars are in millions. for companies whose fye is in january or february, data is from 2010 to 2014. for all other companies, data is from 2009 to 2013. 134 journal of business strategies b. total assets included cash equivalents, marketable securities, etc.; assets for sale; investments; and financing related assets (e.g., notes receivables). if the company has a separate financing subsidiary (caterpillar, general electric), the subsidiaries “total assets” were excluded. c. total liabilities included short-term notes payable, current portion of long-term debt due, long-term debt, and short-term and long-term capital leases if itemized on the balance sheet. capital leases are assumed not material if not itemized on the balance sheet. if the company has a separate financing subsidiary (caterpillar, general electric), the subsidiaries financing line items were excluded, similar to how “total assets” were adjusted. procedure for determining price/earnings ratios a. stock prices at fiscal year end (fye) 2009 through 2013 were downloaded from http://finance.yahoo.com/. because home depot and walmart have january fyes, the prices for those companies are from 2010 through 2014. the specific values are the adjusted close prices closest to but not past the fye date or month as given the fye financials. for example, if a company has a december 31st fye, the december 31st 2013, december 31st 2012, december 30th 2011, december 31st 2010, and december 31st 2009 adjusted close prices are used. b. annual earnings per share (eps) companies report “basic” eps and “diluted” eps in their fye financials. the “basic” eps value is used for determining the p/e ratios. further, “basic” eps can consist of both eps from continuing operations and eps from other activities (e.g., discontinued operations). some companies break out the “basic” eps into these two components, some do not. for those companies that did not, the eps from continuing operations was not readily apparent and the eps used is the net (total) “basic” eps. end notes 1. lander and pettengill (2012) show that the modigliani-miller arbitrage process, and thus both mm i and mm ii, are inconsistent with an increase in the cost of debt with increasing leverage. 2. book values do not change when all earnings are paid out as dividends. also textbooks do not mention market values implicitly making the assumption that market values equal book values. volume 32, number 2 135 3. an exception to this presentation is provided by brigham and daves (2013) where the graphic presentation of the cost of equity is shown in debt ratio space. lander and pettengill (2010) argue that presentation of the cost of equity in the standard debt-to-equity space provides students with an inappropriate impression that the increase in the cost of equity is moderate at high levels of leverage. 4. we choose to exemplify textbook examples using the brealey, myers and marcus undergraduate textbook because of the high regard with which this textbook is held and the special rigor of their undergraduate text. we examine other textbooks listed in the reference to ensure consistency with our comments. 5. the interest expense deduction is not available in all countries. estonia, for example, has no corporate tax. 6. miller is quoted using this example to summarize their theory quickly in tanous (1997). 7. the normal calculation of return on equity, roe, is calculated as earnings available to shareholders divided by book equity value. we take the liberty of labeling this value robe because of the importance of the difference in return to book value and return to market value for our analysis. 8. the precise assumption made concerning the level of business risk as measured by the standard deviation of returns and the required return for that business risk do not affect the resulting conclusions. if, for example, we had assumed an average annual return of 8% with a standard deviation in annual returns of 4%, we still would have reached the conclusion that share prices would be constant across all levels of leverage if mm ii were to hold absolutely. the exact price would depend on the ratio of total assets to shares outstanding for the unlevered firm. a firm with $200,000,000 in assets and 8,000,000 shares outstanding would dictate a constant price of $25. 9. investors are indifferent because they equally value, in present value terms, each risk-return tradeoff. consider two assets. the first has a one year effective life, is expected to generate $105 at the end of year 1, and has a 5% expected rate of return. in present value terms, this asset is worth $100. the second also has a one year effective life, but is expected to generate $110 at the end of year 1, and has a 10% expected rate of return. in present value terms, this asset also is worth $100. we would say investors are indifferent, in present value terms to the two assets. 136 journal of business strategies 10. the expected return to the firm with any given level of leverage may be determined as follows: robe = ((ebi – i)/(k * ta)), where robe is return to book equity, ebi is expected earnings before interest, i is the constant interest payment for the level of leverage, k is 1 – the percent of debt (in decimal format) and ta is total assets. expected return to the unlevered firm is assumed to be normally distributed with a mean of 10% and a standard deviation of 5%. the variance of expected returns is determined as (1/k)2 * var(ebi/ta). for the unlevered firm, the variance of expected returns is (1/1)2 * (25%) = 25%. when the firm is 10% debt financed, the variance of expected returns is (1/0.9)2 * (25%) = 30.86%. the standard deviation reported in table 1 is the square root of this value. 11. instructors may find the calculation of standard deviation a more effective way of illustrating financial risk than the traditional one year’s return with three states of nature: good, ordinary and bad. 12. for an alternative view see pastor and stambaugh (2012). 13. we ran the simulation 10 times with each simulation including 1,000 revenue observations. from these 10 simulations we selected for presentation the simulation that provided results closest to the assumed firm structure. this selection does not bias our comparison between leverage levels, but merely allows our comparisons to be made with the assurance that our comparisons are made with data that are consistent with the annual returns calculated in table 1. 14. the 1% is as high as it is because of an extreme outlier in an annual return. in one year, the simulation showed an annual return of less than -37%. this annual return was included in ten of the ten-year overlapping return periods. in each one of these ten-year periods, but in no other ten-year period, the unlevered firm outperforms. this extreme value was more than 8 standard deviations below the mean; the highest annual return was just three standard deviations above the mean. we suspect that if the simulation was run again there would be zero periods in which the unlevered position outperforms over a ten-year period. in the interest of academic integrity, we report results from the original simulation. 15. we also test for a relation between leverage and the cost of equity. we find the debt ratios for our sample firms as described in appendix 1. the five-year returns to equity from the 12/13/08 to 12/31/13 adjusted close prices (yahoo finance). there should be a positive relationship between the debt ratio and the cost of equity if mm ii holds. we run two regressions. first we regress the 2009 debt ratio against the five-year return for each firm in our sample with the following results: r2= 0.61%, adjusted r2= -3.36%; the sample regression line volume 32, number 2 137 of the 2009 debt ratio against the five-year return to equity is y= 30.03% + 0.16 * x with t=0.39 for the slope coefficient. we also regressed the change in the debt ratio over the five-year period against the five-year return for each firm with the following results: r2= 0.90%, adjusted r2= -3.06%; the sample regression line of the 2009 to 2013 change in debt ratio against the five-year return to equity is y= 34.10% 0.30 * x with t=0.47 for the slope coefficient. contrary to the very basis of mm ii, we find no evidence of increased required return with regard to moderate increases in leverage. references basu, s. (1983). the relationship between earnings yield, market value and return for nyse common stocks: further evidence. journal of financial economics, 12, 129-156. brealey, r., myers, s. & marcus, a. (2013). fundamentals of corporate finance (7th ed.). boston, ma: mcgraw-hill irwin. ibbotson sbbi classic yearbook: market results for stocks, bonds, bills, and inflation 1926-2012. (2014). chicago il: morningstar, inc. kiviat, b. (2008, december 16). stock winners (yes, there were a few) and losers of ’08. time. retrieved from http://content.time.com/time/business/ article/0,8599,1866799,00.html lander, d. m., & pettengill, g. n. (2010). enhancing understanding of the 1958 modigliani-miller propositions. journal of instructional techniques in finance, 2(1), 35-40. lander, d. m., & pettengill, g. n. (2012). are increasing interest rates from leverage consistent with modigliani-miller arbitrage? journal of instructional technology in finance, 4(1), 1-8. modigliani, f., & miller, m. (1958). the cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. american economic review, 48(3), 261-297. modigliani, f., & miller, m. (1963). taxes and the cost of capital: a correction. american economic review, 53(3), 433-443. pastor, l., & stambaugh, r. (2012). are stocks really less volatile in the long run? journal of finance, 67(2), 431-478. rendleman, r. j. jr., jones, c. p., & latane, h. a. (1982). empirical anomalies based on unexpected earnings and the importance of risk adjustments. journal of financial economics 10, 269-287. tanus, j. (1997). investment gurus. englewood cliffs, nj: new york institute of finance. 138 journal of business strategies other textbooks examined berk, j., & demarzo, p. (2013). corporate finance (3rd ed.). boston, ma: pearson. booth, l., cleary, w. s., & drake, p. (2013). corporate finance. hoboken, nj: john wiley & sons. brigham, e., & daves, p. (2013). intermediate financial management (11th, ed.). mason, oh: south-western, cengage learning. parrino, d., kidwell, d., & bates, d. (2014). fundamentals of corporate finance (3rd ed.). hoboken, nj: john wiley & sons. short biographical sketch of authors glenn pettengill is a professor of finance at grand valley state university. he earned his phd in economics from the university of arkansas. his research focuses on market efficiency, asset pricing, and finance education. pettengill has served as president, program chair, and executive director for the midwest finance association. diane m. lander is an associate professor in the business administration and accounting department at saint michael’s college. she earned her phd in finance from the university of kansas. her research focuses on real asset valuation techniques, both traditional discounted cash flow models and the real options approach to capital budgeting, and finance education. volume 32, number 2 17 the role of psychic distance in internationalization strategy evaluations and strategic choices stephen horner pittsburg state university • pittsburg, ks daniel baack university of denver • denver, co donald baack pittsburg state university • pittsburg, ks abstract this analysis examines views of the term “psychic distance” and its application to the strategic choice process and managerial arrangements in international operations. it offers a background and conceptual framework of psychic distance, which stresses individual experience as part of the process. individual experience is explored in terms of its components and through the use of information processing models that appear in the marketing literature. next, applications to strategic management are made with regard to the choice to enter specific international markets, modes of entry selected, and the managerial structures that will be established. introduction one major decision facing executives in many companies is in regard to conducting business with or in another country. such a choice affects activities throughout the organization, while the actual judgements regarding whether to internationalize and how to do so boil down to the conclusions drawn by individual managers. the concept of psychic distance, which appears frequently in the international business literature, applies to a variety of theoretical models that relate to this strategic management concern, especially with regard to internationalization strategies and strategic choice processes. the international business literature suggests that psychic distance influences strategic decision makers as they consider expansion into international markets. it may play a role in strategic decisions about whether or not to pursue international expansion, the choice of entry mode (exporting, licensing, franchising, joint ventures, strategic alliances, wholly owned subsidiaries, acquisitions (minority, majority, total), and greenfield ventures), as well as subsequent levels of international affiliate performance. although the concept has been in use for many years (beckermann, 18 journal of business strategies 1956) some complain that applications of the concept are unclear (see shenkar 2001) and the construct has been criticized (stottinger & schlegelmilch, 1998). this analysis examines views of the term “psychic distance” and its application to the strategic choice process and managerial arrangements in international operations. the first section provides a background explaining how the psychic distance concept emerged, primarily within the field of the international business, and to a lesser degree, international marketing. a conceptual framework of psychic distance is then offered. the framework stresses individual perceptual processing of psychic distance, both at the national and business levels, through individual experience. individual experience is explored in terms of its components and through the use of information processing models that appear in the marketing literature. next, applications to strategic management are made. the final section offers some basic conclusions. background and conceptualization of psychic distance welch and luostarinen (1988) defined psychic distance “as the sum of factors preventing the flow of information from and to the market” (in johanson & vahlne, 1977, p. 23; revised 2009). another definition of psychic distance suggests it represents “the mind’s processing, in terms of perception and understanding, of cultural and business differences” (evans, treadgold, & mavondo, 2000, p.375). conceptually, psychic distance may be divided into three components: cultural affinity, trust, and individual experience. cultural affinity includes national level differences, including cultural differences, language, and the legal environment. trust is a business level (rather than national level) consideration that represents the level of confidence between members of companies in an international business relationship. personal experience is strongly linked to the initial discussions of psychic distance and becomes an individual, rather than national or business-level consideration. these components led baack and baack (2006) to describe the construct in the following manner: psychic distance may be viewed as the aggregate of national distance and business distance being processed through individual experience. figure 1 provides a model of this conceptualization as it would apply to strategic management. volume 32, number 2 19 figure 1 a psychic distance conceptual framework this conceptualization essentially divides psychic distance into two components: psychic and distance. distance, refers to differences between domestic and foreign markets, which differences occur at both the national and business levels. these factors create the knowledge deficiencies that individuals must overcome. psychically, knowledge deficiencies are then processed through personal mental processes. therefore, this definition and conceptual model suggest that the impact of distance will be interpreted through individual experience. a review of the literature suggests that individual experience directly affects perceptions of psychic distance. evans and mavondo (2002) write that differences between countries result from an individual’s perceptions of another country’s general values and attitudes. the johanson and vahlne (1977; 2009) definition of psychic distance views it in terms of information flow from source to source, or from individual to individual. these individuals along with their experiences affect perceptions of psychic distance. mitra and golder (2002), using a model that includes both knowledge and distance, found that the distance between markets, when isolated, has no effect on the entry decision. instead, it is only in the context of individual knowledge that distance plays a role. consequently, the framework displayed as figure 1 represents a modification of the way in which psychic distance may be viewed. the construct moves beyond cultural distance to include additional national differences and business level differences. as noted, psychic distance only impacts managerial activities as it is interpreted through individual perceptions and experiences. a further elaboration of these components follows. components: cultural affinity, trust, and individual experience. cultural affinity includes national level differences, including cultural differences, language, and the legal environment. trust is a business level (rather than national level) consideration that represents the level of confidence between members of companies in an international business relationship. personal experience is strongly linked to the initial discussions of psychic distance and becomes an individual, rather than national or business-level consideration. these components led baack and baack (2006) to describe the construct in the following manner: psychic distance may be viewed as the aggregate of national distance and business distance being processed through individual experience. figure 1 provides a model of this conceptualization as it would apply to strategic management. figure 1 a psychic distance conceptual framework psychic distance outcomes nation distance: cultural distance administrative distance geographic distance economic distance individual experience business distance industry distance firm distance entry decision entry mode choice managerial structure 20 journal of business strategies nation distance the first component of psychic distance, nation distance, includes dimensions of cultural, administrative, geographic, and economic distance, which comprise the cage distance framework (ghemawat, 2001). these four dimensions emphasize the importance of relative distance rather than absolute metrics (e.g., cost structures, market access, market size, and markets’ purchasing power). each dimension plays a role in creating perceptions of psychic distance as interpreted through the individual experiences of organizational members. cultural distance has served as a surrogate for psychic distance. national culture consists of the systems of values and norms shared by nationals that in aggregate provide a design for living that are then reflected in the workplace (hill, 2011). differences in national cultures are expressed in language, ethnicity, religion, and social norms (ghemawat, 2001). shenkar (2001) noted that few constructs have gained as much acceptance in the international business literature as cultural distance. it appears in studies in the fields of management, marketing, finance, and accounting. the concept has also been used to investigate innovation patterns (gomez-mejia & palich, 1997) and expatriate adjustment (black & mendenhall, 1991). the cultural distance concept has been criticized (shenkar, 2001). problems may have taken place because it was used in isolation, a situation in which it fails to completely represent every component of psychic distance. further, the measures used to operationalize cultural distance have been critiqued. one measure, the kogut and singh’s (1988) assessment, has its basis in the research of hofstede (1980), which itself has been called into question as being static, insensitive, and flawed (see shenkar, 2001). in spite of these conceptual problems, it seems apparent that differences between national cultures exist. the kogut and singh (1988) questionnaire provides one measure of these differences. future studies may offer additional value if multiple measures of culture are included, possibly incorporating other research on culture utilizing such variables as dominant religions and language differences (schwartz, 1990; hall, 1959). administrative and political distance encompasses nations’ historical and political association, shared monetary systems, and legal and financial institutions (ghemawat, 2001; hill, 2011; rothaermel, kotha, & steemsa, 2006). links between former colonies and their colonial power can increase trade considerably as in relations between the united kingdom and its commonwealth nations and in spain’s relationship with the nations of latin america. shared monetary systems volume 32, number 2 21 also impact administrative distance, of which the euro area is perhaps the most prominent example (ghemawat, 2001). key issues regarding similarity in legal systems include distinctions between common law and civil law, the nature of contract law, treatment of intellectual property, and product safety and liability. differences in legal systems and institutions include conditions emanating from the host country such as tariffs, quotas, and restrictions on foreign direct investment (fdi) as well as protection of certain favored industries in the form of subsidies and regulations such as those extended by nations of the european union to airbus (hill, 2011). differences may also be manifest in practices by the home country. domestic restrictions on bribery along with policies regarding health, safety, and the environment in the u.s. sometimes constrain development of trade relations in countries not sharing similar values (ghemawat, 2001). firms incorporating administrative differences and similarities into decision processes increase the likelihood of success in international trade. geographic distance, the third dimension of the cage framework, encompasses linear distance along with a range of geographic considerations that impact the attractiveness and, ultimately, the perceived psychic distance between one global market and another (ghemawat, 2001). differences in physical size, host country waterways and access to oceans, distances to other nations’ borders, topography, and number of time zones (e.g., russia has 16) are aspects of geographic distance beyond simple linear distances that can significantly influence perceptions of differences between nations. infrastructure (e.g., roads, power, and telecommunications) clearly affects transportation but also impact flows of intangibles such as equity, knowledge, and information. further, the types of products a potential trading partner offers can be heavily affected by geographic considerations (ghemawat, 2001; rothaermel et al., 2006). low value to weight products (e.g., cement) and fragile or perishable products are sensitive to transportation issues. overall, evidence suggests that geographic distance tends to constrain flow of investment and trade (ghemawat, 2001). economic distance often plays a primary role. the conditions of a potential host country’s consumer market as indicated by wealth and consumer per capita income are key characteristics affecting distance between countries. further impacting distance is similarity across countries in the use of economies of experience, scale, and scope, and of standardization. differences in supply chains and distribution channels can also affect trade. firms in industries with key cost drivers whose prices vary widely across borders (e.g., garment and footwear) are often able to create value by exploiting these cross-border differences through economic arbitrage 22 journal of business strategies (ghemawat, 2001). each of these economic features may separate and distance countries from one another. distance is a crucial consideration for managers attempting to expand beyond domestic markets. the cage framework offers a granular approach to identifying relative differences between global markets. it is a multi-dimensional concept intended to help managers assess the challenges of distance and the opportunities of similarity in determining the attractiveness of a foreign market. business distance it seems likely that perceptions of psychic distance will be affected by differences in business practices between firms operating in two separate international markets. therefore, including business distance in any conceptual representation of the psychic distance seems prudent. business distance contains two levels: industry level differences and firm level differences. research by evans and movonda (2002) provides one measure of business distance. the authors note impact of industry structure, which is shaped by forms of competition (monopoly, oligopoly), growth rates, and concentration ratios, such as the number of competitors found in a nation or geographic region (hennart & larimo 1998; trimeche 2002). industry level differences are also manifest in the way industry value chains are organized, especially with respect to distribution channels such as what procter & gamble encountered in japan. there the firm discovered a highly fragmented system involving an intricate series of intermediaries including general wholesalers, product wholesalers, product-specialty wholesalers, regional wholesalers, local wholesalers, and finally retailers adding costs and complexity (kotler, 2003). the evans and movonda approach notes that in some industries, distance levels differ across international boundaries. some industries remain highly standardized across national boundaries (low distance), while in others international differences become much more pronounced (higher distance). in international finance, one nation may not allow interest to be charged. this in turn affects a wide variety of investment evaluations and decision. another perspective regarding industry difference focuses on variances in consumer traits and behaviors (davidson, 1980; mitra & golder, 2002). this industry level difference creates implications for a variety of strategic business activities ranging from product exporting choices to marketing strategies for those products. beyond industry differences, evans and mavondo (2002) describe firm level business distance in terms of business language, business practices, and marketing volume 32, number 2 23 infrastructures. other researchers use similar measures (klein & roth, 1990; vahlne & wiedersheim-paul, 1973). also, corporate culture tends to be separate from national level cultural differences and often permeates every business activity (erammilli & rao, 1990; weber, shenkar, & rayeh, 1996). when interpreted through the individual experiences of managers, these forces may exert greater or lesser influence on perceptions of psychic distance. individual experience individual experience constitutes the final component of psychic distance as conceptualized in figure 1. the inclusion of individual experience constitutes an important component of the psychic distance construct. it may impact the process of strategy evaluation, strategic choice, and the type of managerial structure chosen to be established in a new foreign operation or entity. several attempts have been made to explain individual experience. among them, within-country diversity, accumulated international experience, the similarityattraction paradigm, attribution theory, social identity theory and inor out-group status, self-categorization theory, cultural intelligence, and confirmation bias serve as indicators of individual experience (a more complete description of these factors appears in baack and colleagues (2014). a brief review of these perspectives follows. individual experience models within-country diversity implies that a variance exists within each nation in terms of language, religion, and ethnicity. for example, while substantial linguistic differences may be found between mexico and the united states, a number of mexican citizens are fluent in english and a number of americans are fluent in spanish. the same would hold true in the case of religion, most notably catholicism. for these individuals, national-level indicators of psychic distance may be misleading, because in that situation psychic distance becomes lower due to the familiarity with the language spoken or religion practiced in the other country. where crossunderstanding or commonality does not exist, the individual experiences increase psychic distance as he or she considers expansion or entry into a more “foreign” country. international experience constitutes a distance-bridging factor (child, ng, & wong, 2002; zhao, luo & suh, 2004). as an individual travels internationally, he or she may become more comfortable with other nations. this in turn may reduce perceptions of the degree of distance in those countries and also reduce the person’s 24 journal of business strategies perceptions of distance with all foreign countries. individuals with international experience contribute to a firm’s stock of knowledge (dierickx & cool, 1989) particularly as it relates to international diversification. in this vein, international expansion to a particular market may be more a means than an end. expansion to a particular foreign market, while certainly providing some opportunities and benefits for the firm’s value creation, may also be a step in building the firm’s store of knowledge in order to create greater opportunities in subsequent international market expansion thereby providing a context for additional learning (verbeke, 2003). a firm’s store of knowledge may benefit from an individual’s international experience in at least two ways. first, with long organizational tenure at the focal firm, the individual’s international experience may combine with a deep understanding of the firm’s codified systems and tacit routines (capron, dussauge & mitchell, 1998; dyer & singh, 1998; nelson & winter, 1982; vermeulen & barkema, 2001) enhancing the firm’s capabilities to create additional value through international diversification. second, an individual may have gained international experience through work experience with a variety of firms. recent upper echelons scholarship suggests that although many strategic leaders still rise through the organizational ranks in a single firm or single industry (kotter, 1982), career variety is increasing among ceos and executives (crossland, zyung, hiller, & hambrick, 2014). the increasing cognitive breadth resulting from this career variety tends to increase a manager’s tendency toward experimentation and change. consequently, individual international experience can bring with it considerable knowledge depth and breadth that decreases the perception of psychic distance and increases the likelihood of expansion into a foreign market thereby affecting the decision to enter a foreign market. this knowledge breadth and depth of individual international experience tends to result in reduction of uncertainty concerning the firm’s future international prospects making it more likely that the firm will pursue international investments entailing greater risk such as the high resource commitments associated with foreign direct investment (fdi) (hill, hwang, & kim, 1990). the similarity-attraction paradigm identifies the ways in which people become attracted to things they view as similar while they also find things viewed as different to be unattractive. in terms of individual experience, such differences may lead to reduced interactions with people in other countries or situations. this in turn lessens the frequency of communication (lincoln & miller, 1979) and eventually results in diminished trust and weaker intentions to associate (thomas & ravlin, volume 32, number 2 25 1995). as managers consider international expansion, differences such as these may cause serious concerns. high psychic distance based on differences and lack of attraction between managers in foreign subsidiaries may make it harder for these individuals to understand one another and reduce their willingness to interact and cooperate with each other. attribution theory (heider, 1958) conceptualizes the methods by which a person assigns or attributes responsibility for an action resulting from various contextual factors, one of which is perceptions of similarities between actors. in a case of high psychic distance resulting from individual experience, a manager would be more likely to place responsibility for an adverse outcome in an international operation on the foreign partner. when low psychic distance is present, the responsibility would more likely be attributed to situational influences that are external to the trading partner. the attribution of the manager, then, filters other factors including nation distance, but more importantly, business distance. social identity theory examines how people view themselves, how others view them, how they operate in groups, and how they view out-groups. these perceptions affect many fundamental aspects of life including self-concept, selfesteem, and group identification (ashforth & mael, 1989). when constructing a perception of the differences between oneself and others; the “other” may become categorized as being part of an out-group. most people express a preference for an in-group (billig and tajfel, 1973). viewing others as an out-group may result in discrimination along with the tendency to consider members of that out-group in more extreme ways (ahmed, 2007; linville & jones, 1980). once again, in-group and out-group status will be reflected as individual experience as it alters views of nation and business distance. consider, for example, the impact of religious affiliation. current american attitudes often reflect the assignment of out-group status to islamic citizens, both foreign and domestic. these attitudes would in turn influence the perceived degree of psychic distance when conducting business or considering expansion into some middle eastern and african countries. self-categorization processes is another key area of study. “selfcategorization theory” and the related concept of cognitive complexity suggest that individuals assign schemas or associative networks in long-term memory (zarate & smith, 1990; turner et al., 1987). each category consists of nodes or bundles of semantic meaning that form the basis of the overall meaning of the category. the categories vary across individuals based on different life experiences and cognitive abilities. 26 journal of business strategies as cognitive complexity increases, individuals become less likely to rely on simple heuristics, such as stereotypes, and more likely to employ in-depth decision-making thought processes (park & lessig, 1981). self-category theory and the concept of cognitive complexity cannot make unidirectional predictions about perceptions of psychic distance. instead, greater cognitive complexity may cause one to view a country as closer or more distant, depending on the nature of the heuristic it replaces. this perspective offers implications for the number of underlying dimensions that constitute individual experience. in perceptions of religion, for example, some individuals hold simple schemas that make no distinction between sunni and shia, which means they view all forms of islam as being the same. others, in contrast, possess more complex schemas and regard the two branches of islam as being different. in essence, the individual’s experience of islam varies, thereby leading to a subsequent difference in perceptions of psychic distance. cultural intelligence concepts originated within the international business domain. it notes that some individuals may more readily adapt to and learn about difference aspects of foreign cultures. such increased intelligence leads to more effective functioning when interacting with people in those cultures and a swifter acclimation to unique cultural situations (thomas et al., 2008). logically, higher levels of cultural intelligence would result in lower perceptions of psychic distance and serve as an individual experience influence on perceptions of other factors. finally, confirmation bias explains how an individual’s existing attitudes or beliefs influence the process by which he or she seeks out and processes new information. the overarching premise, that when an individual has a hypothesis or belief about a particular issue, that hypothesis or belief then influences the inferences or conclusions he or she draws about any new information (jussim, 1991). when considering entry into new markets, managers tend to rely on low involvement sources (reid, 1984). consequently, the potential for a manager to discount or disregard information that contradicts his or her existing perceptions occurs. thus, if a manager does exhibit a tendency to focus heavily on information that confirms his or her existing perceptions of psychic distance while avoiding or doubting information contrary to that perception, then the individual considers that information using a strong bias for or against expansion into a new country. through the use of an experimental design, baack et al. (2014) demonstrated that, even with a relatively modest intervention, the impact of confirmation bias on perceptions of distance and risk as well as managerial choices was detected. in summary, the factors associated with nation distance including cultural, administrative, geographic, and economic factors and the factors associated with volume 32, number 2 27 business distance such as industry and firm distance are all going to be examined in the light of individual experience. a manager’s perception of psychic distance, as it is affected by personal experiences, may constitute an important influence on decisions to enter a country, the mode of entry selected, and the managerial structure to be implemented. the manner in which a manager considers these issues may further impact such decisions and actions. information processing models consumer buying decision-making processes have been studied for many years. the result has been a set of models which may be applied to the ways in which individuals consider product purchases. these same models appear to have implications for strategy evaluations and choice processes as they are influenced by individual experiences and subsequent perceptions of psychic distance. four such models include cognitive mapping, the multi-attribute approach, the evoked set method, and affect referral. cognitive maps are used to represent the knowledge structures and memories embodied in an individual’s brain (kearny & kaplan, 1997). these internal mental structures contain a person’s assumptions feelings, beliefs, interpretation of reality, and attitudes regarding the world. within this framework, when a manager encounters information about a country, it can be processed in several ways. if the new information appears to be consistent with current information the individual holds, then an internal linkage becomes stronger. in other words, the concept that australia has a great deal in common with the united states may be strengthened by any new information that suggests similarities between the two countries, much in the manner suggested by confirmation bias. if, on the other hand, new information does not have a linkage to any knowledge in the individual’s brain, a new linkage will be established. thus, a person who does not know that cars are driven on the left side of the road, rather than the right as is the case in the u.s. will need to establish a new linkage. the same person may be aware that drivers in england also use the left hand side of the road. the corresponding linkage may be that the united kingdom and australia have something in common and that, in spite of driving patterns, other similarities remain with the u.s., such as language. psychic distance would be lessened as a consequence. cognitive mapping also explains how short term processing of information moves into longer term memory (kaplan & kaplan, 1982). repetition represents the process by which a message is processed more than once using the person’s 28 journal of business strategies mental linkages, and over time the information becomes stored into the person’s knowledge structure. this structure, normally conceptualized as an associative network, serves as the foundation of memory. consequently, repeated information suggesting that a country “is not all that different from us” would lead to lessened perceptions of psychic distance. such an approach features messages designed to accentuate similarity-attraction, positive attributions, and suggest an in-group status to recipients. as cognitive complexity increases, the number of linkages present in a mental “web” rises. an individual with higher levels of cognitive complexity would likely find more similarities but also differences among nations. subsequent conclusions regarding the perceived degree of psychic distance would then be affected. cognitive mapping explains such processes much in the same way that cognitive complexity appears to operate. that is, the individual may draw differing conclusions about the degree of psychic difference present by the manner in which he or she considers the perceived or experienced similarities and differences between countries. the multi-attribute approach applies to high-involvement purchases, and by inference, high-involvement strategic decisions (wilkie & pessemier, 1983). a consumer considers products in terms of performance over a series of attributes along with the importance of each attribute. for example, when buying a car, the consumer thinks about gas mileage, comfort, reliability, and the looks of the vehicle. a purchaser ranks the attributes from most important to least important and then rates each individual attribute. someone who values comfort over every other feature gives that factor the greatest weight, with the most comfortable car gaining the highest ranking on that factor (bettman, 1979). the sum of the evaluations of the total set of factors, each weighted in terms of importance, then influences the final purchasing choice. in terms of psychic distance, a manager considers the components displayed in figure 1, or nation distance in terms of cultural, administrative, geographic, and economic factors along with business distance in terms of industry and firm factors. each nation under consideration receives a mental rating for all of the factors which are have been ranked in terms of importance to the manager. these assessments will be influenced by the manager’s individual experience. a person who values similarity or in-group status may rank a common language or religion as the most important factor and economic distance as the least, for example. the net result would be a cumulative evaluation of the nation in terms of psychic distance as interpreted volume 32, number 2 29 across various attributes with varying levels of importance to the manager making the assessment. the evoked set conceptualization suggests that individuals make purchases by considering a set of products or companies that first come to mind when the person experiences a need (zeithaml, 1981). for example, if asked, “where do you go for a good steak at a restaurant?” the respondent will recall a set of dining establishments that immediately enters his or her thoughts. that group is the evoked set. in strategic terms, the question, “which country do you think would be best for entry?” would lead to a response naming the nations that come to mind, or the respondent’s evoked set. two additional factors are present. an inept set contains the products, brands, or companies that individuals will not consider because they elicit negative feelings. someone with a negative attitude toward a specific restaurant would not consider going to that establishment to dine. in psychic distance/individual experience terms, those in the out-group stay in the out-group and those that are dissimilar remain dissimilar, which further reflects the presence of a confirmation bias. in terms of strategic decision-making, individual experience would dictate that a nation will not be considered as a target for expansion as a result. any nation which has been engaged in a war with the home company’s country may be quickly placed into an inept set due to individual experience perceptions and its corresponding confirmation bias tendency. the inert set contains brands the consumer knows about but has neither positive nor negative feelings regarding them. in cognitive mapping terms, no linkage is present. the consequence will be that the brand may be eliminated simply due to lack of knowledge. often, marketers seek to change that outcome through advertising and other marketing messages. many nations may be found in the inert sets of managers considering international expansion. the goal for leaders in those countries would be to help their nations move into a decision-maker’s evoked set by creating positive emotions and increasing memories of those countries and emotions. affect referral posits that consumers select the brands they like or the ones with which they hold emotional connections (sneider, 2004). this eliminates thoughts about other brands or products. most of the time, affect referral applies to low involvement purchases. in terms of strategic choice, affect referral would imply that managers will only consider expansion into countries with which they hold positive emotions and those that they perceive would be relatively easy to enter. once again, similarity, in-group status, and confirmation bias might become part of a response modeled by 30 journal of business strategies affect referral. for example, a canadian manager asked to choose the next country to expand into might quickly respond “the united states,” due to positive feelings and the perceived ease of entry. affect referral requires the least amount of mental energy. it also explains how a previous choice (sending one product into a new country), which has been made using a more complex information processing model such as the multi-attribute approach, will simply be confirmed in a subsequent choice. nations belonging to the european union may contain managers who only consider other member nations when making strategic internationalization choices. these information processing models imply that the individual experience components can be combined with models of how individuals make purchasing decisions to further explain the ways in which managers considering internationalization think about their choices. subsequent decisions to enter or not enter a specific country, to utilize a certain mode of entry, and to establish a form of managerial structure may be more clearly understood through such an analysis. previous international experiences, perceptions of similarity, confirmation bias, ingroup status, and various attributions may influence such choices. operationalization of individual experience very few marketing studies include measures of individual experience in any model or methodology regarding psychic distance. the studies that include experience serve as the foundation for operationalizing this component of psychic distance. dicthl, keoglmayr, and mueller (1990) studied individual manager variables including education level, proficiency in foreign languages, degree of foreign travel, and foreign market orientations. other measures of individual experience might include a manager’s knowledge of the foreign market and actual experience and comfort level with this market. additional research could incorporate the personal variables noted here, including perceptions of similarity and difference, the degree or amount of international experience, reflections on inor out-group status with a particular country in mind, the presence of confirmation bias (as explored in the baack et al. 2014 study), and measures of cultural intelligence. individual experience is open to investigation using qualitative methods, such as in-depth interviews combined with observations of the decision-maker’s activities. post hoc analyses of decisions to enter foreign markets, choices of entry modes, and the types of managerial structures volume 32, number 2 31 implemented might also provide valuable insights into strategic decision-making processes in international settings. psychic distance and strategic management the psychic distance concept has been applied to strategic marketing management studies. the foreign direct investment (fdi) process serves as an example. the three main fdi outcomes connected to psychic distance in the marketing literature include: foreign market investment location decisions and the sequence of the investments, the choice of entry mode into a foreign market, and the performance levels of multinational firm affiliates (shenkar, 2001). two of these outcomes apply to strategic management. that is, psychic distance may affect decisions to engage in international operations, choices of country to enter, and modes of entry selected. psychic distance may further explain the managerial structure that will be put into place. choices of countries to enter psychic distance has been strongly linked to the decision to begin international activity in the first place (johanson and vahlne, 1977; 2009). then, deciding where to compete constitutes an integral part of a firm’s corporate level strategy. the role psychic distance plays in such decisions may be an important factor in a strategic manager’s (or management team’s) decision to enter a specific foreign market, because the impact of psychic distance may be context specific and vary in importance by industry and by certain firm characteristics. such evaluations can be modeled using the multi-attribute approach or through assessments of a manager’s evoked set. as a general rule, perceptions of low degrees of psychic distance would seemingly be associated with greater propensities to enter specific countries. if another nation is viewed as “not all that much different,” the decision to select that country as a place to enter becomes easier. in contrast, high perceived psychic distance between a home country and a potential host country would logically result in increased concern regarding the difficulty of entering that specific nation. as an example, industries producing highly consumable products such as food and entertainment may be greatly impacted by cultural factors, thereby influencing perceptions of psychic distance. industries enmeshed tightly with a country’s reputation or national security, such as aerospace, would also affect the degree of psychic distance experienced by a top level manager. further, low value32 journal of business strategies to-weight ratios in the cement industry constrain potential international market options, and the demand for automobiles is income dependent, thereby constraining the potential for development of international markets. consequently, the industry in which a firm operates affects perceptions of psychic distance as part of the decision to enter a specific foreign market (ghemawat, 2001), and these factors may be assessed in the manner suggested by the various decision-making modes, such as the multi-attribute approach or confirmation bias. with regard to the actual choices of countries, some research suggests that firms are more likely to enter geographically-close countries (davidson 1980, johanson and wiedersheim-paul, 1975; denis and depelteau, 1985; welch and luostarinen, 1988). logically, a nearby country may influence individual strategic decision-makers because their perceptions include the view that those nations are culturally similar and may have a greater number of economic, industry-level and business-level similarities, thereby reducing perceived psychic distance. at the same time, the primary impact of psychic distance in the decision to expand into another country has not always been clearly supported by past research. it is possible that a more complex conceptualization, such as the one provided in figure 1, may lead to more in-depth analyses of these relationships in the future. as an example, consider the differences between perceptions of canada and mexico by managers in the united states. factors such as similarity-attraction based on language and/or religion may come into play. modes of entry psychic distance may be a factor that affects the choice of entry mode. standard entry modes include exporting, licensing, franchising, joint ventures, strategic alliances, acquisitions (minority, majority, or total), and greenfield (startup) ventures (agarwal, 1994; hill et al., 1990). costs, levels of risk, and the degree of control constitute three factors influencing such choices (anderson & gatignon, 1986). in general terms, the more involved the modes of entry, in terms of a company’s investment of time and other resources, the greater degree of control that company will seek to hold. at the same time, greater involvement creates increased costs and higher levels of risk. psychic distance, then, may play a key role in the selection of entry mode. the lower the degree of perceived psychic distance, the more likely it becomes that entry will include a more complex and involved entry strategy. volume 32, number 2 33 conversely, greater psychic distance would be associated with increased reticence with regard to making an involved, higher cost, more complex entry choice. in some cases, exports may be the only mode available due to a lack of knowledge and/or risk aversion. when considering exporting, structural arrangements for such an approach typically depend on either arm’s length relationships with intermediaries specializing in foreign trade including traveling sales representatives and foreign-based distributors or agents or on internally coordinated organizational subunits such as domestic-based export departments or overseas sales branches. the choice of exporting as a mode of entry may be impacted by psychic distance in a number of ways. the uncertainty of local market acceptance of the entering firm’s product offering increases that firm’s risk in entering the market. a firm may lack understanding of local business practices and may only with difficulty be able to reach local potential customers without the assistance of local partners. the entering firm may also lack sufficient knowledge to recruit, hire, and manage local personnel. these attributes reflect both nation distance, as demonstrated by the cage framework, and business distance in terms of a lack of knowledge by the firm of local practices. exporting avoids the investment costs of establishing operations in the host country and may allow an exporting firm pursuing a cost leadership strategy to benefit from potential cost advantages from production in its home market (hill et al., 1990; hitt, ireland, & hoskisson, 2009), which in turn may lower perceptions of psychic distance. on the other hand, exporting entails transportation costs and regulatory constraints including potential tariffs and other import duties. reliance on third party intermediaries for marketing, distribution, and sales means higher transaction costs will be associated with contract specification, monitoring, and enforcement (hill et al., 1990; williamson, 1996), thereby producing heightened feelings regarding the degree of distance present. the size of the potential market can require the firm to seek more effective ways of reaching local customers while still recognizing the impact of constraints of distance driving a firm to pursue licensing as a mode of entry. in a licensing arrangement, the licensee assumes the business risks and fixed and variable costs associated with manufacturing and marketing the product (hill et al., 1990), because the home firm sells the rights to a host country firm to manufacture and market the home firm’s products in the host country in exchange for royalties. licensing may allow the firm to make use of host country expertise, for example, in product development or distribution systems and also allow a local 34 journal of business strategies firm access to the foreign firm’s knowledge base allowing both firms to share in the revenue. consequently, perceptions of the degree of psychic distance may decrease, due to the conclusion that lower levels of risk and cost are present. factors that might heighten the perceived degree of psychic distance would include the other costs associated with contracting (searching for an agent, negotiating, monitoring, and enforcement) and the risks that the licensee may learn how to develop the product on its own (dissemination risk) (hill et al., 1990). the multi-attribute model may be used to assess the relative importance of each of these factors (in the mind of the decision-maker/s) affecting the choice of entry mode. with franchising, the franchisee bears the bulk of the investment risk as the franchisor bears the costs of enforcing quality control in addition to the larger issues of contract specification, monitoring, and enforcement which are exacerbated by distance (hill et al., 1990) and, in some cases, differences in the institutional environments of the two countries. business level factors constitute the primary force affecting psychic distance in such deliberations, and these in turn would be influenced by factors such as similarity-attraction or out-group status. multi-firm equity strategic alliances include european aeronautic defense and space (eads), an alliance of aerospace firms from the u.k., spain, germany, and france, a collaborative arrangement between microsoft and toshiba to develop embedded processors for running on-board entertainment functions in automobiles, and nestlé’s 16% stake in l’oreal. in these arrangements, the credible commitment implied by the equity investment may offer partial security against opportunism by the foreign partner (williamson, 1990) which would reduce perceptions of psychic distance. conversely, the same arrangements entail clear long-term agreements with the foreign partners, which create high exit costs. strategic decision-makers would likely be influenced by such factors, which would be associated with the perceived degree of distance present. high-profile examples of international joint ventures exist. general motors is involved in a three party joint venture in china with shanghai automotive industrial corporation (saic) and wuling, a chinese manufacturer, to produce the wuling sunshine, a mini-commercial vehicle for use within china (muller, 2010). in the petroleum industry, chevron and phillips have combined subunits to create chevron phillips chemical company to develop petrochemicals (stynes, 2014). managers assessing economic and business level factors would filter such considerations through the lens of individual experience, when considering potential mergers. strategic alliances including both equity strategic alliances and joint ventures are volume 32, number 2 35 dependent on a certain level of trust that is likely only with a relatively low degree of distance (dyer and singh, 1998). in the case of wholly owned subsidiaries either as acquisitions or as greenfield ventures, the firm shoulders 100% of the risk but also maintains 100% of control. the expanding firm must be capable of understanding and controlling local operations suggesting that only in situations of low distance should firms engage in wholly owned subsidiaries as a mode of entry. cross-border acquisitions, such as kraft’s 2009 purchase of cadbury, are on the increase (jarrone, 2011). these provide a rapid means for large scale initial international expansion and afford the acquirer full control over operations. cross-border acquisitions entail several difficulties. they often involve large amounts of debt financing, are typically more complex than domestic deals (weitzel & berns, 2006), and may involve legal and regulatory considerations of both the acquirer’s home country and the host country of the target firm (hitt, ireland, & hoskisson, 2009). evaluations of such complexity would likely increase perceptions of psychic distance as interpreted through individual experience. factors such as within-country diversity in the company to be acquired along with the accumulated international experience and level of cultural intelligence of the decision-maker may influence such deliberations. acquisitions should typically occur only when there is low distance because the existence in the host market of businesses ripe for acquisition implies an established market for the firm’s product and existing know-how in terms of production, marketing, and distribution. when such attributes are not present but market conditions have demonstrated strong existing and growing demand, greenfield ventures become more likely. greenfield ventures are the establishment of a wholly owned subsidiary built from the ground up. greenfield ventures may allow protection of intangible capabilities (barney, 1991; conner, 1991; dierickx and cool, 1989; kor and mahoney, 2000). in its u.s. market, toyota shifted from exporting to wholly owned subsidiaries bypassing collaborative strategies to protect its knowledge base from appropriation from potential u.s. partners. firms generally use acquisition and greenfield ventures in later stages of development of international strategies. at the same time, when wholly owned subsidiaries are warranted from a business standpoint and under conditions of low psychic distance, local regulations may require a certain level of local ownership suggesting the need for joint ventures instead. in such cases, most of the components of psychic distance are low, but administrative distance in the form of local regulations becomes a rather stubborn driver of distance. mcdonald’s faced similar conditions during its early expansion into europe, forcing the firm to 36 journal of business strategies create a number of joint ventures when it might otherwise have chosen to operate wholly owned subsidiaries. advantages of greenfield ventures include maintaining control over technology, production, marketing, and distribution. disadvantages include high fixed costs and employment of host nationals. psychic distance may play differing roles in the determination of whether to pursue a greenfield venture. a foreign firm pursuing a wholly owned subsidiary entry mode may construct its own facility rather than acquire existing operations. toyota was quite familiar with the u.s. automobile market by the time the company was ready to manufacture cars in the u.s., and the japanese firm was generating considerable revenues from u.s. operations. the firm’s leaders did choose to build company-designed plants (moving from exporting to greenfield ventures) conforming to its rather unique business practices that would likely not have fit well with u.s. automotive plant layouts. in that case, the impact of psychic distance was reduced through the individual, group, and enterprise levels of experience with the u.s. market, but the firm chose greenfield ventures in order to maintain and protect many of its unique capabilities. kikkoman’s construction of a soy sauce production facility may also have been driven by factors other than psychic distance. the firm was also familiar with the u.s. market, having sold its products for nearly two decades through exporting, licensing, and joint ventures. company managers concluded, however, that the complexities of soy sauce production, the need for deep expertise in those processes, and the lack of existing soy sauce plants in the u.s. created the need for a greenfield venture (tanaka, taylor, and claterbos, 2001). in both the kikkoman and toyota cases, nation distance may have been reduced through long periods of individual experience, while business distance may have continued to play a role. ultimately, it was the demands of the product and processes that were largely the determinants of the choice of greenfield ventures. the final choice of mode of entry is somewhat dependent on internal firm processes, and the dynamics of the various modes of entry mean that the choice of mode is highly situation-dependent (hitt et al., 2009). firms whose creation of value is knowledge intensive are more likely to gravitate toward modes of entry associated with greater levels of control. although such a choice increases the level of investment risk, it tends to reduce the level of dissemination risk, the risk that the firm’s knowledge base may be appropriated by an opportunistic foreign partner and used by the foreign firm to develop its own market for the focal firm’s products (hill et al., 1990). therefore, it seems plausible that when individual experience factors volume 32, number 2 37 reduce perceptions of psychic distance, the likelihood of entering a foreign market would increase, assuming all things remain equal. some studies have investigated the impact of psychic distance on entry mode choice, with mixed results (brouthers & brouthers, 2001). eclectic theory suggests that location familiarity (an individual experience component of psychic distance) affects several managerial decisions including the choice of entry mode (hill et al., 1990; brouthers & brouthers, 2000). although a relationship between psychic distance and the choice of entry mode may be present, the form that relationship takes has not been consistent. for instance, high levels of cultural distance are associated with modes in which greater control is present, such as wholly-owned subsidiaries in anand and delios (1997). in other research, high levels of psychic distance were associated with shared or low control modes (kogut & singh, 1988; erramilli & rao, 1990; kim & hwang, 1992). in other research, no relationship was found (erramilli, 1996; gatignon & anderson, 1988; larimo, 1993). again, future research utilizing a more complex conceptualization of psychic distance might yield more precise and informative results. managerial structure the choice of managerial structure accompanies the selection of an entry mode. the assignment of general managers of foreign markets (managerial structure) typically centers around three choices: whether to assign a home country national, a host country national, or a third country national. as with the decision to enter a foreign market and which mode of entry to use, all things being equal, individual experience may also influence these managerial decisions. numerous factors might affect the choice of managerial structure (agarwal & ramaswami, 1992; barkema, shenkar, & vermeulen, 1997). culture, religion, and language affect perceptions of nation distance. industry and firm distance represent business level factors that also influence the degree of psychic distance. a mechanism by which such decisions are made or influenced would be to incorporate components in individual experience into the degree of psychic distance perceived and subsequent choices. in other words, considering managerial structure choices in terms of similarity-attraction, in-group/out-group status, attribution considerations, the degree of foreign experience, and confirmation bias might provide quality insights into such selections. as a component of individual experience, within-country diversity may impact international choices facing organizational decision makers with regard 38 journal of business strategies to managerial structure. also, exposure to a variety of differences within one’s own country (e.g., language, religion, and ethnicity) may make one more readily adaptable and accepting of cultural differences, thereby reducing psychic distance. the example provided earlier of diversity in the u.s. of anglo and hispanic cultural diversity may also extend to other countries. switzerland has three official national languages, belgium two, and spain has several unofficial languages although spanish is the official language in most areas of the country. people raised in such diverse cultures in their own countries may view other cultures as less psychically distant. furthermore, this tendency may be magnified by certain geographical factors such as size and population. a densely populated, diverse country may result in more pronounced experiences of diversity among its populace. in addition, a relatively small country geographically will have less distance to its borders and may border many more countries than would a geographically larger country. further, a small population may drive local firms to seek overseas markets sooner than would firms in countries with larger domestic markets (ghemawat, 2001). thus, withincountry diversity might result in individual experiences that reduce perceptions of psychic distance. cognitive maps, the multi-attribute model, evoked sets, and the affect referral model could be also used to explain the processes by which managers consider and analyze the type of individual who would be suited to an international expansion operation. for example, the combination of international knowledge and reduction of uncertainty may lead the firm to consider other managerial structures by examining the range of managerial talent. this suggests that third country expatriates would become candidates as country subsidiary managers. low psychic distance, or similarity, would likely lead a firm entering a foreign market to assign general management responsibilities to a host country national. low psychic distance implies a high degree of mutual understanding by firm managers and host country nationals regarding host country culture, administrative infrastructure, geography, and economic system. as psychic distance increases, it becomes more likely for the firm to prefer a home country national as general manager in order to maintain control over the foreign division and maintain consistency in communications within the division and between the division and corporate offices. cases of highest psychic distance may lead the firm to assign general management responsibilities to a third country national. this individual may be one with firm experience in another foreign division or an outsider with a certain level of international experience who understands the firm and its home country as well as understanding the host country. volume 32, number 2 39 in general, the greater the degree of perceived psychic distance, the less likely a host country national is to assume general management responsibilities of the foreign division. further, as psychic distance increases it becomes more likely for the firm to rely heavily first on intrafirm experience in the host country, then on intrafirm experience abroad, and then on experience outside the firm but with strong international experience. the experience of kikkoman, the soy sauce producer, expanding into the u. s. market illustrates some of these processes (tanaka et al., 2001). the firm first entered the market as an exporter relying on such specializing intermediaries as domestic-based export agents and u.s. distributors knowledgeable about the u.s. and perhaps with some knowledge of kikkoman’s products and their consumer applications. as the market grew, the firm grew to rely on more involved modes of entry until it built its own production facility in walworth, wisconsin. although kikkoman had had a u.s. presence for nearly twenty-five years, this was the first japanese owned manufacturing plant to be built in the u.s. the plant manager, the finance manager, and the laboratory manager were considered the three key senior management positions and were held by japanese employees of kikkoman. this was due to the rather complex production processes, the associated technologies, and the century long involvement of kikkoman in soy sauce production and distribution. this management structure allowed the u.s. division of kikkoman to operate as an american firm in the japanese style. as the firm’s u.s. market developed further, the management became more american in character, and the plant manager position eventually went to an american. hence, upon entering the u.s. market, kikkoman relied on home country nationals as general managers but became sufficiently assimilated to u.s. styles that a host country national eventually took the position. the knowledge breadth and depth of individual international experience (as may be modeled with cognitive maps) will likely result in less cognitive simplification typical of management when confronted with cognitive complexity leading to less reliance on simplifying heuristics such as stereotypes and leading to greater cultural intelligence. the result is that attributes and characteristics encountered in the realms of international expansion will be seen as more similar than to individuals with more narrow and more shallow knowledge bases, and those attributes and characteristics may seem more attractive resulting in greater attraction thereby reducing psychic distance. in addition, there might be fewer tendencies to categorize differences based on in-group/out-group distinctions. 40 journal of business strategies conclusions and implications this investigation seeks to explore relationships between psychic distance and strategic international considerations as reflected in strategy evaluations, strategic choices, and the choice of managerial structure to be deployed in an international expansion. figure 2 summarizes these proposed relationships. the assertion being made is that individual experience plays an important role in such deliberations. individual experience can be viewed as the various components involved or through the use of consumer purchasing decision models. figure 2 proposed relationships of psychic distance and involvement in international expansion 1. greater nation distance as interpreted through individual experience results in greater perceived psychic distance. 2. greater business distance as interpreted through individual experience results in greater perceived psychic distance. 3. greater perceived psychic distance as interpreted through individual experience reduces managerial intentions to expand across national borders. 4. greater perceived psychic distance as interpreted through individual experience results in less complex modes of entry involving lower levels of investment risk and lower levels of control by the focal firm. 5. greater perceived psychic distance as interpreted through individual experience results in a higher likelihood of employing a foreign national either from the host country or from a third country. in general, greater psychic distance would be viewed as likely to reduce the inclination to enter any new country or pursue an internationalization strategy. greater psychic distance would logically influence leaders (through processes interpreted by individual experience) to avoid or be less inclined to enter certain countries, while low psychic distance would make a nation appear to be more inviting. psychic distance influences the degree of complexity and control associated with various modes of entry. and finally, psychic distance has an impact on the choice of home country, host country, or third party nationals as managers in international subsidiaries. volume 32, number 2 41 two arguments have been made for including individual experience in the psychic distance construct. one is that that individual experiences were part of the initial development of the construct (johanson & vahlne, 1977; hallen and wiedersheim-paul, 1984). second, removing individual experience would take away the psychic aspect, leaving only “distance.” it may be that the actual relationships are more complex and multidimensional. interactions between the three components within the domain of the construct (nation distance, business distance, and individual experience) are likely to be complex and interact with one another. these relationships may become more complicated in strategic decision-making processes, especially those in which groups of individuals voice views reflecting each person’s perception of the degree of psychic distance present with regard to any given potential target nation. some international business experts believe that, for the concept of psychic distance to remain useful, greater clarity regarding terms will be necessary (shenkar, 2001; dow, 2000; evans et al., 2000; brouthers & brouthers, 2001; barkema, bell, & pennings, 1996). brouthers and brouthers (2001) argue that business practice differences and perceptual components of psychic distance are key facets of the construct that have not been included in various studies. instead, the majority of empirical studies substitute cultural distance for psychic distance (shenkar, 2001). this approach limits psychic distance to one facet. such an approach may explain some of the conflicting findings present in studies of psychic distance and subsequent outcomes. therefore, the complete conceptualization of the psychic distance construct as presented here may be of some use. in the end, the goal of this paper is to change the way the psychic distance construct is viewed and used. in addition, the suggestion being offered is that the psychic distance construct provides an insightful lens into studies of the ways in which top managers make strategic internationalization decisions as well as influence the forms of entry strategies and managerial arrangements that result. references agarwal, s. (1994) socio-cultural distance and the choice of joint ventures: a contingency perspective, journal of international marketing, 2(2), 63-80. agarwal, s., & ramaswami, s. n. (1992). choice of foreign market entry mode: impact of ownership, location and internalization factors. journal of international business studies, first quarter, 1-27. 42 journal of business strategies ahmed, a. m. (2007). group identity, social distance and intergroup bias. journal of economic psychology, 28(3), 324-337. anand, j., & delios, a. (1997). location specificity and the transferability of downstream assets to foreign subsidiaries. journal of international business studies, 28 (3), 579-603. anderson, e., & gatignon, h. (1986). modes of foreign entry: a transaction cost analysis and propositions. journal of international business studies, fall, 1-26. ashforth, b. e., & mael, f. (1989). social identity theory and the organization. academy of management review, 14 (1), 20-39. baack, d. w., & baack, d. (2006). psychic distance: a conceptual framework. proceedings, association of collegiate marketing educators meeting, oklahoma city, ok, cd rom. baack, d. w., dow, d., parente, r., & bacon, d. (2014). confirmation bias in individual-level perceptions of psychic distance: an experimental investigation. manuscript submitted for publication. barkema, h. g., bell, j. h. j., & pennings, j. m. (1996). foreign entry, cultural barriers, and learning. strategic management journal, 17 (2), 151-166. barkema, h. g., shenkar, o., vermeulen, f., & bell, j. h. j. (1997). working abroad, working with others: how firms learn to operate international joint ventures. academy of management journal, 40(2), 426-442. barney, j. (1991). firm resources and sustained competitive advantage. journal of management, 17(1), 99-120. beckerman, w. (1956). distance and the pattern of inter-european trade. the review of economics and statistics, 38(1), 31-40. bettman, j. b. (1979) an information processing theory of consumer choice, reading, ma: addison-wesley. billig, m., & tajfel, h. (1973). social categorization and similarity in intergroup behaviour. european journal of social psychology, 3(1), 27-52. black, j. s., & mendenhall, m. e. (1991). the u-curve adjustment hypothesis revisited: a review and theoretical framework. journal of international business studies, 22(2), 225-247. boyacigiller, n. (1990). the role of expatriates in the management of interdependence. journal of international business studies, 21(3), 357-381. brouthers, k. d., & brouthers, l. e. (2000). acquisition or greenfield start-ups? institutional, cultural, and transaction cost influences. strategic management journal, 21(1), 89-97. volume 32, number 2 43 brouthers, k. d., & brouthers, l. e. (2001). explaining the national cultural distance paradox. journal of international business studies, 32(1), 177-189. buckley, p. j., & casson, m. c. (1979). analyzing foreign market entry strategies: extending the internalization approach. journal of international business studies, 29(3), 539-562. capron, l., dussauge, p., & mitchell, w. (1998). resource deployment following horizontal acquisitions in europe and the united states, 1988-1992. strategic management journal, 19(7), 631-661. child, j., ng, s. h., & wong, c. (2002). psychic distance and internationalization. international studies of management and organizations, 32(1), 36-56. conner, k. r. (1991). a historical comparison of resource-based theory and five schools of thought within industrial organizational economics: do we have a new theory of the firm? journal of management, 17(1), 121-154. crossland, c., zyung, j., hiller, n. j., & hambrick, d. c. (2014). ceo career variety: effects on firm-level strategic and social novelty. academy of management journal, 57(3), 652-674. davidson, w. h. (1980). the location of foreign direct investment activity: country characteristics and experience effects, journal of international business studies, 11(2), 9-22. denis, j-e., & depelteau, d. (1985). market knowledge, diversification and export expansion. journal of international business studies, 16(3), 77-89. dicthl, e., keoglmayr, h. g., & mueller, s. (1990). international orientation as a precondition for export success. journal of international business studies, first quarter, 23-40. dierickx, i. & cool, k. (1989). asset accumulation and sustainability of competitive advantage. management science, 35(12), 1504-1513. dow, d. (2000). a note on psychological distance and export market selection journal of international marketing, 8(1), 51-64. dyer, j. h., & singh, h. (1998). the relational view: cooperative strategy and sources of interorganizational competitive advantage. academy of management review, 23(4), 660-679. erramilli, m. k. (1996). nationality and subsidiary ownership patterns in multinational corporations. journal of international business studies, 27(2), 225-248. erramilli, m. k., & rao, c. p. (1990). choice of foreign market entry modes by service firms: role of market knowledge. management international review, 30(2), 135-150. 44 journal of business strategies evans, j., treadgold, a., & mavondo, f. t. (2000). psychic distance and the performance of international retailers – a suggested theoretical framework, international marketing review, 17(4/5) 373-391. evans, j., & mavondo, f. t. (2002). psychic distance and organizational performance: an empirical examination of international retailing operations. journal of international business studies, 33(3), 515-532. gatignon, h., & anderson, e. (1988). the multinational corporation’s degree of control over foreign subsidiaries: an empirical test of a transaction cost explanation. journal of law, economics, and organization, 4(2), 305-335. ghemawat, p. (2001). distance still matters: the hard reality of global expansion, harvard business review, 79(8), 137-147. gomez-mejia, luis r. & leslie e. palich (1997). cultural diversity and the performance of multinational firms, journal of international business studies, second quarter, 309-335. hall, e. t. (1959). the silent language. greenwich, ct: fawcett publishers. hallen, l., & wiedersheim-paul, f. (1984). the evolution of psychic distance in international business relationships. in i. hägg and f. wiedersheim-paul (eds.), between market and hierarchy (15-27). uppsala, sweden: university of uppsala press. heider, f. (1958). the psychology of interpersonal relations. new york: wiley. hennart, j-f., & larimo, j. (1998). the impact of culture on the strategy of multinational enterprises: does national origin affect ownership decisions? journal of international business studies, 29(3), 515-538. hill, c. w. l. (2011). global business today. 7th edition. new york: mcgraw-hill irwin. hill, w., hwang, p., & kim, w. c. (1990). an eclectic theory of the choice of international entry mode. strategic management journal, 11(2), 117-128. hitt, m.a., ireland, r.d., & hoskisson, r.e. (2009). strategic management: competitiveness and globalization (8th edition), cincinnati: south-western/ cengage learning. hofstede, g. (1980). culture’s consequences. beverly hills, ca: sage. jarrone, j. (2011, august 5). kraft breakup alone won’t nourish investors. the wall street journal. retrieved from http://www.wsj.com/articles/sb1000142405311 1903454504576488521705501438. johanson, j., & vahlne, j-e. (1977). the internationalization process of the firm – a model of knowledge development and increasing foreign market commitments, journal of international business studies, 8(1), 23-32. volume 32, number 2 45 johanson, j., & vahlne. j-e. (1990). the mechanism of internationalization, international marketing review, 7 (4) 11-24. johanson, j. & vahlne, j.-e. (2009). the uppsala internationalization process model revisited: from liability of foreignness to liability of outsidership. journal of international business studies 40, 1411-1431. johanson, j., & finn, w-p. (1975). the internationalization of the firm – four swedish cases, the journal of management studies, october, 305-322. jussim, l. (1991). social perception and social reality: a reflection-construction model, psychological review, 98(1) 54-73. kaplan, s., & kaplan, r. (1989). cognition and environment: functioning in an uncertain world, ann arbor, mi: ulrich. kearny, a. r., & kaplan. s. (1997). toward a methodology for the measurement of knowledge structures of ordinary people: the conceptual content cognitive map, (3cm), environment and behavior, 28(5) september, 579-617. kim, w. c., & hwang, p. (1992). global strategy and multinationals entry mode choice. journal of international business studies, first quarter, 29-53. klein, s., & roth, v. j. (1990). determinants of export channel structure: the effects of experience and psychic distance reconsidered. international marketing review, 7(5), 27-38. kogut, b., & singh, h. (1988). the effect of national culture on the choice of entry mode, journal of international business studies, fall, 411-432. kor, y. y., & mahoney, j. t. (2000). penrose’s resource-based approach: the process and product of research creativity. journal of management studies, 37, 109139. kostova, t. (1999). transnational transfer of strategic organizational practices: a contextual perspective. academy of management review, 24 (2) 308-324. kostova, t., roth, k., & dacin, m. t. (2008). institutional theory in the study of multinational corporations: a critique and new directions. academy of management review, 33(4), 994-1006. kotler, p. 2003. marketing management, 11th edition. upper saddle river, nj: pearson education. kotter, j. p. (1982). the general managers. new york: the free press a division of macmillan, inc. larimo, j. (1993). foreign direct investment behaviour and performance: an analysis of finnish direct manufacturing investments in oecd countries (no. 13). universitas wasaensis. 46 journal of business strategies lincoln, j. r., & miller, j. (1979). work and friendship ties in organizations: a comparative analysis of relation networks. administrative science quarterly, 181-199. linville, p. w., & jones, e. e. (1980). polarized appraisals of out-group members. journal of personality and social psychology, 38(5), 689. mitra, d., & golder, p. n. (2002). whose culture matters? near-market knowledge and its impact on foreign market entry timing. journal of marketing research, 39, 350-365. muller, j. (2010). can china save gm? forbes, 185(8), 72-78. nelson, r. n., & winter, s. g. (1982). an evolutionary theory of economic change. cambridge, ma: harvard university press. park, c. w., & lessig, v. p. (1981). familiarity and its impact on consumer decision biases and heuristics. journal of consumer research, 223-231. reid, s. (1984). information acquisition and export entry decisions in small firms. journal of business research, 12(2), 141-157. rothaermel, f. t., kotha, s., & steensma, h. k. (2006). international market entry by us internet firms: an empirical analysis of country risk, national culture, and market size. journal of management, 32(1), 56-82. schwartz, s. h. (1992). universals in the content and structure of values: theoretical advances and empirical tests in 20 countries. in m. zanna (ed). advances in experimental social psychology, 25(1), 1-65. new york: academic press. sethi, s. p. (1971). comparative cluster analysis for world markets. journal of marketing research, 8, 348-354. shenkar, o. (2001). cultural distance revisited: towards a more rigorous conceptualization and measurement of cultural differences. journal of international business studies, 32(3), 519-535. sneider, m. (2004). creating emotional ties with brands for sales. marketing news, 38(may 15), 44-45. stottinger, b., & schlegelmilch, b.b. (1998). explaining export development through psychic distance: enlightening or elusive? international marketing review, 15(5), 357-372. stottinger, b., & schlegelmilch, b.b. (2000). psychic distance: a concept past its due date? international marketing review, 17(2), 169-173. stynes, t. (2014, jan. 29). phillips 66 profit rises as margins fall. the wall street journal. retrieved from http://www.wsj.com/articles/phillips-66-profit-soarson-refining-margins-chemical-growth-1414586714. volume 32, number 2 47 tanaka, n., taylor, m. l., & claterbos, j. a. (2001). kikkoman corporation in the mid 1990s: market maturity, diversification, and globalization. case research journal, 21(3), 1-28. thomas, d. c., & ravlin, e. c. (1995). responses of employees to cultural adaptation by a foreign manager. journal of applied psychology, 80(1), 133. thomas, d. c., elron, e., stahl, g., ekelund, b. z., ravlin, e. c., cerdin, j-l., & poelmans, s. (2008). cultural intelligence domain and assessment. international journal of cross cultural management, 8(2), 123-143. trimeche, m. (2002). toward an actualization of the factors determining the firm’s export expansion: insights from the literature, http://aib.jibs.net/ literature review archive, 1-21. turner, j. c., hogg, m. a., oakes, p. j, reicher, s. d., & wetherell, m. s. (1987). rediscovering the social group: a self-categorization theory. basil blackwell. vahlne, j.-e., & wiedersheim-paul, f. (1973). economic distance: model and empirical investigation. in e. hornell, j.-e. vahlne, & finn wiedersheimpaul, (eds). export and foreign establishments, (81-159). uppsala, sweden: university of uppsala press. verbeke, a. (2003). the evolutionary view of the mne and the future of internalization theory. journal of international business studies, 34(6), 498-504. vermeulen, f. & barkema, h. (2001). learning through acquisitions. academy of management journal, 44(3), 457-476. weber, y., shenkar, o., & rayeh, a. (1996). national and corporate cultural fit in mergers/acquisitions: an exploratory study. management science, 42(8), 12141227. weitzel, u., & berns, s. (2006). cross-border takeover, corruption, and related aspects of governance. journal of international business studies, 37(6), 786806. welch, l. s., & luostarinen, r. (1988). internationalization: evolution of a concept. journal of general management, 14(2), 34-55. wilkie, w. l., & pessemier, e. a. (1983). issues in marketing’s use of multi-attribute models, journal of marketing research, 10, november, 428-441. williamson, o.e. (1996). the mechanisms of governance. oxford university press: new york. xu, d., & shenkar, o. (2002). note: institutional distance and the multinational enterprise, academy of management review, 27(4), 608-618. zarate, m. a., & smith, e. r. (1990). person categorization and stereotyping. social cognition, 8(2), 161-185. 48 journal of business strategies zeithaml, v. a. (1981). how consumer evaluation processes differ between goods and services. marketing of services, 9(1), 25-32. zhao, h., luo, y., & suh, t. (2004). transaction cost determinants and ownershipbased entry mode choice: a meta-analytical review, journal of international business studies, 35(6), 524-544. biographical sketch of authors stephen v. horner is an assistant professor of management in the kelce college of business at pittsburg state university. he previously held positions at bethany college and arkansas state university and taught courses at kansas state university-salina college of technology and aviation and mcpherson college. he is consulting editor for the journal of managerial issues and a member and former president of the southwest academy of management. his research appears in several academic publications. daniel baack is the assistant dean and mba director for the daniels college of business program at the university of denver, after previous time at ball state university. he received his phd in international business and marketing from saint louis university. he has published in a variety of academic journals. he serves on the editorial board of the journal of promotion management and is a regular participant in the academy of international business conferences. donald baack is a professor of management in the kelce college of business at pittsburg state university. he previously held positions at dana college, southwest missouri state university, and missouri southern state college. he is a consulting editor for the journal of managerial issues and is an active participant in the southwest academy of management, receiving its outstanding educator award in 2014. he has authored or co-authored numerous textbooks along with academic journal publications. futures options vs. conventional futures: when to use which russ ray department of finance university of louisville louisville, kentucky in october of 1982, the chicago board of trade introduced a remarkably innovative futures contract options on treasury bond futures which offers some very impressive risk-management features not afforded by conventional futures. unlike prior futures contracts, this particular contract was immediately successful. indeed, the volume in this first-ever "futures option" has already exploded to over ten million contracts per year, and continues to grow. the twofold purpose of this article is to articulate these new risk-management opportunities for money managers, and to compare the hedging effectiveness of this new instrument with that afforded by conventional futures. options are options futures options are essentially the same as any other options: calls or puts can be either bought or written (sold). as with other options, buyers of futures options post no margins; writers do. hedging with futures options is transacted by buying _. not writing calls and puts. call options a call option on futures gives the buyer the right to assume a long position in the underlying futures contract anytime before the expiration of the option. upon exercise of the option, the exercise (or striking) price of the option becomes the futures contract price. the risk of being adversely affected by falling interest rates can be hedged by buying call options on futures. consider, for example, a pension-fund manager who has just been notified that three months from now he'll receive a significant sum of money to invest for long-term purposes. the manager intends to invest the funds in u.s. treasury bonds and he can hedge this future investment against the risk of falling interest rates in the interim by buying call options on treasury bond futures. (see box 1.) assume that it's now late may, that the september 17 may august futures price of a treasury bond is 75-00 (yielding 12%), and that a september/75 call option can be bought at a premium of $1,000. buying a september/ 75 call gives the manager the right but not the obligation to exercise the option and thereafter take delivery of a treasury bond next september at a price of $75,000 (assuming he does not close out his futures position before then). suppose that, by august, yields on long-term u.s. treasury bonds do in fact drop to 10%, causing the september futures price to rise from 75-00 to 85-00. because exercise of the call option would result in an immediate $10,000 gain per bond (by virtue of being able to sell a september bond at $85,000 after having bought it at $75,000), the premium on each call option will reflect at least this intrinsic value. assuming no time value, each of the manager's september/75 calls will rise in value to $10,000. boxl hedging costs/bond using call futures hedge: protect a planned, future investment against the risk of falling interest rates in the interim by buying call options on futures. interest current price/bond of hedging rate september investment strategy 12% $75,000 buy sep/75 calls @ $ 1,000 10% $85,000 sell sep/75 calls @ $10,000 loss = $10,ooolbond gain = $9,000/bond net loss = $l,ooolbond = cost of the option consequently, when the manager lifts his hedge by selling his september/ 75 calls, the net gain of $9,000 per bond ($10,000 premium revenue less $1,000 premium cost) will roughly offset the $10,000 extra cost of each spot treasury bond ($85,000 august price less $75,000 may price) resulting from the decline in interest rates. alternatively, the manager could have exercised his options and thereafter taken delivery of the treasury bonds in september for $85,000 each. selling. the options would, of course, be much easier than taking actual delivery of the treasury bonds. either way, the bottomline cost of the hedge per bond is the $1,000 cost of the option. more importantly, this $1,000 hedging cost per bond is but a small fraction of the $10,000 extra cost the manager would have paid for each of his bonds had he not hedged. the unique advantages of a futures-option hedge over a hedge utilizing conventional futures will be enumerated following a brief discussion of put options. 18 put options put options which give buyers the right to assume a short position in the underlying futures contract enable their holders to hedge against the risk of rising interest rates. suppose a portfolio manager wanted to protect the value .of a treasury bond currently price at 80-00 (yielding 11 %) against the risk of rising interest rates. (see box 2.) suppose also that the premium on a december/80 put option were $500. the manager could protect the value of his spot bond against the risk of rising interest rates by buying a december/so put which gives him the right but not the obligation to exercise the option and thereafter sell a· deliverable treasury bond next december for $80,000. if interest rates subsequently rose from, say, 11 % to 13%,causing the value of his spot bond to drop from 80-00 to 70-00, then his put option would be worth (at least its intrinsic value of) $1,000. the $9,500 increase in the value of his option would roughly offset (and, most likely, more than offset, if time value were considered) the $10,000 decrease in the value of his spot bond. again, the bottom-line cost of the hedge is the $500 cost of the option. box 2 hedging costs/bond using put futures hedge: protect the value of a portfolio against the risk of rising interest rates by buying put options on futures. now later interest portfolio rate value 11% $80,000 13% $70,000 loss = $10,ooo/bond net loss = $500 = cost of the option hedging strategy buy dec/80 puts @ $ 500 sell dec/so puts @ $10,000 gain = $9,500/bond the advantages of futures options the advantages of hedging with futures options instead of with conventional futures are impressive. first, the major advantage is that futures options allow hedgers to avoid potentially adverse interest rates, yet still benefit from more favorable interest rates. such a feature is unique to this new instrument and is not afforded by conventional futures which require a hedger to forfeit more favorable interest rates. thus, in the first example, the manager who hedged against the risk of falling interest rates by buying a call option effectively established an interest rate floor for his future investment but not an interest rate ceiling. if interest rates had subsequently risen instead of fallen, the manager could have 19 simply let his option expire worthless (assuming, again, no time value) and thereafter invested his funds at the more favorable rate. similarly, in the second example, the manager who hedged against the risk of rising interest rates by buying a put option effectively established an interest rate ceiling but not an interest rate floor. in essence, then, futures options are insurance policies against potentially adverse interest rates, with the cost of the insurance being the cost of the option(s). a second advantage of futures options is that margins are not required, so that the cost of hedging is generally less. if the exercise price of the option is equal to (or at least close to) the underlying futures price as was the case in both of the examples above then the cost of the option will generally be significantly less than the cost of margin. finally, a third signific~~t advantage is that the cost of a futures-option hedge is known and fixed in advance it is simply the cost of the option. this is not the case with conventional futures whose margins are marked to the market daily, so that hedging against incorrect expectations can cause unpre.dictable futures losses every day. thus, futures options help stabilize future cash flows. the disadvantage of futures options the disadvantage of hedging with futures options is that option costs are not refundable, whereas margins (on conventional futures) are. if interest rates remain roughly unchanged over the hedging period, then the manager hedging with futures options must incur the cost of the option regardless, whereas the manager hedging with conventional futures will have his margin refunded. obviously, then, the question becomes when f this paper are to describe the size of the underground economy, identify those factors that have caused the underground economy to flourish and to examine the effect that the underground economy has had on the business practices. both the ethical and economic impact of the underground economy are examined. dr. edgar feige of the university of wisconsin estimates that the unreported income from the underground economy is as high as 27 percent of our gnp (3). in terms of the 1986 economy, this would mean an underground economy in the vicinity of $1 trillion. research at the federal reserve bank of atlanta concluded that the underground economy grew from 9 percent of reported gnp in 1970 to at least 15 percent of gnp in 1978 (5). in 1977, professor peter gutmann of baruch college estimated the underground economy at 10 percent of. the recorded gnp (4). while estimates by gutmann assume that all hidden transactions are done with cash, feige's estimate of 27 percent uses additional methods of payment, such as checks. however, 34 none of the estimates take into consideration unreported barter-the practice of exchanging one service or product for another (1). the first in-depth effort by the irs to measure unreported individual income uses 1976 tax-year data (2). this study reported that individuals failed to declare $75-$100 billion in legal income that year, resulting in a loss of $13-$17 billion in tax revenue. the greater part of business activity covered in the irs study was legal, but the participating individuals illegally failed to report the generated income. the same study estimated that unreported income from illicit trade costs the government some $6-$9 billion in lost tax revenues annually. however, as increasingly larger caches of illegal drugs are discovered, this amount may be understated. one bank in florida reports receiving $1.2 million in $20, $50, and $100 bills in one afternoon and more than $10 million in currency in one week, all from illegal cash transactions of its depositors (9). another bank in california reported its em ployees a.s 'almost suffering hernias' from having to carry in so many boxes of currency from a dope-dealing depositor (10). such efforts on the part of the underworld to 'launder' money have become commonplace. while no one can be sure of the exact size of the underground economy, it is certain that it is growing at a faster rate than the above ground economy. using an econometric model, professor feige estimated that during the 1970's the underground economy increased at 2 1/2 times the rate of the above ground economy (15). probably the most serious threat posed by the underground economy directly on legitim ate american businesses is in the area of illegally counterfeited products. the true extent of this aspect of the underground economy cannot be measured, but the counterfeit intelligence bureau in london estimates that up to $60 billion in annual world trade involved counterfeit products in 198-&. the united states house of representatives' energy and commerce committee recently estimated direct losses for american firms to counterfeit products at approximately -$20 billion annually. not only does product counterfeiting involve such consumer goods as cartier watches and cabbage patch dolls, but also chemicals, drugs, pesticides, military hardware, food, and thousands of replacement and component parts. the impact of counterfeit goods on one american based multinational corporation is shown by general motors' estimate that nearly 40 percent of all gm parts in the middle east are counterfeit (10). there are many factors that have caused the underground economy to flourish at an ever increasing rate. one such factor is the overall increase in criminal activity in recent decades, especially drug and narcotic trafficking. in addition to this, high income tax rates, overall inflation, and a distrust of government at all levels have caused many average citizens to explore the possibility of operating in the underground economy. because of actual and potential economic benefits, operating in the underground economy tends to be habit forming for the individuals directly involved, and it tends to spread like a communicable disease as others in society observe the apparent 35 economic rewards accruing to those operating in the underground economy_ in fact, because of the perceived low probability of legal punishment, the major deterrent for most individuals is their particular moral and ethical convictions. one measure of the level of these convictions is seen in the results of two recent surveys concerning cheating on income taxes. a 1984 poll commissioned anonymously by the internal revenue service found 19 percent of the respondents admitted being less than completely honest on their tax returns. a similar poll completed for u.s. news and world report in 1985 found 24 percent of the respondents admitted to dishonesty when filing federal income taxes (7). business iitlplications from the business point of view, it is useful to separate the underground economy into two large segments based on the legal dimensions of the activities. first, we have those economic activities that are illegal for all persons engaged in the production or marketing of the good or service. in this group we find businesses actively engaged in the drug market, trafficking in stolen goods, producing counterfeit goods and smuggling. for reference purposes, we have chosen to designate these as class i activities. again, readers are reminded that class i activities are all in violation of various local, state or federal laws. the second major segment of the underground economy is composed of legal economic activities, but which become illegal because of the way some dimension of the activity is handled. for example, hiring a carpenter to inst~ll storm windows on a house is a perfectly legal activity and paying him in cash is equally legal. however, if he fails to report this cash as income he is in violation of federal income tax laws. in this paper, all such activities are classified as class ii a.ctivities. class i activities businesses should never be involved in class i activities because they are illegal. however, such illegal economic activities are of major concern to business managers because of the following reasons: 1. smuggled, stolen and counterfeit goods are .sold in the market in competition with ordinary goods which tends to give their marketers an unfair cost profit / advantage. 2. huge potential tax revenues are lost in the class i segment of the economy. these are tax revenues that will have to be ultimately paid by the above ground segment of the economy. 3. efforts to police and punish offenders in the class i segment of the economy represents a major drain on governmental budgets at all levels of government. this is money that could and should be spent on more socially desirable projects. 36 4. the class i underground economy tends to have a corrupting influence on governmental officials through attempted bribery and political contributions; thus, lowering the overall efficiency of government. 5. consumer expenditures for illegal goods and services represent lost sales for the legitimate businesses of government. these class i aspects of the underground economy represent a major component of what has been called an 'unwholesome demand' (6). in such situations, the primary goal of the ethical business organization is to unsell the target market on the goods and services involved. unselling a market tends to be very slow, expensive and difficult because it often represents an attempt at intervening in the ways people think and behave. the time, difficulty, and expense associated with unselling a target market or the elimination of the 'unwholesome demand' helps explain why it tends to be most often a.tternpted by large corporations, trade associations, nonprofit organizations and governments. it is obviously desirable for businesses to be informed on the nature and extent of the class i segment of the underground economy. this is especially true when the illegal activity represents direct or indirect competition for their lines of business. also, because of the pro'bable inferior quality and performance of most counterfeit goods, business firms must be on the alert to take legal action against all types of offenders, as well as being ready to defend against product liability suits growing out of consumer injury from the use of counterfeit products and replacement parts. class ii activities business interest in the class ii segment of the underground economy stems from many of the same reasons as does their interest in the class i activities. namely, the unfair competitive element, lost tax revenues for governments, and social costs associated with legal enforcement. in addition, there is an ethical dimension when a marketer has reason to believe that one or more of his business contacts is operating in the class ii underground economy. for example, if a supplier of goods or services requests payment in cash, should the buyer report such a transaction to tax authorities on the presumption that the recipient does not plan to report the cash received as income? obviously, the answer to such ethical questions will depend upon the ethical standards of the persons involved. businesses that contend that they know very little about the underground economy surrounding their lines of business may be telling the truth, but if so, they are probably equally uninformed about the above ground economy in which they operate. for example, a good sales analysis will tell a business who is buying, what they are buying, how they are paying, who is making the sales, and how the goods are being shipped, such that an alert business will have a pretty good idea of the extent of his intentional and a.ccidental involvement in the underground economy. what is really being said is that the 37 extent of a firm's involvement in the underground economy is very dependent on the ethica.l values of the management personnel in the firm. impact on business planning use of incorrect data businesses who engage in strategic planning rely heavily on data from both public and private sources. it is a certainty that omission of data on the underground economy causes many economic indicators to understate the health of the u.s. economy and its various segments. it is widely believed that unemployment figures are too high and personal savings too low. peter gutmann of baruch college maintains that the underground economy causes the true unemployment rate to be overstated by two percentage points, or about 2 million people (15). in recent years,' economic statistics have indicated that personal savings have been decreasing. because of the increased activity in the underground economy, many economists and business planners believe that the commerce department's personal savings estimates are incorrect. further proof of the magnitude of this problem is seen by observing that at a given time the flow offund~ data from the federal reserve showed the savings rate could actually be as high as 9.4 percent at the time the department of commerce was estimating it to be 5.3 percent of disposable income. this translates into a difference of approxim ately $75 billion in savings. the use of incorrect economic data will certainly impact business planning. high unemployment and low personal savings data will cause businesses to be too conservative in their forecasting. in general, businesses may have held off on expansion-both in the purchase of capital equipment and in the addition of new product lines as a result of erroneous data which did not consider the operations of the underground economy. human resource planning the underground economy is even thought to be having a major impact in the area of human resource planning. consider that in 1980 the level of total employment rose by only 0.3 percent, but the number of self-employed rose by 3 percent to a new high of 6.9 million. in the decade of the 1970's, the number of self-employed increased 30 percent faster than did total employment (15). large business corporations appear to be suffering most from this move to become self-employed as increasing numbers of highly skilled personnel have left after the corporation had invested heavily in developing their various abilities. while no data appears to be available on the true extent of talented people moving into the underground economy, the mere fact that the underground economy exists and is growing rapidly among self-employed people leads the authors to believe that many of these talented people are contributing to the growth of the underground economy. sumdlary and conclusions existing environmental factors indicate that the underground economy will continue to grow at a faster rate than the above ground economy_ in38 creases in the level of criminal activity, high taxes, inflation, changing moral values, and a general distrust of government all point toward this trend. the total business implications of the underground economy are numerous, complicated and varied. when analyzing the und,erground economy it is useful to divide it into two broad segments. the first segment, which we have designated as the class i segment, is composed of business activities that are illegal in all respects and should never be practiced. the second major segment of the underground economy has been designated the class ii segment and refers to those business activities that are not inherently illegal, but certain aspects of these business activities become illegal when practiced in an illegal way. the underground economy has caused many businesses to offer a dual pricing structure rewarding customers with special discounts if they pay cash instead of using checks or credit cards. it has also fostered increases in bartering among both households and businesses, and may be contributing toward the growing level of self-employment; particularly in markets where it is relatively easy for the business person to conceal profits. changing moral and ethical values of our society coupled with the inabilit~y of legal authorities to· enforce laws governing activities involved in the underground economy also point toward the continued rapid growth of this segrnent of the american economy. in fact, unless the non-participants in the underground economy become concerned to the point of drastic political or legal action, the underground economy will eventually become so large as to seriously cripple the health and efficiency of the above ground economy. references 1. batt, "'illiam. "the underground economy: what is it? how big is it? and how is it f\1easured?" manhattan college journal of busines~ fall, 1985, pp. 5-10. 2. "estimates of income unreported on individual income tax returns," department of the treasury, internal revenue service, publication 1104, pp. 9-79. 3. feige, edgar. "the irregular economy: its size and macroeconomic implications," working paper 7916, social system research institute. 4. gutmann, peter. "the subterranean economy," financial analysts journal, november-december, 1977, pp. 23-26. 5. haulk, charles, j. "thoughts on the underground economy," economic review of the federal reserve bank of atlanta march-april, 1980, pp. 23-24. 6. kotler, philip. "the major tasks of marketing management," journal of marketing, october, 1973, pp. 41-49. 39 7. mcbee, susanna. "morality," u.s. news & world report, december 9, 1985, pp. 52-58. 8. molefsky, barry. "the underground economy in the united states and abroad," conference board, federal reserve system. 9. montgomery, jim. "feds crack down on 'laundering' of narcotics money," the wall street journal, march 12, 1981, p.l. 10. o'donnell, thomas c., et ai, "the counterfeit trade," business week, december 16, 1985, pp. 64-72. 11. penn, stanley, "narcotics agents track big cash transactions to trap dope dealers," the wall street journal, november 2226, 1980, p.l. 12. poweii~ eileen a. "irs chief lists achievements as he departs," the wall street journal, november 5, 1980, p. 27. 13. simon, carl p. and ann d. witte, beating the system, chicago: auburn press~ 1982. 14. "the income farmers hide,'~ business h"eek, april 17, 1978, pp. 91-92. 15. "the underground economy's hidden force," business week, i\pril 5, 1982, pp. 64-70. 16. "the ltnderground econoffi)t's hidden force," the wall street journal, january 21, 1981, p.l. 17. "underground economy: $100 billion jn lost taxes," u.s. news & world report, april 19, 1982, pp. 48-49. 40 the impact of the underground economy on american business volume 32, number 2 139 net present value simulation: a case study robert stretcher sam houston state university • huntsville, texas introduction this paper presents a strategy for teaching monte carlo simulation using the case of a capital expansion decision for arkmed corporation, a small biomedical device manufacturer located in houston, texas. the company is considering investing in a facility that can provide custom products using 3d printing. the facility would serve the custom orthotics and solid implant needs of the medical community of the greater houston metropolitan area. a simulation of the financial feasibility of the new facility is appropriate since the manufacturing method is unfamiliar to the firm’s management, and because the facility would serve a custom ordered product that would be expeditiously provided, within a few hours to a few days, unlike the company’s current business. the case provides an opportunity to augment coverage of capital budgeting scenario analysis, and to give students an exercise that requires multi-page referencing in excel. it also can provide output data that can be summarized into a histogram and frequency distribution chart. this process allows for a visual of the risk that a project could return a negative npv result. the distribution of npvs thus provides better information on which to base a capital asset expansion decision than would a discrete npv value based on averages of sales growth, expense ratios, and tax rate. case assignment given to students mark findley finished off the last of the coffee and started a new pot brewing. he was waiting for a message from the vice president of arkmed corporation. a new expansion project had been proposed, and it would be mark’s responsibility to analyze the project. the firm had never invested in a project of this type before, a production facility that would custom “print” biomedical devices with a 3d printer. the firm had other types of custom manufacture, so mark figured he could use knowledge from those facilities for cost estimates, but the potential sales could range from disappointing, making little use of the capacity of the plant to full capacity, where the plant would be used around the clock. randle gere, the vice president, finally called. “mark! i’ve asked roberts in operations to coordinate with atwood in cost 140 journal of business strategies accounting to get you operating cost estimates for the new plant. they should be emailing you a spreadsheet soon.” “what is our timing, mr. gere?” asked mark. “do i need to stay late today?” “no, no not necessary. in fact they are both staying late to provide you with the information. you can just do it tomorrow. can you get me your output and a report by the end of the day tomorrow? “not a problem,” mark responded. “i will get it to you around mid-afternoon.” because of the unfamiliarity of 3d printing technology and the range of possible sales, mark planned to carry out a simulation for the net present value of the project. the simulation was similar to other npv analyses he had carried out in the past. he had been with arkmed for four years and had taken over the “chief” position for the forecasting and analytics office after his boss had retired last year. mark had already heard from the firm’s marketing manager, who had done a breakdown of expected revenues by sales region, based on custom manufacturing sales for other products the firm offered. the facility under consideration was sort of a wild card, though, because business would be based mainly on quick turnaround. measurements and specifications would be provided by technicians dealing with patients, an order submitted electronically, and then arkmed would “print” the custom device, coat it with sterile coatings, package it in sterile packing, and expedite delivery to the hospital or medical office where the procedure was being done. while these devices could be delivered in as little as half a day, it was also possible that quick delivery would not be so critical, and that the firm could schedule production within a three to four day window. there was thus potential for the facility to produce at capacity, but it was also possible that there would be times where the three to four day backlog would be completed with no new orders in the queue. that brought about the possibility of idle capacity, but a full staff would have to be retained in order to handle new orders as they came in. the resulting variation in sales could be significant. mark had waited until 7:00 pm, working on other forecasting tasks, and the email from roberts and atwood finally came in. mark began summarizing the analytical inputs for his simulation immediately (exhibit 1). he then structured the inputs into the typical inputs page template in excel (exhibit 2) so that he could spend the next day carrying out the simulation and writing up a brief for mr. gere. volume 32, number 2 141 exhibit 1. mark’s summary. 2015 sales estimate (as if the project were already up and running): $2,748,000 expected sales growth per year: 2016: 8%, 2.8% std deviation 2017: 6.2%, 5.2% std deviation 2018: 6%, 2.5% std deviation 2019: 4%, 2.7% std deviation 2020: 3.5%, 3.1% std deviation 2021: 2%, 3.5% std deviation 2022: 2%, 3.7% std deviation 2023: 2%, 3.8% std deviation 2024: 2%, 4% std deviation 2025: 2%, 4.1% std deviation cash expenses: 2016: 34% of sales, 1.3% std deviation 2017: 34% of sales, 1.5% std deviation 2018: 34% of sales, 1.6% std deviation 2019: 34% of sales, 1.8% std deviation 2020: 34% of sales, 2.0% std deviation 2021: 34% of sales, 2.2% std deviation 2022: 34% of sales, 2.4% std deviation 2023: 34% of sales, 2.6% std deviation 2024: 34% of sales, 2.7% std deviation 2025: 34% of sales, 2.8% std deviation $7,997,000 asset expansion, depreciated on a 7-year macrs schedule, with a 10-year life 142 journal of business strategies macrs 7-year depreciation percentages per year: year 1 14.29% year 2 24.49% year 3 17.49% year 4 12.49% year 5 8.93% year 6 8.92% year 7 8.93% year 8 4.46% tax rates expected: 33.4% of ebit on average, 1.6% standard deviation, based on higher income levels after the expansion and expected political action concerning tax policy) appropriate discount rate for the project: 18.9% volume 32, number 2 143 exhibit 2. mark’s input parameters page. 144 journal of business strategies teaching strategy for the case this simulation will involve many rows of calculated data. spreadsheets, by default, recalculate the entire workbook when any equation is entered. wait time may become problematic when 10,000 iterations times seven pages is recalculating. to speed things up a bit, students may want to turn off autocalculation. this is done in excel 2003 by selecting tools… options… calculate from the toolbar and select “manual” or in excel 2007 by selecting formulas... calculation options... “manual.” the user can then recalculate the workbook at any time by pressing f9. students might also benefit from some guidance on how to specify random numbers or normally distributed random numbers: the “math and trig” function rand() generates uniformly-distributed random numbers. random normallydistributed numbers with, for example, a mean 100 and standard deviation 20, can be generated using the “statistical” function norm.inv, specifying uniform random number inputs rand() within the norm.inv formula: norm. inv(rand(),100,20)). this can also be specified by selecting formulas... more... statistical... norm.inv and entering rand(), 100, and 20, as the specifications. for a bit more orderly analysis, students should set up a standard workbook with five worksheets: mark’s inputs page, sales, cash expenses, nocf, and pvnocf. the “inputs” worksheet (mark’s exhibit) lists the parameters of the model. in the rest of the worksheets, it is most convenient to put the data in “row form” – see exhibit 3 for an example sales worksheet. the sales worksheet generates data as a simple random growth rate model. specifically, salest+1=salest*(1+gt). for each cell of data, the growth rate is normally distributed, with mean and standard deviation specified in the “parameters” worksheet. since each year’s sales may be serially correlated, the sales figure for each year should be based on the prior year’s sales times (1+gt). an initial (year zero) sales figure is shown in cell a17 in exhibit 2. this is used as a base to calculate the expected sales in year 1 (2016). panel a of exhibit 3 shows the syntax for the fx input field for the 2016 sales calculation. each subsequent year’s calculation is based on the prior year’s calculation. once the calculation is established for 2017, the cell can be dragged (copied) to all other years by dragging the cell to year 2025. the student’s own result will differ since every student will have different randomly selected inputs. although only a few rows of data are shown as an example here, the students’ spreadsheets will have 10,000 rows of data per sheet, dragging the row b3:k3 down to 10,000 lines. the remaining worksheets are constructed in a volume 32, number 2 145 similar fashion, with 10,000 rows each by 10 years of projections (2016-2025) in the columns. exhibit 3. sales worksheet visual. panel a panel b the cash expenses worksheet contains values calculated simply as percentages of estimated sales. for convenience, base the cash expenses in a specified cell on the same column and row specified cell from the sales sheet, and the same for the other sheets. exhibit 4 shows a sample, again with the calculations for cells b3 and b4 shown in the fx field. 146 journal of business strategies exhibit 4. cash expense worksheet visual. panel a panel b in this simple model, nocf is calculated as: (salest cash expensest depreciationt)*(1-tax rate)+depreciationt exhibit 5 shows a sample, again with the calculations for cells b3 and b4 shown in the fx field. exhibit 5. nocf worksheet visual. panel a volume 32, number 2 147 panel b the last worksheet is the present value of nocft. recall that: pv(nocft) = nocft/[1+δ] (t-2015) where δ is the discount rate for cashflows. exhibit 6 shows a sample, again with the calculations for cells b3 and b4 shown in the fx field. exhibit 6. pvnocf worksheet visual. panel a panel b 148 journal of business strategies on the pvnocf sheet, construct a single column of data for pv(ncf) within the pvncf worksheet by summing the ten years of pvnocfs. then create another column subtracting the initial cash outlay from the pvnocf total, to get a column of 10,000 npvs. exhibit 7. sum of pvnocf column and npv column visual. excluding the “inputs” worksheet, each worksheet should have a header row representing years 2016-2025 and a single row of data. this single row represents one possible future for our company (based on the chosen parameters). the purpose of the simulation is to generate many realizations of the future and use the distribution of valuations to make meaningful insights into the economic value of the project under consideration. to do so, we must fill each of the data worksheets with 10,000 rows of data. if the formulas were carefully constructed (with proper relative and/ or absolute cell addressing) then this is a trivial matter. for example, suppose you have data in cells b3:k3 and you want to fill in the next 1,000 rows. to do so, click the “name box” in the upper left hand corner and type b3:k1002. this will highlight a block of cells. from the edit menu, select fill->down and all contents are copied. do this for the sales, cash expenses, nocf, and pvnocf worksheets. after all the data is filled, students should be sure to manually recalculate the cells if autocalculation is off (note: the fill can also be accomplished by ‘dragging’ the cell or cells through to the 10,000th line using excel’s “+” function). to create the column of 10,000 npv’s on the pvnocf sheet, or each row (iteration), sum the pvnocf for all ten years and subtract the initial cash outlay, $7,997,000. add descriptive statistics of the distribution of npv to the parameters worksheet. specifically, calculate the minimum, median, mean, maximum, and volume 32, number 2 149 standard deviation of npv using excel’s automated statistical functions (or use the data analysis toolpack to calculate all these measures and more in a single step). an analysis with this level of sophistication has the potential of making or breaking a capital budgeting decision, or the decision by a capital provider to either fund the project or not. absence of an analysis such as this may cause the same to question the firm’s ability to provide valid estimations of the impact of the project on the welfare of the firm’s shareholders. a chart of the distribution of npv’s is a good visual to see the likelihood, given the input distributions, that a positive (or negative) npv would occur. the negative probability can be calculated easily by counting all of the negative npv’s out of 10,000 (this is the probability of a negative npv). the same can be repeated for the positive values. exhibit 8 shows an example of the resulting frequency distribution, created by charting the histogram output using the histogram function in the data analysis toolpack, with an indicator line showing the critical npv value of zero drawn in. while each student’s result will differ a bit from this visual, it is clear to see that the npv has a greater likelihood of being positive, but there is also substantial risk that the npv could be negative as well. exhibit 8. frequency distribution of npv’s. an optional requirement could be to request that students prepare a professional report and correspondence, taking the role of mark, and selling the analysis to upper management. 150 journal of business strategies a solution excel workbook may be downloaded by jbs readers from the author’s website: www.shsu.edu/~fin_rhs/jbssolution.xlsx brief biographical sketch of author dr. robert stretcher is a professor of finance at sam houston state university. he earned his phd in finance and monetary economics from the university of tennessee. his research focuses on empirical market studies, applied finance, and finance education. dr. stretcher has held prominent positions in the academy of economics and finance and the institute of finance case research, and has served on editorial boards and as editor of various finance journals. an empirical examination of the relationship between the background characteristics of the ceo and overall corporate reputation peter a. stanwick sarah d. stanwick auburn university auburn,al abstract this paper examines the relationship between the overall corporate reputation ofan organization and the background characteristics ofthe chiefexecutive officers (ceos) across twenty one major industry classifications. four background characteristics are examined: (1) age, (2) tenure with the company, (3) tenure as ceo, and (4) functional background (career path). these characteristics are explored by examining the overall corporate reputation ofthe organization through a proxy, the fortune corporate reputation index. drawing on past research in the area of background characteristics (hambrick and mason, 1984) and corporate reputation (fombrun and shanley, 1990), hypotheses were tested which examined the background characteristics ofceos and the company soverall corporate reputation. the results of this paper show that, in general, the ceo's background characteristics impact the level of overall corporate reputation of the firm. the type offunctional background of the ceo has a significant positive impact on the level of overall corporate reputation. over afour year time period (1990 to 1994), age, tenure with the company, and tenure as ceo were negatively related to the overall corporate reputation oforganizations that retained their ceo, forfirms that had replaced the ceo, a positive relationship between overall corporate reputation and tenure with the company and age was discovered. introduction fombrun and shanley (1990) state that a firm's corporate reputation can send a strong signal of how well a company is performing compared with other firms in the industry. a strong favorable corporate reputation demonstrates the firm's ability to properly position the firm's products and the effective implementation of the firm's strategies. both caves and porter (1977) and wilson (1985) argue that a favorable corporate reputation can yield excess financial returns for firms by generating a competitive advantage by differentiating themselves from their competitors. a critical component in the development of a competitive advantage is the decision making by the top level management within the organization in142 journal ofbusiness strategies vol. 14, no.2 eluding the ceo. the ceo is considered a dominant force in the decision making process of an organization (beatty and zajac, 1987). dalton and kesner (1985) state that the ceo is the central focal point within the organization. therefore, the purpose of this study is to the examine the relationship between the overall corporate reputation of a firm and the background characteristics of the ceo. this study examines the relationship between background characteristics which include: (1) age, (2) functional background (career path), (3) tenure with the company, and (4) tenure as ceo with the company_ these characteristics are compared with the organization's fortune corporate reputation index. theoretical framework and hypothesis development the underlying theoretical framework is based on a seminal work by hambrick and mason (1984). hambrick and mason (1984) proposed that specific characteristics of top level managers influenced the type of strategic choices made by the firm. as a result, it is proposed in this study that the background characteristics of the ceo can impact the "strategy" of developing a favorable overall corporate reputation. hambrick and mason (1984) present a number of observable upper echelon characteristics which include: functional track, age, and tenure. functional background hambrick and mason (1984) separate functional tracks into three different segments: (1) output functions, (2) throughput functions, and (3) peripheral functions. executives with output functions (marketing, sales, and product research and development) are expected to emphasize growth, product innovation, and the development of new market opportunities. chaganti and sambharya (1987) discovered that firms that were proactive in their approach to new product and new market development had a higher level of executives who had a marketing andlor research and development background. thomas, litschert, and ramaswamy (1991) also discovered that high performing proactive finns had ceos with an output functional background. ceos with an output functional background are committed to the belief that an aggressive proactive strategic philosophy will yield high performance results. output based ceos will be more likely to be not only committed, but are also more likely to convert product innovation efforts into actual product innovations (barbosa, 1985). barbosa (1985) discovered that ceos with marketing experience were more likely to transfer research and development innovations into new products. barbosa (1985) asserts that firms with a ceo who has a marketing background are more likely to: be creative, be market driven, and believe in growth opportunities for the firm. ceos with an output functional background focus on the aggressive expansion of the firm based on examining new product and/or market related opportunities. the ceos believe that the long term success of the firm is based on incorfall 1997 stanwick & stanwick: an empirical examination 143 porating a "pioneering" perspective by embracing new opportunities and new technologies. they believe that a favorable overall corporate reputation could lead to a competitive advantage in the marketplace (caves and porter, 1977; wilson, 1985). these ceos will encourage creative and market driven solutions which would result in favorable overall corporate reputations. it is also posited that ceos with a throughput functional background (production, process engineering, or accounting) are concerned with improving the efficiency of the overall organization by such actions as automation and the improvement of plant and equipment. thomas, litschert, and ramaswamy (1991) found that firms that focused on stability and efficiency had ceos who had a throughput functional background. therefore, the ceos are not as proactive in their strategic focus. strategic issues are classified based on a focus of efficiency. as a result, it is expected that firms with a throughput ceo will have less favorable corporate reputations than ceos with an output functional background. peripheral functional background (law and finance) are functions that are not directly involved with the organization's core activities. song (1982) found that ceos with a peripheral functional background focused on growth opportunities by acquiring firms that were unrelated to the firm's core business. hambrick and mason (1984) assert that peripheral functional ceos do not focus on strategies that relate to the core operations of the firms (i.e., new productlmarket development or efficiency issues) since they do not have the necessary "hands on" experience in their core business. as a result, ceos with a peripheral functional background are more likely to have a reactive instead of a proactive stance concerning strategic issues. therefore, the development of new products which would incorporate new market opportunities would not be developed in a firm with a peripheral ceo nor would the integration of efficiency issues take place as they would with a firm that has a throughput ceo. as a result, it is expected that firms with a ceo with a peripheral functional background will have the least favorable overall corporate reputations. therefore, the following hypothesis is empirically tested in this study: hypothesis 1: firms with ceos with a peripheral functional background will have the least favorable overall corporate reputations. ceo tenure previous research on the relationship between the ceo's age, tenure, and decision making have yielded conflicting results. some studies have shown that ceos that are younger and have less tenure are more flexible and proactive in their decision making (hambrick and fukutomi, 1991; miller, 1991). hambrick and fukutomi (1991) state that there are certain seasons of tenure for a ceo. for the first two years of tenure, the ceo will make organizational adjustments to 144 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 match the ceo's vision. up to the first four years of tenure, the ceo will experiment with new ideas as a re-configuration of the organization occurs. after this relatively short period of time, the ceo becomes further committed to the existing paradigm. as a result, a status quo belief becomes firmly entrenched with a high level of rigidity and commitment to the established policies and procedures of the organization. therefore, as the tenure of the ceo increases, so does the resistance to change by the ceo of the current operations of the organization (finkelstein and hambrick 1990). finkelstein and hambrick (1990) also discovered that there is a positive relationship between the tenure of the ceo and general strategic philosophy of other firms in the industry. chaganti and sambharya (1987) examined the relationship between tenure and strategic focus and discovered that ceos with a long length of tenure focused on stability and efficiency issues, while ceos with less tenure concentrated on more proactive strategies including new product and new market development. the age of the ceo or the 'tenure of life' (finkelstein and hambrick, 1996) has also been empirically examined and has shown the same inverse relationship with pro-activeness and flexibility that was shown with tenure with the organization. vroom and pahl (1971) found a negati ve association between age and risk taking in the decision making process. this finding was supported in subsequent work which demonstrated an inverse relationship between age and product/market innovation strategies (thomas et ai., 1991) and strategic change (grimm and smith, 1991; wiersema and bantel, 1992). therefore, it is expected that tenure would also have an inverse relationship with overall corporate reputation of the organization. based on the ceo seasons of tenure presented by hambrick and fukutomi (1991), a four year time period was selected. hambrick and fukutomi (1991) categorize the tenure of the ceo into 5 major seasons which are: response to mandate (i to 2 years), experimentation (1 to 2 years), selection of an enduring theme (1 to 2 years), convergence (3 to 5 years), and dysfunction (all remaining years). the four year time frame allows the ceo to potentially go into the fourth season (selection of an enduring theme). therefore, this would reduce the probability that the sample would just demonstrate the strategic actions of new ceos. based on the work of miller (1991) and hambrick and fukutomi (1991), it is proposed that over a specific time period (1990 to 1994), there will be an inverse relationship between age and the overall corporate reputation of the organization. it is expected that younger ceos will implement strategic activities that will enhance the overall corporate reputation of the firm. in addition, it is proposed that within a specific time period (1990 to 1994) firms with ceos with less tenure in the organization and less tenure as ceo will have more favorable overall corporate reputations since the ceos are less entrenched in the organization's overall beliefs (hambrick and fukutomi, 1991). since a change in ceo could occur within this four year time frame, the sample will be analyzed based on whether there has been a succession of the ceo or not. it is expected that the relationship between the characteristics will be the fall 1997 stanwick & stanwick: an empirical examination 145 same regardless of whether or not a ceo succession has occurred. as a result, the following hypotheses are empirically tested in this study: hypothesis 2: within a certain time period (1990 to 1994),firms with younger ceos will have more favorable overall corporate reputations. hypothesis 3: within a certain time period (1990 to 1994), firms with ceos with less tenure with the organization will have more favorable overall corporate reputations. hypothesis 4: within a certain time period (1990 to 1994),firms with ceos with less tenure as the ceo with the organization will have more favorable overall corporate reputations. in addition to examining the relationship between the background characteristics of the ceo and the overall corporate reputation of the organization, this paper examines these relationships across different industries. cross industry comparisons have been largely ignored in previous research on overall corporate reputations. methodology sample selection i. for hypothesis 1: the sample of firms for years 1990 and 1994 included in this study meet the following criteria: 1. the firm must be ranked in the fortune corporate reputation index. 2. the firm must be listed in business weeks corporate elite so that the background characteristics of the ceos can be examined. 3. the firm must be listed in fortune's top 1000 companies in order to obtain the firm's industry classification. this criteria resulted in the selection of 235 firms in 1990 and 267 firms in 1994. ii. for hypotheses 2-4: 1. the same criteria as stated in 1. in addition, 2. the firms must be in both the 1990 and the 1994 sample. 3. the firms are separated into two categories: a) firms that retain the same ceo and, b) firms that had a new ceo. this resulted in the selection of 169 firms in which 114 firms had the same ceo and 55 firms had a ceo succession. 146 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 overall corporate reputation overall corporate reputation is based on the fortune corporate reputation index. this index employs over 8,000 executives and outside industry experts who evaluate organizations within their own industry on eight different variables on a scale from zero (poor) to ten (excellent). the eight attributes are: (1) quality of management, (2) quality of products or services, (3) innovativeness, (4) longterm investment value, (5) financial soundness, (6) ability to attract, develop, and keep talented people, (7) wise use of corporate assets, and (8) responsibility to the community and the environment. based on the ranking of these eight variables, an overall reputation number is derived. previous research has used the fortune corporate reputation index to measure the relationship between overall corporate reputation and various accounting, institutional, and strategic signals presented by the firm (fombrun and shanley, 1990). in addition, previous research has also examined the relationship between corporate reputation and prior firm performance using the fortune corporate reputation index (hammond and slocum, 1996). previous studies have also supported the validity of this instrument by using all or part of the fortune corporate reputation index as a measurement of corporate social performance (hoft, hunger and shrader, 1991; mcguire, sundgren and schneeweiss, 1988; thomas and simerly, 1994; wokutch and spencer, 1987). functional background functional background was coded based on the description given in business week s corporate elite. after examining the description of the functional background, it was evident that numerous ceos had multiple functional backgrounds which could not be coded into only one categorization (output, throughput, or peripheral). in addition, the 1990 and 1994 sample did not yield enough observations of ceos with solely peripheral functional background (90 in 1990 and 116 in 1994) to identify significant differences. as a result, the functional backgrounds were grouped into two major categories which are: ceos whose functional background included peripheral training and ceos that did not. as was stated previously, peripheral functional background did not supply the ceo with the necessary "hands-on" experience to become actively involved in the strategic decisions about the core businesses of the firm. even though the ceos may have additional experience in other functional areas, this lack of grounded experience limits their ability to envision the potential benefits of new productj market development and efficiency gains that would enhance overall corporate reputations. as a result, if the ceo had a functional background in output or throughput or a combination of the two, they were classified into the non-peripheral group. if the ceos had functional backgrounds in peripheral or a combination of peripheral and throughput or output, they were classified as having a peripheral functional background. in the 1990 sample, 118 ceos were classified as having a non-peripheral functional background and 117 were classified as having fall 1997 stanwick & stanwick: an empirical examination 147 a peripheral functional background. in the 1994 sample, 127 ceos were classified as having a non-peripheral functional background and 140 ceos were classified as having a peripheral functional background. industry classifications the industries were classified based on the categorizations used in the forbes 500 listing. results a total of 235 firms in 1990 and 267 firms in 1994 were examined. the results showed that firms with favorable overall corporate reputations have a higher incidence of peripheral functional background ceos which is the opposite direction of the relationship that was proposed in hypothesis 1. in addition, when the ceos remain the same over the four year time period, firms with favorable overall corporate reputations had a higher incidence of younger ceos, with less tenure within the organization and less tenure as ceo which supports hypotheses 2 through 4. however, the relationship showed an opposite pattern when a new ceo took over during the four year time period. table 1 provides descriptive statistics for both samples of firms. table 1 descriptive statistics mean std dev minimum maximum 1990 sample rep90 6.36 0.92 3.10 8.86 age 57.58 6.26 41.00 92.00 ten 25.67 11.52 1.00 54.00 tenceo 7.41 7.60 0.50 45.00 1994 sample rep94 6.48 0.81 3.65 8.65 age 57.29 5.80 38.00 79.00 ten 24.67 11.49 1.00 55.00 tenceo 8.44 7.69 1.00 55.00 index: rep90 =fortune corporate reputation index for 1990 rep94 =fortune corporate reputation index for 1994 age =age of the ceo ten =number of years of tenure in the company by the ceo tenceo =number of years of tenure as ceo 148 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 the mean ofthe fol1une corporate reputation index was 6.36 in 1990 and 6.48 in 1994. in addition, this table shows that in 1990, the ceos average age was 57.58 years, tenure with the company was 25.67 years, and tenure as ceo was 7.41 years. the same information for 1994 indicated that the average age was 57.29 years, tenure with the company was 24.67 years, and tenure as ceo was 8.44 years. regression analysis was used to examine the relationship between the firm's overall corporate reputation and the background characteristics of the ceo of the firm. using regression analysis, the results showed that there were indeed strong relationships between the background characteristics of the ceo and the level of overall corporate reputation. in the 1990 sample, the results showed a significant positive relationship between age and overall corporate reputation (t=2.09, p<.0379) and tenure as ceo and overall corporate reputation (t=2.73, p<.oo69) as indicated in table 2. table 2 regression results for overall corporate reputation all finns in the 1990 sample dependent variable = rep90 source model error total df 7 227 234 sum of square 13.1701 188.5911 201.7612 mean square 1.8814 0.8307 fvalue 2.26 prob>f 0.0302* r-square :: 0.0652 variable parameter standard t for ho: prob>t estimate error parameter=o intercept 2.3723 1.6818 1.41 0.1597 tenceo 0.4683 0.1717 2.73 0.0069* age 0.0609 0.0291 2.09 0.0379* ten 0.0898 0.0680 1.32 0.1877 age"'ten -0.0012 0.0011 -1.10 0.2739 tenceo*age -0.0069 0.0027 -2.55 0.0113* tenceo* ten -0.0109 0.0052 -2.10 0.0370* tenceo* age*ten 0.0001 0.0000 1.97 0.0495* *significant at p :: 0.05 index: rep90 :: fortune corporate reputation index for 1990 age:: age of the ceo ten :: number of years of tenure in the company by the ceo tenceo :: number of years of tenure as ceo fall 1997 stanwick & stanwick: an empirical examination 149 in addition, there were significant interactions between tenure as ceo and age and tenure, and a significant three way interaction among all three of the variables, also as indicated in table 2. table 3 presents the results from ex.amining overall corporate reputations of firms with a ceo who was classified as having a peripheral functional background. table 3 regression results for overall corporate reputation for firms with a ceo with a peripheral functional background 1990 sample dependent variable =rep90 source df sum of square mean square fvalue prob>f model 7 16.0056 2.2865 2.52 0.0192* error 109 98.7721 0.9061 total 116 114.7778 r-square ;;;: 0.1394 variable parameter standard t for ho: prob>t estimate error parameter=o intercept -1.0487 2.5825 -0.41 0.6855 tenceo 0.5040 0.2878 1.75 0.0827# age 0.1210 0.0464 2.61 0.0104* ten 0.2038 0.1061 1.92 0.0575# age*ten -0.0032 0.0018 -1.78 0.0780# tenceo*age -0.0070 0.0049 -1.43 0.1546 tenceo*ten -0.0139 0.0072 -1.93 0.0558# tenceo* age*ten 0.0001 0.0001 1.72 0.0891# #significant at p =0.10 *significant at p = 0.05 index: rep90 =fortune corporate reputation index for 1990 age =age of the ceo ten = number of years of tenure in the company by the ceo tenceo = number of years of tenure as ceo results for firms with a ceo classified as having a peripheral career path had a significant positive relationship with age and overall corporate reputation (t=2.61, p<.ol04), tenure and overall corporate reputation (t=1.92, p<.0575), and tenure as ceo and overall corporate reputation (t=1.75, p<.0827). in addition, the results yielded significant interactions between age and tenure, and tenure as ceo and tenure with 150 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 the firm. a significant three way interaction between the three variables was also present. therefore, the results show a significant relationship in the opposite direction than was proposed in hypothesis 1. finns with a favorable overall corporate reputation had a higher incidence of peripheral functional background ceos. the regression analysis for the 1994 sample did not yield significant results. correlation analysis (tables 4 and 5) was used to examine the strength of the relationship between each of the variables examined in this study (reputation, age, tenure, tenure as ceo) from the time period 1990 to 1994 across all 21 industries. the firms were categorized based on whether the firm had replaced the ceo or not within the same period. for the 114 firms that had the same ceo from 1990 to 1994, there were a number of significant correlations. table 4 correlation analysis results change from 1990 to 1994 same ceos industry =computers/communications age ten tenceo crep94 -0.5703 -0.7532 -0.0808 0.1399 0.0310* 0.8491 industry =: consumer durab1es age ten tenceo crep94 0.1639 0.7445 0.4296 0.6509 0.0135* 0.2153 industry = consumer nondurables age ten tenceo crep94 -0.5825 -0.0531 0.1770 0.0998# 0.0819 0.6485 industry =: transportation age ten tenceo crep94 0.6594 -0.6725 -0.9980 0.5416 0.5304 0.0396* industry =: travel age ten tenceo crep94 -0.1316 -0.9998 -0.4488 0.9160 0.0108* 0.7037 #significant at p =0.10 *significant at p =0.05 index: crep94 =: change in fortune corporate reputation index from 1990 to 1994 age =age of the ceo ten =number of years of tenure in the company by the ceo tenceo = number of years of tenure as ceo fall 1997 stanwick & stanwick: an empirical examination 151 from the time period 1990 to 1994, there was an inverse relationship between tenure with the firm and the change in overall corporate reputation in the computer/communications and travel industry and a positive relationship in the consumer durables industry. there was an inverse relationship between age and the change in overall corporate reputation in the consumer nondurables and the health industry. there was an inverse relationship between tenure as ceo and the change in overall corporate reputation in the transportation industry. therefore, hypotheses 2 through 4 are supported. firms with a favorable overall corporate reputation who have the same ceos for the four year time period are younger and have less tenure as ceo and less tenure within the organization. there were also significant correlations for the 55 firms that did change their ceo within the time period 1990 to 1994. table 5 correlation analysis results change from 1990 to 1994 different ceos crep94 crep94 industry = capital goods age ·0.2184 0.7816 industry =computers/communications age crep94 -0.1088 0.8374 industry = consumer durables age 0.9997 0.0148* industry = foodldrinkffobacco age crep94 0.9501 0.0498* #significant at p=o.lo *significant at p=0.05 ten 0.9478 0.0521 * ten 0.8205 0.0454* ten 0.9856 0.1079 ten -0.0933 0.9067 tenceo tenceo 0.2644 0.6126 tenceo 0.9063 0.2778 tenceo 0.3994 0.6005 index: crep94 = change in fortune corporate reputation index from 1990 to 1994 age = age of the ceo ten = number of years of tenure in the company by the ceo tenceo = number of years of tenure as ceo 152 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 there was a positive relationship between tenure with the compapy and the change in overall corporate reputation in the capital goods and computers/communications industry. there was a positive relationship between age and the change in the overall corporate reputation of the firms in the consumer durables and the food/drink/tobacco industries. in contrast to the relationships presented in hypotheses 2 through 4, for firms that had a change in ceo, firms with a favorable overall corporate reputation had older ceos who had more tenure within the organization. conclusions and suggestions for future research the results of this study highlight the complex relationship between the background characteristics of the ceo and the overall corporate reputation of the firm. the results show that, in general, the background characteristics of the ceo do impact the overall corporate reputation. the surprising positive relationship between peripheral functional background and overall corporate reputation can be explained, in part, by recognizing the vast business experience of ceos. this study has demonstrated that ceos have exposure to multiple functional areas as they move up the corporate ladder. as a result, the broad functional training which ceos are exposed to may reduce the resistance to implementing strategies which would enhance the overall corporate reputation of the firm. the results of this study have shown the ceos with a peripheral functional background have been able to compensate for their lack of "hands on" experience as it relates to the firm's core business. through their exposure to different functions of the organization, peripheral ceos have been able to incorporate proactive strategies in their decision making processes. of equal importance is the significant difference between the various industries over the time periods of the study. for firms that retained their ceo, there were significant inverse relationships in five of the six industries. this demonstrates that tenure, tenure as ceo, and age do playa role in the level of overall corporate reputations of organizations. firms with ceos who are younger and have less time vested in the organization are more likely to have a favorable overall corporate reputation. these results support the view of hambrick and fukutomi (1991) and miller (1991) who state that as the ceo establishes himlherself in the ceo position, the ceo will firmly establish a rigid paradigm that will not be altered. the results of firms that have had a change in their ceo during the sample time period also provide some very interesting observations. contrary to what was proposed in hypotheses 2 through 4, the results showed a positive relationship between overall corporate reputation and tenure and age. this could be explained, in part, through the type of ceo succession that took place. of the four industries that had significant correlations, only two of the seventeen firms (11.7%) fall 1997 stanwick & stanwick: an empirical examination 153 had new ceos from outside the firm. therefore, ceo succession from within the company was the dominant form of succession. even though insider succession is considered to support maintenance of the current strategic focus (finkelstein and hambrick, 1996), the ceo succession event will create the opportunity to consider alternative viewpoints (hambrick and futukomni, 1991). since the new ceo is in the early "season" of hislher tenure, the ceo will accept adjustments in the existing paradigm. therefore, the positive relationship between overall corporate reputation and tenure and age is the result of new ceos with the willingness to accept alternative viewpoints. in addition, because the ceos have a long length of tenure with the organization, they previously have acquired a high level of experience about the operations of the organization (thomas and simerly, 1994). there are some limitations of this study that could be addressed in future research. the first limitation is the use of the fortune corporate reputation index. although the authors believe that the fortune corporate reputation index is a valid proxy for overall corporate reputation, the authors realize that this index is only one measure of a very complex construct. another limitation is that the sample contains data from only two years. an extension of this paper would include the tracking of overall corporate reputation over a number of consecutive years in order to examine whether there are trends in the data, possibly between industries. which could be identified. references barbosa, r. (1985). innovation in a mature industry. unpublished ph.d dissertation, columbia university: new york. beatty, r., & zajac, e. (1987). ceo change and firm performance in large corporations: succession effects and manager shifts. strate&ic management journal. 8, 305-317. caves, r., & porter, m. (1977). from entry barriers to mobility barriers. quarterly journal of economics. 91, 421-434. chaganti, r., & sambharya, r. (1987). strategic orientation and characteristics of upper management. strategic management journal. 8, 393-401. dalton, d., & kesner, i. (1985). organizational performance as an antecedent of inside! outside chief executive succession: an empirical assessment. academy of mana&ement journal. 28, 749-762. finkelstein, s., & hambrick, d. (1990). top management team tenure and organizational outcomes: the moderating role of managerial discretion. administrative science quarterly. 35,484-503. 154 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 finkelstein, s., & hambrick, d. (1996). strategic leadership: top executive and their effects on organizations. new york: west publishing. fombrun, c., & shanley, m. (1990). what's in a name? reputation building and corporate strategy. academy of management journal. 33,233-258. grimm, c. & smith, k. (1991). management and organizational change: a note on the railroad industry. strategic management journal. 12,557-562. hambrick d., & mason, p. (1984). upper echelons: the organization as a reflection of its top managers. academy of management review. 9, 193-206. hambrick d., & fukutomi, d. (1991). the seasons of a ceo's tenure. academy of management review. 16, 719-742. hammond, s., & slocum, j. (1996). the impact of prior firm financial performance on subsequent corporate reputation. journal of business ethics. 15, 159-165. hoft, 1., j. hunger, & shrader, c. (1991). characteristics of boards of directors and perceptions of corporate social responsibility: an examination of the fortune survey.lm!m.aj. of business strategies. 8, 77-85. mcguire, j., j. sundgren, & schneeweiss, t. (1988). corporate social responsibility and firm financial performance. academy of management journal. 31 i 854-872. miller, d. (1991). stale in the saddle: ceo tenure and the match between organization and environment. management science. 37, 34-52. thomas, a" r. litschert, & ramaswamy, k. (1991). the performance impact of strategymanager coalignment: an empirical examination. strategic management journal. 12, 509522. thomas, a. & simerly, r. (1994). the chief executive officer and corporate social performance: an interdisciplinary examination. journal of business ethics. 13, 959-968. song, j. (1982). diversification strategies and the experience of top executives of large firms. strategic management journal. 3, 377-380. vroom, v., & pabl, b. (1971). relationship between age and risk-taking among managers. journal of applied psychology. 55, 399-405. wiersema, m., & bantel, k. (1992). top management team demography and corporate strategic change. academy of management journal. 35, 91-121. wilson, r. (1985). reputations in games and markets. in a.e. roth (ed.), game-theoretic models of bargaining. new york: cambridge university press. 65-84. fall 1997 stanwick & stanwick: an empirical examination 155 wokutch, r. & spencer, b. (1987). corporate saints and sinners: the effects of philanthropic and illegal activity on organizational performance. california management review. 29,62-77. appendix major industry classifications aerospaceldefense business services/supplies capital goods chemicals computers/communications construction consumer durables consumer nondurables electric utilities energy entertainmentlinformation financial services food distributors foodldrinkftobacco forest productslpackaging health insurance metals retailing transportation travel dr. peter a. stanwick received his ph.d. in strategic management from florida state university. he is an assistant professor in the department of management at auburn university. dr. sarah d. stanwick received her ph.d. in accounting from florida state university. she is an assistant professor in the school of accountancy at auburn university. an empirical examination of the relationship between the background characteristics of the ceo and overall corporate reputation volume 34, number 1 thunder up the taxes! kyle dean oklahoma city university • oklahoma city, oklahoma russell evans oklahoma city university • oklahoma city, oklahoma jonathan willner oklahoma city university • oklahoma city, oklahoma abstract oklahoma city taxpayers approved a 1% sales tax to raise an estimated $120 million for improvements to lure the seattle supersonics, now the oklahoma city thunder. city civic leaders engaged a “big league city” campaign, touting economic growth, increased business activity and jobs, and better quality of life as reasons to support the initiative. we evaluate the “big league city” economic claims using local sales tax revenues to estimate the level and growth impacts resulting from the relocation of the now oklahoma city thunder. we find no significant relationship between the operation of the franchise and contemporaneous sales tax collections. however, we find a modest positive significant relationship between the presence of the franchise and the year-over-year growth rate of aggregate sales tax collections, providing some support for the amenity “big league city” argument. keywords: sports, tax revenue introduction in 2008 the former seattle supersonics of the national basketball association (nba) began the 2008 – 2009 season as the oklahoma city thunder. in a wellpublicized move, new owners based in oklahoma city relocated the franchise to oklahoma’s capital city. as a relocation incentive, oklahoma city residents agreed to continue a 1% temporary sales tax to fund improvements to the then “ford center” arena and to fund the construction of a new team practice facility. passed in march of 2008, the tax lasted 15 months and raised just over $105 million in revenues to fund the thunder projects. according to forbes’ christopher helman (2012), the oklahoma city-based owners purchased the franchise with the promise to remain in seattle “so long as we are able to negotiate an attractive successor venue and lease arrangement”. following a protracted discussion, the seattle legislature failed to approve the 2 journal of business strategies necessary incentives for new construction and the franchise owner group set the move to oklahoma city in motion. oklahoma city gained experience hosting an nba franchise, the new orleans hornets, after hurricane katrina. the city served as the hornets’ temporary host for two seasons (2005-06 and 2006-07). hosting the hornets created enthusiasm for the nba within okc. the experience provided positive evidence of the city’s ability to support an nba franchise; the announced paid attendance averaged 18,737 per game according to an economic impact study by bryant and evans (2007). while citizens hoped to retain the hornets, their relocation to okc was temporary and they returned to new orleans after only two seasons. however, the hornets experience changed the expectations of okc residents and signaled to the nba that okc was in the market and could support an nba franchise. without support from seattle taxpayers, the new ownership group decided to move the team after okc voters approved the extension of an existing $0.01 (1%) sales tax to fund arena and practice facility improvements. the sales tax extension was widely supported by local leaders as a means to increase economic activity and create long run growth, in turn making okc a desirable place to live and work. okc voters had previously approved two sales tax initiatives beginning in 1993 aimed at increasing local amenities, the metropolitan area projects (maps) and maps for kids. in a supportive “vote yes” television advertisement, mayor mick cornett along with two previous mayors, kirk humphries and ron norick stated “…just like maps, improving the ford center will grow our economy, help attract even more companies, creating better paying jobs and improving quality of life”. using the tagline “big league city,” the message was clear that local leaders expected a long-run amenity effect from the relocated franchise. the potential impacts from professional sports franchises may include both contemporaneous impacts on local sales tax collections and long run impacts on local labor markets and business development from the improved local amenity package and quality of life enhancement. we investigate both impact avenues in the body of this paper. the empirical investigation is intentionally limited to oklahoma city in an effort to identify case-specific fiscal and amenity effects. the relevant literature is reviewed in the next section followed by a discussion of the data and methodology, results, and a conclusion. volume 34, number 3 literature the economic benefits of sports franchises are difficult to estimate. indeed, even obtaining agreement on the term “benefit” is a challenge as evidenced by the multiple approaches for estimation used in the literature. the first best method for determining the net value of public expenditure is to compare total benefits to total costs and estimate the net present value of net benefits for the years of implementation and operation. while the cost of local investment is relatively easy to calculate, benefit calculation requires the estimation of both use and non-use values as well as local growth benefits that may or may not occur due to amenity induced migration. these non-use and growth benefits are at best, difficult to determine and at worst, unknowable. non-use valuation can be estimated, as seen by johnson et al (2001), but the problem of determining the appropriate stakeholders still exists. haughwout and inman (2002) and rappaport (2005) find that the benefits of local amenities are shared between central city and suburban dwellers, as the urban and suburban areas grow (or decline) together. in the case of a top-level sports franchise, the suggestion that cooperative efforts between the urban and suburban areas are likely to yield the best outcome for the region should result in cost sharing agreements, yet in practice, it is difficult to convince suburbs to bear, at least partially, any of the development costs. in oklahoma city, voters within the city agreed to the continued 1% sales tax premium without explicit participation from nearby suburbs. suburban residents contributed to the funding efforts only to the extent that local market conditions allowed for the tax to be successfully exported. studies examining the economic impact of hosting athletic events and franchises admit that the impact is generally negative to neutral, with a few exceptions worth noting. coates and humphreys (1999) find an overall negative effect on per capita income from supporting professional sports franchises in 37 msas from 1969 through 1994. hudson (1999) examines 17 us cities for employment effects from professional franchises in those cities, but finds none. matheson (2005) examines personal income growth in cities with super bowl champion teams and finds no evidence of a positive effect. lertwachara and cochran (2007) use an event study approach to examine the effect of relocation and expansion of professional sports teams on msa per capita income and growth rates of per capita income. they find that professional sport franchises reduce msa per capita income. propheter (2012) examines 24 nba host cities and finds only scant evidence of a positive effect on personal income from building nba arenas. conversely, davis and end (2010) find that winning nfl teams increase local 4 journal of business strategies per capita gdp. coates and humphreys (2003) find both positive and negative wage effects for cities hosting professional franchises estimating the net effect to be neutral and interpret the finding as evidence of household’s substituting in consumption. carlino and coulson (2004) show that wages are lower in franchise cities, though not statistically significant, while rents are significantly higher. coates, humphreys, and zimbalist (2006), in a rejoinder, find that the carlino and coulson results are not robust to model specifications. coates and humphreys (2011) admit that there are some positive effects on wages for nfl hosting cities, but the results are confined to announcers, athletes and others employed in recreation. a subset of papers focus more narrowly on the fiscal impacts of sporting events and franchises. coates (2006) examine the effect of the super bowl and the mlb all-star game on houston sales tax revenues and find positive and significant effects. coates and depken (2009) examine 4 mid-sized texas cities and the effect that college football games had on sales tax revenues in those cities, finding mixed effects, but generally negative and dependent on the opponent in each game. extending their 2009 paper, coates and depken (2011) examine texas sales tax revenue responses to hosting college and professional sports. they find, in many cases, negative effects on sales tax revenues, with positive effects limited to college football towns and the super bowl. finally, somerville & wetzel (2010) find that there was no effect on the residential property tax base from hosting the olympics in vancouver. for the purposes of this paper, the most directly comparable work is baade, baumann, & matheson, (2008). within the work, they examine the impacts to taxable sales in florida counties from hosting a variety of one-time major sporting events and building/improving the venues necessary to accommodate them. in virtually all cases neutral to negative effects were found. in a subsequent paper baade and matheson (2011) discuss the quality of life justification directly, stating that while there is evidence in support of the quality of life argument, the significance of the quality of life benefit may be appropriate for public/private development partnerships but inappropriate for 100% public subsidization. where previous research investigated the impacts of hosting one-time events across a series of cities, this paper modifies the strategy by investigating a series of one-time events hosted in a single city. the quality of life literature provides some guidance in considering the growth effects of local franchises. local quality of life measures were pioneered by roback (1982) who looks specifically at local amenity and productivity effects using hedonic estimates of willingness to pay for local amenities. initial research included naturally occurring amenities leading to questions of whether localities’ long run volume 34, number 5 equilibrium condition rested only with the uncontrollable forces of mother nature. gyourko and tracy (1991) add local fiscal conditions to the mix and find that manmade factors could influence long-run outcomes for municipalities. later research by glaeser et al (2001) finds that not only is urban density good for productivity growth, it is also vital for the creation of consumer amenities which are directly correlated with population growth, as discovered by ciccone and hall (1996). rappaport (2009) studied the migration-induced effects of local amenities and concludes that amenities are the sole determinant of population density asymptotically and that the population densities of cities with identical amenities but different productivity levels eventually converged. noll & willner (2003) provide evidence of a positive role for professional franchises in the quality of city life. in this paper we examine changes in the oklahoma city sales tax revenue growth rates from hosting a series of “one-time” thunder events and finding no evidence of a contemporaneous effect on year-over-year growth rates but modest evidence in support of a longer run, amenity growth effect. data monthly gross sales tax receipts were provided by the city of oklahoma city. the data in levels exhibits a unit root indicating a nonstationary time series. accordingly, the monthly data is converted into year-over-year growth rates for the january 2002 – june 2014 period. a little more than half of the observations occur in the pre-thunder period. the potential amenity effect is represented by a thunder binary variable that takes the value of 1 from november 2008, the thunder’s inaugural season in oklahoma city. the thunder has experienced both deep playoff runs and disappointing season finishes outside the eighth and final playoff position. this reality provides richness in the dataset as many months are characterized by significantly more (or less) home games than the same month of the previous year. the difference between the number of home games played in a month relative to the same month of the previous year serves effectively as a series of “one-time” hosted events. if a contemporaneous effect on monthly sales tax receipts (as measured in year-over-year growth rates) exists, we expect to see it in the differential number of home games variable. yearover-year differentials in the number of away games is also captured and reported. a vector of regional economic control variables is included in the model to capture fluctuations in city economic conditions. the preferred model specification includes economic control variables on the annualized change in oklahoma city 6 journal of business strategies msa nonfarm employment, a u.s. recession dummy variable, and the annualized change in statewide active rig counts (a proxy for expansion or contraction in the state’s primary oil and gas industry). this parsimonious control vector minimizes concerns of correlated explanatory control variables. alternative specifications are reported for other economic controls, including measures of year-over-year growth in oklahoma personal income and year-over-year growth in crude oil and natural gas spot prices for the months under study. all time-series data are stationary in their transformations. the tax rate is unchanged over the entire set of observations. the model results are robust to alternative specifications of the macroeconomic control vector. finally, a time trend is included in all models. a summary of all model variables is provided in table 1. volume 34, number 7 analysis year-over-year growth rates of aggregate tax collections are modeled as a function of regional economic activity, a time trend, a thunder amenity effect, and fluctuations in the number of home and away games played. tax rates, generally a component of revenue models, were unchanged over the entire observation period and are therefore omitted from our analysis. using a general linear model we estimate the following model: a positive fiscal impact attributable to the presence and operations of the thunder franchise would be expected to manifest in either or both of the coefficients on the thunder presence and change in home games played being reported as positive and statistically significant. the primary purpose of the investigation is the influence of a change in the number of home games – the one-time events for that month but, also of interest, is a secondary investigation of the potential amenity effect captured by the thunder presence binary indicator. results and discussion the results are reported in table 2 with nine alternative specifications of the macroeconomic control vector. across all models, the thunder presence variable is positive and statistically significant, but may be overstated as a result of lingering serial correlation. this finding is consistent with the anecdotal evidence that the arrival of the thunder as a permanent oklahoma city franchise is correlated with a rapid development of the city’s core as both businesses and residents return to the city center. we acknowledge that it is difficult to interpret the magnitude of the estimated amenity effect, but our findings suggest we cannot dismiss the notion that a professional sports franchise can be an important component of the urban amenity complex and a catalyst for encouraging density. of course, our findings are not necessarily portable to other locales. it may be that the amenity effects are concentrated in the city’s first franchise, where the franchise is most likely to be a significant component of the urban amenity portfolio, while diminishing returns exist to expansions into subsequent franchises. similarly, 8 journal of business strategies the amenity returns to oklahoma city may be exaggerated by its economic geography. oklahoma city is one of the largest major metropolitan areas in the nation as measured by area (square miles). in terms of area, oklahoma city is roughly the size of houston (about 600 miles2) and considerably larger than dallas, chicago, or san diego. as such, oklahoma city is historically one of the least dense metropolitan areas and conceivably was poised to benefit disproportionately from the productivity and agglomeration benefits associated with increased density. it is possible that the amenity effect is manifest through increased population growth rates generally or expedited urbanization of the city’s core. finally, it should be noted explicitly that our findings do not necessarily imply the optimality of public support for a professional sports franchise as there are potentially other public investment and infrastructure projects that could have impacted the urban amenity portfolio similarly. in contrast to the positive and statistically significant amenity effect, we find no evidence of a contemporaneous impact on city sales tax collections. across all models, playing more home games in a given month relative to the same month in the previous year does not appear to have a positive effect on year-over-year collections growth. this result is consistent with the literature on consumption substitution that concludes one-time events merely shift expenditures from one activity to another with no net increase in aggregate taxable activity. in our dataset, the months with the greatest change in home games played are the result of making a deep playoff run. for example, in the thunder’s second year the team secured the eighth and final playoff spot and faced the would-be champions that year, the los angeles lakers. the thunder lost the series in six games, but in the process secured three additional home games in oklahoma city that were not part of the economic landscape the previous may. if a contemporaneous effect existed, we would expect to find it in this one-time event of hosting three nba playoff games. however, purchase of playoff tickets is not a taxable sale. therefore purchases of playoff tickets may actually be a substitution in discretionary spending away from taxable activities and towards a nontaxable activity. in addition to variations caused by playoff performance, our dataset also captures the effects of the 2011 nba lockout. the combination of playoff performance and the lockout provides ample opportunity to find a contemporaneous effect if it existed in the dataset. volume 34, number 9 10 journal of business strategies conclusion it often seems that economic development agents support the economic benefits of professional sport franchises with an enthusiasm that is only matched by the passion with which economists dismiss them. perhaps the truth lies somewhere in the middle and benefits from case-specific rather than generalized analysis. we investigate the case of oklahoma city, examining specifically the municipal fiscal impacts of the city’s first and only major professional franchise. we find no evidence that the variation in the number of home games played has a statistically significant effect on sales tax growth. however, we do find some evidence of an amenity level effect, suggesting the franchise is an important component of oklahoma city’s developing urban amenity portfolio. references baade, robert a., & matheson, victor a. (2011). “financing professional sports facilities.” college of holy cross, department of economics faculty research series, paper no. 11-02 n.d. baade, robert a., baumann, robert & matheson, victor a. (2008). “selling the game: estimating the economic impact of professional sports through taxable sales.” southern economic journal 74, no. 3: 794-810. bryant, brent and evans, monty. (2007, may). “new orleans/oklahoma city hornets economic impact, city of oklahoma city-revised analysis.” oklahoma capital investments board. carlino, gerald, and coulson, n. edward. (2004). “compensating differentials and the social benefits of the nfl.” journal of urban economics 56, no. 1: 25-50. ciccone, antonio, and hall, robert e. (1996). “productivity and the density of economic activity.” american economic review 86, no. 1: 54-70. coates, dennis. (2007, october). “stadiums and arenas: economic development or economic redistribution.” contemporary economic policy 25, no. 4: 565-577. coates, dennis. (2006). “the tax benefits of hosting the super bowl and the mlb all-star game: the houston experience.” international journal of sport finance 1, no. 4: 239-252. coates, dennis, and humphreys, bard r. (2008). “do economists reach a conclusion on subsidies for sports franchiese, stadiums and mega-events?” econ journal watch 5, no. 3: 294-315. volume 34, number 11 coates, dennis, & brad r humphreys. (2011). “the effect of professional sports on the earnings of individuals: evidence from microeconomic data.” applied economics 43, no. 29: 28-30. coates, dennis, and humphreys, brad r. (2008). “do economists reach a conclusion on subsidies for sports franchiese, stadiums and mega-events?” econ journal watch 5, no. 3: 294-315. coates, dennis, and humphreys, brad r. (2003). “the effect of professional sports on earnings and employment in the services and retail sectors in us cities.” terional science and urban economics 33: 175-198. coates, dennis, and humphreys, brad r. (2011). “the effect of professional sports on the earnings of individuals: evidence from microeconomic data.” applied economics 43: 28-30. coates, dennis, and humphreys, brad r. (1999). “the growth effects of sport franchises, stadia and arenas.” journal of policy analysis and management 18, no. 4: 601-624. coates, dennis, and depken, craig a. (2011). “mega-events: is baylor football to waco what the super bowl is to houston?” journal of sports economics 12, no. 6: 599-620. coates, dennis, and depkin, craig a. (2009). “the impact of college football games on local sales tax revenue: evidence from four cities in texas.” eastern economic journal 35, no. 4: 531-547. coates, dennis, humphreys, brad r., & zimbalist, andrew. (2006). “compensating differentials and the social benefits of the nfl: a comment.” journal of urban economics 60, no. 1: 124-31. davis, michael c., and end, christian m. (2010). “a winning proposition: the economic impact of successful national fottball league franchises.” economic inquiry 48, no. 1: 39-50. glaeser, e. l., kolko, j., & saiz, a. (2001). “consumer city.” journal of economic geography 1, no. 1 (2001): 27-50. gyourko, j., and tracy, j. (1991). “the structure of local public finance and the quality of life.” journal of political economy 99, no. 4: 774-806. haughwout, a. f. and inman, r. p. (2002). should suburbs help their central city:. brookings-wharton papers on urban affairs. helman, christopher. (2012, june). “the sordid deal that created the oklahoma city thunder.” forbes.com. hudson, ian. (1999). “bright lights, big city: do professional sports teams increase employment?” journal of urban affairs 21, no. 4: 397-407. 12 journal of business strategies johnson, bruce k., groothuis, peter a., & whitehead, john c. (2001, february). “the value of public goods generated by a major league sports team: the cvm approach.” journal of sports economics 2, no. 1: 6-21. lavoie, marc, and rodriguez, gabriel. (2005). “the economic impact of proressional teams on monthly hotel occupacny rates of canadian cities: a box-jenkins approach.” journal of sports economics 6, no. 3: 314-324. lertwachara, kaveephong, and cochran, james j. (2007). “an event study of the economic impact of professional sport franchises on local u.s. economies.” jounral of sports economics 8, no. 3: 244-54. matheson, victor a. (2005). “contrary evidence on the economic effect of the super bowl on the victorious city.” journal of sports economics 6, no. 4: 420428. mcgregor, p. g., swales, j. k., & yin, y. p. (1996). “a long-run interpretaion of regional input-output analysis.” journal of regional scinece 36, no. 3: 479500. nelson, arthur c. (2001). “prosperity of blight? a question of major lague stadia locations.” economic development quarterly 15, no. 3: 255-265. noll, dennis, and willner, jonathan. (2003). “professional sports and the quality of city life.” southwestern journal of economics 5, no. 2: 133-153. noll, roger g. and zimbalist, andrew. (1997). sports, jobs and taxes: the economic impact of sports teams and stadiums. brookings institute press. porter, philip k. (2001). mega-sports events as municipal investments: a critique of impact analysis. vol. 2, in the economics of sport, by andrew zimbalist, 370-283. edward elgar. propheter, geoffrey. (2012). “are basketball arenas catalysts of economic development?” journal of urban affairs 34, no. 4: 441-459. rappaport, j. (2009).”the increasing importance of quality of life.” journal of economic geography 9, no. 6: 779-804. rappaport, j. (2005).”the shared fortunes of cities and suburbs.” economic review 90, no. 3: 33-60. rappaport, jordan and wilkerson, chad. (2001). “what are the benefits of hosting a major league sports franchise?” economic review (federal reserve bank of kansas city), first quarter: 55-91. roback, j. “wages, rents and the quality of life.” journal of political economy 90, no. 6 (1982): 1257-1278. volume 34, number 13 siegfried, john, and zimbalist, andrew. (2006). “the economic impact of sports facilities, teams and mega-events.” austalian economic review 39, no. 4: 420-7. siegfried, john, and zimbalist, andrew. (2000). “the economics of sports facilities and their communities.” journal of economic perspectives 14, no. 3: 95-114. somerville, tsur, and wetzel, jake. (2010). “hunting for the olympics bounce: any evidence in real estate?” centre for urban economics and real estate, discussion paper 2010-01, university of british columbia. zaretsky, adam m. (2001, april). “should cities pay for sports facilities.” the regional economist (federal reserve bank of st. louis): 5-9. biographical sketch of authors kyle dean is the associate director, steven c. agee economic research & policy institute and an assistant prof. of economics in the meinders school of business, oklahoma city university. he holds a ph.d. in economics from oklahoma state university. dr. dean began consulting in 2005 and his client list includes some of oklahoma’s most influential businesses and trade associations, including the oklahoma independent producers association (oipa), the oklahoma bankers’ association (oba), the oklahoma telephone association (ota) and many others. he is best known for his comprehensive work with oklahoma tribes, having completed the first ever estimate of the combined economic impacts from oklahoma tribal activities. russell evans is the executive director of the steven c. agee economic research and policy institute (erpi), director of the center for regional economic forecasting and policy analysis, and assistant professor of economics. and assistant professor of economics in the meinders school of business, oklahoma city university. he holds a ph.d. in economics from oklahoma state university. he is a co-founder principal of the economic impact group, llc. as the executive director of erpi he is involved in developing relationships with the business community and directing funded research projects. dr. evans’ research involves issues important to local civic leaders including the economic and fiscal outlook for the okc economy, the oklahoma consumer sentiment index, the oklahoma energy index, and the economic impact of the state’s primary industries including oil and gas and native american operations. jonathan willner is the b.c. clark jr. chair in economics and professor of economics in the meinders school of business, oklahoma city university. dr. 14 journal of business strategies willner specializes in three main areas: sports economics, international trade, and industrial organization. additional areas of expertise are those related to intellectual property rights and natural disasters. his research in sports economics deals with the economic impacts of the olympics and u.s. major league franchises. his industrial organization research deals with conglomerate effects in korea as well as domestic issues associated with legal structures. he teaches courses in a variety of fields including international economics and game theory. a framework for developing an effective mission statement daniel s. cochran and fred r. david department of management mississippi state university mississippi state, mississippi c. kendrick gibson school of business henderson state university arkadelphia, arkansas introduction an increasing number of profit and nonprofit organizations across america are incorporating strategic management activities into their overall operations. strategic management can be defined as the formulation, implementation, and evaluation of actions that will enable a firm to achieve its objectives. the strategic management process is based on the belief that a firm should continually monitor key internal and external events and trends; firms should seek to pursue strategies that capitalize on internal strengths, take advantage of external opportunities, improve internal weaknesses, and minimize the effect of external threats. it is widely acknowledged today that the rate, magnitude, and complexity of changes that impact organizations are accelerating. these changes are creating a different type of consumer, different types of products and services, and consequently a need for different strategies. increased competitiveness worldwide, coupled with rapid social, technological, and economic changes, are major reasons why the strategic management process is being adopted by more and more firms. in a recent review of strategic management models, the mission statement was noted as being an essential first step in the strategic management process (david, 1984, staples and black, 1984). a mission statement can be defined as an enduring document of purpose that distinguishes one business from other firms of its type (pearce, 1982). a mission statement is a declaration of an organization's business or "reason for being." a clear statement of a company's mission is essential to effectively establishing objectives, formulating strategies, setting goals, devising policies, allocatin, 4 resources, and motivating employees. a mission statement is thus an integral component of the strategic management process. as evidenced in the following quotation from peter drucker's classic book entitled management: tasks, responsibilities, and practices, a good mission statement makes strategy formulation, strategy implementation, and strategy evaluation much easier. unless the basic concepts on which a business has been built are visible, clearly understood, and explicitly expressed, an organization is at the mercy of events. not understanding what it is, what it represents, and what its basic concepts, values, policies, and beliefs are, a business cannot rationally change itself. only a clear definition of the mission and purpose of the business makes possible clear and realistic business objectives. the business mission is the foundation for priorities, strategies, plans, and work assignments. it is the starting point for the design of managerial jobs and, above all, for the design of managerial structures. structure follows strategy. strategy determines what the key activities are in a given business. and strategy requires knowing "what our business is and what it should be ." (druckeri p.75). the importance of a mission statement to effective strategic management is well supported in the management literature (staples and black, 1984). a mission statement may be the most visible and public part of a strategic plan. as such, steps should be taken to insure that the statement includes all of the essential components and attributes. in addition, a company mission should be evaluated to insure that it communicates clearly the desired feelings that will guide and motivate employees to action. the purpose of this article is to present a practical framework for developing an effective mission statement. a developmental model is presented and exemplified through application to actual organizations. the proposed mission statement developmental framework is presented in figure i, and includes the following four stages: orientation, component analysis, communication analysis, and applicability analysis. figure 1 steps in the development of an effective mission statement (ms) orientation • create a strategic planning task force • review the strategic planning process • review mission statement significance in strategic planning • review ms development process 5 component analysis • identify desired components • draft ms including derived components communication analysis denotative analysis (readability) • write clear and concise • compute fog index • rewrite if necessary connotative analysis • identify connotative feelings desired from reading ms • administer questionnaire to users (readers) • rewrite if necessary applicability analysis • identify likely situations where ms might be applied develop case • have users evaluate case based on mission statement • determine if mission statement can be applied a strategic planning task force is an appropriate group to do the initial development of an organization's mission statement. however, if this group is too large, a sub-committee could be developed called a "mission statement committee" and charged with going through the suggested stages presented in this paper. orientation process the purpose of orientation is to insure that individuals in the strategic planning task force understand the strategic management process. this orientation training should raise the level of awareness about particular individual's significance and role in planning. a training session would include the following: an overview of the strategic management process, a review of the significance of the mission statement to strategic management, and an introduction into the development process used to design an effective mission statement for their organization. the process of developing a mission statement involves rendering differences of opinion. this is a vital part of achieving an appropriate mission statement for a firm. the task force must become aware that the process the organization goes through in coming to concensus in the development of the mission statement is as important as the output of the process the mission statement itself. 6 component analysis given the understanding of what a mission statement is, the components of such a statement are important. the strategic planning task force must identify the major components to be included in their mission statement. pearce (1982) recently identified eight key components of mission statements: customers, products or setvices, markets, technology, concern for survival, growth, and profitability, philosophy, self-concept, and concern for public image. these components could be used as a guideline by the committee. according to pearce, a well conceived mission statement answers the following questions about an organization: 1. customers who are the enterprise's present and future customers? 2. products or services what are the finn's major products or services? 3. markets where does the firm compete? 4. technology what is the firm's basic technology? 5. concern for survival, growth, and profitability what is the firm's attitude towards economic goals? 6. philosophy what are the basic beliefs, values, aspirations, and philosophical priorities of the firm? 7. self-concepts what are the finns major strengths and competitive advantages? 8. concern for public image what is the finn's public image? an actual example for each component is included in table 1. the mission statement committee would write a draft mission statement from their derived components. actual company examples of each component is included in table 1. the mission statement committee would use these components as a guide in developing their initial mission statement draft. various idea generation techniques* such as nominal grouping or brainstorming could be used to identify other important components for inclusion in this initial draft. table 1 identifying mission statement components: a compilation of excerpts from actual mission statements i. excerpts from corporate mission statements 1. customers we believe our first responsibility is to the doctors, nurses, and patients, to mothers and all others who use our products and services. (johnson & johnson) to anticipate and meet market needs of farmers, ranchers, and rural communities within north america. (cenex) 7 2. product or service 3. markets 4. technology 5. concern for survival 6. philosophy 7. self-concept 8. concern for public image amax's principal products are molybdenum, coal, iron ore, copper, lead, zinc, petroleum and natural gas, potash, phosphates, nickel, tungsten, silver, gold, and magnesium. (amax) we are dedicated to the total success of corning glass works as a worldwide competitor. (corning glass) control data is in the business of applying micro-electronics and computer technology in two general areas: computer-related hardware; and computing-enhancing services, which include computation, information, education and finance. (control data) the common technology in these areas relates to discrete particle coatings. (nashua) in this respect, the company will conduct its operations prudently, and will provide the profits and growth which will assure hoover's ultimate success. (hoover universal) we are committed to improve health care throughout the world. (baxter travenol) we believe human development to be the worthiest of the goals of civilization and independence to be the superior condition for nuturing growth in the capabilities of people. (sun company) hoover universal is a diversified, multiindustry corporation with strong manufacturing capabilities, entrepreneurial policies, and individual business unit autonomy. (hoover universal) we are responsible to the communities in which we live and work and to the world community as well. oohnson & johnson) also, we must be responsive to the broader concerns of the public including especially the general desire for improvement in the quality of life, equal opportunity for all, and the constructive use of natural resources. (sun company) 8 3. markets 4. technology 6. philosophy 7. self-concept 2. product or service 5. concern for survival ii. excerpts from university mission statements 1. customers thus, winthrop fully accepts its role as a forum for public examination of issues as part of its responsibilities, not only to its students, but to all the citizens of south carolina. (winthrop college) the school of business administration has the role of providing at both the undergraduate and graduate levels a sound education and high quality professional training in the broad field of administration for prospective managers and staff specialists ... rendering professional public service in the form of educational programs, research, consultation and assistance to montana organizations.... (university of montana) to develop a partnership with business, community and government leaders and alumni in the detroit metropolitan area, serving one of the most influential industrial metropolitan areas in the world. (university of detroit) . . . to expand the involvement of faculty in research endeavors in the various fields of business and economics by providing ... ample computer facilities . . . . (arkansas state university) use human and financial resources in creative ways to pursue academic excellence within acceptable levels of human cost. (georgetown university) the school's approach is based on the belief that three cornerstones are essential to the development of a quality educational program: 1) the motivated student ...; 2) a faculty dedicated to the highest standards in teaching and research ...; and 3) a curriculum of sufficient depth, breadth, and flexibility to meet diverse student needs and expectations. (atlanta university) along with emphasis on academic quality goes an active effort to use the university's extraordinary locational advantage to build a strong interface with the business, banking, and professional groups in the city, as well as 9 8. concern for public image to develop an equally strong set of ties to leading foreign universities. (new york university) the overall goal of the university of miami school of business administration is to achieve and maintain a position of nationally acknowledged quality within the top fifteen private university schools of business administration in the united states .... (university of miami) more important, the strategy fits well into the demographic trends of the 80' s, for it positions us among the 10 best undergraduate business schools in the nation, with only the wharton school at pennsylvania as a competitor in the northeast. (new york university) communication analysis eventhough the mission statement includes the necessary componets, its communication effectiveness may be poor. recent writings involving "corporate culture" and successful companies have emphasized the significance of effective communications between the organizations many constituents. (peters and waterman, 1982; kennedy, 1984) kennedy reports: the companies and organizations that do the best job thinking through what they are all about, deciding how and to whom these central messages should be communicated and executing the communication plan in a quality way invariably build a strong sense of esprit within their own organization and among the many constituents they serve. (kennedy, 1983, p. 26) since written communication involves denotative as well as connotative meanings both are suggested as part of the community analysis for mission statement development. (bradley and baird, 1983) denotative analysis this aspect or stage is defined as determining the readability of the mission statement e.g., is it written in a clear and concise manner? a classic readability index called the fog index is an appropriate technique to mea sure readability (blundell, 1980). table 2 illustrates how the fog index 10 computed. the mission statement committee would evaluate their drafted mission statement to determine its readability index. if the index was considered too high for their average readership they would rewrite the ms draft by reducing sentence length and usage of multiple syllabled words. table 2 steps in determining a mission statement's readability level 1. compute the number of words 2. compute the number of sentences 3. compute the average number of words per sentence (item 1 divided by item 2) 4. compute the number of hard words (treat as hard words all words of three or more syllables, abbreviations and symbols. do not count capitalized words, unless symbolized or abbreviated.) 5. compute the number of hard words per 100 words (item 4 divided by item 1 times 100) 6. compute the sum of the word average and the hard word percent (item 3 plus item 5) 7. compute the fog index which indicates the readability level (item 6 multiplied by 0.4) source: adapted from how to take the fog out of writing by robert gunning and dougles mueller, chicago, illinois: the dartnel corporation, revised edition, 1981. connotative analysis in their book entitled communication for business and professions, bradley and baird reveal that the connotative meanings and emotional aspects of a written document are important. relating this to development of a good mission statement, a mission statement should arouse one's feelings and emotions for an organization. that is, an effective mission statement results in feelings that a particular organization is successful, knows where it is going, and is worthy of the reader's time, support, and investment. a good mission statement does more than simply include the needed components; it is also inspiring and motivating. quinn (1980) states that such a stateqtent should create elan or create an identity larger than the limits placed upon the firm by the individuals themselves. zaleznik (1970) has found that effective organizational "missions" help satisfy people's needs to produce something worthwhile, to gain recognition, help others, to beat opponents or earn respect. furthermore, according to quinn, the firms must distinguish themselves from all others in the competitive environment. so far, at least, the mission statement must transcend the criteria usually attributed to objectives such as measurable, achievable, etc. in that it should lift the firm above 11 its present state. keller (1983) reminds managers that what is important is the quality, daring and sagacity of the strategy. this connotative step for the mission statement committee involves asking managers to evaluate the mission statement using words that describe the feelings management wanted to be communicated. the feelings/ impressions that should be present are only briefly discussed in the literature. glueck (1980) mentions such things as coherence, agreed upon, top down, etc., while quinn (1980) includes elan in the description. other concepts/words may be more representative for a particular organization and rna; be developed by the management team; however, the following terms are offered as suggested words to use when measuring the "felling/! that others perceive to be inherent in the mission statement, the connotative meanings. optimism the impression that while the goals are large they can be achieved certainty impressions of resoluteness, completeness, commitment aggressiveness impressions of assertiveness or competitiveness inspiration impression of vision, far reaching nature concreteness references to recognition of environmental influences, explicitness, and clarity activity impressions of implementation of ideas, motion forward to measure whether these feelings are present, managers should be asked to indicate their level of agreement or disagreement with several statements or questions related to these terms as reflected in their mission statement. table 3 suggests a format for measurement. table 3 suggested method of measuring connotative feelings generated by mission statement scale used 1 = strongly disagree 2 = disagree 3 = neither agree nor disagree 4 = agree 5 = strongly agree concept scale optimism (not shown on rating sheet) 1. this mission statement gives me the 1 2 3 4 5 feeling that the university is on the verge of achieving great things. 2. i am hopeful for the future of our 1 2 3 4 5 organization. 3. the mission of the organization 1 2 3 4 5 is uninspiring. 12 4. the goals included in the plans 1 2 3 4 5 for the future are too optimistic. .tl\ggressiveness/assertiveness (not shown on rating sheet) 1. we will find it difficult to be 1 2 3 4 5 competitive in our area in the future. 2. the future of our university will be 1 2 3 4 5 insured by following the ideas presented in our mission statement. 3. the goals we have talked about will 1 2 3 4 5 help us achieve little more than we presently are doing. 4. the direction we will be taking in 1 2 3 4 5 the future is much clearer to me. inspiration (not shown on rating sheet) 1. i cannot agree with much of what 1 2 3 4 5 we have decided to do. 2. in my opinion, we will exceed our 1 2 3 4 5 expectations of success by following the plans included in our mission statement. 3. it is better to be on the safe side 1 2 3 4 5 than to try some of these ideas. 4. the foresight exhibited in this 1 2 3 4 5 planning process will help us be prepared for the future better than other colleges i am aware of. applicability analysis the fourth step of the process is to measure the extent to which the statement can be applied in a given situation. use of mini-cases to give the committee an opportunity to apply the direction of the mission statement is suggested to aid in the measurement of practicality. several mini-case situations should be prepared which would require managers to make a decision or recommendation concerning a situation with implications for the various component parts of the statement. the responses or decisions would indicate how well these managers understood the direction provided through the statement as well as their ability to apply the mission statement to the situation. (cochran and gibson, 1979) table 4 gives one example of such a situation for wallace women's college. table 4 wallace women's college* wallace's women's college is a small, exclusive women's college located 13 in north carolina. its major purpose is to foster an understanding and appreciation of the intellectual and cultural heritage of man, cultivate the student's love of the beautiful and the good, and prepare graduates to live in society with happiness for themselves and helpfulness to others. this will be accomplished with classes to improve communication, such as math, languages, and music, classes to improve understanding of the human condition, such as literature, history, and philosophy, and classes on which to build professional and civic careers, such as nursing and education. the college will strive to provide quality education with a highly qualified and stable faculty and a high student/teacher ratio. the college will strive to be sensitive to the educational demands of the area, provide an atmosphere conducive to women's liberal education, and provide cultural activities for students and surrounding residents through student activity, concerts, and recitals. *rudolph e. koletic and lawrence r. jauch, "wallace women's college," in business policy and strategies management, 4th ed., by w.f. glueck, l. table 5 mini-case situation for wallace women's college wallce women's college has recently received an offer of a significant donation from the estate of a retired area businessman who had built a national reputation in his hardware wholesale distributorship. the donation is contingent upon the establishment of a school of business at the college. the college has been experiencing a decline in enrollment for some time, dropping from a total enrollment of over 900 to 600 over the last nine years. as a result, wal!ace women's college had been operating at a deficit and had been using it's endowment funds and borrowed funds for operating expenses. the proposed education program and endowment could keep the college's finances from deteriorating further and help support the schools of music and nursing. what should be the decision of wallace women's college? write your recommendation here and justify based on your understanding of your schools mission statement. from this example the college should not accept the donation under the given restraints since it violates the organization's mission statement. the college would need to either convince the doner to change the constraints to be in line with the mission statement or change the mission statement. the point in this example is to see if the organization's mission statement can be applied to a typical situation regarding the strategic plan. 14 summary the mission statement may be the most visible and public part of a firm's strategic plan. as such, steps should be taken to insure that the statement includes all those correspondents critical to the continued success of the organization. in addition, the statement should be critically evaluated to insure that it communicates both an understanding and the desired feeling that will guide or motivate managers to action. finally, it should be practical. this article proposes a four step process or model for strategic mission statements. this process may be utilized by "mission statement committees" in all types of organizations; it can be accomplished "in house" with only a minimum amount of time and resources. a process of self-evaluation of the mission statement should help managers view their planning concepts more accurately and help the organization to relate the desired planning direction in a positive and forceful way. carefully prepared missions have been the source of success for many companies. poorly formulated missions have brought disaster to some companies. revised missions have turned some companies around. a well developed mission statement can be a unifying and motivating light for all the stakeholders of an organization. an increasing number of organizations today are implementing strategic management concepts. as part of this process, more and more firms are striving to develop a clear and meaningful company mission statement. the framework presented in this article for developing and evaluating mission statements could enhance the strategic management process in organizations. this framework could also provide some direction for much needed empirical research on mission statements. references bennis, warren g. "where have all the leaders gone?" technology review, vol. 79, no.5, (march/april 1977), pp. 37-46~ blundell, w.e. "confused, overstuffed corporate writing often costs versus much time-and money," the wall street journal. thursday, august 28, 1980. bradley, patricia h. and baird, john e. jr., communication for business and the professors, 2nd edition, wm. c. brown, co., dubuque, iowa, 1983. budd, r.w., thorp, r.k., and donohew, l., content analysis of communications, macmillan co., new york, 1967. cochran, daniel s. and gibson, c.k., "putting a square peg into a round hole: communication models and their application." journal of business communication, vol. 17, no.1, (fall, 1979), pp. 27-36. cohen, kalman j., and cyert, richard m., "strategy: formulation; implementation, and monitoring," the journal of business, vol. 46, no.3, ouly, 1973), pp. 349-367. 15 david, fred r. "towards an integration of strategic management models." southern management association, proceedings, 1984, p. 195-197. drucker, peter f., management, tasks, responsibilities, practices. harper and row, new york, 1974. ferguson, charles r., and dickinson, roger. "critical success factors for directors in the eighties," business horizons, (mayljune, 1982), pp. 14-18. gardner, john w., excellence, can we be equal and excellent too, perennial library, harper and row, new york, 1961. gardner, john w., self renewal, the individual and the innovative society, harper and colophon books, harper and row, new york, 1964. glueck, william f., business policy and strategic management, 3rd edition, mcgraw-hill book co., new york, 1980. goldhaber, gerald m., organizational communication, 3rd edition, wm. c. brown co., dubuque, iowa, 1983, p. 411. gunning robert, techniques of clear writing, mcgraw-hill publishing, new york, 1952. hanakawa, 5.1., "how words change our lives," appearing in communication for management and business, 2nd edition, by norman sigband, scott foresman and co., flenview, ill., 1976, pp. 489-496. hollowood, james r., "college and university strategic planning: a methodological approach," planning for higher education, vol. 9 no. 4 (summer, 1981), pp. 8-18. jakobson, r. "closing statement: linguistics and poetics," appearing in style in language, edited by t. sebeok, the m.i.t. press, cambridge, mass., 1960. katz, robert l. management of the total enterprise, prentice-hall, englewood cliffs, n.j., 1970, p. 19. katz, robert l. "skills of an effective administrator," harvard business review, vol. 33, no.1, ijanuary/february, 1955). kennedy, allan. (1984, november). back-fence conversations: new tools for quality conversations. communication world, 1984, november, pp. 2630. koprowski, eugene }., "exploring the meaning of good managment," academy of management review, vol. 6, no.3, (1981), pp. 459-467. kotler, phillip, marketing for nonprofit organizations, 2nd edition, prentice-hall, inc., englewood cliffs, n.j., 1982. lazer, william, and cullev, james d., marketing management, foundations and practices, houghton mifflin co., boston, 1983. mcpherson, michaels., "value conflicts in american higher education, a survey," journal of higher education, vol. 54, no.3, (mayljune, 1983), pp. 243-278. myers, james h., and warner, gregory w., "semantic properties of selected evaluation adjectives," journal of marketing research, vol. v (november, 1968), pp. 408-412. 16 ohmae, kenichi, "the secret of strategic vision," management review, april, 1982, pp. 9-13. pearce, john a. ii., "the company mission as a strategic tool," sloan management review, spring, 1982, pp. 15-24. pearce, john a. ii., and robinson, richard b., jr., strategic management, strategy formulation and implementation, richard d. irwin, inc., homewood, ill., 1982. peters, thomas j., & robert h. waterman. (1982). in search of excellence: lessons from america's best-run companies. new york: harper & row. quinn, james b., strategies for change: logical incrementalism, richard d. irwin, inc., homewood, ill., 1980. staples, w.a. and black, k.v. "defining our business mission: a strategic perspective." journal of business strategies. vol. 1, no. i, spring, 1984, p.33-39. vancil, richard f., '/strategy formulation in complex organizations," appearing in strategic planning systems, by peter lorange and richard f. vancil, prentice-hall, englewood cliffs, n.j., 1977, pp. 4-22. zaleznik, a., "power and politics in organizational life," harvard business review, mayljune, 1970, pp. 47-60. 17 a framework for developing an effective mission statement 154 journal of business strategies the pci – a global risk index for the simultaneous assessment of macro and company individual investment risks christina pakusch bonn-rhein-sieg university • sankt augustin, germany franz w. peren bonn-rhein-sieg university • sankt augustin, germany markus arian shakoor price waterhouse coopers • duesseldorf, germany abstract companies often have difficulties determining which criteria to base their investment decisions in different countries on. when considering direct foreign investment several risk indices are available. the pci (peren-clement-index) in its original form was developed in 1998. its further refinement improves the pci in three major ways: first, it offers a dynamic adjustment of criteria and consideration of recent changes in the international environment. second, it provides business specificities of a company or its industrial sector to be considered in addition to macroeconomic aspects by a two-dimensional presentation, which ensures a customized assessment. third, the pci allows for consolidating investment decisions by combining a resource-orientated with a market-oriented view. the pci allows, unlike other indices, a customized and company-specific strategic planning process. ultimately companies must take up both perspectives in the context of an international investment decision. the use of risk indices in corporate planning for assessing global investments decision creates a fundamentally new of risk assessment. keywords: risk analysis, scenarios, strategic planning, country risks, internationalization introduction companies often have difficulty determining which criteria to choose for their investment decisions in different countries and specific locations. due to the fact that location decisions cannot be easily revised (cheng and kwan 2000; morschett, schramm-klein and swoboda 2010), it is expected that companies use in a wide range of criteria for their considerations and review of possible sites (moran 2001; volume 33, number 2 155 berlemann and tilgner 2006). foreign direct investment (fdi) is the financial participation by an investor in a company located in another country that aims to have a lasting impact on the management of that company. according to international standards a lasting influence is to be expected, if the investment represents at least 10% of the company’s capital stock in the target country (unctad 2006: 294; imf (ed.) 1993: 86). to consider a fdi decision several risk indices are available. the pci (perenclement-index) was published in its original form in 1998 (peren/clement 1998). the index is firmly established in the literature as an instructional tool (wankel 2009: 137; roebuck 2011: 472; hiram 2012). the pci has been further revised into version 2.0 with the following three objectives: 1. creating a process for dynamic adjustment of criteria and consideration of recent changes in the international environment. these include: • intensification of globalized economic relations, which have led to technology and knowledge transfers in emerging and developing countries. • the emergence of outsourcing and offshoring in many industrial sectors. • increasing openness and transparency of corporate decisions due to globally available information and communications technologies. • progress in reduction of tariff and other trade barriers 2. critics claim that risk indices do not consider the specificities of a company or its industrial sector (daum, greife and przywara 2009: 186). this problem has now been addressed by a two-dimensional presentation, which ensures a customized assessment. 3. unlike other indices, the pci uses a theoretical basis to consolidate investment decisions. fundamentally, it combines two main streams of thought within the strategic planning: combining a resourceand a market-oriented view (barney,wright and ketchen 2001; newbert 2007). • the resource based view looks at the uniqueness of the resources of a site as the basis for competitive advantage. these resources have limited mobility and tradability. they interact with the internal resources of an enterprise (inside-out perspective). • the market-based view takes an outside-in perspective. thus the industry structure (production and sales) affects how a company can be positioned in a market. these two perspectives are not mutually exclusive, but complement each other. ultimately companies must address both perspectives in the context of an 156 journal of business strategies international investment decision and consider them as complementary elements in their strategic planning. the quality of location of a region can neither be observed nor easily measured. attempting to measure quality with an empirical study requires that appropriate indicators (variables) need to be identified. as part of an econometric analysis, the market entry motive and the identification of the local production conditions can be identified as significant motives for fdi. additionally, the political and legal frameworks of a site are important (tallmann 1988; chung and alcácer 2002; yeaple 2003; berlemann and göthel 2008). framework for decision making investment decisions of companies should correspond to a systematic and structured order. a differentiation must be drawn between the macro-environment and company-individual micro-environment. on the site-specific micro-level, core competencies can be identified that have a positive impact on the individual competitiveness of a company. in addition, concrete production and sales-oriented motives that reflect the supply and demand conditions of an observed market can be found as well. this framework is illustrated in figure 1. figure 1 framework for decision making of international location decisions resource based view market based view macroenvironment localization (micro-environment) production sales market the framework for decision making of these factors is broken down into 20 criteria. these 20 criteria is assigned a point value of 50 points. each criteria is then weighted from 0 to 2 points, so that the 20 criteria has a maximum total score possible of 100 points.1 1 the weighting is based on an extensive literature review. volume 33, number 2 157 macro-environment this category is largely predefined for companies and the elements are exogenous (table 1). the company observes or anticipates these factors and reacts with strategic adaptation. to assess the macroeconomic environment, a number of current international statistics and aggregate assessments in the form of indices are available that facilitate classification. however, the different norms of these indices and their different characteristics for the measurement and quantification of risk and opportunities for direct investment need to be considered. a few examples: • to assess characteristics such as economic policy, legal security and solvency the detailed analysis of the world economic forum can be used (world economic forum (ed.) 2014a). a high score in the global competitiveness report (e.g. switzerland in 2014, rank 1 with 5.67 points) implies a low risk for direct investment, a low score (e.g. algeria in 2014, rank 100 with 3.79 points), a corresponds to a higher risk (world economic forum (ed.) 2014b). • the indicator of political and social stability describes the capabilities of a government to implement its program, the unity of government, its legislative power and its public support. a high index value expresses a high degree of stability and is thus associated with a lower risk of direct investment. relevant data are, for example, provided by international country risk guides (icrg) (the prs group (ed.) 2014). • to evaluate the bureaucratic obstacles, data from the “index of economic freedom” developed by the heritage foundation can be used (the heritage foundation (ed.) 2014). this index measures the degree of economic freedom on the basis of property rights and the extent of government regulations of the market. other parameters are government corruption, restrictions on foreign trade, income and corporate taxes, and the rule of law. the highest score is set at 100. a high score (e.g. hong kong in 2014 with 90.1 points, rank 1) is associated with greater freedom and tends to be associated with a relatively lower risk of direct investment. a low score (e.g. indonesia in 2014, rank 100 with 58.5 points) would point to a significantly higher risk due to bureaucratic obstacles to foreign direct investment. 158 journal of business strategies table 1 macro-environment factors macro-environment points weighting sum political and social stability 4 bureaucratic obstacles 2 economic policy 3 legal security 3 solvency 3 sum 15 localization (micro-environment) in the globalized world, usually regions, not countries, are competing to attract productive enterprises. here, other factors, as identified in table 2, are important and may not be offered, or may be of lower quantity or quality, at other sites. this dimension can be theoretically linked to the resource-based view (peteraf 1993). specifically, a site`s endowment of human capital, their transport connections, the existing management skills, their access to markets and the quality of life offered are all important. additionally, all the above-mentioned factors are impacted by a variety of other items. for example, the quality of life of a site as a “soft factor” is usually higher the lower the crime rate, the better the health care system and the lower the regional price level is, i.e., the higher is the purchasing power of a monetary unit. other positive effects on the quality of life are cultural activities, education and training opportunities, quality of environment and local recreation and leisure opportunities (cheng and kwan 2000; berlemann and tilgner 2006). these factors are generally not transferable and can be duplicated by competing sites only within limits. the importance of these relationships is emphasized by the factor conditions in porter’s diamond model (porter 1990). in this context the interaction effects between corporate and site-specific resources are especially important. first, local resources affect the attractiveness of a site for companies. second, the investments of companies add to and generate the development and the know-how of a site (windsperger 2006). resources that are available at a site then generate a competitive advantage if company-specific resources and skills are complemented by site-specific resources. therefore, a change volume 33, number 2 159 of location or an alternative location would result in a competitive disadvantage for companies (peteraf and barney 2003). table 2 localization (micro-environment) factors localization points weighting sum human capital 4 transport connections 2 management skills 2 access to markets 2 quality of life 3 sum 13 even if a country can offer an investment-friendly environment, fdi will not take place unless additional company-specific reasons are present. theoretical literature and empirical studies differentiate particularly production-oriented and market-oriented elements. both market aspectssupply and demandcan thus be recorded. in theory, both dimensions can be linked with the market based view, which was strongly shaped by porter (porter 1980), making the analysis of the market an elementary task. competitive advantages of a company emerge mainly due to the proper selection of a market or segment of a target market and (over time) superior positioning within this market (outside-in view) (sakarya, eckman and hyllegard 2007; weber 2008: 277). production of fundamental importance for location decisions is the prevailing economic and property rights, which defines the way in which rights or actions are distributed to economic goods or to the economic actors. these include (see table 3) for example, the right to use assets (decision and right of use), the right to change the ownership of a property or vary it (right to require a change) or the right to transfer the asset completely or partly (transfer rights). moreover, freedom of contract and the principle of liability should be clarified before a location decision is made (berlemann and tilgner 2006: 18). 160 journal of business strategies taken as a whole, it can be assumed that a set of economic and property rights, not based on market principles, significantly inhibits the activity of a company and has a negative effect on prospect settlement decisions. in this context, empirical analyzes also demonstrates the importance of property rights on intellectual property (e.g. patent protection). establishing a company is often based on cost-oriented motives. this can be, for example, lower labor costs, tax benefits, or purchasing and procurement advantages (bevan and estrin 2004). in terms of labor cost advantages the relationship between wages and embodied human capital (unit labor cost) is crucial. low costs in rich countries, neither define the competitive advantage of companies, nor the economic growth of countries. on a macroeconomic level, low costs and high per capita income in the long run may even be contradictory. the stock of human capital thus acts as a kind of procurement advantage in addition to cost orientation. for the implementation of investments companies often need additional capital. if an investment cannot be financed with retained earnings and its current shareholders won’t add additional funds, other appropriate resources can be procured from external equity with either a loan or the issuance of new equity capital. accordingly, positive effects can be a well-functioning capital market and the presence of sufficient investment capital. likewise, important for a stable production are complementary production sectors that are capable of supplying key raw and auxiliary materials. the motive for purchasing and procurement security is particularly relevant for foreign direct investment in countries that are rich in raw material. thus, for example, uncertainties in the pricing of preliminary products can be reduced, if company subsidiaries provide the raw materials. in terms of production-oriented motives, investment incentives are also relevant. they can be provided by the host country, the home country of the investing company, or from multinational agencies. according to the oecd investment reform index, incentives may appear in the following three forms (oecd (ed.) 2010: 43): • regulatory incentives, such as relaxation of working, environmental and social standards. • financial incentives, such as grants for training specialized personnel by the government, subsidized loans and guarantees for loans. • fiscal and tax incentives, e.g., tax reductions for foreign investors such as reductions in the corporate income tax or a temporary tax allowance and the establishment of special tax-privileged areas. volume 33, number 2 161 table 3 production factors production points weighting sum economic and property constitution 2 manufacturing costs 2 capital procurement 3 complementary production sectors 2 investment incentives 2 sum 11 sales location decisions are often based potential market development with the aim at serving a nonor poorly served market (dunning 1998; berlemann and tilgner 2006: 19). table 4 identifies the factors that are likely to impact sales. of initial importance is the size and dynamics of the market. high per capita income can be used as an indicator of a well-funded demand and turns an otherwise uninteresting location into a potentially interesting market for local market development investments (berlemann and göthel 2008: 41). if trade barriers exist between the current location of a company and the potential sales market, this can require a separate location in the target country. trade barriers including both tariff and non-tariff barriers. for the successful development of new markets, adequately functioning distribution structures as well as a high level of confidence in the local distributor are of significant importance. 162 journal of business strategies table 4 sales factors sales points weighting sum size and dynamic of the market 3 per capita income 2 avoidance of tariff barriers 2 reliability of local contractors 2 distribution structures 2 sum 11 risk assessment the design of the pci is based on the cost-benefit analysis which is also called an index scoring model. the index is thus one of the quantitative, non-monetary, analytical methods of the decision theory. the objective is the analysis of alternative courses of action for the purpose of organizing preferences for the decision maker in a multi-dimensional scoring system. results are ordered by specifying the utility values (total) values of the alternatives. the allocation of points is just like other comparable indices e.g. business environment risk intelligence index (beri) (beri s.a. (ed.) 2014) – carried out with a subjective point of view. an option can be the delphi method where points are allocated by various experts. based on the degree of fulfillment of the criteria the following points can be awarded: 0 = not acceptable 0.5 = questionable 1 = acceptable 1.5 = good 2 = very good the 20 criteria, which are identified in tables 1--4 have a total weighting of 50. when each factor is multiplied by the points identified above, a site can receive a maximum of 100 points. based on this point value each site receives a classification of foreign risks can be constructed as shown in table 5. volume 33, number 2 163 table 5 gradation of country risks gradation of country risks (maximum 100 points) points hardly recognizable risk > 80 low risk 70 79 moderate risk, barriers in daily operations, risk covering recommended 60 69 relatively high risk, strongly defected investment environment, risk covering inevitable 50 59 location is not recommended for direct investments < 50 of great benefit is the use of critical variables (knock-out variables). if certain key factors are defined as knock-out variables and a location receives a score of 2 or less among these key factors, a direct investment is rejected. this would also apply even if all other factors had received positive valuations and the overall score showed a good result which made the location appear to be a positive choice. examples: • a company particularly wants to use foreign human capital. however, the de facto use seems questionable. in this case the resulting value is: 0.5 (questionable) • 4 (weighting of the criterion human capital)2 = 2 points • a company intends to benefit from cost advantages in production. in this case, the total evaluation for the criterion must be at least acceptable so that the value is above 2: 1.0 (acceptable) • 3 (weighting of the criterion manufacturing costs)3 = 3 points. the pci allows, unlike other indices, a customized and company-specific presentation. the assessment of the investment risk is based on a two-dimensional presentation. therein both the economical-macroeconomic and the companyindividual point of view are combined in a useful way. this approach will now be explained in an exemplary case study. case study company a and company b wish to internationalize through direct foreign investment, and are considering the two countries/regions x and y. for the measurement and comparative-quantitative assessment of country risks, both companies use the pci index. the pci shows a total score of 71 for country x (table 2 see table 2. 3 see table 3. 164 journal of business strategies 6). this value implies a relatively low investment risk. the calculation for the alternative country/region y also reaches a total score of 71 points (table 7). company a and company b now know that both direct investments would be associated with a relatively low risk. however, the site that would be the most appropriate location for the company cannot be derived from the economical-macroeconomic risk assessment. table 6 risk assessment for country/region x investment alternative 1: country x pci = 71 macro-environment points weighting sum political and social stability 1.5 4 6 bureaucratic obstacles 2 2 4 economic policy 2 3 6 legal security 1.5 3 4.5 solvency 1.5 3 2.5 sum 15 4.5 localization points weighting sum human capital 0.5 4 2 transport connections 2 2 4 management skills 0 2 0 access to markets 1.5 2 3 quality of life 2 3 6 sum 13 15 production points weighting sum economic and property constitution 2 2 4 manufacturing costs 2 2 4 capital procurement 2 3 6 complementary production sectors 2 2 4 investment incentives 2 2 4 sum 11 22 volume 33, number 2 165 sales points weighting sum size and dynamic of the market 0 3 0 per capita income 0.5 2 1 avoidance of tariff barriers 2 2 4 reliability of local contractors 0.5 2 1 distribution structures 1.5 2 3 sum 11 9 total score pci 71 this evaluation deficiency using only the risk indices, shall now be supplemented with another company-individual dimension. table 7 risk assessment for country/region y investment alternative 2: country y pci = 71 macro-environment points weighting sum political and social stability 2 4 8 bureaucratic obstacles 1 2 2 economic policy 1 3 3 legal security 2 3 6 solvency 1.5 3 4.5 sum 15 23.5 localization points weighting sum human capital 1.5 4 6 transport connections 2 2 4 management skills 1.5 2 3 access to markets 2 2 4 quality of life 1.5 3 4.5 sum 13 21.5 166 journal of business strategies production points weighting sum economic and property constitution 2 2 4 manufacturing costs 0.5 2 1 capital procurement 0 3 0 complementary production sectors 0 2 0 investment incentives 0.5 2 1 sum 11 6 sales points weighting sum size and dynamic of the market 2 3 6 per capita income 2 2 4 avoidance of tariff barriers 1.5 2 3 reliability of local contractors 1.5 2 3 distribution structures 2 2 4 sum 11 20 total score pci 71 the two companies are pursuing their internationalization with different company-specific goals. the weighting of these goals is shown in table 8. while it is most important for company a to develop the overseas market and expand the resources available through acquiring additional resources from foreign locations, company b focuses on the cost/benefits that can be generated in producing at the foreign location. table 8 company-specific internationalization goals internationalization goals / company a weighting (=100%) sales in overseas market 50% expanding resources trough localization 30% safeguard foreign location / strategic importance (macro-environment) 15% generating cost benefits (production) 5% volume 33, number 2 167 internationalization goals / company b weighting (=100%) generating cost benefits (production) 70% safeguard foreign location / strategic importance (macro-environment) 15% expanding resources trough localization 10% sales in overseas market 5% the companies now combine this second dimension, shown in table 8, with the weightings of their individual goals to the individual factors of the pci. the factors “macro-environment”, “localization”, “production” and “sales,” shown in tables 1 – 4, with the company-specific goals shown in table 8. the result is a company-specific, two-dimensional total score, which now allows for a particular goal-oriented decision (fig. 2). the two-dimensional cumulative scores now clearly shows in contrast to all prevailing risk indices which site is best suited for which investor for direct investment. company a should opt for direct investment in country/region x, since it will best be able to achieve its individual company goals at its best there. country / region x reaches with company a a company-specific total score of 20.275 points, while the country/region y is company individually evaluated only with a total of 13.85 points. the reason for the now visible distinction is that the two factors “sales” and “localization”, which are the most important for company a, (”sales in the foreign market: 50% “and” expanding resources by localization: 30%”) provide a better starting position in country/region a. company b wants to internationalize in order to achieve cost advantages in production (“generating cost savings in production: 70%”). therefore, company b should choose location y. the country / region y with a total company-specific score of 21.1 points is much better suited for a direct investment for company b as the country / region x (total score of 10.875 points). 168 journal of business strategies figure 2 individual assessment of country risks company specific country results: country x company a: factor pci target weights sum macro-environment 23.5 0.15 3.525 localization 21.5 0.30 6.450 production 6 0.05 0.300 sales 20 0.50 10.000 total score pci 71 1.00 20.275 company b: factor pci target weights sum macro-environment 23.5 0.15 3.525 localization 21.5 0.10 2.150 production 6 0.70 4.200 sales 20 0.05 1.000 total score pci 71 1.00 10.875 company specific country results: country y company a: factor pci target weights sum macro-environment 25 0.15 3.750 localization 15 0.30 4.500 production 22 0.05 1.100 sales 9 0.50 4.50 total score pci 71 1.00 13.850 company b: factor pci target weights sum macro-environment 25 0.15 3.750 localization 15 0.10 1.500 production 22 0.70 15.400 sales 9 0.05 0.450 total score pci 71 1.00 21.100 volume 33, number 2 169 this two-dimensional, graphical presentation clearly shows the advantages of such a combinatorial assessment on an economic macro level on the one hand and company-individual objectives on the other hand, using the example of country/ region x versus country/region y (fig. 3). figure 3 pci simultaneous assessment on an economic macro-level and companyspecific goals in direct investments conclusion the pci (peren-clement-index) has been revised and reorganized to reflect and account for changed global conditions. various levels of assessment are now combined, which should be considered in a direct foreign investment decision. an international location decision is often performed in stages, the first looks at the macroand the micro-environment which offers core competencies and will have a positive impact on a company’s competitiveness. in addition, concrete production and sales-oriented motives that reflect the supply and demand sides must also be incorporated into the investment decision. 170 journal of business strategies the index presented in this paper links two main currents of thoughts in strategic planning in the context of an international investment decision -the resource view and the market-oriented view: • the resource based view uses the uniqueness of the resources of a site as the basis for competitive advantages. these resources have a limited mobility and tradability. they interact with the internal resources of an enterprise (inside-out perspective). • the market-based view takes up an outside-in perspective. thus the industry structure (production and sales) affects how a company can be positioned in a market. these two perspectives are not mutually exclusive, but complementary. ultimately companies must consider both perspectives in the context of an international investment decision and use them as complementary elements in their strategic planning. by a two-dimensional linkage of the economically relevant macro level with the company-individual goals of a prospective direct investment a practical decisionmaking is facilitated. the use of risk indices in the corporate planning for assessing global investments reaches a fundamentally new quality. references barney, j., wright, m., & ketchen, d. j. (2001). the resource-based view of the firm: ten years after 1991. in: journal of management, 27(6), 625-641. beri s.a. (ed.) (2014). the leading country risk rating agency since 1966. url: http://www.beri.com/. berlemann, m., göthel, m. (2008). determinanten der internationalen standortwahl von unternehmen – ergebnisse einer empirischen analyse (determinants of the choice of the international location). in: ifo dresden berichtet, issue 4, 33-43. berlemann, m., tilgner, j. t. (2006). determinanten der standortwahl von unternehmen (determinants of the choice of the international location). ein literaturüberblick. in: ifo dresden berichtet, issue 6, 14-24. bevan, a. a., estrin, s. (2004). the determinants of foreign direct investment into european transition economies. in: journal of comparative economics, 32(4), 775-787. cheng, l. k., kwan, y. k. (2000). what are the determinants of the location of foreign direct investment? the chinese experience. in: journal of international economics, 51(2), 379-400. volume 33, number 2 171 chung, w., alcácer, j. (2002). knowledge seeking and location choice of foreign direct investment in the united states. in: management science, 48(12), 15341554. daum, a., greife, w., przywara, r. (2009). bwl für ingenieurinnen und ingenieure (business for engineers). wiesbaden. dunning, j. h. (1998). location and the multinational enterprise: a neglected factor? in: journal of international business studies, 45-66. hiram, e. c. (ed.) (2012). peren-clement index. plac publishing, london. imf (ed.) (1993). balance of payments manual, 5th edition, washington dc. moran, t. h. (2001). foreign direct investment. blackwell publishing ltd., hoboken, new jersey. morschett, d., schramm-klein, h., & swoboda, b. (2010). decades of research on market entry modes: what do we really know about external antecedents of entry mode choice? in: journal of international management, 16(1), 60-77. newbert, s. l. (2007). empirical research on the resource‐based view of the firm: an assessment and suggestions for future research. in: strategic management journal, 28(2), 121-146. oecd (ed.) (2010). investment reform index 2010. monitoring policies and institutions for direct investment in south-east europe. url: http://www. rciproject.com/rcibhreports_files/iri.pdf [as of: 30.10.2014]. peren, f.w., clement, r. (1998). globale standortanalyse (global location study). in: harvard businessmanager, 20(6), 70-77. peteraf, m. a. (1993). the cornerstones of competitive advantage: a resource-based view. in: strategic management journal, 14(3), 179-191. peteraf, m. a./ barney, j.b. (2003). unravelling the resource-based tangle, managerial and decision economics, 24, 309-323. porter, m. e. (1980). competitive strategy. techniques for analyzing industries and competitors, new york . porter, m. e. (1990). the competitive advantage of nations, new york. reineke, r. d., bock, f. (ed.). gabler lexikon unternehmensberatung, wiesbaden. roebuck, k. (2011). risk management standards: high-impact strategies – what you need to know: definitions, adoptions, impact, benefits, maturity, vendors. emereo pty limited, brisbane. sakarya, s., eckman, m., & hyllegard, k. h. (2007). market selection for international expansion: assessing opportunities in emerging markets. international marketing review, 24(2), 208-238. 172 journal of business strategies springer gabler verlag (ed.) (2014). gabler wirtschaftslexikon, stichwort: perenclement-index, 18th edition, volume 4 wiesbaden. tallman, s. b. (1988). home country political risk and foreign direct investment in the united states. in: journal of international business studies, 219-234. the heritage foundation (ed.) (2014). 2014 index of economic freedom. url: http://www.heritage.org/index/. [as of: 30.10.2014]. the prs group (ed.) (2014). international country risk guide. url: https://www. prsgroup.com/about-us/our-two-methodologies/icrg. [as of: 29.10.2014]. unctad (2006). world investment report 2006. fdi from developing and transition economies: implications for development, united nations, new york, geneva. wankel, c. (2009). encyclopedia of business in today’s world, volume 1, california. weber, j. (2008). das advanced-controlling-handbuch, richtungsweisende konzepte, steuerungssysteme und instrumente, 2nd edition, weinheim. windsperger, j. (2006). a resource-based view of the competitive advantages of cities: empirical results on advantages for headquarters in vienna for central europe. in: south east european journal of economics and business, 2. world economic forum (ed.) (2014a). reports. url: http://www.weforum.org/ reports/ [as of: 22.10.2014]. world economic forum (ed.) (2014b). global competitiveness report 20142015. url: http://www.weforum.org/issues/global-competitiveness [as of: 28.10.2014]. yeaple, s. r. (2003). the complex integration strategies of multinationals and cross country dependencies in the structure of foreign direct investment. in. journal of international economics, 60(2), 293-314. brief biographical sketch of authors christina pakusch is a research assistant at the bonn-rhein-sieg university and is a doctoral candidate at the university of siegen. she received her m.sc. from the heinrich heine university duesseldorf. her field of research comprises sharing and service economies and sustainable development with the focus on future mobility. franz w. peren, ph.d., is a professor of business administration specializing in quantitative methods at the bonn-rhein-sieg university, germany, where he has taught since 1993, and at the columbia university in new york,. his practical experience includes working as a consultant for the german automotive industry at volume 33, number 2 173 the federal ministry of economics and as a strategy consultant for global companies markus arian shakoor is a consultant in finance at pricewaterhousecoopers. he studied business administration at bonn-rhein-sieg university. he completed his postgrad studies in international business (m.com.) at swinburne university of technology in melbourne and in leadership (m.sc.) at northeastern university in boston. volume 33, number 2 95 building a community garden: a collaborative cross-disciplinary academic community engagement project jeffrey r. wozniak sam houston state university • huntsville, tx jeremy bellah west texas a&m university • canyon, tx jason m. riley sam houston state university • huntsville, tx abstract most research concerning service learning discusses the benefits students experience when working on a project; however, for faculty, the challenges involved in facilitating the project are also great. we designed a collaborative crossdisciplinary project to address two goals: 1) to increase student engagement through service learning, while also 2) redistributing the work involved in managing the project from the instructor to a second group of upper-level operations management students. specifically, we used the academic community engagement (ace) pedagogy, which combines community engagement with academic instruction, in a collaborative project between a freshman-level environmental science class and an upper-level operations management class. the project goal for the students was to research and establish a formal plan for the creation of a community garden in the local town. the community garden project goal was achieved over the course of the semester and survey results suggest that we accomplished both of the crossdisciplinary project goals. specifically, many of the students developed a deeper sense of connection to the local community and a more tangible idea of how they can serve their communities in the future. keywords: academic community engagement (ace), community garden, environmental science, experiential learning, operations management, service learning introduction service learning projects can provide a more holistic educational experience at the undergraduate level. while the benefits of small scale, single semester service learning projects are considerable, larger scale (e.g., multiple classes and more than 96 journal of business strategies one community partners), and long-term (e.g., extending multi-semester) projects may offer students a more dynamic service learning experience. these large scale projects may also be beneficial to the community partners engaged in the project. however, while positive outcomes increase with project scope and scale, so do the project management and logistics challenges for instructors overseeing such projects. in response, we propose a collaborative, cross-disciplinary service-learning project that includes students from a target discipline (environmental science) and a support discipline (operations management) to assist in managing the project. for students, the learning objectives are enhanced by the cross-disciplinary design of the project. specifically, students are exposed to several theoretical streams of research, including experiential learning, problem-based learning, and service learning. the target discipline students operated as content specialists and focused on the individual goals of the environmental science course. these students were responsible for the scientific research and design of the community garden project from an environmental science perspective. conversely, the support discipline students functioned as project managers and applied operations management principles from their class to the project and target students. the support discipline students supervised all logistical, project, and operational processes associated with the community garden project. the objective of this paper is to communicate the results of the implementation of a collaborative cross-disciplinary project to address two goals: 1) to increase student engagement through service learning, while also 2) redistributing the work involved in managing the project from the instructor to a second group of upper-level operations management students. in the following sections, we review the related literature, draw connections between different pedagogical foundations and this service learning project, describe the pedagogy in detail, and report both quantitative and qualitative data collected from project participants. literature review service learning projects can take many forms, and at times borrow from different pedagogical foundations. our cross-disciplinary project involves aspects of experiential learning, problem-based learning, and service learning. here we highlight the use and application of these different subject areas in different academic settings and draw connections to their respective roles in this collaborative crossdisciplinary community garden project. volume 33, number 2 97 cross-disciplinary projects cross-disciplinary projects have been used in classes with great success at many universities, but often include disciplines that are closely related. bhavnani and aldridge (2000) for instance, described how product design projects were used to integrate different engineering disciplines at auburn university. similar projects were used at the university of michigan and stanford university, with the main difference being the inclusion of mba students (lovejoy and srinivasan, 2001). another project at stanford university had architecture, engineering, and construction students’ design, plan, and schedule construction projects on the university campus (fruchter, 2001). other university based cross-disciplinary projects include the use of semiconductor processing to integrate physics, chemistry, and engineering activities at san jose state university (muscat et al., 1998); the use of robotics to integrate engineering and computer science students at southern illinois university, edwardsville (weinberg, engel, gu, and karacal, 2001); the use of a proteomics stock market project to integrate marketing, management, and biochemistry classes at murray state university (keller and cox, 2004); and the use of a collaborative clinical teaching project used with nursing and clinical pharmacy across the college of pharmacy and health sciences at butler university, and the indiana university school of nursing (robertson and mcdaniel, 1995). furthermore, some crossdisciplinary projects extend beyond on the academic institution itself. for example, long and carlo (2013) described a multi-institutional initiative involving students from supply chain management, production planning, scheduling, facility layout, and design courses. the goal was the design of a decentralized manufacturing organization for a company that planned to manufacture industrial proton-exchange membrane fuel cells. while all of these projects were successful at integrating multiple, closely related disciplines, they stopped short of actually implementing the deliverables and expanding the collaborative scope to far reaching disciplines. experiential learning existing research suggests that experiential learning is used by educators to help students understand concepts taught in class (ferrari and chapman, 2014). based on kolb’s (1984) learning cycle, this pedagogy involves learning activities such as concrete experience (direct observation), reflective observation (evaluation, comparison), abstract conceptualization (modeling and analysis), and active experimentation (synthesis, design), which leads to a new concrete experience. examples of service learning include the development and publication of quality 98 journal of business strategies management content (foster, jr., 2004), the use of simulation to demonstrate the complexity of project management execution (hartman, et al., 2013), turning business cases into consulting exercises (erzurumlu and rollag, 2013), and hands-on research to stimulate learning in an introductory management information systems course (wu and sankar, 2013). in our community garden project, students from the target and support disciplines gained different forms of experiential learning exposure. the environmental science students for example, engaged in active experimentation when designing the community garden plan, while the support students partook in concrete experiences by directly interacting with target students. further, all of students were required to write a reflective observation at the end of the project. this allowed the participants to reflect on their overall experience. problem-based learning problem-based learning (pbl) uses the problem-solving context to facilitate experiential learning. when using this pedagogy, students are presented with a problem, and then use the appropriate theory and tools to solve the problem. many researchers support the need for pbl in higher education (lenschow, 1998; rouvrais et al, 2006; lehmann, et al., 2008). according to lenschow (1998), the choice of projects is extremely important to the pedagogy because the degree to which the project actually reflects reality determines its effectiveness. when students work on projects that accurately reflect reality, they learn from their experiences. thus, pbl offers significant benefits when compared with traditional lecturing (hicks, 1996). a benefit of working on projects that reflect reality is that the likely cross disciplinary lines. this is important because university students need to understand how organizations from varying backgrounds function (athavale et al., 2008). pbl has been implemented at many universities. heineke, et al. (2010), for instance, described an interactive exercise used to teach the concepts of uncertainty and variability. an innovative teaching method introduced by nargundkar, et al. (2014) presented problems first, with blank spaces for students to work them out. after the problems were presented, key concepts and the corresponding theory were provided. these tools enabled students to understand and ultimately solve the problem. the authors presented evidence suggesting that the proposed method improved critical thinking skills. with our community garden project, we employed pbl by presenting the “problem” of food security in the city of huntsville, texas. huntsville is a mostly rural community with a population of 40,435 and a median household income from volume 33, number 2 99 2012-2014 of $29,257 (us census bureau, 2016). with 37.3% of the population living below the poverty level (us census bureau, 2016), we assert that food security is a concern for public officials and the community at large. students were presented with this issue as a real world problem and were tasked with the need for a real-time, community-based solution. addressing food security was fundamental to the project and served as a driving force for both target and support students throughout the duration of the project. service learning “service learning refers to a teaching strategy that engages students in organized service activities” (what, 2015). instructors regularly leverage this learning technique when teaching students how to work with community organizations and clients. these types of undertakings are called service-learning projects because they provide real value to the receiving organizations. while generally effective, class based projects are often difficult to implement since they are time-consuming and require much coordination when they involve interacting with individuals or organizations outside of the university. the current research is additionally complex since our project crossed disciplines (environmental science and operations management) and was planned to elapse over multiple semesters. service learning projects have been used extensively within the university setting. for instance, students in a strategic management capstone course, at indiana state university, acted as consultants and offered advice to local businesses with respect to organizational objectives (robinson, et al., 2010). similarly, xavier university students worked with local non-profit organizations while completing a project management course (kloppenborg and baucus, 2004). larson and drexler (2010) designed a service-learning assignment for a project management course where students planned and executed events for local charitable organizations. business and communication students at california state university, fullerton, participated in a community project to advise target (department store) about how to communicate with college students to find future leaders (brzovic and matz, 2009). students at grand valley state university worked to solve problems at the university in a course focused on teaching students how to function effectively as members of a work team (mckendall, 2000). students at the university of nebraska, kearney learned six sigma concepts in the context of collaborating with local businesses on quality improvement projects (zuckweiler, 2011). students at kansas state university participated in total quality management (tqm) projects for local businesses, 100 journal of business strategies integrating the disciplines of engineering, business, statistics, and human ecology (mccahon and lavelle, 1998). faculty members at western carolina university used service learning projects to collaborate across multiple classes and multiple semesters for a management information system course (richmond, et al., 2008). sroufe and ramos (2011) compiled information from experiences with 39 service learning projects over a 3-year period and suggested a pedagogy for delivering live projects in mba curriculum focusing on sustainability concepts. these projects provided tremendous value to the participating organization and enabled the students involved a unique learning opportunity. for typical service learning projects, the instructor initiates the project, assigns students to an appropriate team, and provides supervision throughout (heriot, et al., 2008). this requires a number of critical resources including the instructor’s time (cook and belliveau, 2005). heriot and campbell (2002) also found that it can be difficult to recruit and supervise project participants. further, some of these resource requirements may be reduced by modifying the project structure or by shifting the workload to students (heriot et al., 2008). however, we caution that this could result in poorer results for the client and a less than ideal educational experience for the student. to potentially lessen the instructor’s time, our project sought to place the operations management students in a leadership role where they directed the project and managed interactions with community partners. giving both support to the instructor and real work exposure to the operations management students. methodology pedagogy our suggested pedagogy builds upon the model proposed by bellah (2014). in this model, students in an applied project management course are used to manage a project in a target discipline. the management students act as “student facilitators” working to increase student communication and productivity throughout the project. there are multiple benefits to this pedagogy. first, the instructor of the target discipline course in which the project is conducted changes roles. instead of acting as the project manager, he/she becomes a project stakeholder. this reduced role allows the instructor to focus on course objectives rather than spending significant time managing the project. in addition to reducing the instructor’s workload, the pedagogy should result in improved project outcomes, a more diversified educational volume 33, number 2 101 experience for students in the management course, as well as improved collaborative skills for students in the target course (bellah, 2014). leveraging bellah’s (2014) model, we propose using students in a decision science course (project management, operations management, etc.) to initiate, plan, execute, monitor, control, and close all of the processes involved in service learning projects. we believe that this would provide multiple direct and indirect benefits. in addition to providing service learning opportunities for the decision science students, it exposes them to diverse ideas and concepts in a different discipline. additionally, it benefits the instructor and students in the target discipline course, as it should result in a smaller workload for the instructor, better coordination, communication and control of projects, and improved learning outcomes for all students involved. application of the pedagogy: cross-disciplinary collaborative project we designed a collaborative project to address two goals: 1) to increase student engagement through service learning, and 2) to redistribute some of the work involved in managing the project from the instructor to students. the project was implemented using an operations management class with 40 students (support discipline), and an environmental science class with 90 students (target discipline). the operations management students managed the project that was executed by the environmental science students. the project’s goal was to research, design, and establish a formal procedure for the creation and operation of a local community garden. the project was planned as part of an academic community engagement (ace) courses. the ace pedagogy enables student learning by developing collaborative partnerships between the university and local community members. when using the ace methodology, a faculty member works in collaboration with a community partner to design an engagement experience that is directly linked to course objectives and meets a community need. the ace project is structured to occur in addition to the specific lecture components of the course, but works to directly leverage the over-arching themes found within the course. a structured written reflection on the community engagement experience is required and is assessed as a part of the final course grade. unlike service learning experiences, ace projects are structured to go beyond community service and attempt to link a student’s academic learning to community needs. students in the target environmental science class were given the opportunity 102 journal of business strategies to choose from one of twenty different groups which they remained in for the entire semester long project (table 1). we found that letting students choose their group, rather than placing student in pre-determined groups, worked to more effectively match student interests with individual group goals and in the end lead to improved quality of student products. operations management students were divided into 10 groups corresponding to the 10 knowledge areas defined by the pmbok guide (project management institute, 2013). each group was responsible for managing the environmental science groups’ work with respect to one knowledge area. the project integration group was responsible for integrating information from different groups to compile a single consistent deliverable. the project scope management group was responsible for helping environmental science groups to define the scope of their work and verifying that they actually accomplished their goals. the project time management group was responsible for helping the environmental science groups to define activities required to complete the project work, estimate the time involved in those activities, and keep track of the actual time worked. the project cost management group was responsible for estimating and keeping track of all cost related items involved in the project. the project quality management group was responsible for helping the environmental science students to define success criteria for each group and evaluating them with respect to the criteria. the project human resource management group was responsible for keeping track of the group members for all groups in both classes. the project communications management group was responsible for defining how communication would happen throughout the project. the project risk management group was responsible for documenting all possible risks and planned responses. the project procurement management group was responsible for finding procurement sources for all necessary materials for the project. finally, the project stakeholder management group was responsible for identifying and communicating with stakeholders. to facilitate communication between the target and support discipline classes, students were required to attend three joint class sessions. during these joint meetings, the faculty members provided status updates and groups were able to both trouble shoot project issues, as well as request critical information from other groups. management students were able to utilize these sessions to provide face-toface guidance and directives to target discipline students. in addition, to facilitate information sharing between groups, a wikispaces page (www.wikispaces.com) was created, with each group having their own space on the website. this allowed students to post documents, comments and questions to other group’s pages and served as the main document sharing portal for the entire project. at the end of the volume 33, number 2 103 semester, all students again convened for a group session where each environmental science target group (table 1) gave an oral presentation on their group’s findings and linked their efforts to the goal of establishing a formal plan for the creation of a community garden in the local town. community partners and stakeholders in the garden project were invited to attend this semester ending presentation. results and discussion at the end of the semester, we performed both quantitative and qualitative analysis to determine the effectiveness of the pedagogy. for the operations management students, the instructor’s goal was to provide students a better understanding of basic project management concepts and to expose them to diverse ideas and perspectives related to environmental science. for the environmental science students, the goal was to link the core concepts from class (e.g., agriculture, food security, and sustainability) to the community engagement experience and to increase their likelihood the students would actively participate in similar projects in the future. quantitative analysis the survey instrument was designed to compare differences between project-based and lecture-based classes and determine what students learned about operations management, project management, and environmental sciences (see appendix 1). we adapted survey questions from existing business case research measures (erzuruml and rollag, 2013). to evaluate the responses, we used a 7-point likert scale: strongly disagree = 1, disagree = 2, somewhat disagree = 3, neither disagree nor agree = 4, somewhat agree = 5, agree = 6, strongly agree = 7. we also asked respondents to comment on the project with an open-ended question. for the operations management students, we collected survey data from the 38 of the 40 students who participated in the service-learning project at the end of spring semester 2014 (table 2). upon detailed inspection, we note that 35 of 37 respondents were in their 4th year of college (1 respondent did not answer the class year question), confirming that participants were senior level management students. since the management students were in a leadership position during the project, their senior level, as compared to the freshman-level environmental science students, was preferred. to determine the effectiveness of the project-leaning approach, we analyzed the survey results to understand the students’ preferences (table 3). in the results 104 journal of business strategies profile, we categorized responses into two groups: disagree 1-3 (strongly disagree, disagree, or somewhat disagree) and agree 5-7 (somewhat agree, agree, or strongly agree). we then reported the percentage of responses for each group. unlike erzurumlu and rollag (2013), the management students in this class did not prefer the project approach to the traditional in-class lecture format. in fact, only 39% of management students indicated they enjoyed the overall experience. the survey results further indicated the majority of students did not feel the project helped them identify (53% disagreed), think through (58% disagreed), or motivate them (53% disagreed) better than an in-class discussion would. particularly concerning was the fact that only 24% of respondents agreed the project approach enabled them to think through different issues. while the evidence suggests the project approach, as compared to traditional in-class discussions, was less appealing for management students, our analysis also indicated that these management students believed they were able to better identify and understand operational issues. since this was an operations management class, we appreciated the fact that students believed the project-management approach allowed them to identify operational issues 79% of the time and understand potential and actual operations issues 71% of the time. further, since the management students actively participated in the initial stages of this project, we surmise they were able to identify and understand operations issues associated with the project planning and execution stages. our analysis further indicated that the management students felt the project approach helped them understand real-world business issues 71% of the time. because the majority of respondents were 4th year students, we assume they will be graduating and entering the business world shortly. thus, by exposing them to real world issues like project planning, deliverable execution, and teamwork, the project approach seems to prepare these students for the job market. it does so by providing details about experiences. we expect that students can leverage the experiential details when discussing real world situations with potential employers. lastly, the analysis indicated 82% of management respondents felt they were involved with the community garden project. we believe this was a good indicator for class participation. hence, the project approach may provide a method to keep students engaged. this is particularly important as instructors work to engage and motivate students who are nearing graduation. besides the survey questions, we also asked the management students several open-ended question about their overall experience. volume 33, number 2 105 1) (the project) made me aware of subject matters outside of my academic major, better than in-class discussions. 2) (the project) made me aware how businesses and environmental groups could work together, better than in-class discussions. 3) the project got me excited by showing me how businesses and community groups work together. over 60% of the students agreed with each of these statements. contrast that with the fact that only 24% of students agreed with the statement, “i would like to learn more about environmental science.” the responses to the latter statement suggest that the students were not interested in the different discipline; therefore, the results of the former questions are much more powerful. despite not having an overwhelming appreciation for environmental science, the management students recognized that the diverse topics were beneficial. qualitative analysis environmental science students who participated in the project were required to write a reflective essay about their experiences with the project. these essays showed that students’ experiences with the project varied. numerous students noted that they did not enjoy working on the project. many specifically noted the challenges associated with group work as the reason for this displeasure. the written reflections further illustrated that some of the environmental science students did not form a close connection with their management student counterparts. however, we did find that the community garden project was seen as a positive experience for the environmental science students. many of the respondents wrote about a connection between the environmental science lecture material and its direct application to the community garden project. specifically, many students reported they developed a deeper sense of connection to the local community and a more tangible idea of how they can serve the community. conclusion the management students were vital in managing the project as they aided the target discipline students in creation of group timelines, task execution, and project 106 journal of business strategies documentation. throughout the process, many environmental science students had difficulty understanding the role of the management students and often were uncertain with level of authority the management students’ held. we acknowledge that the different roles were not defined in a clear manner at the onset of the project and attribute this confusion to this fact. future iterations of this pedagogy would benefit from a more detailed presentation of the roles of the management students and the target discipline students, and the interaction between the groups, at the start of the project. in the future, the goal will be to illustrate to all students that they are all working in collaboration on the project and the increased communication between management and target discipline students will only result in a more developed final product. we were unable to follow bellah’s (2014) model completely because the management students had not previously completed a project management course. instead, the management students had been exposed to project management principles for two weeks during an operations management class. in retrospect, this limitation in resources likely affected the accomplishment of project goals. this study provided key insight in to the how experiential learning, problembased learning, and service learning can be used to enhance teaching and student experiences. because this was the first time attempting such an endeavor, we encountered multiple unforeseen challenges. some students displayed negative comments related to the experience, but we believe much of the reason behind these comments were due to the exploratory nature of the project and were necessary “growing pains”, which occurred throughout the semester. moving forward, we plan to refine our processes and experiment in many different courses related to decision sciences. in addition, we plan to operationalize many of our processes so they can be replicated for other instructors who want to connect their students with diverse disciplines and the community outside the university. it is important to expose students to diverse ideas and perspectives in education. this can be accomplished successfully by using service learning projects. while the benefits of these projects are great, they come at a cost. the management of the projects always requires significant time and resources, and this can be overwhelming as class size or the number of classes grow. our proposed pedagogy attempts to achieve the benefits of service learning while managing the logistical challenges. our results also show that tangible benefits occurred from the project to students and faculty in both disciplines. volume 33, number 2 107 acknowledgments the authors would like to acknowledge the center for community engagement (cce) at sam houston state university and extend appreciation to dr. joyce mccauley and dr. lee miller. in addition, we thank the cce advisory board and the academic community engagement college coordinators – without their support of academic community engagement this work would not have been possible. funding this research received no specific grant from any funding agency in the public, commercial, or not-for-profit sectors. references athavale, m., davis, r. and myring, m. (2008). the integrated business curriculum: an examination of perceptions and practices. journal of education for business, 291-301. bellah, j. (2014). a systems perspective of project management to support service learning projects. the proceedings of swdsi. bhavnani, h.s. and aldridge, m.m. (2000). teamwork across disciplinary borders: a bridge between college and the work place. journal of engineering education, 13-16. brzovic, k. (2009). students advise fortune 500 company: designing a problembased learning community. business communication quarterly, 72(1): 21-34. cook, r.g. and belliveau, p. (2005). the experiential student team consulting process. dog ear publishing. erzurumlu, s.s. and rollag, k. (2013). increasing student interest and engagement with business cases by turning them into consulting exercises. decision sciences journal of innovative education, 11(4): 359-381. ferrari, j.r. and chapman, j.g. (2014). educating students to make a difference: community-based service learning. routledge. foster, s.t. (2004). freequality: using service learning to motivate student learning. decision sciences journal of innovative education, 2(1): 57-63. fruchter, r. (2001). dimensions of teamwork education. journal of engineering education, 17(4-5): 426-430. 108 journal of business strategies fruchter, r. and emery, k. (1999). teamwork: assessing cross-disciplinary learning. proceedings of the 1999 conference on computer support for collaborative learning. international society of the learning sciences. govekar, m.a. and rishi, m. (2007). service learning: bring real-world education into the b-school classroom. journal of education for business, 3-10. hartman, n.s., watts, c.a. and treleven, m.d. (2013). appreciating the complexity of project management execution: using simulation in the classroom. decision sciences journal of innovative education, 11(4): 323-334. heineke, j., meile. l., liu, l.b., et al. (2010). project flip: a project management case/exercise experience. decision sciences journal of innovative education, 8(1): 113-127. heriot, k.c. and campbell, n.d. (2002). starting new small business institute programs: a survey of new programs begun since 1996. journal of small business strategy, 13(2): 90-96. heriot, k.c., cook, r., jones, r.c., et al. (2008). the use of student consulting projects as an active learning pedagogy: a case study in a production/operations management course. decision sciences journal of innovative education, 6(2): 463-481. hicks, e.r. (1996). experiential learning in a postgraduate project management programme. education + training, 38(3): 28-38. keller, h. and cox, j.r. (2004). the proteomics stock market project – a crossdisciplinary collaboration in biochemistry and business education. journal of chemical education, 81(4): 519-522. kloppenborg, t.j. and baucus, m.s. (2004). project management in local nonprofit organizations: engaging students in problem-based learning. journal of management education, 28(5): 610-629. kolb, d.a. (1984). experimental learning. englewood cliffs, nj: prentice-hall. larson, e. and drexler (jr), j.a. (2010). project management in real time: a servicelearning project. journal of management education, 34(4): 551-573. lehmann, m., christensen, p., du, x., et al. (2008). problem-oriented and projectbased learning (popbl) as an innovative learning strategy for sustainable development in engineering education. european journal of engineering education, 33(3): 283-295. lenschow, j.r. (1998). from teaching to learning: a paradigm shift in engineering education and lifelong learning. european journal of engineering education, 23(2): 155-161. volume 33, number 2 109 long, s.k. and carlo, h.j. (2013). collaborative teaching and learning through multi-institutional integrated group projects. decision sciences journal of innovative education, 11(3): 233-241. lovejoy, s.w. and srinivasan, v. (2001). perspective: ten years of experience teaching a multi-disciplinary product development course. the journal of product innovation management, 19: 32-45. mccahon, c.s. and lavelle, j.p. (1998). implementation of cross-disciplinary teams of business and engineering students for quality improvement projects. journal of education for business, 73(3): 150. mckendall, m. (2000). teaching groups to become teams. journal of education for business, 277282. muscat, j.a., allen, l.e., green, d.h.e., et al. (1997). interdisciplinary teaching and learning in a semiconductor processing course. journal of engineering education, 653-658. nargundkar, s., samaddar, s. and mukhopadhyay, s. (2014). a guided problembased learning (pbl) approach: impact on critical thinking. decision sciences journal of innovative education, 12(2): 91-108. project management institute (2013). a guide to the project management body of knowledge (pmbok guide), 5th edition, newtown square, pennsylvania: project management institute, inc. richmond, w., banerjee, d. and white, b.j. (2008). integrating curriculum across courses in the same semester and across semesters using a service learning project. decision sciences journal of innovative education. 6(2): 509-513. robertson, k.e. and mcdaniel, a.m. (1995). interdisciplinary professional education: a collaborative clinical teaching project. american journal of pharmaceutical education, 59: 131-136. robinson, d.f., sherwood, a.l. and depaolo, c.a. (2010). service-learning by doing – how a student-run consulting company finds relevance and purpose in a business strategy capstone course. journal of management education, 34(1): 88-112. rouvrais, s., ormrod, j., landrac, g., et al. (2006). a mixed project-based learning framework: preparing and developing student competencies in a french grande ecole. european journal of engineering education, 31(1): 83-93. sroufe, r. and ramos, d. (2011). mba program trends and best practices in teaching sustainability: live project courses. decision sciences journal of innovative education, 9(3): 349-369. 110 journal of business strategies united states census bureau (2016). huntsville, texas. available at: http:// quickfacts.census.gov/qfd/states/48/4835528.html (accessed 25 march 2016). what is service learning? (2015, october). retrieved from the virginia commonwealth university, division of community engagement web site: http://www.servicelearning.vcu.edu/what-is-service-learning/. weinberg, b.j., engel, l.g., gu, k., et al. (2001). a multidisciplinary model for using robotics in engineering education. american society for engineering education. wu, y. and sankar, c.s. (2013). impact of hands-on research experience on students’ learning in an introductory management information system course. decision sciences journal of innovative education, 11(4): 335-358. zuckweiler, k.m. (2011). teaching six sigma to undergrads: a simplified real project approach. decision sciences journal of innovative education, 9(1): 137-142. volume 33, number 2 111 biographical sketch of authors jeffrey r. wozniak is an assistant professor of biological sciences at sam houston state university. he received his phd from florida international university and his bs from allegheny college. dr. wozniak is an ecosystem ecologist and his research interests include coastal, estuarine and wetlands ecology. he teaches a wide range of environmental science, ecology and sustainability courses and often includes academic community engagement in these offerings. jeremy bellah is an assistant professor of computer information systems and decision management at west texas a&m university. he received his ph.d. from texas tech university. dr. bellah teaches classes in software development and project management. he conducts research in the areas of offshore information systems development, rfid technology utilization, software use in small and medium sized enterprises, and pedagogical research related to project management. he has published in journals including journal of computer information systems, international journal of productivity and quality management, and journal of information technology case and application research. jason m. riley earned his ph.d. from clemson university. he is an assistant professor of supply chain management in the department of management and marketing at sam houston state university. dr. riley’s research interests include supply chain risk, retail product management, and course modality. he has published in several peer-reviewed journals including the international journal of information systems and social change, journal of business management, and international journal of physical distribution and logistics management. 112 journal of business strategies table 1 list of the main organizational themes and twenty student subgroups for the community garden project in the target environmental science course. project introduction, purpose and implementation plan 1. implementation plan: overview and organization 2. mission statement and needs assessment 3. local community asset assessment overview of other community gardens 4. successful community garden summary 5. garden reconnaissance and site visits garden site selection, preparation and planning 6. local site selection: options and feasibility 7. site preparation 8. soil chemistry garden components and operation 9. organic farming 10. composting 101 11. garden security and safety 12. garden signage outreach and education 13. k-12 educational opportunities 14. university educational opportunities 15. garden communication network 16. publicity and community outreach long-term garden sustainability 17. garden rules and procedures 18. garden budget 19. garden financial sustainability plan 20. garden master plan and organization volume 33, number 2 113 table 2 descriptive statistics compared to in-class discussions, the project count mean std dev min max helped me to identify different issues better than in-class discussions. 38 3.55 1.62 1 7 helped me to think through different issues... 38 3.37 1.62 1 7 helped me to apply critical reasoning... 38 3.68 1.58 1 7 stimulated my interest in the course subject... 38 3.50 1.69 1 6 motivated me to do my best work... 38 3.55 1.52 1 6 allowed me to learn more about the subject matter... 38 3.47 1.62 1 7 made me aware of subject matters outside of my academic major... 38 4.53 1.66 1 7 made me aware how businesses and environmental groups could work together... 38 4.64 1.69 1 7 general response to the project the project allowed me to identify operational issues. 38 5.16 1.39 1 7 the project allowed me to understand operational issues. 38 4.92 1.51 1 7 the project helped me apply concepts i learned in class. 38 4.55 1.43 1 7 i gained valuable experience from this project. 38 3.97 1.67 1 7 i was involved with this project. 38 5.42 1.46 1 7 overall, the project was helpful to my learning. 38 4.18 1.72 1 7 overall, i enjoyed the experience. 38 4.00 1.76 1 7 i would like to learn more about project management. 38 5.50 1.16 2 7 i would like to learn more about environmental science. 38 2.95 1.68 1 6 the project got me excited by showing me how buinesses and community groups work together. 38 4.68 1.44 2 7 allowed me to understand real world business issues. 38 5.11 1.45 1 7 the project challenged my thinking about environmental science. 38 3.47 1.66 1 7 the project helped me realize there is more to the world than just business. 38 4.42 1.37 2 7 control questions gender 36 1.47 0.56 1 2 first generation student 36 1.47 0.51 1 2 age 35 22.54 2.02 19 30 class year 37 3.95 0.23 3 4 114 journal of business strategies table 3 result profile compared to in-class discussions, the project count mean disagree 1-3 disagree % agree 1-3 agree % helped me to identify different issues better than inclass discussions. 38 3.55 20 53% 15 39% helped me to think through different issues... 38 3.37 22 58% 9 24% helped me to apply critical reasoning... 38 3.68 17 45% 12 32% stimulated my interest in the course subject... 38 3.50 19 50% 12 32% motivated me to do my best work... 38 3.55 20 53% 13 34% allowed me to learn more about the subject matter... 38 3.47 18 47% 10 26% made me aware of subject matters outside of my academic major... 38 4.53 11 29% 24 63% made me aware how businesses and environmental groups could work together... 38 4.64 7 18% 26 68% general response to the project the project allowed me to identify operational issues. 38 5.16 4 11% 30 79% the project allowed me to understand operational issues. 38 4.92 6 16% 27 71% the project helped me apply concepts i learned in class. 38 4.55 7 18% 23 61% i gained valuable experience from this project. 38 3.97 15 39% 17 45% i was involved with this project. 38 5.42 3 8% 31 82% overall, the project was helpful to my learning. 38 4.18 11 29% 17 45% overall, i enjoyed the experience. 38 4.00 15 39% 15 39% i would like to learn more about project management. 38 5.50 2 5% 33 87% i would like to learn more about environmental science. 38 2.95 24 63% 9 24% the project got me excited by showing me how buinesses and community groups work together. 38 4.68 9 24% 23 61% allowed me to understand real world business issues. 38 5.11 5 13% 27 71% the project challenged my thinking about environmental science. 38 3.47 20 53% 12 32% the project helped me realize there is more to the world than just business. 38 4.42 8 21% 17 45% volume 33, number 2 115 appendix 1 management student questionaire compared to in-class discussions, the project. 1. helped me to identify different issues better than in-class discussions. 2. helped me to think through different issues better than in-class discussions. 3. helped me to apply critical reasoning better than in-class discussions. 4. stimulated my interest in the course subject better than in-class discussions. 5. motivated me to do my best work better than in-class discussions. 6. allowed me to learn more about the subject matter, than i would have during in-class discussions 7. made me aware of subject matters outside of my academic major, better than in-class discussions 8. made me aware how businesses and environmental groups could work together, better than in-class discussions general response to the project 9. the project allowed me to identify operational issues 10. the project allowed me to understand operational issues 11. the project helped me apply concepts i learned in class. 12. i gained valuable experience from this project. 13. i was involved with this project 14. overall, the project was helpful to my learning. 15. overall, i enjoyed the experience. 16. i would like to learn more about project management 17. i would like to learn more about environmental science 18. the project got me excited by showing me how businesses and community groups work together. 19. allowed me to understand real world business issues. 20. the project challenged my thinking about environmental science. 21. the project helped me realize there is more to the world than just business. 22. what did you like most about the project? control questions 23. male/female 24. age: 25. are you a first generation student (neither parent graduated from a four year college or university): yes, i am a first generation student, no, i am not a first generation student. open-ended question 26. what did you like about the project? volume 34, number 2 75 the stock price effect of emerging from bankruptcy and the associated effect of switching auditors post-bankruptcy…an industry analysis ronald stunda valdosta state university • valdosta, ga abstract this study analyzes firms that emerge from chapter 11 bankruptcy with specific attention given to two groups; those that switch auditors post-bankruptcy, and those who retain previous auditors in a post-bankruptcy environment. in addition, further analysis is made to assess whether or not industry membership, along with pre or post sox environment play a role in results. results indicate that when the pre versus post sox environment is assessed, a significant difference is noted in the sample firms. post sox firms emerging from chapter 11 that switch auditors carry positive information content, therefore, investors tend to bid up the price of stock of these firms. firms emerging from chapter 11 in a post sox environment that do not change auditors tend to convey negative information content as their stock price is bid down by investors. with respect to a pre sox environment, results indicate that investors do not behave significantly different whether the firms change auditors or not after emerging from chapter 11. in both cases, there is a positive correlation between earnings response and stock price. when attention turns to assessing individual industries in a post sox environment, a positive correlation between earnings response and stock price is seen across all industries evaluated when the firm emerging from chapter 11 switches auditors. growth industry firms show the greatest stock price reaction to earnings. with respect to firms that do not switch auditors post-bankruptcy, results are mixed across industries. most industries show a negative stock price reaction but certain growth industries reflect a positive reaction. in a pre sox environment, no significant industry difference is noted, either by firms that switch auditors or those that do not switch. all pre sox industry firms, on average, have a positive correlation between earnings response and stock price. 76 journal of business strategies introduction bankruptcy has the potential to be a tremendously traumatic experience for a firm. the primary purpose of the u.s. bankruptcy code, through chapter 11 filing, is to provide temporary respite from financial obligations to companies with sufficiently high probability of reorganizing obligations successfully. a successful reorganization would allow the company to ultimately emerge from bankruptcy as a much more financially healthy organization. the news of a successful emergence from chapter 11 is then viewed as good market news relative to other firms in the industry. ferris et al (1997) separate firms in comparable industries by those that file for bankruptcy and those that do not. an analysis is then made three years prior to the bankruptcy and three years after emerging from bankruptcy. they find that when the bankruptcy announcement is made, the firms declaring chapter 11 filings see a decline in stock prices, but so do rivals firms in the same industry. when the firms emerge from chapter 11, they see an even greater increase in stock price than stock prices of rival firms. client firms switch auditors for many different reasons. one reason is that a firm may change to a better quality auditor to supply more credible information to creditors, investors, and regulators (schwartz and menon 1985). another reason is that a client firm may be engaged in opinion shopping. a firm may seek a new auditor to conceal or downplay “bad news” or to avoid a qualified or going concern opinion (fried and schiff 1981; chow and rice 1982). a third reason for an auditor change is a disagreement between the auditor and client (davidson et al. 2006). with the advent of sarbanes oxley (sox), the public company accounting oversight board (pcaob) was created and empowered to promulgate new auditing standards for public company audits. one change the pcaob has made is a modification to the second paragraph of statement on auditing standards (sas) no. 59. this change directs auditors to use their knowledge of subsequent events following the financial statement date but before the audit opinion date when considering whether to issue a going concern opinion [pcaob, 2 010, p. 538]. before this change, sas no. 59 instructed auditors to consider subsequent events at the completion of fieldwork [aicpa, 1988]. geiger et al, (2005) find that this change may also result in a selffulfilling prophecy regarding issuance of going concern opinions and resultant bankruptcy declarations. this paper attempts to merge much of the past literature regarding bankruptcy and auditor switches to assess the stock price impact of firms emerging from bankruptcy, and the extent to which those firms switch auditors. another aspect of volume 34, number 2 77 this study, which is beginning to receive greater interest, is the impact of these two issues from an industry-specific basis. the goal of this study is to help provide a clearer picture of the relationship between post-bankruptcy performance and auditor retention by specific industry. the rationale for inclusion of this metric in the study is because any industry-specific findings could have relevance and significance to managers, investors and creditors of those industries. literature review truman and weinstein (1983) posit that most corporate bankruptcies are fully anticipated to the point that no new information is released when bankruptcies are filed. the authors find that greater information follows the emergence from bankruptcy. they find that primary events ocurring around post-bankruptcy include; new management, new corporate form, and new auditors. none of these events are explored by the authors. aharony, jones and swary (2010) find that corporate failure is an indication of resource misallocation and can be industry-specific, although there is no attempt to measure industry differences. lang and stulz (1992) explore a premise that when more than one firm in the same industry announces a chapter 11 filing there exists a tendency for other firms in the same industry to follow. they refer to this as an intra-industry contagion effect. smith and nichols (1992) document a significantly positive share price reaction within 60 days after emerging from bankruptcy. whereas eberhart et al. (1999) find an abnormal positive price change in days following bankruptcy emergence, klock (2004) documents that firms in heavy industry have a significant drop in stock price upon emergence from chapter 11. eberhart et al. (1999) study the stock market performance of firms emerging from chapter 11 bankruptcy. they find that in the first 200 days after shedding the chapter 11 cover, abnormal stock returns average from +24.6% to +138.8%. this result is similar to the findings of bradley and rosenzweig (1992). lang and stulz (1992) extend the analysis and find that this market reaction can exert a positive competitive effect, particularly since the chapter 11 bankruptcy can be an indication of a general negative contagion in the industry in which the chapter 11 emerging company competes. in several of these studies, post-bankruptcy firms have either changed auditors or retained previous ones. there has been no control for assessing either. regarding auditor switches, prior research shows that a reduction in audit fees motivates auditor changes (johnson and lys 1990). lower audit fees may improve company financial performance through lower costs but may also diminish 78 journal of business strategies audit quality (ettredge et al. 2007). auditor changes may be related to higher auditor litigation risk (krishnan and krishnan 2007), auditor industry specialization, carcello and neal 2003), management desire to manage or manipulate earnings (davidson et al. 2006), and better service provided by auditors (johnson and lys 1990; chang et al 2010). asthana, balsam, and krishnan (2010) posit that corporate governance is a factor in switching auditors and that this is especially true after the enron debacle and creation of sarbanes oxley (sox) in 2002. they also find that governance varies from industry to industry, and a multivariate analysis assessing multiple industry firms in a five year study period indicates differing market reaction to the auditor switch within 120 days of the switch. stunda (2012) provides evidence of stock prices changes triggered by new regulation may vary among industries. evidence is found within 90 days of the new regulation taking effect. mackay and phillips (2015) find that industry dictates financial structure. in some cases, financial leverage can be higher or lower depending upon the industry. the study assesses various equilibrium models and discovers that industry firms with higher leverage and risk are more apt to ultimately switch auditors. fries, miller and perraudin (2015) have similar findings of mackay and phillips (2015). in assessing debt in industry equilibrium, the study shows that over-leverage in certain industries can lead to a host of reactions including bankruptcy, and certainly in a post sox environment, a change in auditors. this study attempts to provide a nexus between the extant bankruptcy and auditor switch literature. it also attempts to assess this linkage in a pre and post sox environment, and from an industry perspective. this issue has become more relevant today in light of recent studies highlighting industry differences, particularly as industries continue to evolve in their governance and capital structure. in addition, it is important to place this linkage in perspective to points in time. therefore, the study compares and contrasts findings in order to analyze results in a pre versus post sox environment, and by industry. data and methodology the sample consists of quarterly earnings and security prices during the two sample period years 1992-2001 (pre sox) and 2007-2016 (post sox), for the first quarter after a firm emerges from chapter 11. the rationale for using the first quarter after emergence is to stay as close to the methodology of smith and nichols (1992), who utilize 60 days after the event, asthana, balsam, and krishnan (2010) who volume 34, number 2 79 utilize 120 days after the event, and stunda (2012) who utilizes 90 days after the event. since quarterly data is used in the study, the first quarter after the event is considered to be the most significant. earnings data are obtained from compustat and security price information is derived from the center for research on security prices (crsp). the analysts’ forecast of earnings is obtained from the investment brokers estimate service (ibes), and consists of quarterly point forecasts for the periods mirroring firms’ earnings releases. also, the electronic data gathering and retrieval system (edgar), and the wall street journal (wsj) are used to analyze financial notes and other associated firm information in order to control for such things as change of corporate form, change in ownership, or change in management. if any of these could be documented during the test period, the firm is subsequently eliminated from the study. in addition, edgar is also utilized to identify prechapter 11 versus post-chapter 11auditor changes in the test period firms. in their analysis of earnings forecast accuracy, sinha, brown, and das (2015) conduct a detailed study of industries incorporating such things as corporate governance, average industry revenues, average industry assets, capital structure, regulatory constraints, and long term investment. the study finds that certain industries have experienced above average growth in the last ten years, while other industries have experienced below average growth during this same period. this study incorporates industry analysis from that study to highlight similar above average growth industries, namely; technology, healthcare, oil/gas, and banking/ finance. in addition, the same below average growth industries are also analyzed, they are; utilities, real estate, transportation, and industrials. tables 1 and 2 below provide the full sample of firms in the test period samples. 80 journal of business strategies table 1 firms emerging from chapter 11 2007-2016 (post sox) firms emerging from chapter 11 industry firms switching auditors firms retaining auditors above average growth industries technology 6 8 healthcare 9 7 oil/gas 11 9 banking/finance 15 11 total 41 35 below average growth industries utilities 17 13 real estate 16 8 transportation 14 9 industrials 27 18 total 74 48 grand total 115 83 table 2 firms emerging from chapter 11 1992-2001 (pre sox) firms emerging from chapter 11 industry firms switching auditors firms retaining auditors above average growth industries technology 2 4 healthcare 3 5 oil/gas 5 6 banking/finance 7 5 total 17 20 below average growth industries utilities 5 7 volume 34, number 2 81 real estate 4 6 transportation 9 7 industrials 15 14 total 33 34 grand total 50 54 hypothesis development difference between firms that switch auditors versus firms that do not switch auditors post sox geiger et al. (2005), notes that firms going through chapter 11 may switch auditors to shed association with a past bad experience, while smith and nichols (1992) finds that auditor switches when emerging from bankruptcy provides a signal that in turn generates a significant share price response. the first question to ask is, does a significant difference exist in price between firms switching auditors versus those retaining the same auditor, after emerging from chapter 11? this leads to the first hypothesis, stated in the null form: h1: in a post sox environment, there is no significant difference in the security price of firms, within the first quarter of emerging from chapter 11, regardless of whether or not the same auditor is retained or changed to a new auditor. the association between accounting earnings and security returns was first propounded by ball and brown (1968). the premise of the ball and brown study was to see whether the magnitude of unexpected earnings (as opposed to merely the sign of unexpected earnings) was related to the magnitude of the stock price response. beaver, clarke and wright (1979) addressed the issue and discovered, in fact, that the magnitude of unexpected earnings was related to the magnitude of the stock price response. again, they focused on market-adjusted stock returns to facilitate across-firm comparisons and to control for market-wide movements in stock prices. ball and brown (1968) and beaver, clarke and wright (1979) show that despite the deficiencies of historical cost accounting, accounting earnings are potentially useful to investors. they also ushered in the so-called information perspective on the decision usefulness of accounting. the information perspective 82 journal of business strategies implies that investors’ response to accounting information can provide a guide as to what type of information is or is not valued by investors. the next logical question to ask was whether the market responded more strongly to unexpected earnings in some firms, and less strongly in other firms. this question is quite pertinent to accountants because accountants potentially would be better able to design financial statements if we knew the factors that predict when and why investors respond more strongly (less strongly) to financial statement information. consistent with the literature, the term “earnings response coefficient,” or “erc” is used to describe the strength of the market response to unexpected earnings. to understand this line of research, one needs to have an intuitive understanding of how investors might respond to accounting information in light of single person decision theory, portfolio theory, and efficient market theory. here is the basic idea: let’s say that last period’s earnings were $1 and, accordingly, that is the level of earnings an investor expects this year. when this year earnings are announced, the level of earnings are, say, $1.25, implying a $0.25 earnings surprise. if the investor believes this $0.25 level of unexpected earnings is a one-time shot that will not recur into the future, the investor will increase his assessment of stock value by $0.25. however, if the investor believes this $0.25 unexpected increase in earnings is a permanent boost to earnings that will recur in future years, then the investor’s increase in stock price is $0.25 + the present value of receiving $0.25 into perpetuity. given this framework for thinking about how investors should respond to unexpected earnings, it can be predicted that investors will respond more strongly to unexpected earnings when those earnings are expected to persist into the future. it can also be predicted that investors’ response to unexpected earnings will be smaller the higher the discount rate they use in discounting those unexpected earnings that are expected to be received into perpetuity. subsequent numerous studies have tested these predictions, and find: (1) erc are increasing in the persistence of earnings. this has implications for accountants because it suggests the importance of clearly identifying on the income statement those transactions that are nonrecurring transactions (baginski and hassell, 1990). (2) erc are decreasing in the riskiness of the firm and the leverage of the firm because both imply that investors demand higher expected returns and thus will use a higher discount rate in discounting the unexpected earnings expected to persist into the future. thus, accountants should minimize the opportunities for off-balance sheet financing (or make sure the off-balance sheet financing is transparent) (ajinkya, atiase, and gift, 1991). volume 34, number 2 83 (3) erc are increasing in the growth opportunities of the firm because unexpected earnings reported by growth firms are expected to persist into the future. thus, the forward-looking management discussion and analysis (md&a) disclosures are particularly important because they provide information about growth opportunities (collins and kothari, 1994). (4) erc are increasing in the quality of accounting accruals. thus, detailed information about the components of accounting accruals might be useful to investors (lev, 1989). using the previously explained ball and brown (1968) model to determine the erc, the following model is established for determining information content: �𝐶𝐴𝑅𝑖𝑡=𝑎+𝑏1𝑈𝐸𝑆𝑖𝑡+𝑏2𝑈𝐸𝑅𝑖𝑡+𝑏3𝑀𝐵𝑖𝑡+𝑏4𝐵𝑖𝑡+𝑏5𝑀𝑉𝑖𝑡+𝑏6𝐸𝑖𝑡+𝑏7𝐷𝑖𝑡+𝑒𝑖𝑡 (1) where: carit = cumulative abnormal return firm i, time t a = intercept term uesit = erc for all firms switching auditors uerit = erc for all firms retaining auditors mbit = market to book value of equity as proxy for growth and persistence bit = market model slope coefficient as proxy for systematic risk mvit = market value of equity as proxy for firm size eit = number of audit committee member as proxy for expertise dit = number of years with current auditor as proxy for tenure eit = error term for firm i, time t the above regression is run for all firms in each of the test samples (i.e., firms switching auditors and firms retaining the same auditors). the coefficient “a” measures the intercept. the coefficient b1 is the erc associated with firms switching auditors. the coefficient b2 is the erc associated with firms retaining the same auditors. the erc is measured by determining unexpected earnings. unexpected earnings (uei) is measured as the difference between the management earnings forecast (mfi) and security market participants’ expectations for earnings proxied by consensus analyst following as per investment brokers estimate service (ibes) (exi). the unexpected earnings are scaled by the firm’s stock price (pi) 180 days prior to the forecast: 84 journal of business strategies 𝑈𝐸𝑖=[𝑀𝐹𝑖−(𝐸𝑋𝑖)]/𝑃𝑖 (2) unexpected earnings are measured for each of the sample firms in the first quarter after emerging from chapter 11. the coefficients b3 through b7, are contributions to the erc for all firms in the sample. to investigate the effects of the information content of earnings on security returns, there must be some control for variables shown by prior studies to be determinants of erc. for this reason, the variables represented by coefficients b3 through b7 are included in the study. for each firm sample, an abnormal return (arit) is generated around the event dates of -1, 0, +1 (day 0 representing the day that the firm’s financials were available per djnrs). the market model is utilized along with the crsp equally-weighted market index and regression parameters are established between -290 and -91 days. abnormal returns are then summed to calculate a cross-sectional cumulative abnormal return (carit). difference between firms that switch auditors versus firms that do not switch auditors pre sox utilizing the same approach as in h1, an analysis is made of firms during the pre sox study period. this leads to the following hypothesis: h2: in a pre sox environment, there is no significant difference in the security price of firms, within the first quarter of emerging from chapter 11, regardless of whether or not the same auditor is retained or changed to a new auditor. difference between pre sox and post sox results in order to compare differences between pre and post sox results, an analysis of variance test (anova) is used. baron and kenny (1986) find that an anova test is effective in that it precludes the concept of multicollinearity that sometimes arises in regression results, along with measurement error. this methodology is also used in asthana, balsam, and krishnan (2010) to assess the effect of auditor switches associated with governance issues. this leads to the following hypothesis, stated in the null form: volume 34, number 2 85 h3: there is no significant difference in security prices of firms emerging from chapter 11 between a pre versus post sox environment regardless of whether or not an auditor switch exists. difference across industries post sox aharony, jones and swary (2010) find that corporate failure is an indication of resource misallocation and can be industry-specific, while klock (2004) documents that firms in heavy industry have a significant drop in stock price upon emergence from chapter 11. an important question unanswered by previous bankruptcy studies is, are post-bankruptcy effect significantly different across industries in a post sox environment. this leads to the second hypothesis, stated in the null form: h4: there is no significant post sox industry difference in the security price of firms, within the first quarter of emerging from chapter 11, regardless of whether or not the same auditor is retained or changed to a new auditor. utilizing a similar approach to that of hypothesis one the following model is presented: car=𝑎+𝑏1𝑈𝐸𝑆𝑖𝑡+𝑏2𝑈𝐸𝑅𝑖𝑡+𝑏3𝑀𝐵𝑖𝑡+𝑏4𝐵𝑖𝑡+𝑏5𝑀𝑉𝑖𝑡+𝑏6𝐸𝑖𝑡+𝑏7𝐷𝑖𝑡+𝑒𝑖𝑡 (3) where: carit = cumulative abnormal return firm i, time t a = intercept term uesit = erc for firms switching auditors by specific industry uerit = erc for firms retaining auditors by specific industry mbit = market to book value of equity as proxy for growth and persistence bit = market model slope coefficient as proxy for systematic risk mvit = market value of equity as proxy for firm size eit = number of audit committee member as proxy for expertise dit = number of years with current auditor as proxy for tenure eit = error term for firm i, time t the above regression is run multiple times for each industry in the sample. the coefficient “a” measures the intercept. the coefficient b1 is the erc associated with firms switching auditors. the coefficient b2 is the erc associated with firms retaining the same auditors. the erc is measured by determining unexpected 86 journal of business strategies earnings. unexpected earnings (uei) is measured as the difference between the management earnings forecast (mfi) and security market participants’ expectations for earnings proxied by consensus analyst following as per investment brokers estimate service (ibes) (exi). the unexpected earnings are scaled by the firm’s stock price (pi) 180 days prior to the forecast, similar to the approach used in hypothesis one. for each firm sample, an abnormal return (arit) is generated around the event dates of -1, 0, +1 (day 0 representing the day that the firm’s financials were available per djnrs). the market model is utilized along with the crsp equally-weighted market index and regression parameters are established between -290 and -91 days. abnormal returns are then summed to calculate a cross-sectional cumulative abnormal return (carit). differences across industries pre sox utilizing the same approach as in h4, an analysis is made of firms during the pre sox study period. this leads to the following hypothesis: h5: there is no significant pre sox industry difference in the security price of firms, within the first quarter of emerging from chapter 11, regardless of whether or not the same auditor is retained or changed to a new auditor. results table 3 provides results of assessing all post sox firms in the sample that switch auditors subsequent to emerging from chapter 11 versus those which retain the same auditor prior to chapter 11 filing. the erc associated with the firms switching auditors, represented by variable b1, is positive .13 and is significant at the .01 level. the erc associated with firms retaining the same auditor, represented by variable b2, is negative .03 and is significant at the .05 level. all other variables in the model are not significant at conventional levels. results indicate that for both variables, b1, and b2, significant information content is present when correlating to stock prices. however, investors perceive the two scenarios differently. for those firms emerging from chapter 11 with different auditors, a positive relationship exists between the earnings response coefficient and security prices, potentially signaling a positive change in direction of the firm, thus supporting the findings of smith and nichols (1992). for firms emerging from volume 34, number 2 87 chapter 11 with the same auditor, a negative relationship exists between earnings response coefficient and security prices. an interpretation may be that the firm has been perceived as not moving past status quo. regardless of the reason, the first hypothesis which states that there is no significant difference in the security price of firms, within the first quarter of emerging from chapter 11, regardless of whether or not the same auditor is retained or changed to a new auditor, must be rejected. in addition, whenever regression variables are employed, there is a probability of the presence of multicollinearity within the set of independent variables which may be problematic from an interpretive perspective. to assess the presence of multicollinearity, the variance inflation factor (vif) is utilized. values of vif exceeding 10 are often regarded as indicating multicollinearity. in the test of hypothesis 2, a vif of 2.5 is observed, thus indicating a non-presence of significant multicollinearity. table 3 test of hypothesis one-post sox analysis of emerging from chapter 11 model:�𝐶𝐴𝑅𝑖𝑡=𝑎+𝑏1𝑈𝐸𝑆𝑖𝑡+𝑏2𝑈𝐸𝑅𝑖𝑡+𝑏3𝑀𝐵𝑖𝑡+𝑏4𝐵𝑖𝑡+𝑏5𝑀𝑉𝑖𝑡+𝑏6𝐸𝑖𝑡+ 𝑏7𝐷𝑖𝑡𝑒𝑖𝑡 + eit a b1 b2 b3 b4 b5 b6 b7 adjusted r2 .06 .13 -.03 .29 .11 .09 .11 .23 .238 (.58) (2.27)*** (1.68)** (.48) (.33) (.29) (.31) (.45) b1 = all post sox firms in sample switching auditors after emerging from chapter 11 (n=115) b2 = all post sox firms in sample retaining auditors after emerging from chapter 11 (n=83) ***significant at the .01 level **significant at the .05 level table 4 provides results of assessing all pre sox firms in the sample that switch auditors subsequent to emerging from chapter 11 versus those which retain the same auditor prior to chapter 11 filing. the erc associated with the firms switching auditors, represented by variable b1, is positive .08 and is significant at the .01 level. the erc associated with firms retaining the same auditor, represented by variable b2, is positive .04 and also is significant at the .01 level. all other variables in the model are not significant at conventional levels. results indicate that for both variables, b1, and b2, significant information content is present when correlating to stock prices. in addition, investors perceive the two scenarios as not being significantly different. unlike the results in the post 88 journal of business strategies sox environment, investors seem to place little significance associated with auditor changes after emerging from chapter 11 in a pre sox environment. hypothesis two, that states that there is no significant difference between these two periods, cannot, therefore be rejected. to assess the presence of multicollinearity, the variance inflation factor (vif) is utilized. values of vif exceeding 10 are often regarded as indicating multicollinearity. in the test of hypothesis 2, a vif of 2.7 is observed, thus indicating a non-presence of significant multicollinearity table 4 test of hypothesis two-pre sox analysis of emerging from chapter 11 model:�𝐶𝐴𝑅𝑖𝑡=𝑎+𝑏1𝑈𝐸𝑆𝑖𝑡+𝑏2𝑈𝐸𝑅𝑖𝑡+𝑏3𝑀𝐵𝑖𝑡+𝑏4𝐵𝑖𝑡+𝑏5𝑀𝑉𝑖𝑡+𝑏6𝐸𝑖𝑡+𝑏7𝐷𝑖𝑡𝑒𝑖𝑡 + eit a b1 b2 b3 b4 b5 b6 b7 adjusted r2 .09 .08 .04 17 .19 .05 .07 .18 .214 (.32) (2.19)*** (2.29)*** (.27) (.41) (.22) (.24) (.40) b1 = all pre sox firms in sample switching auditors after emerging from chapter 11 (n=50) b2 = all pre sox firms in sample retaining auditors after emerging from chapter 11 (n=54) *** significant at the .01 level table 5 indicates the one-way anova results for the two groups analyzed (i.e. pre and post sox samples). the one-way anova test indicates an f-ratio of 23.614 with an associated p-value of .0000. when the levene test is performed to assess for homogeneity of variance, a levene statistic of 6.7719 is obtained with a significance level of .001. this test indicates significant differences in the variances of the groups. because the variances of the groups are not equal, there exists violation of the assumption of homogeneity across the samples. in order to account for this, the welch’s test is performed. this test assesses significance between groups when variances do not equal. based on the welch’s test, and as indicated in table 5, a t-statistic of 1.750 is computed with a p-value of less than .025. this indicates that the means of the sample groups are significantly different, and thus the null hypothesis of similarity between the groups is rejected. in addition, close analysis of table 5 indicates that the average composite change in stock price for the pre sox sample is +10.669, the respective change for volume 34, number 2 89 the post sox sample is +5.115. this indicates that stock price swings are nearly double in a pre sox environment. in addition, the variance in the stock movements for pre sox firms is approximately half of that for the post sox firms studied, indicating the potential for less risk in the pre sox environment. table 5 test of hypothesis threeone way anova test pre versus post sox samples groups count sum average variance pre sox firms 104 1109.5 10.669 6.228719 post sox firms 198 1012.9 5.115 13.289172 source of variation ss df ms f-ratio p-value between groups 2517.158 1 426.691 23.614 .0000 within groups 988.621 301 3.327 total 3507.881 302 levene statistic df1 df2 two-tail significance 6.7719 1 301 .001 t-stat df p-value welch’s t-test 1.750 1<.025 tables 6 and 7 provide results of assessing post sox firms in the sample by industry membership. table 6 presents results, by industry, of variable b1-firms switching auditors subsequent to emergence from chapter 11. results indicate that the ercs associated with each industry sample are positively related to security prices and are significant at conventional levels. the association between earnings response and security price seems to be stronger for growth industry firms (i.e. technology, healthcare, oil/gas and banking/finance). with respect to firms retaining the same auditor after emergence from chapter 11 (b2 variable), table 7 indicates that the ercs are predominantly negative. the exceptions are the growth industry firms in technology, healthcare, and oil/ gas. these results further detail the findings of hypothesis one and pinpoint those industries which are more likely to be perceived from a negative security price perspective after recovering from chapter 11. table 7 indicates that there is no real consistency among industry firms when the auditor is retained after chapter 11 emergence, except that high growth industry firms may possess a greater advantage 90 journal of business strategies over low growth industry firms, most likely as a result of their inherent growth component. as a result, hypothesis four which states that there is no significant post sox industry difference in the security price of firms, within the first quarter of emerging from chapter 11, regardless of whether or not the same auditor is retained or changed to a new auditor, must be rejected. in addition, the variance inflation factor (vif) is assessed in each of the regressions run for this hypothesis test. in each case, the vif is found to be below 3, indicating a non-presence of significant multicollinearity. table 6 test of hypothesis four auditor switching firms by industry, b1 variable-post sox model: car=𝑎+𝑏1𝑈𝐸𝑆𝑖𝑡+𝑏2𝑈𝐸𝑅𝑖𝑡+𝑏3𝑀𝐵𝑖𝑡+𝑏4𝐵𝑖𝑡+𝑏5𝑀𝑉𝑖𝑡+𝑏6𝐸𝑖𝑡+𝑏7𝐷𝑖𝑡+eit industry n erc p-value technology 6 .25 1.62*** healthcare 9 .19 1.59*** oil/gas 11 .38 1.67*** banking/finance 15 .17 1.89** utilities 17 .08 1.78** real estate 16 .05 2.19* transportation 14 .12 2.25* industrials 27 .03 2.38* *** significant at the .01 level ** significant at the .05 level * significant at the .10 level volume 34, number 2 91 table 7 test of hypothesis four auditor retaining firms by industry, b2 variable-post sox model: car=𝑎+𝑏1𝑈𝐸𝑆𝑖𝑡+𝑏2𝑈𝐸𝑅𝑖𝑡+𝑏3𝑀𝐵𝑖𝑡+𝑏4𝐵𝑖𝑡+𝑏5𝑀𝑉𝑖𝑡+𝑏6𝐸𝑖𝑡+𝑏7𝐷𝑖𝑡 + eit industry n erc p-value technology 8 .06 1.67*** healthcare 7 .03 1.85** oil/gas 9 .02 1.91** banking/finance 11 -.01 2.32* utilities 13 -.02 1.82** real estate 8 -.04 2.02* transportation 9 -.01 1.76** industrials 18 -.10 1.66*** *** significant at the .01 level ** significant at the .05 level * significant at the .10 level tables 8 and 9 provide results of assessing pre sox firms in the sample by industry membership. table 8 presents results, by industry, of variable b1-firms switching auditors subsequent to emergence from chapter 11. results indicate that the ercs associated with each industry sample are positively related to security prices and are significant at conventional levels. results appear consistent, regardless of industry membership. with respect to firms retaining the same auditor after emergence from chapter 11 (b2 variable), table 9 indicates that the ercs are again positively related to security prices. there also appears to be little variation in significance in this sample, regardless of industry membership. findings indicate that in a pre sox environment, industry memebership appears to be discounted when a firm emerges from chapter 11 regardless of whether or not the firm switches auditor. as a result, hypothesis five which states that there is no significant pre sox industry difference in the security price of firms, within the first quarter of emerging from chapter 11, regardless of whether or not the same auditor is retained or changed to a new auditor, cannot be rejected. 92 journal of business strategies in addition, the variance inflation factor (vif) is assessed in each of the regressions run for this hypothesis test. in each case, the vif is found to be below 3, indicating a non-presence of significant multicollinearity. table 8 test of hypothesis five auditor switching firms by industry, b1 variable-pre sox model: car=𝑎+𝑏1𝑈𝐸𝑆𝑖𝑡+𝑏2𝑈𝐸𝑅𝑖𝑡+𝑏3𝑀𝐵𝑖𝑡+𝑏4𝐵𝑖𝑡+𝑏5𝑀𝑉𝑖𝑡+𝑏6𝐸𝑖𝑡+𝑏7𝐷𝑖𝑡 + eit industry n erc p-value technology 2 .10 1.58*** healthcare 3 .07 1.64*** oil/gas 5 .09 1.66*** banking/finance 7 .05 1.57*** utilities 5 .09 1.60*** real estate 4 .07 1.69*** transportation 9 .04 1.55*** industrials 15 .06 1.61*** *** significant at the .01 level ** significant at the .05 level * significant at the .10 level volume 34, number 2 93 table 9 test of hypothesis five auditor retaining firms by industry, b2 variable-post sox model: car=𝑎+𝑏1𝑈𝐸𝑆𝑖𝑡+𝑏2𝑈𝐸𝑅𝑖𝑡+𝑏3𝑀𝐵𝑖𝑡+𝑏4𝐵𝑖𝑡+𝑏5𝑀𝑉𝑖𝑡+𝑏6𝐸𝑖𝑡+𝑏7𝐷𝑖𝑡 + eit industry n erc p-value technology 4 .05 1.77** healthcare 5 .06 1.82** oil/gas 6 .04 1.66*** banking/finance 5 .03 1.72** utilities 7 .05 1.66*** real estate 6 .02 1.69*** transportation 7 .05 1.71** industrials 14 .02 1.78** a significant at the .01 level b significant at the .05 level c significant at the .10 level conclusions this study analyzes firms that emerge from chapter 11 bankruptcy with specific attention given to two groups; those that switch auditors post-bankruptcy, and those who retain previous auditors in a post-bankruptcy environment. in addition, further analysis is made to assess whether or not industry membership, along with pre or post sox environment play a role in results. results indicate that when the pre versus post sox environment is assessed, a significant difference is noted in the sample firms. post sox firms emerging from chapter 11 that switch auditors carry positive information content, therefore, investors tend to bid up the price of stock of these firms. firms emerging from chapter 11 in a post sox environment that do not change auditors tend to convey negative information content as their stock price is bid down by investors. with respect to a pre sox environment, results indicate that investors do not behave significantly different whether the firms changes auditors or not after emerging from chapter 11. in both cases, positive information content is inferred by the bidding up of stock price. 94 journal of business strategies when attention turns to assessing individual industries, in a post sox environment, a positive correlation between earnings response and stock price is seen across all industries evaluated when the firm emerging from chapter 11 switches auditors. growth industry firms, namely; technology, healthcare, oil/ gas, and banking and finance seem to show the greatest stock price reaction to earnings. with respect to firms that do not switch auditors post-bankruptcy, results are mixed across industries. most industries show a negative stock price reaction but certain growth industries (i.e. technology, healthcare, and oil/gas) reflect a positive reaction. in a pre sox environment, no significant industry difference is noted, either by firms that switch auditors or those that do not. all pre sox industry firms, on average, have a positive correlation between earnings response and stock price. this study brings together previous bankruptcy and auditor switching research and interjects the differing environment between the pre and post sox era. operating in a post sox period, greater emphasis is placed on industry distinction when it comes to emerging from chapter 11. above average growth industry firms, generate greater positive investor reaction when an auditor switch is made while below average growth industry firms generate a greater negative investor reaction when an auditor switch is not made. these results are beneficial to managers, investors, and creditors associated with the affected industries. references aharony, j., c. jones, & j. swary (2010). an analysis of corporate bankruptcy using capital market data. the journal of finance, 55(4), 1001-1016. ajinkya, b., r. atiase, & m. gift (1991). volume of trading and the dispersion in financial analysts’ earnings forecasts, the accounting review 66, 389-401. american institute of certified public accountant (aicpa) (1988). institution of the public company accounting oversight board, new york, 1-23. asthana, s., s. balsam, & j. krishnan (2010). corporate governance, audit firm reputation, auditor switches, and client stock price reaction, international journal of auditing, vol 14 (3), 274-293. baginski, s., & j. hassell (1990). the market interpretation of management earnings forecasts as a predictor of subsequent financial analyst forecast revision, the accounting review 65, 175-190. ball, r., & p. brown (1968). an empirical evaluation of accounting income numbers, journal of accounting research, (autumn) 159-178. volume 34, number 2 95 baron, r., & d. kenny (1986). the moderator-mediator variable distinction in social psychological research: conceptual, strategic, and statistical considerations, journal of personality and social psychology, vol. 51, no. 6, 1173-1182. beaver, w, r. clarke, & w. wright (1979). the association between unsystematic security returns and earnings forecast errors, journal of accounting research (autumn), 316-340. bradley, m., & m. rosenzweig (1992). the untenable case for chapter 11, yale law journal, 101, 1043-1089. carcello, j., & t. neal (2003). audit committee characteristics and auditor dismissals following new going concern reports. the accounting review, 78(1), 95-117. chang, h., a. cheng, and k. reichelt (2010). market reaction to auditor switching. journal of practice and theory, 29(2), 83-114. chow, c., & s. rice (1982). qualified audit opinions and auditor switching. the accounting review, 57 (april), 326-335. collins, d., & s. kothari (1994). lack of timeliness and noise as explanations for the low returnearnings associations, journal of accounting and economics 18, 289-324. davidson, w., p. jiraporn, & p. dedatt (2006). causes and consequences of auditor shopping. quarterly journal of finance and accounting, 45 (winter), 69-87. eberhart, a., e. altman, & r. aggarwal (1999). the equity performance of firms emerging from bankruptcy. journal of finance, 54, 1885-1868. ettredge, m., c. li, & s. scholz (2007). audit fees and auditor realignments. accounting horizons, 21(4), 371-386. ferris, s., n. jayaraman, & a. makhija (1997). the response of competitors to announcements of bankruptcy: an empirical examination of competitive effects. journal of corporate finance, 3, 367-395. fried, d., & a. schiff (1981). cpa switches and associated market reactions. the accounting review, 56 (april), 326-342. fries, s., m. miller, & w. perraudin (2015). debt in industry equilibrium, the review of financial studies, 10 (1), 39-67. geiger m, k. raghunandan, & d. rama (2005). recent changes in the association between bankruptcies and prior audit opinions. audit practice and theory, 24(1), 21–35. johnson, w., & t. lys (1990). the market for audit services: evidence from voluntary auditor changes. journal of accounting and economics, 12 (january), 281-308. klock, m. (2004). the stock market reaction to a change in certifying accountant. auditing and finance, 9(2), 339-347. 96 journal of business strategies krishnan, j., & j. krishnan (2007). litigation risks and auditor resignations. the accounting review, 72 (october), 539-560. lang, l., & r. stulz (1992). contagion and competitive intra-industry effects of bankruptcy announcements. journal of financial economics 32, 45-60. lev, b. (1989). on the usefulness of earnings and earnings research, journal of accounting research 27, 153-192. mackay, p., & g. phillips (2015). how does industry affect firm financial structure? the review of financial studies, 18 (4), 1433-1466. schwartz, k., & k menon (1985). auditor switches by failing firms. the accounting review, 60 (april), 248-261. sinha, p, l. brown, & s. das (2015). “a re-examination of financial analysts’ differential earnings forecast accuracy,” contemporary accounting research, 30-44. smith, d., & d. nichols (1992). a market test of investor reaction to auditor disagreements. journal; of accounting and economics, 4(2), 109-120. stunda, r. (2012). auditor switches in a post-sox environment, does the change in auditor mean a change in stock price? journal of business and behavioral sciences, 24(3), 58-69. truman, c., & m. weinstein (1983). the behavior of the bankrupt firm. the journal of finance, 38(3), 489-504. biographical sketch of author dr. ron stunda is professor of accounting and department chair at valdosta state university in valdosta, georgia. his primary area of interest is market-based financial accounting. he has published in numerous accounting and finance journals and is a reviewer and editorial board member of several academic journals. volume 40(1) p.21-36 received: july 30, 2022 revision received: october 28, 2022 accepted: october 31, 2022 https://doi.org/10.54155/jbs.40.1.21-36 personal and social determinants of fear of missing out (fomo) in younger consumers timothy h. reisenwitza, jie g. fowlerb a corresponding author. department of management and marketing, valdosta state university, valdosta, georgiatreisenw@valdosta.edu b department of management and marketing, valdosta state university, valdosta, georgia jgfowler@valdosta.edu abstract this study expands the exploration of a consumer behavior concept that has received considerable attention recently: the fear of missing out (fomo). several variables were analyzed in terms of their potential influence on fomo: social media usage, self-concept, social identity, smartphone usage, innovativeness, and gender. the study builds upon the premise that the construct has two distinct components: a personal dimension and a social dimension. the importance of these results is discussed in terms of advancing fomo theory as well as assisting practitioners in directing their promotional efforts. keywords fear of missing out (fomo), younger consumers, personal dimension of fomo, social dimension of fomo 1. introduction an emerging concept in consumer behavior is the fear of missing out (fomo). it was introduced in academia by herman (2000) who offered it as an explanation for the success of limited-edition brands. fomo was later introduced by the news media (columnist, 2010; fake, 2011). however, the concept has been present throughout history in any communication form that increases a consumer’s knowledge about his or her friends, family, or even strangers. these communication forms include newspapers, letters, annual holiday newsletters, and emails (wortham, 2011). however, more recently its influence has greatly expanded via the context of social media marketing. fomo is the feeling of being “left behind” when someone sees that peers own or experience something that seems rewarding that he or she is not owning or experiencing. researchers have provided many definitions of fomo (see table 1). according to zhang et al. (2020), the construct has two components, particularly when following a self-concept approach: the private self and/or the public self or a personal and/or a social dimension. fomo is characterized as an uneasy feeling, a feeling of anxiety. so, consumers can fear missfunding for this research was provided by a steele foundation summer grant. this work is licensed under a creative commonsattribution-noncommercial 4.0 international license. © 2023 the authors. https://doi.org/10.54155/jbs.40.1.21-36 treisenw@valdosta.edu jgfowler@valdosta.edu reisenwitz & fowler/ journal of business strategies (2023) 40:21-36 22 ing out on experiences that other people enjoy (social fomo) and can also fear missing out on experiences they had wished for themselves (personal fomo). the purpose of the study is to assess the influence of variables on the fear of missing out (fomo). much of the previous research on fomo has examined variables individually and how each influences fomo. this study addresses multiple variables and how they influence fomo. the study also assesses the efficacy of the two-component depiction of the fomo construct based upon the self-concept approach introduced by zhang et al. (2020). 2. literature review and theoretical framework of fomo past studies show that fear illustrates how social power is constituted, legitimated, and communicated through media logic with mediated formats guiding the use of technology (altheide, 2013). fear is an emotion resulting from perceived threats to one’s well-being (gill & burrow, 2018). threats involve adverse outcomes that the individuals want to terminate, escape from, or avoid (gray, 1971). the concept of fomo was first introduced by herman (2000) as a potential explanation for the success of limited edition brands. he argues that when consumers feel incapable of exhausting all the options of products in the marketplace, they become fearful about the risk of possibly missing desirable opportunities. thus, fomo increases consumers’ urgency to exhaust all available offerings, especially those that are scarce. as a result, fomo could be a powerful motivation to encourage buying (herman, 2000). in consumer psychology, the fomo phenomenon has been defined as a pervasive apprehension that others might be having rewarding experiences from which one is absent and is characterized by the desire to stay continually connected with what others are doing (przybylski et al., 2013). in other words, fomo refers to the anxiety social media users feel when they perceive their peers are doing, experiencing, or possessing something rewarding while they are not (przybylski et al., 2013). research has explored the prevalence of fomo and its relation to social media (abel et al., 2016). a recent study by alt (2015) finds a positive link between social media engagement and fomo. in fact, social media users have grown exponentially in the past decade. in 2021, over 4.26 billion people were using social media worldwide, a number projected to increase to almost six billion in 2027 (statista, 2022). college students are the heaviest social media users (alt, 2015). smartphone penetration is believed to be one of the dominating forcesdrivingsocialmediausage(swar&hameed, 2017). research has shown that the excessive use of smartphones links to adverse outcomes, such as smartphone addiction (aljomaa et al., 2016; lee et al., 2014). in addition, the research examines the conceptual background of fomo with offline consumer behavior. zhang et al. (2020) propose a theoretical foundation for fomo by following a self-concept approach. they posit that consumers experience fomo when they perceive that missing experience poses a psychological threat to the private and/or public self. the private self refers to the evaluation of oneself (e.g., self-identify or membership), and the public self is the projection of others’ view of oneself (e.g., self-concept/feeling of the self). finally, zhang et al. (2020) indicate novelty seeking or innovativeness may be a variable associated with fomo. recent research also shows that fomo may be multidimensional (zhang et al., 2020) and that fomo involves two dimensions: a personal fomo and a social fomo. accordingly, a new scale was developed, offering researchers to further test the concept of fomo and related variables. to conclude, many variables may activate fomo. fomo may be activated by threats to the selfconcept (zhang et al., 2020). consumers tend to purchase goods and services that are consistent with or enhance, their self-concept. consumers may perceive that missing out on experiences may be inconsistent with their self-concept. furthermore, higher social media engagement may activate fomo (alt, 2015), although the construct has been found in non-online contexts as well, includreisenwitz & fowler/ journal of business strategies (2023) 40:21-36 23 table 1: previous definitions of fear of missing out (fomo) author (year) definition jwt intelligence inprzybylski et al.(2013) the uneasy and sometimes all-consuming feeling that you are missing out,that your peers are doing something, are in the know about, or in posses-sion of more of something better than you. przybylski et al.(2013) a phenomenon characterized by the desire to stay continually connectedwith what others are doing and a pervasive apprehension that others mightbe having rewarding experiences from which one is absent. gil et al. (2015) fear of missing out is a concept that aims to describe the feeling that some-thing is happening on social networks and you are not part of it. riordan et al. (2015) the uneasy and often all-consuming sense that “friends or others are hav-ing rewarding experiences from which one is absent.” salem (2016) a kind of anxiety, a sense that you will be inadequate or left behind if youdon’t react. abel et al. (2016) fomo is comprised of irritability, anxiety, and feelings of inadequacy, withthese feelings tending to worsen when an individual logs on to social mediawebsites. (zhang et al., 2020) ing smartphone overuse (elhai et al., 2016). those consumers who are considered innovators (early users) in the product adoption process may also significantly impact fomo (manning et al., 1995). finally, higher degrees of social identity in consumers may also influence fomo (reed, 2002). social media usage it is well-documented that those with a high dependence on social media also have a high level of fomo (argan & tokay argan, 2020; asif, 2020; classen et al., 2020; kang et al., 2020; przybylski et al., 2013). so, social media services such as instagram, youtube, facebook, twitter, and tiktok may be especially attractive for those who fear missing out. furthermore, there are positive and negative consequences of this attraction. on a positive note, social media are excellent for those who are seeking social connection and may provide greater social involvement. knowing what friends and family are doing and buying is beneficial for connection and interaction. however, time is a scarce commodity and so the negative result is missing out on some of the activities found via social media. so, unfortunately, social media and a fear of missing out may result in overall unhappiness. feelings of irritability, anxiety (gray, 1971), and inadequacy can impact the fear of missing out and these may intensify when individuals view social media (abel et al., 2016). providing the ability to see others’ updates inreal-time, socialmediaallowsconsumerstoconstantlyseewhattheymaybemissingouton, possibly resulting in dissatisfaction, anxiety, and unworthiness (abel et al., 2016). elhai et al. (2016) state that fomo can drive the overuse of social media. in sum, social media is “kerosene on fomo’s fire” (miller, 2012, p.2). based on this discussion, the following hypothesis is proposed: hypothesis 1a. individuals exhibiting greater social media usage will have a greater personal fear of missing out. hypothesis 1b. individuals exhibiting greater social media usage will have a greater social fear of missing out. self-concept sirgy (1982) first suggested that some purchase decisions can be affected by a consumer’s selfconcept. he stated that self-concept is the sum reisenwitz & fowler/ journal of business strategies (2023) 40:21-36 24 of an individual’s thoughts and feelings about himself or herself relative to other objects. consumers generally have favorable attitudes towards products and brands that are consistent with their self-concept and less favorable attitudes towards products and brands perceived to be inconsistent with their self-concept (graeff, 1996). furthermore, zhang et al. (2020) proposed that fomo, “is the fear an individual feels from missing out on an experience that can enhance or maintain her/his self-concept” (p. 1630). although they can overlap, zhang et al. (2020) posit that there are two major types of selfconcept: a private self and a public self. the private self refers to thoughts that the individual does not share with others or perhaps a small group of people. these thoughts include reflections, daydreams, or fantasies that can be satisfied through a consumption experience, which would maintain or enhance their private selfconcept. most research dealing with fomo has focused on the public self, which is based upon what other people are doing or saying, fueled largely by social media. what people say on social media, whether discussing others or discussing events, can intensify fomo (zhang et al., 2020). based on this discussion, the following hypothesis is proposed: hypothesis 2a. individuals with a greater selfconcept will have a lower personal fear of missing out. hypothesis 2b. individuals with a greater selfconcept will have a lower social fear of missing out. social identity social identity theory divides self-concept into two categories: personal identity, or how people view themselves, and social identity, or collective identity, which refers to how they view their social groups (dutot, 2020). additionally, social identity theory shows the importance of social group memberships to individuals’ self-concept (dutot, 2020). similarly, duman and ozkara (2021) state that social identity is a part of self-concept that comes from the knowledge that an individual belongs to a social group(s) coupled with the value and emotional significance of that membership. based on this discussion, the following hypothesis is proposed: hypothesis 3a. individuals exhibiting greater social identity will have a greater personal fear of missing out. hypothesis 3b. individuals exhibiting greater social identity will have a greater social fear of missing out. smartphone usage the mental disorders associated with excessive smartphone use have been well-documented, including depression, anxiety, sleeping issues (demirci et al., 2015), stress, depression, and suicidal ideation (kim et al., 2019). people high in fomo overuse their smartphones in order to stay connected. elhai et al. (2016) found that excessive smartphone use was associated with anxiety, the need for touch, and fomo. additionally, fomo was the variable that was most related to excessive smartphone use on a bivariate and multivariate basis. fomo and the need for touch were significant predictors of dysfunctional smartphone use. furthermore, both elhai et al. (2016) and przybylski et al. (2013) found that fomo is a discriminating variable between problematic and non-problematic smartphone use. based on this discussion, the following hypothesis is proposed: hypothesis 4a. individuals exhibiting greater smartphone usage will have a greater personal fear of missing out. hypothesis 4b. individuals exhibiting greater smartphone usage will have a greater social fear of missing out. innovativeness innovativeness is the degree to which an individual adopts a new idea faster than others (vandecasteele & geuens, 2010). rogers (1995) introduced the diffusion of innovations model, which grouped adopters of innovations based on the time of adoption. the two earliest groups in the reisenwitz & fowler/ journal of business strategies (2023) 40:21-36 25 model are innovators and early adopters (girardi & chiagouris, 2018). early adopters connect the innovators with the mass groups of adopters, the early majority and the late majority. innovators and early adopters are both depicted as having a high degree of innovativeness. clark and goldsmith (2006) report that academicians contend that innovators prefer to use nonpersonal sources of information versus interpersonal sources of information when making new product purchase decisions. in other words, innovativeness has been shown to be more closely associated with opinion leadership than opinion seeking: “innovativeness is the degree to which an individual makes innovation decisions independently of the communicated experience of others” (midgley & dowling, 1978, p. 235). they use nonpersonal sources, such as mass media versus interpersonal sources, such as social media. this discussion of innovativeness and the behavior of innovators runs counter to the concept of fomo, in which consumers place great importance on knowing what others are doing. although communicating with innovators is a critical requirement for the acceptance of an innovation and its diffusion, it can be concluded based on the literature that those with a high fomo are not part of the innovator group. therefore, the following hypothesis is proposed: hypothesis 5a. individuals exhibiting greater innovativeness will have less personal fear of missing out. hypothesis 5b. individuals exhibiting greater innovativeness will have less social fear of missing out. gender knowledge involving gender differences may be useful for fomo research in order to control potential gender effects. however, previous research provides mixed results regarding the relationship between gender and fomo. przybylski et al. (2013) and qutishat (2020) found that young males tended to have higher levels of fomo than females. in contrast, beyens et al. (2016) and stead and bibby (2017) found that females reported higher levels of fomo than males. moreover, rozgonjuk et al. (2021) found no significant gender differences in experiencing fomo. therefore, the following hypothesis is proposed: hypothesis 6a. there are no gender differences regarding the personal fear of missing out. hypothesis 6b. there are no gender differences regarding the social fear of missing out. 3. method the sample consisted of undergraduate students, alumni, and non-students belonging to either generation y or generation z. the questionnaire was sent via a university “student announcements” email. any completed questionnaires that were outside of the age range of the latter two generational cohorts (generation y, 1981-1996, and generation z, 1997-2012) were omitted from the sample. although a convenience sample, these respondents are appropriate for the study since fomo is more evident in young people (zhang et al., 2020). similarly, przybylski et al. (2013) found that younger consumers had higher levels of fomo, concurring with early industry reports that fomo was more prevalent in younger people (jwt, 2011, 2012). respondents were introduced to the study in the body of the email and then asked to click on the link that would take them to the qualtrics questionnaire. the questions capture the respondents’ demographics (age, race, education, occupation, religion, etc.) and psychographic information, which focused on the variables in the hypotheses. a pretest was conducted before the questionnaire was distributed to the main sample. the questionnaire was completed by six undergraduate students who were currently enrolled in at least one class. an additional questionnaire was sent to a recent alumnus who was named “student of the year” for the university’s college of business. no problems were reported by anyone taking the pretest questionnaire. as a result, no changes were made to the questionnaire before its administration to the main sample. reisenwitz & fowler/ journal of business strategies (2023) 40:21-36 26 the total number of questionnaires received over a two-week period, with a one-week reminder email after the first week, was 280. since the focus of the study is younger consumers, only those respondents in generation y (millennials) or generation z were retained, leaving a total of 229 respondents. next, questionnaires with a significant amount of missing data were eliminated, leaving a total of 225 for the final sample size. the final sample’s demographics were analyzed. the profile emerged that the typical respondent is described as the following: female (73%), a member of generation z (63%), has an income of $010,000 (55%), has never married (79%), is white (caucasian) (58%), has completed an undergraduate degree (45%), and is a student (59%). the complete demographic data is presented in table 2. scales existing multiple-item scales will be used for each of the psychographic variables or constructs that may have an impact on fomo. they will be included as independent variables in a multiple regression analysis with fomo as the dependent variable. social media usage rapp et al. (2013) created this scale, consisting of ten, seven-point items from “strongly disagree” to “strongly agree” to measure how much someone uses social media to stay current with brands, retailers, and consumers. three statements were removed due to their context-specificity. the last question was changed from “retail stores” to “retailers” to accommodate online sellers. self-concept the six-item, seven-point semantic differential scale was created by de angelis et al. (2012) (bruner, 2016). it is intended to measure how one feels about himself or herself. social identity the social identity scale was created by narioredmond et al. (2004). there are eight items on a seven-point scale from “not at all important to who i am” to “extremely important to who i am.” it was reduced from a nine-point to a seven-point scale forconsistency withthe other psychographic measures in this study. social identity was defined for the respondent as how an individual is identified by his or her group memberships. smartphone usage the smartphone usage scale was used in several studies (cheever et al., 2014; hoffner & lee, 2015; smith, 2015). the scale was expanded from six to seven points for consistency across scales in this study. it consists of 11 items on a “never” to “very often” scale. respondents who did not own a smartphone were instructed to skip these questions. innovativeness the scale used for innovativeness was based upon the notion that a consumer’s level of innovativeness is domain-specific, i.e., it is based upon a product category (klink & athaide, 2010). the other forms of consumer innovativeness are consumer innate innovativeness (cii) and vicarious innovativeness (vi) (chao et al., 2012). prior research shows that the relationship between consumer innate innovativeness and new product adoption is weak and inconsistent. and although it has been shown that mass media and wordof-mouth influence new product adoption, few researchers have used vicarious innovativeness (chao et al., 2012). the innovativeness scale in this study was used by shalev and morwitz (2012). bruner (2016) reported that the scale was actually developed by shalev. it was domain-specific and used the product category of high-technology products. shalev and morwitz (2012) justified using the category based on the fact that younger consumers tend to be innovators of high-technology products. the scale was a ten-item, seven-point likert “strongly disagree” to “strongly agree” measure. fomo the scale used for fomo was developed by zhang et al. (2020). they proposed that fomo has two components: personal fomo, related to the private self, and social fomo, related to the public self. their analysis treated fomo as a feeling that individuals can experience not only online, especially via social media, but also offline. the scale was a seven-point likert scale from “strongly disagree” to “strongly agree.” it consisted of five items to measure the personal fomo dimension reisenwitz & fowler/ journal of business strategies (2023) 40:21-36 27 table 2: descriptive information of the sample items percent (n) gender male 24 (54)female 73 (164)non-binary/ third gender 3 (6) birth year 1981 1996 37 (83)1997 2012 63 (142) income 0-10k 55 (124)10,001 30k 20 (46)30,001 50k 12 (27)50,0001 70k 7 (15)above 70k 5 (12) marital status married 18 (40)widowed 1 (3)divorced 1 (2)separated 1 (2)never married 79 (178) race white(caucasian) 58 (131)black 27 (60)hispanic 6 (14)asian american 3 (7)pacific islander 1 (2)other 6 (13) educ completed ged & high school 36 (81)undergraduate 45 (101)graduate 13 (29)other 6 (13) occupation student 59 (133)homemaker/not employed 2 (5)self-employed 1 (3)educator 5 (11)professional 8 (18)work for company/business 22 (49)other 3 (6) percentages may not total 100 due to missing data or may exceed 100 due to rounding reisenwitz & fowler/ journal of business strategies (2023) 40:21-36 28 and four items to measure the social fomo dimension. 4. results reliability coefficients were computed for each of the scales (table 3a and 3b). all coefficient alphas were above the 0.70 value recommended by nunnally (1978). in this analysis, the independent variables consisted of social media usage, selfconcept, social identity, smartphone usage, and innovativeness; the dependent variable was fear of missing out (fomo). since the study focuses on both personal and social aspects of fomo, fomo was treated as two dependent variables, i.e., fomopersonal and fomosocial. according to the analysis, the independent variables have a relationship to personal fomo, i.e., fomopersonal (f = 9.746, p < 0.001) (see table 4, table 5). as hypothesized, social media usage has a positive influence on fomopersonal (β = 0.208, t = 2.713, p < 0.05) (h1a). moreover, individuals with greater self-concept are negatively associated with fomopersonal (β = -0.39, t = -5.852, p < 0.05) (h2a). in addition, the analysis shows smartphone usage has a positive impact on fomopersonal (β = 0.174, t = 2.493, p < 0.05) (h4a). yet, neither social identity (h3a) nor innovativeness (h5a) are associated with fomopersonal (β = -0.115, t = -1.562, p > 0.05) (β = -0.118, t = -1.679, p > 0.05). furthermore, the results show that self-concept is significant with a negative impact on fomosocial (β = -0.482, t = -7.503, p < 0.05) (h2b) (see table 6, table 7). also, there were no gender differences in relation to fomo (tpersonal = -0.72, p > 0.05; tsocial = 0.475, p > 0.05) (h6a), (h6b). 5. discussion fomo is an emerging topic in consumer psychology, which is a feeling of being “left behind” (salem, 2016). it generally relates to technological advancements, such as social media and smartphone usage. according to zhang et al. (2020), fomo not only refers to the fear of missing out on experiences other people may enjoy but also the feeling of missing out on experiences they had wished for themselves. therefore, fomo tends to be activated by psychological threats to the selfconcept. it is often a result of threats to the public and/or private self. this study contributes to fomo theory by examining the personal and social aspects of fomo. specifically, it explores possible connections between social media, smartphone usage, innovativeness, social identity and self-concept, and fomo. it also supports the lack of gender difference in relation to fomo. as przybylski et al. (2013) posit, social media can be “thought of as reducing the ‘cost of admission’ for being socially engaged” (p. 1841). yet, it was found that the use of technology, such as social media engagement and smartphone usage, has an impact on the personal dimension of fomo but does not have an impact on the social dimension of fomo, indicating that technology may have a more significant effect on personal fomo than social fomo. the non-significant results for social fomo may indicate that ultimately consumers will engage in activities or purchase products that are right for them versus right for their social group(s). to concur with earlier research, the analysis shows that individuals with greater self-concept tend to exhibit less personal fomo or social fomo. individuals with a confident “self” are less likely to be fearful. the results also reveal that innovativeness and social identity are not related to either personal fomo or social fomo. finally, there was a non-significant difference between gender and fomo. this finding may reflect the gender roles among generation z. generally speaking, generation z favors gender role flexibility and is less in favor of the patriarchy (lampert, 2021). theoretical and practical implications this study aimed to examine the relationship between the two dimensions of fomo and the“self” andtoevaluatetherelevantliterature. specifically, the study contributes to theory by supporting the self-concept view of fomo proposed by zhang et al. (2020), which differentiates the personal and reisenwitz & fowler/ journal of business strategies (2023) 40:21-36 29 table 3a: reliability coefficients items coefficient alpha social media usage 0.90i use social media to follow sales and promotions.i use social media to monitor events.people use social media to reach me.i use social media to improve my relationship with different brands.i use social media to communicate with retailers.i use social media to improve my relationship with retailers.my relationship with my retail stores is enhanced by social media. self-concept 0.95unsatisfied with yourself satisfied with yourselfnot proud of yourself proud of yourselffeel bad about yourself feel good about yourselffeel unsuccessful feel successfulnot confident about yourself confident about yourselffeel worthless feel like a person of worth social identity 0.83the similarity i share with others in my group(s)my family nationality or nationalitiesthe memberships i have in various groupsthe places where i have livedmy sense of belonging to my own racial groupmy gender groupthe color of my skinmy being a citizen of my country smartphone usage 0.81video and voice calls (making and receiving)text/instant messaging (sending and receiving)email (sending and receiving)social networking sitesinternet/websitesgamesmusic/podcasts/radiotaking pictures or videoswatching videos/tv/moviesreading books/magazinesmaps/navigation reisenwitz & fowler/ journal of business strategies (2023) 40:21-36 30 table 3b: reliability coefficients items coefficient alpha innovativeness 0.95in general, i am among the first in my circle of friendsto buy a new high-tech product when it appears.if i heard that a new high-tech product was available,i would be interested enough to buy it.i am usually one of the first people to know about new high-tech products.i will buy a new high-tech product even if i haven’t tried it yet.i actively try to learn about new high-tech products.i generally keep up on high-tech products news and events.i consider myself very up-to-date when it comes to high-tech products.in general, i have a strong interest in high-tech products.high-tech products are a very important product category to me.high-tech products matter to me a lot. personal fomo 0.90i feel anxious when i do not experience events/opportunities.i believe i am falling behind compared with others when imiss events/opportunities.i feel anxious because i know something important or fun must happenwhen i miss events/opportunities.i feel sad if i am not capable of participating in events due to constraintsof other things.i feel regretful of missing events/opportunities. social fomo 0.93i think my social groups view me as unimportant when i missevents/opportunities.i think i do not fit in social groups when i miss events/opportunities.i think i am excluded by my social groups when i miss events/opportunities.i feel ignored/forgotten by my social groups when i miss events/opportunities. table 4: hypothesis testing for fomopersonal hypotheses results hypothesis 1a individuals exhibiting greater social media usage willhave a greater personal fear of missing out. accepthypothesis 2a individuals with greater self-concept will have less per-sonal fear of missing out. accepthypothesis 3a individuals exhibiting greater social identity will have agreater personal fear of missing out. rejecthypothesis 4a individuals exhibiting greater smartphone usage willhave a greater personal fear of missing out. accepthypothesis 5a individuals exhibiting greater innovativeness will haveless personal fear of missing out. rejecthypothesis 6a therearenogenderdifferencesregardingpersonalfearof missing out. accept reisenwitz & fowler/ journal of business strategies (2023) 40:21-36 31 table 5: regression analysis for fomopersonal β standardized β t sig. (constant) 3.395 5.557 0.000social media usage 0.217 0.208 2.713 0.007self-concept/image -0.378 -0.390 -5.852 0.000social identity 0.133 0.118 1.679 0.095smartphone usage 0.276 0.174 2.493 0.013innovativeness -0.122 -0.115 -1.562 0.120 table 6: hypothesis testing for fomosocial hypotheses results hypothesis 1b individuals exhibiting greater social media usage willhave a greater social fear of missing out. rejecthypothesis 2b individuals with greater self-concept will have less socialfear of missing out. accepthypothesis 3b individuals exhibiting greater social identity will have agreater social fear of missing out. rejecthypothesis 4b individuals exhibiting greater smartphone usage willhave a greater social fear of missing out. rejecthypothesis 5b individuals exhibiting greater innovativeness will haveless social fear of missing out. rejecthypothesis 6b there are no gender differences regarding social fear ofmissing out. accept table 7: regression analysis for fomosocial β standardized β t sig. (constant) 3.746 5.645 0.000social media usage 0.169 0.144 1.945 0.053self-concept/image -0.526 -0.483 -7.503 0.000social identity 0.133 0.118 1.679 0.095smartphone usage 0.276 0.174 2.493 0.013innovativeness -0.122 -0.115 -1.562 0.120 reisenwitz & fowler/ journal of business strategies (2023) 40:21-36 32 social aspects of fomo. table 5 and table 7 report the differences in regression analysis results between the personal dimension of fomo and the social dimension of fomo in regard to variables. the findings show that social media engagement and smartphone usage have a positive influence on the personal dimension of fomo, whereas selfconcept has a negative influence. the findings regarding social media and smartphone usage are consistent with previous research that fomo is related to the overuse of technology (e.g. elhai et al., 2016). in other words, for those who are afraid of missing out, social media and smartphones provide means to connect with others. fomo is an anxiety disorder that is defined as not being aware of exciting things when not being looked at, or missing out on the experiences of others. although the fomo effect has a negative meaning, businesses manage to use this concern to their advantage. for example, the results show that social fomo is associated with selfconcept. these findings may help social media marketers to identify fomo consumers based on the “self-concepts.” that being said, social media marketers may use selfies as an indicator of selfconcept on social media, thus finding insights into fomo consumers. additionally, limited production, shortage of products in stock, short-term discounts, showing the number of people interested in the same product, and promotions offered as opportunities not to be missed are among the efforts of businesses to persuade consumers through fomo. furthermore, the call to action (e.g., do not miss out, a one-day sales event) may likely be contingent on social media usage and smartphone use. digital marketers may use these “calls to action” to leverage more effective social media marketing campaigns. in particular, digital marketers may be able to incorporate consumers’ desires or fear as a motivational tool to purchase a product or seek out information. moreover, digital marketers may need to be aware that individuals exhibiting greater smartphone usage and more significant socialmediausehaveagreaterfearofmissingout. this finding indicates that marketers can use software to track the usage of screen time and identity a particular consumer group that is afraid of missing out. finally, the results show that gender and innovativeness have no impact on fomo, which offers marketers insights that gender and innovativeness are not the variables needed to be considered or focused on for market segmentation in the context of fomo in social media advertising campaigns. in sum, the fear of missing out on something can be a powerful emotion, and it is one that many individuals struggle with, especially members of gen z. this idea has been studied by various researchers who have found evidence supporting its validity as an explanation for why consumers select special editions over others (altheide, 2013). as a result, fomo may drive consumers to make impulsive buying decisions. thus, consumers should be aware of fomo in the context of social media promotion and be conscious of the consequences of fomo. a similar construct to fomo, cognitive dissonance, which has been described as post-purchase anxiety in non-routine purchases, is an undesirable consumer behavior condition that both marketers and consumers wish to minimize or eliminate. although fomo is similar to cognitive dissonance in that it is a form of consumer anxiety, it is actually a condition that can be advantageous to the marketer. for the marketer who wishes to leverage fomo as a promotional tool, a “don’t be left out” or “limited edition” approach may be prudent, specifically via social media and/or smartphone technology. limitationsanddirectionsforfutureresearch this study has some limitations. first, the sample, although representative of the target of younger consumers, was a convenience sample since an email list of students, alumni, and non-students of one university was used. second, the results regarding gender may have been compromised due to the groups being rather unbalanced, with the majority of the sample consisting of female respondents (73%). this shortcoming is often addressed in studies using panels and/or offering incentives for participation. additionally, this study has concluded that there are no gender differreisenwitz & fowler/ journal of business strategies (2023) 40:21-36 33 ences regarding fomo, concurring with some previous research. yet, due to inconsistencies in the results found in other studies, this finding may need to be validated in future research. fomo has often been seen as a novel phenomenon that emerged with the increasing popularity of social media. this is perhaps the first study to simultaneously investigate multiple variables, specifically, innovativeness, self-concept, and social identity with both dimensions of fomo. future research may investigate why technology has not had an impact on the social aspect of fomo. it is also worthwhile to examine why social identity is not related to fomo and why most of the results for fomosocial were non-significant. the fomo construct is based upon social relationships, so intuitively, those results were unexpected. researchers may further collect a nonstudent sample to compare generations y and z with the other generational cohorts, i.e., matures, baby boomers, and generation x. nevertheless, generation y and generation z may be important cohorts to target since younger consumers still use technology to a greater degree than older consumers (thanasrivanitchai et al., 2017). references abel, j. p., buff, c. l., & burr, s. a. (2016). social media and the fear of missing out: scale development and assessment. journal of business & economics research (jber), 14(1), 33–44. https://doi.org/ 10.19030/jber.v14i1.9554 aljomaa, s. s., al.qudah, m. f., albursan, i. s., bakhiet, s. f., & abduljabbar, a. s. (2016). smartphone addiction among university students in the light of some variables. computers in human behavior, 61, 155–164. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2016.03.041 alt, d. (2015). college students’ academic motivation, media engagement and fear of missing out. computers in human behavior, 49, 111–119. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2015.02.057 altheide, d. l. (2013). media logic, social control, and fear: media logic, social control, and fear. communication theory, 23(3), 223–238. https://doi.org/10.1111/comt.12017 argan, m., & tokay argan, m. (2020). share or worry! relationship among fomo, social visibility and conspicuous sharing. journal of internet applications and management, 11(2), 63–80. asif, s. (2020). herd consumption behaviour of indian youth towards luxury fashion brands: the mediating role of fomo. xi’an dianzi keji daxue xuebao/journal of xidian university, 14, 707–728. https: //doi.org/10.37896/jxu14.10/075 beyens, i., frison, e., & eggermont, s. (2016). “i don’t want to miss a thing”: adolescents’ fear of missing outanditsrelationshiptoadolescents’socialneeds,facebookuse,andfacebookrelatedstress. computers in human behavior, 64, 1–8. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2016.05.083 bruner, g. c. (2016). marketing scales handbook. 8: multi-item measures for consumer insight research / gordon c. bruner (2. edition). gcbii productions. chao, c.-w., reid, m., & mavondo, f. t. (2012). consumer innovativeness influence on really new product adoption. australasian marketing journal, 20(3), 211–217. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ausmj. 2012.02.001 cheever, n. a., rosen, l. d., carrier, l. m., & chavez, a. (2014). out of sight is not out of mind: the impact of restricting wireless mobile device use on anxiety levels among low, moderate and high users. computers in human behavior, 37, 290–297. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2014.05.002 clark, r. a., & goldsmith, r. e. (2006). interpersonal influence and consumer innovativeness. international journal of consumer studies, 30(1), 34–43. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1470-6431.2005. 00435.x classen, b., wood, j. k., & davies, p. (2020). social network sites, fear of missing out, and psychosocial correlates. cyberpsychology: journal of psychosocial research on cyberspace, 14(3). https://doi. org/10.5817/cp2020-3-4 https://doi.org/10.19030/jber.v14i1.9554 https://doi.org/10.19030/jber.v14i1.9554 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2016.03.041 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2015.02.057 https://doi.org/10.1111/comt.12017 https://doi.org/10.37896/jxu14.10/075 https://doi.org/10.37896/jxu14.10/075 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2016.05.083 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ausmj.2012.02.001 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ausmj.2012.02.001 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2014.05.002 https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1470-6431.2005.00435.x https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1470-6431.2005.00435.x https://doi.org/10.5817/cp2020-3-4 https://doi.org/10.5817/cp2020-3-4 reisenwitz & fowler/ journal of business strategies (2023) 40:21-36 34 columnist, m. m., sf gate. (2010). oh my god you are so missing out. retrieved october 28, 2022, from https://www.sfgate.com/entertainment/morford/article/oh-my-god-you-are-so-missing-out2536241.php de angelis, m., bonezzi, a., peluso, a. m., rucker, d. d., & costabile, m. (2012). on braggarts and gossips: a self-enhancement account of word-of-mouth generation and transmission. journal of marketing research, 49(4), 551–563. https://doi.org/10.1509/jmr.11.0136 demirci, k., akgönül, m., & akpinar, a. (2015). relationship of smartphone use severity with sleep quality, depression, and anxiety in university students. journal of behavioral addictions, 4(2), 85–92. https://doi.org/10.1556/2006.4.2015.010 duman, h., & ozkara, b. y. (2021). the impact of social identity on online game addiction: the mediating role of the fear of missing out (fomo) and the moderating role of the need to belong. current psychology, 40(9), 4571–4580. https://doi.org/10.1007/s12144-019-00392-w dutot,v. (2020).asocial identityperspectiveofsocialmedia’s impactonsatisfactionwithlife.psychology & marketing, 37(6), 759–772. https://doi.org/10.1002/mar.21333 elhai, j. d., levine, j. c., dvorak, r. d., & hall, b. j. (2016). fear of missing out, need for touch, anxiety and depression are related to problematic smartphone use. computers in human behavior, 63, 509–516. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2016.05.079 fake, a. c. (2011). fomo and social media. retrieved october 28, 2022, from https://caterina.net/2011/ 03/15/fomo-and-social-media/ gil, f., chamarro, a., & oberst, u. (2015). po-14: addiction to online social networks: a question of" fear of missing out"? journal of behavioral addictions, 4(s1), 51–52. gill, m. j., & burrow, r. (2018). the function of fear in institutional maintenance: feeling frightened as an essential ingredient in haute cuisine. organization studies, 39(4), 445–465. https://doi.org/ 10.1177/0170840617709306 girardi, p., & chiagouris, l. (2018). the digital marketplace: early adopters have changed. journal of marketing development and competitiveness, 12(1). https://doi.org/10.33423/jmdc.v12i1.1412 graeff, t. r. (1996). using promotional messages to manage the effects of brand and self-image on brand evaluations. journal of consumer marketing, 13(3), 4–18. https : / / doi . org / 10 . 1108 / 07363769610118921 gray, j. a. (1971). the psychology of fear and stress. weidenfeld; nicolson. herman, d. (2000). introducing short-term brands: a new branding tool for a new consumer reality. journal of brand management, 7(5), 330–340. https://doi.org/10.1057/bm.2000.23 hoffner, c. a., & lee, s. (2015). mobile phone use, emotion regulation, and well-being. cyberpsychology, behavior, and social networking, 18(7), 411–416. https://doi.org/10.1089/cyber.2014.0487 jwt. (2011). jwt explores fear of missing out phenomenon: report outlines how fomo is manifesting in the zeitgeist. https://www.prweb.com/releases/2011/5/prweb8378292.htm jwt. (2012). jwt explores fear of missing out report, sxsw presentation spotlight how brands can leverage fomo. https://www.prweb.com/releases/2012/3/prweb9265660.htm kang, i., he, x., & shin, m. m. (2020). chinese consumers’ herd consumption behavior related to korean luxury cosmetics: the mediating role of fear of missing out. frontiers in psychology, 11, 121. https://doi.org/10.3389/fpsyg.2020.00121 kim, h.-j., min, j.-y., kim, h.-j., & min, k.-b. (2019). association between psychological and self-assessed healthstatusandsmartphoneoveruseamongkoreancollegestudents. journalofmentalhealth, 28(1), 11–16. https://doi.org/10.1080/09638237.2017.1370641 klink, r. r., & athaide, g. a. (2010). consumer innovativeness and the use of new versus extended brand names for new products: consumer innovativeness and brand names. journal of product innovation management, 27(1), 23–32. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5885.2009.00697.x https://www.sfgate.com/entertainment/morford/article/oh-my-god-you-are-so-missing-out-2536241.php https://www.sfgate.com/entertainment/morford/article/oh-my-god-you-are-so-missing-out-2536241.php https://doi.org/10.1509/jmr.11.0136 https://doi.org/10.1556/2006.4.2015.010 https://doi.org/10.1007/s12144-019-00392-w https://doi.org/10.1002/mar.21333 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2016.05.079 https://caterina.net/2011/03/15/fomo-and-social-media/ https://caterina.net/2011/03/15/fomo-and-social-media/ https://doi.org/10.1177/0170840617709306 https://doi.org/10.1177/0170840617709306 https://doi.org/10.33423/jmdc.v12i1.1412 https://doi.org/10.1108/07363769610118921 https://doi.org/10.1108/07363769610118921 https://doi.org/10.1057/bm.2000.23 https://doi.org/10.1089/cyber.2014.0487 https://www.prweb.com/releases/2011/5/prweb8378292.htm https://www.prweb.com/releases/2012/3/prweb9265660.htm https://doi.org/10.3389/fpsyg.2020.00121 https://doi.org/10.1080/09638237.2017.1370641 https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5885.2009.00697.x reisenwitz & fowler/ journal of business strategies (2023) 40:21-36 35 lampert, m. (2021). meet gen z: redefining gender roles and challenging patriarchy. retrieved october 28, 2022, from https://glocalities.com/reports/meet-gen-z lee, y.-k., chang, c.-t., lin, y., & cheng, z.-h. (2014). the dark side of smartphone usage: psychological traits, compulsive behavior and technostress. computers in human behavior, 31, 373–383. https: //doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2013.10.047 manning, k. c., bearden, w. o., & madden, t. j. (1995). consumer innovativeness and the adoption process. journalofconsumerpsychology,4(4),329–345.https://doi.org/10.1207/s15327663jcp0404_ 02 midgley, d. f., & dowling, g. r. (1978). innovativeness: the concept and its measurement. journal of consumer research, 4(4), 229. https://doi.org/10.1086/208701 miller, s. (2012). fear of missing out: are you a slave to fomo? https://abcnews.go.com/health/ wellness/fear-missing-slave-fomo/story?id=16629972 nario-redmond, m. r., biernat, m., eidelman, s., & palenske, d. j. (2004). the social and personal identities scale: a measure of the differential importance ascribed to social and personal selfcategorizations. self and identity, 3(2), 143–175. https://doi.org/10.1080/13576500342000103 nunnally, j. c. (1978). psychometric theory (2d ed). mcgraw-hill. przybylski, a. k., murayama, k., dehaan, c. r., & gladwell, v. (2013). motivational, emotional, and behavioral correlates of fear of missing out. computers in human behavior, 29(4), 1841–1848. https: //doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2013.02.014 qutishat, m. g. m. (2020). academic adjustment, emotional intelligence, and fear of missing out among undergraduate students: a descriptive correlational study. oman medical journal, 35(5), e174– e174. https://doi.org/10.5001/omj.2020.116 rapp, a., beitelspacher, l. s., grewal, d., & hughes, d. e. (2013). understanding social media effects across seller, retailer, and consumer interactions. journal of the academy of marketing science, 41(5), 547–566. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-013-0326-9 reed, a. (2002). social identity as a useful perspective for self-concept-based consumer research. psychology and marketing, 19(3), 235–266. https://doi.org/10.1002/mar.10011 riordan, b. c., flett, j. a., hunter, j. a., scarf, d., & conner, t. s. (2015). fear of missing out (fomo): the relationship between fomo, alcohol use, and alcohol-related consequences in college students. annals of neuroscience and psychology, 2(7), 1–7. https://doi.org/http://dx.doi.org/10.7243/20553447-2-9 rogers, e. m. (1995). diffusion of innovations (4th ed) [oclc: 700853045]. free press. rozgonjuk, d., sindermann, c., elhai, j. d., & montag, c. (2021). individual differences in fear of missing out (fomo): age, gender, and the big five personality trait domains, facets, and items. personality and individual differences, 171, 110546. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.paid.2020.110546 salem, p. j. (2016). human communication technology [oclc: 956331419]. sentia publishing. shalev, e., & morwitz, v. g. (2012). influence via comparison-driven self-evaluation and restoration: the case of the low-status influencer. journal of consumer research, 38(5), 964–980. https://doi.org/ 10.1086/661551 sirgy, m. j. (1982). self-concept in consumer behavior: a critical review. journal of consumer research, 9(3), 287. https://doi.org/10.1086/208924 smith,a. (2015).u.s.smartphoneusein2015.retrievedoctober28,2022,fromhttps://www.pewresearch. org/internet/2015/04/01/us-smartphone-use-in-2015/ statista. (2022). number of worldwide social network users from 2017 to 2027. https://www.statista.com/ statistics/278414/number-of-worldwide-social-network-users/ https://glocalities.com/reports/meet-gen-z https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2013.10.047 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2013.10.047 https://doi.org/10.1207/s15327663jcp0404_02 https://doi.org/10.1207/s15327663jcp0404_02 https://doi.org/10.1086/208701 https://abcnews.go.com/health/wellness/fear-missing-slave-fomo/story?id=16629972 https://abcnews.go.com/health/wellness/fear-missing-slave-fomo/story?id=16629972 https://doi.org/10.1080/13576500342000103 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2013.02.014 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2013.02.014 https://doi.org/10.5001/omj.2020.116 https://doi.org/10.1007/s11747-013-0326-9 https://doi.org/10.1002/mar.10011 https://doi.org/http://dx.doi.org/10.7243/2055-3447-2-9 https://doi.org/http://dx.doi.org/10.7243/2055-3447-2-9 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.paid.2020.110546 https://doi.org/10.1086/661551 https://doi.org/10.1086/661551 https://doi.org/10.1086/208924 https://www.pewresearch.org/internet/2015/04/01/us-smartphone-use-in-2015/ https://www.pewresearch.org/internet/2015/04/01/us-smartphone-use-in-2015/ https://www.statista.com/statistics/278414/number-of-worldwide-social-network-users/ https://www.statista.com/statistics/278414/number-of-worldwide-social-network-users/ reisenwitz & fowler/ journal of business strategies (2023) 40:21-36 36 stead, h., & bibby, p. a. (2017). personality, fear of missing out and problematic internet use and their relationship to subjective well-being. computers in human behavior, 76, 534–540. https://doi. org/10.1016/j.chb.2017.08.016 swar, b., & hameed, t. (2017). fear of missing out, social media engagement, smartphone addiction and distraction: moderating role of self-help mobile apps-based interventions in the youth: proceedings of the 10th international joint conference on biomedical engineering systems and technologies, 139–146. https://doi.org/10.5220/0006166501390146 thanasrivanitchai, j., moschis, g. p., & shannon, r. (2017). explaining older consumers’ low use of the internet. international journal of internet marketing and advertising, 11(4), 355. https://doi.org/ 10.1504/ijima.2017.087271 vandecasteele, b., & geuens, m. (2010). motivated consumer innovativeness: concept, measurement, and validation. international journal of research in marketing, 27(4), 308–318. https://doi.org/10. 1016/j.ijresmar.2010.08.004 wortham, j. (2011). feel like a wallflower? maybe it’s your facebook wall. the new york times. retrieved october 28, 2022, from https://www.nytimes.com/2011/04/10/business/10ping.html zhang, z., jiménez, f. r., & cicala, j. e. (2020). fear of missing out scale: a self-concept perspective. psychology & marketing, 37(11), 1619–1634. https://doi.org/10.1002/mar.21406 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2017.08.016 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.chb.2017.08.016 https://doi.org/10.5220/0006166501390146 https://doi.org/10.1504/ijima.2017.087271 https://doi.org/10.1504/ijima.2017.087271 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijresmar.2010.08.004 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijresmar.2010.08.004 https://www.nytimes.com/2011/04/10/business/10ping.html https://doi.org/10.1002/mar.21406 introduction literature review and theoretical framework of fomo social media usage self-concept social identity smartphone usage innovativeness gender method scales results discussion theoretical and practical implications limitations and directions for future research a review of interfirm networks: a deeper understanding of the relationships paradigm jie g. fowler valdosta state university • valdosta, georgia timothy h. reisenwitz valdosta state university • valdosta, georgia abstract interfirm relationships or networks take a variety of forms and can potentially provide significant synergy for the participants. yet, most of research studies, to date, have primarily analyzed interfirm networks based upon one paradigm/ perspective. this review aims to examine a complete theoretical basis of network research and looks for research gaps and practical implications for both researchers and practitioners. specifically, it summarizes six conceptual perspectives regarding interfirm networks: motivational, relational, structural, evolutionary, interactional, and governance, in order to address similarities and differences among different perspectives. with this purpose in mind, the relevant literature is reviewed and, at the conclusion of each conceptual perspective, areas of research that require more development and investigation are identified. finally, suggestions for managers contemplating or engaged in interfirm networks are presented. introduction the network paradigm originally built upon the notion that economic actions are embedded in a social network of relationships. in essence, organizations can be interconnected with other organizations through a wide array of social networks in order to improve effectiveness and efficiency. for instance, through examining a variety of forms of collaboration, ranging from consortia to joint venture, to franchising, to dealership, fabrizio (2011) found collaboration among firms of different sizes helps to overcome weaknesses without increasing transitional costs. other scholars found that firms organized in networks have higher survival chances and that prestigious partners help firms to go to ipo faster (gulati, dialdin & wang, 2002). in addition, networks may also enable firms to gain access to capital in order to sustain operations and investment, while lower the transitional costs (khanna & rivkin, 2001). for instance, research findings show that network members in china reported higher financial performance and productivity (keister, 1998). further, networks may reduce consumer uncertainty attitudes towards the brand. for instance, volume 30, number 1 53 ingram and baum’s (1997) study of chain affiliation of manhattan hotels suggests that a hotel that joins a high status hotel chain signals its high status. recent literature on networks attempted to examine the knowledge transfer among connected firms. for instance, the vertical networks between toyota and its suppliers and among suppliers themselves facilitate knowledge learning and provide members learning and productivity advantages over non-members (dyer & nobeoka, 2000). traditional economic literature identified that a firm has at least three alternatives in order to maintain its strategies, such as searching for suppliers and new markets (mariti & smiley, 1983): the firms have options to develop a cooperative agreement with other firms, firms may make resources available to individual market transactions, and firms may organize themselves internationally. the last two alternatives can illustrated by the technological approach based upon economies and diseconomies of scale and adam smith’s principle of division of labor---refined and elaborated by stigler (1951), coase (1937), and williamson (1975). however, recent empirical evidence shows that the maxim of “networks matter” may contradict the traditional economics of scope/scale and successful exploitation of personal or organizational relationships is essential for firms to gain and maintain competitive advantages (khoja, 2010). as such, practitioners should be vigilant to develop relationships in networks. by definition, a network describes a collection of actors (e.g., persons, divisions, firms, countries) and their connections (iacobucci, 1996; thorelli, 1986). brass, galaskeiwica, greve, and tsai (2004) define a network as “a set of nodes and the set of ties representing some relationships, or lack of relationships, between the nodes” (p. 481). the ties that connect actors take many different forms. they can be directed (i.e., potentially unidirectional as in giving advice to someone) or undirected (e.g., being physically proximate), and they can be dichotomous (e.g., present or absent) or valued (e.g., the strength of a friendship) (borgatti & foster, 2003). an organizational network is defined as a collection of more than two firms that pursue repeated exchange relationships with one another but lack a legitimate organizational authority to manage the exchange process (podolny & page, 1998). this definition encompasses a wide range of interfirm relations, including alliances, joint ventures, business groups, franchises, and research consortia, while excluding such market arrangements as short term contracts or spot-market transactions. sydow and windeler (1998) investigate the properties of interfirm networks, which they consider “as an institutional arrangement among distinct but related for-profit organizations which are characterized by a special kind of network relationship, a certain degree of flexibility, and a logic of exchange that operates differently from 54 journal of business strategies that of markets and hierarchies” (p. 266). in essence, interfirm networks differ from any interorganizational arrangement of firms at least with respect to the three properties above. traditionally, networks have been investigated in connection with other topics, such as sociology. for instance, various sociologists have investigated such topics as embeddedness (uzzi, 1997), social capital (portes, 1998), social exchange (cook, 1977), and structuration theory (giddens, 1984) in an organizational network context. increasingly, they have become interesting topics unto themselves in organizational research. organizational scholars found that economic actions are embedded in social relations and interfirm relations generate and are generated by embedded relations that differ from traditional arm’s-length market ties. in marketing and management, over the last three decades, this recognition is reflected in the increase in, and the character of, research on distribution channels, supply chain management, buyer-seller relationships, buying centers, diffusion of innovations, and new product alliances. as a result, recent expansion of research interest in management and marketing calls for a review and classification of work in interfirm networks. as such, the primary objective of this paper is to review, synthesize, and integrate empirical and conceptual articles on interfirm networks in management and marketing literature and to offer suggestions and direction for researchers and practitioners in this area. we examine the articles in six groupings, based upon what we interpret as one of six primary conceptual perspectives that they reflect: motivation, relational, structural, evolutionalist, interactionalist, and governance. the following discussion begins with examinations of interfirm network research that reflects each of the previously noted six conceptual perspectives. for each perspective, the literature is reviewed and the research gap in each perspective is identified at the end of each section.1 the motivation perspective and research gaps the motivation perspective is concerned with why firms behave in certain ways with respect to the networks. it focuses on two basic questions: why do firms enter into network entities such as alliances, joint ventures and other business groups such as buying groups and trade associations; and why do they make certain strategic choices about relations and interactions with other network members? in general, this body of work is based upon cost factors (transaction costs), internal factors (firm’s capabilities, resources-based view), and external influences (social volume 30, number 1 55 capital, institutional-based view) (e.g., eisenhardt & schoonhoven, 1996; williamson, 1985). traditionally, the approach that has been used to understand how strategic alliances form is transaction cost economics (williamson, 1985). transaction cost economics emphasizes transaction cost efficiency as a motivation for the corporation to enter into a network (eisenhardt & schoonhoven, 1996). it has been effective in predicting vertical integration among suppliers and buyers in mature industries, such as automobile manufacturing (e.g., osborn & baughn, 1990). however, the logic of transaction costs does not capture many strategic aspects of networks, such as learning, creation of legitimacy, and fast market entry (eisenhardt & schoonhoven, 1996). in order to address the firm’s capabilities in forming strategic alliances, eisenhardt and schoonhoven began to examine strategic needs as motivation for firms forming alliances and positioning themselves in a network. such work begins to move beyond transaction costs and looks at logical resource needs and social resource opportunities. in comparison, the resource-based view of motivation in interfirm networks emphasizes strategic factors and characteristics of the firm rather than transaction costs. furthermore, this view focuses on the logic of needs rather than efficiency. many studies on firms’ motivations for entering into alliances take a resource-based view. das and teng (2000) attempt to relate different resource characteristics (i.e., property-based and knowledge-based resources) to alliance formation and structure. lee, lee, and pennings (2001) further examine the influence of internal capabilities and external networks. lavie (2006) borrows the notion of network resources (gulati, 1999) to extend the resource-based view by incorporating network resources of interconnected firms. lavie (2006) proposes a model that distinguishes shared resources from non-shared resources and reveals how interconnected firms can extract value from resources that are not fully-owned or controlled by the organization. another stream of research on firms’ motivations employs social capital theory. scholars who have contributed to social capital theory include bourdieu (1983, 1986), burt (1997), coleman (1988), lin (1999), portes (1998), and putnam (2000). specifically, social capital theory explains how organizations access and use resources embedded in a social network to gain returns (e.g., seeking economic help). based upon this theory, organizations are motivated to engage in interaction and networking in order to enhance outcomes (lin, 1999). organizational scholars have utilized social capital theory for decades. for instance, koka and prescott (2002) suggest that social capital could yield informational benefits for the firm. lee et al. (2001) argue that the firms’ capabilities and social capital interactively influ56 journal of business strategies ence start-up firms’ performance in terms of sales growth but that social capital alone has weak main effects on firm performance. in recent years, due to the rising global marketplace, scholars have begun to apply social capital theory to cross-cultural research. for instance, gu, huang, and tse (2008) draw upon social capital theory to examine how firms make strategic choices through guanxi networks in china. additionally, a series of studies grounded in the institutional-based view can be used to explain the firm’s motivation to make strategic choices as well. institutional theories (dimaggio & powell, 1983; scott, 1987) believe that organizational actions are driven by social justification. from this perspective, strategic decisions are social and normatively defined because their motives derive from an actor’s propensity to legitimate cooperating activities. participants in the network believe that their effectiveness is judged by other constituents (e.g., shareholders, customers, suppliers). according to the theory, organizations are motivated to seek legitimacy or approval from those potential constituents. so far, there are only a few scholars who have applied this theory in network research. for instance, dacin, oliver, and roy (2007) examine the legitimating aspect of strategic alliances. drawing upon an institutional-based view, they argue that the social symbolic and signaling characteristics of alliances serve as a source of legitimacy for partnering, and legitimacy serves as a means to achieve competitive advantage. as previously mentioned, motivational studies in network research tend to explain why firms enter into networks and why they make certain strategic choices within those networks. the research reviewed thus far highlights many of the theories (transaction cost economics, resource-based view, social capital theory, and the institutional-based view), and each of them emphasizes different aspects of what motivates firms to enter into networks. however, each also tends to ignore or tradeoff other important factors that may lead firms to enter into networks. for instance, transaction cost economics theorists highlight the cost and efficiency but lack explanations of social legitimacy. the resource-based view theorists focus upon firms’ capabilities but ignore the cost factor. additionally, social capital theorists concentrate on social gain and membership but lose sight of stakeholders’ capabilities. furthermore, while researchers have shown that different theories can explain different kinds of motives, there are no clear boundaries among these theories. for instance, the institutional-based view, which concerns social norms, may potentially overlap with social capital theory in terms of social sanctions and expected reciprocity. the resource-based view may overlap with social capital theory in terms of instrumental return. in general, while a few scholars (e.g., lee et al., 2001) often acknowledge that there is a need for combining theories when conducting research, volume 30, number 1 57 we believe that examining the commonality and difference between theories can create an outlet for future research. finally, though much research has been done in terms of organizational motives to enter into a network, there is a lack of research concerning the retreat or exit from a network. there is a need to investigate the causes/motivations for exiting a strategic network. factors such as relational conflicts, asymmetric exchange, new partnership formation, relationship maintenance costs, industrial environmental change, and network structure transition need to be examined as well. such studies will not only inform us as to what motivates firms to exit networks but potentially what motivates firms to enter them. the relational perspective and research gaps relational studies represent one of the earliest streams of research related to networks and continue to be of interest to network researchers. in general, the relational perspective is concerned with how aspects of the relationships among networks members—including strength, distance, and other qualities of ties—affect and are affected by other factors, such as member firms’ strategic choices, performance, and knowledge creation. specifically, relational network studies are based upon the relational tie literature, which is primarily concerned with the nature of the relational bond between two or more actors. scholars in this domain typically classify the relationship between social actors as being linked by weak or strong, instrumental or expressive, and direct or indirect ties. for instance, larson (1992) shows that strong ties promote or enhance trust, mutual gain, and reciprocity among firms from a long-term perspective. consequently, partners are likely to form joint problem solving arrangements as well (powell, 1990; uzzi, 1996). several important studies have clarified, and in some cases modified, the theory of relational ties by extending the research in new directions. gulati and westpal (1999) examine how interlocking ties have different effects on the formation of joint ventures between firms. based upon this finding, the content of ties (direct vs. indirect) can have a strong influence over corporate strategy decisions; some ties may promote the creation of a new alliance, while others could actually reduce the likelihood. in addition, gulati, nohria, and zaheer (2000) argue that network ties are important sources of referrals that enable prospective partners to identify and learn about each other’s capabilities and reduce the informational asymmetries that increase contracting costs. in order to test the hypothesis, the authors define tie strength by the frequency of interaction between partners and their level of resource 58 journal of business strategies commitment to the relationship. further, rowley, behrens, and krackhardt (2000) explore the conditions under which strong and weak ties are positively related to firm performance. specifically, the authors argue that whether or not firms form their strategic alliances through strong or weak ties depends on how it is structurally embedded in the network. in essence, ties can act as a social control agent in terms of governing how alliance partners behave or cooperate in the marketplace. a few recent studies provide useful challenges and an extension to the traditional relational-based view of interfirm networks. rindfleisch and moorman (2001) examine the acquisition and utilization of information in new product alliances from a strength-of-ties perspective. drawing upon network theory (granovetter, 1973, 1983), the authors suggest that horizontal alliances have a lower level of relational embeddedness and a higher level of knowledge redundancy than do vertical alliances. the results also question the key underlying assumptions of the strength-of-ties literature. for instance, strong ties are typically assumed to share both high levels of embeddedness and high levels of redundancy; however, the findings of rindfleisch and moorman (2001) indicate that this assumption does not hold for organizational contexts. in an organizational context, strong ties are more likely to act as “bridges” than weak ties. additionally, khanna and rivkin (2006) extend interfirm ties beyond the strength-of-ties literature and define ties by their content. based upon a survey in chile, the findings suggest that the content of ties (e.g., family connections, common owners) play a role in determining the boundary of a business group. mariotti (2011) investigated how firms gather and combine knowledge through strengthened bridging ties and high quality relationships. most recently, lee, kroll and walters (2011) developed a model of corporate governance stages and suggested that, in transitional economics, corporate governance is likely to shift from a bureaucratic control-based structure to a more relational governance structure. although few studies have provided challenges and extensions to the relational-based view, a large amount of research is grounded in network theory (granovetter, 1973, 1983). however, we should also realize that network theory originally examined individuals within those networks and not organizations. we should further investigate the theoretical boundaries of organizational network research. in other words, we are not clear as to whether or not individual ties can be fully applied to organizational research. additionally, we have to acknowledge that organizations do not build ties, people build ties. if this is true, how managers transfer their personal ties to the organization becomes an interesting research question which has yet to be studied in detail. lastly, there is no clear definition of the qualities of interorganizational ties, and other qualities of ties besides tie strength (i.e., volume 30, number 1 59 distance, symmetry, etc.) have not been fully examined as well. the structural perspective and research gaps despite the value and quality of work conducted under the relational perspective, many recent studies have moved from the relational perspective to a network structure perspective. for instance, liao (2010) studies the firm’s ability to process and create knowledge in interfirm networks from a structural perspective. westbrock (2010) found that an efficient network typically has a dominant group in the structure of oligopolistic markets. the structural perspective is concerned with how the overall structure of networks and structural factors within networks affect and are affected by other factors such as member firms’ strategic choices, performance, knowledge creation, and knowledge transfer. overall, the structure of networks refers to vertical networks (e.g., vertical alliances or marketing channel networks that typically include suppliers, manufacturers, distributors, and/or retailers), horizontal networks (e.g., horizontal alliances and buying groups that are typically composed of competitors in the same industry and that share the same market), mixed networks that include both horizontal and vertical networks (e.g., multichannel networks), and intermarket or concentric networks (e.g., japanese keiretsu). structural factors within networks refer to factors such as size, density, actors’ positions (centrality), network composition, interlocking board memberships, and structural holes (e.g., achrol & kotler, 1999; fombrun, 1982; gulati, nohria, & zaheer, 2000; provan & kenis, 2007; sydow & windeler, 1998). early research in the structural perspective has attempted to understand and define interorganizational relations within marketing channels (reve & stern, 1979), leaving little question as to why marketing has a long tradition of examining vertical relationships between firms. in the past, many authors conceive of networks in this sense (snow et al., 1992). by definition, the vertical network is the organizational set of firms comprising vertical exchange relations (achrol, 1997). scholars have brought together a variety of research arenas relating to vertical networks such as interdependency, contracting, and relational behavior in marketing channels (e.g., kumar, heide, & wathne, 2011; lusch & brown, 1996) and power (walker, 1972). achrol and kotler (1999) argue that marketing can be a network integrator in vertical channels because the network members are highly specialized and the burden rests on marketing managers to organize information and resource flow. in marketing, ganesan et al. (2009) further brought vertical network research into a retailing context, finding that retailers are looking beyond their or60 journal of business strategies ganizational boundaries to develop and leverage the resources and capabilities of their supply chain partners to create superior value and competitive advantage in the marketplace. the authors also discuss how global sourcing, multichannel routes, and relationship-based innovation lead to performance improvements with regard to brand image, reputation, sales, profits, innovation, and relationships. additionally, a recent study conducted by zaheer and bell (2005) concludes that firms with superior network structure may be better able to exploit their internal capabilities and thus enhance performance. horizontal networks have also been examined in recent literature (e.g., frels, shervani, & sriastava, 2003; provan & sebastian, 1998; rindfleisch & moorman, 2009; rowley, behrens, & krackhardt, 2000; swaminathan & moorman, 2009; zaheer & bell, 2005). for instance, nygaard and dahlstrom (2002) state that horizontal arrangements are increasingly deployed in organizational networks. in order to address the lack of horizontal alliances in the marketing literature, the authors examine the distribution system of two oil companies that operate through a horizontal alliance at the retail level in order to address the role of stress in horizontal alliances, the influence of role stress on organizational outcomes, and the organizational and communicative processes that influence the level of stress in alliances. additionally, rindfliesch and moorman (2001) suggest that horizontal alliances have lower levels of relational embeddedness and higher levels of knowledge redundancy than vertical alliances. aside from vertical and horizontal networks, the concentric network is also a network form that marketers are becoming more and more aware of. the concentric network, also known as an intermarket network, is defined as an enterprise group consisting of affiliations that operate in several related and unrelated industries and center around a major corporation (achrol & kotler, 1999) the concentric network, at this point, is largely a phenomenon of the japanese and korean business environment (achrol, 1997). normally, the enterprise group is organized around one or more major financial institutions in the financial market. however, we believe that concentric networks not only exist in the japanese and korean environments but also in the western marketplace. a possible example is in uzzi’s (1997) study of structural embeddedness. uzzi did not identify his research context as a concentric network. however, his study involves a major manufacturer surrounded by an interfirm network (e.g., design studio, warehouse, showroom, and retailer), which can be considered a concentric network. mixed networks, a fourth network structure, have rarely been examined, much less defined, in past literature. mcguire and dow (2009) reviewed the major volume 30, number 1 61 theoretical and empirical work of japanese keiretsu, dividing the keiretsu structure into vertical and horizontal networks and claiming that the distinction between the two is often blurred. often, there is an overlap between the two. for instance, the overlap between the mitsubishi horizontal and production centered grouping and the overlap between toyota (vertical) and mitsui (horizontal) groups are classic examples. it seems that researchers have made considerable efforts to study vertical or horizontal networks. however, we take note that any discussion of vertical or horizontal network structures is likely to be oversimplified. networks are characterized by permeable and evolving ties. for instance, each of the ties could move from horizontal to vertical structures and vice versa. practically, simply examining horizontal networks may neglect the other vertical relationships the firms may have established that have an impact on the horizontal networks at play. possibly, the combination of ties leads to superior performance instead of any one single vertical or horizontal tie. in other words, simply looking at vertical or horizontal networks separately may lead to inaccurate research results. as such, we believe that investigating the mixed network could possibly provide a new research arena. the evolutionary perspective and research gaps an already large and still growing body of literature concerning organizational networks draws attention to the importance of network evolution. the evolutionist perspective focuses on how and why changes in networks affect and/or are affected by firms’ strategic choices, industry events, and institutional factors (i.e., changing social norms, laws, or regulations) within a network. for example, how do the changing size, density, and positions of new or existing firms in a network, joint venture, and alliance formation impact the relationships within those networks? additionally, research has focused on the stages of relationship development among existing and potential network members. specifically, the majority of the body of work concerning the evolutionist perspective focuses on network formation and network dissolution. in the view of network formation, organizations build ties based upon theories of social and socioeconomic exchange (larson & starr, 1993), social capital (walker, kogut, & shan, 1997), and structure roles. for instance, larson and starr (1993) detail the three stages of network building, focusing on dyads and converting dyadic ties to socioeconomic exchanges while layering the exchanges with multiple exchange processes. during the three stages, organizations selectively use the network dyads 62 journal of business strategies to match their business decision making. further, gulati (1993) investigates how social structure affects interfirm alliance formation patterns through a longitudinal study in which he proposes that the social context emerging from prior alliances and consideration of strategic interdependence influences partnership decisions between firms. the social network then facilitates new alliances by providing information to firms about the capabilities and reliability of the potential partners. as such, organizations create ties to manage uncertain environments and to satisfy their resource needs (gulati & gargiulo, 1999). in addition, organizational scholars investigate network evolution from other social theories other than social exchange which, to some extent, overlap with the motivational perspective. however, evolutionists focus upon the stage and process of building networks. for instance, changes in political and economic power can affect channel structure and firms’ decisions in terms of social network formation (dahab, gentry, & sohi, 1996). resource dependence theorists have argued that the formation of interorganizational ties, such as strategic alliances, is a result of underlying resource dependence (pfeffer & nowak, 1976). in addition, madhavan, koka, and prescott (1998) draw upon the structural perspective to theorize about how and why interfirm networks change over time. they argue that interfirm networks evolve in response to key industry events. scholars of corporate strategy have suggested that firms form or change alliances to improve their strategic position in the network and in the marketplace (contractor & lorange, 1988; kogut, 1988; porter & fuller, 1986). interestingly, gulati and garguilo (1999) argue that the new alliance modifies the existing network, prompting a dynamic between organizational action and network structure. through testing the ideas over a nine-year period, the study shows a new alliance may increase with their interdependence and also with their prior mutual alliances, common third parties, and joint centrality in the alliance networks. in recent years, scholars have begun to investigate network dissolution. due to the complexity of collecting data, the research is mostly theoretical. baker, faulkner, and fisher (1998) analyzed the dissolution of interorganizational ties between advertising agencies and their clients as a function of competition, power, and institutional forces. specifically, they find that most exchange relationships between advertising agencies and their clients are exclusive, and most last for several years; but competition, power, and institutional forces support or undermine these relationships. powerful advertising agencies use resources to increase stability, but their clients mobilize resources to increase or decrease stability. competition has an effect on tie dissolution, and institutional forces, such as changing norms, destabilize volume 30, number 1 63 relationships. although researchers have made significant strides in understanding how networks evolve through joining new networks, modifying existing networks, and natural evolution within current networks, they have left a few questions relatively unexplored. some scholars, for example, assume that exchange relationships between two firms exist as a given and seek to explain how those relations are formalized (c.f. pisano, 1989). this assumption that exchange relations may guide tie formation between firms may actually lead to false conclusions. some scholars, despite an understanding that other reasons may guide tie formation, may not account for network formation and change. for instance, little research has been conducted that explains if marketing capabilities are a resource that firms do not rely upon when entering a new network. interestingly enough, though resource factors have been specified in the past, the question remains whether or not these resources are tangible (e.g., financial or human resources) or intangible (e.g., accessibility to other networks, capabilities in managing partnerships). further, a large body of studies in this domain focuses upon the formation of alliances instead of the formation and change of networks. although the formation of alliances can provide insights into network formation, it is hard to know how other business networks (e.g., buying groups or business associations) form through this conceptual perspective. as such, research on informal business groups could be a possible future research arena. lastly, arguably, institutional forces, such as cultural norms, play an important role in network formation. although a few scholars (c.f. peng, 2003; peng & zhou, 2005) investigate how firms use network-centered strategies and how networks evolve in a transitional economy, little work has been done to compare network evolution in different cultures or to analyze network evolution that involves firms from more than one culture. the interactionist perspective and research gaps much network research draws attention to the importance of interaction among firms (e.g., belle, katsikeas, & robson, 2010). the interactionist perspective focuses on the types, conditions, and consequences of interaction among firms in networks. as such, informational exchange, knowledge transfer, organizational learning, contractual and informal exchange, and reciprocity are important transactions that concern the interactionists. this perspective can be traced back to the 1970s. in general, early research simply focused on exchange interactions between entities in a network, and scholars agreed that conditions such as power, exchange 64 journal of business strategies behavior, and environmental forces served as important factors influencing and facilitating interactions among firms. for instance, bensen (1975) proposes that resource concentration, power network dependence, resource abundance, and environmental control mechanisms are dimensions for firms to build networks and make interactive strategic decisions. cook (1977) borrowed an exchange model for analysis of interorganizational relations and defines interorganizational linkages as networks of exchange interaction. organizational activities are viewed as networks of exchange network relations. in order to develop his exchange model, cook proposes that building interorganizational relationships such as alliance formation are correlated with power and position in the network. in addition to these early conceptual articles, larson (1992) further conducted a field study through a sample of dyadic relationships established by high growth entrepreneurial firms and finds that a process model of network formation, which emphasizes reciprocity and mutual interdependence. jones, hesterly, and borgatti (1997) further combine network theory and transaction cost economics to assert that the interaction among firms are based upon asset specificity, demand uncertainty, task complexity, and frequency. these conditions drive firms to use their social mechanisms for exchange interaction. although early research focuses on the exchange interaction aspect of networks, little has been done to investigate alliance constellations in recent years. das and teng (2002) were the first scholars to propose that social interaction should be applied to alliance constellations. alliance constellations are strategic alliances formed by multiple partner firms. popular constellation types include r&d consortia, joint bidding, and code-sharing among airlines and other industries. in the process of exchange among firms, reciprocity plays an important function for subsequent transactions. while the early work with an interactional perspective is dominated by exchange theorists, researchers have focused on learning aspects of interaction in the past two decades. scholars generally agree that economic exchanges among firms may involve both more obvious and less obvious tangible and intangible resources (such as market information). for instance, uzzi (1997) finds that information exchange is very proprietary in arm’s length ties and that learning synergies can arise from sharing insights within a network (morgan, 2004). in addition, bell and zaheer (2007) examine the geographic impact on knowledge flow among networked firms. they acknowledge that knowledge—which is closely linked to a firm’s innovativeness—is accessed across interorganizational boundaries and geographic space via networks. using a combination of primary and secondary data on mutual fund firms, volume 30, number 1 65 they find that institutional level ties (ties formed by the industry trade association structure arising incidentally to the firms involved rather than purposefully by the firms or their executives) are valuable in knowledge transmission only when such ties are geographically proximate. organizational ties fail to act as transmitters of knowledge transference regardless of the location while, on the other hand, individual ties are superior for knowledge flow. in general, past research has focused on common themes, such as exchange behavior among firms and organizational learning. however, there is much left to be done in terms of the interactivity among firms. peters, gassenheimer, and johnston (2009) call for a more explicit connection to the interactivity and network literature. the nature of interactions, as a dynamic phenomenon, has presented researchers with challenges that are both conceptual and empirical. for instance, although scholars focus upon interfirm interaction, we still lack an understanding of how individual ties serve as transmitters of knowledge flow among or within firms. we do not yet know much about how specific knowledge links to a specific tie or resource. we also do not know how different ties influence the levels or amount of knowledge or information flow. in addition, we may need to seek a better understanding of how the types of interaction (e.g., frequency, the length of the relationship, etc.) impact organizational learning. the governance perspective and research gaps in recent years, scholars have recognized that the forms of governance may serve as key factors affecting research results. the governance perspective focuses on the locus of control within networks. major examples of governance include network administrative organizations (nao) networks that govern by an overarching entity that is separate from the firms within the network (i.e., a trade association), lead organizational governed networks (log) that are governed by a lead or dominant organization within the network, and participant governed networks (pgn) that are jointly governed by the many firms in the network. provan and kenis (2007) propose that the simplest and most common form of network governance is the pgn, which is governed by the network members themselves with no separation of the governance entity. in health and human services, shared governance networks are common, in part because networks are often considered to be an important way of building community (chaskin et al., 2001). in such a context, network members will only be likely to be committed to the goals of the network if they all participate on an equal basis. in business, shared governance 66 journal of business strategies may be used in small, multi-firm strategic alliances and partnerships to develop new products or attract new businesses, which could not be easily done through the independent efforts of network members (venkatraman & lee, 2004). shared governance may also be used in multilateral relations among banking firms to assemble financial investment (eccles & crane, 1988). at another extreme, log governance can occur in horizontal networks, most often when one organization has sufficient resources to play a lead role (provan & kenis, 2007). it can also occur in vertical, buyer-supplier relationships, especially when there is a single, powerful buyer/supplier/funder and several weak and small suppliers or buyers. the most classic example can be found in the japanese keiretsu model (gerlach, 1992) and other similar models of cooperative buyer-supplier models in the u.s. (uzzi, 1999) and europe (inzerilli, 1990; lazerson, 1995). additionally, lead organizations play important roles across different industries. for instance, in the entertainment industry, the log may be a major firm’s studio (jones & defillippi, 1996). the log can also occur in health and human services; in community health, it may be a hospital or health clinic (weiner & alexander, 1998). teisman and klijn (2002) also argue that a government agency can act as a lead organization in networks. graddy and chen (2006) focus on the role of the lead organization in governing child welfare in los angeles. a third form of network governance is the nao in which the basic governance model is a separate administrative entity set up to govern the network. although the network members still interact with one another, the nao model is highly centralized (provan & kennis, 2007). for example, human and provan (2000) describe two networks in the wood processing industry that are both guided by an nao. all the firms were for-profit, but the naos were non-profit. however, the nao can be for a for-profit organization as in the case of nexial international, the global accounting network discussed by koza and lewin (1999). other scholars (e.g., mcevily & zaheer, 2004; provan, isett, & milward, 2004) argue that the nao can also be used as a mechanism to enhance network legitimacy, to deal with unique and complex network level problems and issues, and to reduce the complexity of shared governance. in recent years, scholars (e.g., provan et al., 2004) find that a more formalized nao typically have board structures that include all or a subset of network members. the board addresses strategic concerns, leaving operational decisions to the nao. organizations join or form networks for a variety of reasons, including the need to gain legitimacy, serve clients efficiently, gain resources, and solve operational problems; and due to the different needs of the network, governance may vary. volume 30, number 1 67 in the past, although marketing scholars have made significant efforts to address the impact of networks, few of them clearly distinguish the type of network governance examined. of the existing literature, only that within the health and human service sector has even attempted to distinguish the type of governance examined. even so, a clear identification of governance within those studies in health and human services was far from universal. most articles lack a specific explanation of the governance structure. as such, there is also a need to classify the network governance structure and discuss the basic characteristics of each form of governance. in marketing, we suspect that each form of governance may have a different impact on marketing variables (e.g., new product development, increasing market share). on the other hand, positive marketing outcomes may require different forms of network governance. last, firms may interact or be embedded within several different types of network governance. from a micro-level, how firms manage their position in a specific or multiple network governance is unknown, providing fuel for additional research in the area. discussion research scholars have conducted interfirm network research for a few decades. however, much research was built upon one paradigm/perspective and lacked a complete theoretical view. for instance, research built upon the relational perspective was only concerned about the strength or quality of ties and ignored the potential network effects of network structure or network density. research on network governance, however, put little emphasis on personal relationships. in other words, there is a need to combine different perspectives in order to have a complete understanding of how networks play roles in terms of gaining and maintaining competitive advantages in different areas such as, facilitating knowledge transfer and innovation, seeking financial support, and reducing consumer uncertainty towards a brand. in addition, research on each of the paradigms was incomplete and may need to be developed further. for instance, the network evolutionists may conduct more longitudinal studies to examine the change of the relationships over time. relational researchers may investigate the quality or characteristics of personal relationships besides the tie strength. for instance, the ties may be built upon reciprocity, and others may be built upon shared objectives. relational ties may also involve emotions. according to past research, emotions play important roles in strategic decision making (flint & fleet, 2011; holmes et al., 2011). as such, studying the emotion elements in tie building can be meaningful. 68 journal of business strategies further, this review provides researchers opportunities to engage in empirical network research. as khoka (2010) suggested, for example, many antecedents have been left out of network research. for instance, resource and financial requirements and organizational structure should be studied as antecedents for organizational network research. in addition, a more balanced view of network performance and network costs needs to be researched. also, a study of comparing formal and informal networks can be valuable. for instance, chinese guanxi, which is considered as an informal relationship, can be a valuable resource to form formal relationships, perhaps because in high context cultures like china, networks are essential in business strategies (liu, atinc, & kroll, 2011). much network research has been done on a theoretical level, which perhaps is due to the difficulties of data collection. though network structuralists, for example, may believe it is feasible to design simulations to calculate network intensity/density or distance between the nodes, it can be out of reach for managers to envision the structure of the network they embedded within. that is to say, there is a deep gap between theoretical network research and its practical value. this may explain why conceptual work tends to focus upon the network level of analysis, but empirical research on networks tends to examine alliances at the firm or relational level (see table 1 and table 2). the conceptual perspectives have implications for managers representing organizations that are contemplating interfirm relationships, managing interfirm relationships, and/or considering expanding or exiting interfirm relationships. thus, for managers, it is also important to understand different network perspectives, such as relational and structure perspectives. this is because network structure/density and other network characteristics in which the relationship is embedded may have effects on the quality of personal ties and such an impact may, as a result, influence the outcome of the relationships, such as sharing information or knowledge. firms also need to evaluate and balance resources, e.g, financial costs, knowledge, social capital/social ties before entering into a network. additionally, the capability of managing interpersonal ties may determine the firm’s potential capability of entering and maintaining its interfirm networks. managers should also give attention to the structure of the network that the firm adopts because the structure may have potential impact on the amount of benefit the firm may obtain from its networks. moreover, as networks change, the benefits that the firm may gain from such a network may decline/increase. as other firms enter or withdraw from the network, managers need to design flexible strategies to react such a change. as a volume 30, number 1 69 result, managers should be aware of both positive (e.g., share resources) and negative consequences (e.g., being dominated by another organization) of a network. last, managers may need to be aware that network structure is culturally-based. for instance, the participant governed networks (png) may not apply to cultures which are rather hierarchical, e.g., india. thus, managers can be cognizant that there are multiple motivations for engaging in interfirm networks and be informed about the possible relational and structural composition of networks. furthermore, there are consequences of the interactions between and/or among network firms and that there will be effects of network change over time (evolutionary). finally, managers can note that there are several ways in which networks are controlled or governed. this paper reviewed the research regarding interfirm networks, and as such, the purpose of this paper has been to provide an overview of the existing research into the phenomenon as well as directions for future research. as with any such review, there are limitations due to the conceptual nature of the paper. unlike a metaanalysis, this paper does not provide a systematic statistical analysis of the interfirm network research findings. also, we approached this review from a managerial marketing perspective as opposed to an economic perspective. in this review, we have outlined the conceptual perspectives and methodological foundations of organizational networks. organizations engaged in and/or considering developing an organizational network need to be aware of the various conceptual perspectives of interfirm networks so that the relationship potential is maximized. a better understanding of organizational network perspectives may not only potentially enhance existing relationships, paving the way for their further development and expansion, but also foster new relationships. in today’s increasingly complex marketplace, successful organizations may no longer be huge, vertically-integrated firms. in many cases, they may be lean, specialized organizations that are part of a network of firms. arguably, these developments signal the need for added and conceptually richer investigations of interfirm networks. intuitively, there are varying levels of synergy as a result of interfirm collaboration. a clear understanding of the way in which these relationships are facilitated may maximize this synergy. note 1 the research gap for each perspective is identified at the end of each section. the overall discussion of research gaps is summarized in the end of the paper. 70 journal of business strategies a ut ho r( s) / y ea r l ar so n (1 99 2) g ul at i ( 19 95 ) e is en ha rd t & sc ho on ho ve n (1 99 6) w al ke r, k og ut & s ha n (1 99 7) c on ce pt ua l pe rs pe ct iv e e vo lu tio na l m ot iv at io na l e vo lu tio na l m ot iv at io na l e vo lu tio na l m ot iv at io na l e vo lu tio na l m ot iv at io na l t he or y ba se (s ) so ci al c on tr ol so ci al e xc ha ng e so ci al n et w or k r b v st ru ct ur at io n (i m pl ic it) r b v so ci al c ap ita l so ci al n et w or k ty pe s of ne tw or ks a lli an ce pg n a lli an ce pg n a lli an ce pg n u nc le ar l ev el o f an al ys is r el at io na l r el at io na l r el at io na l n et w or k k ey fi nd in gs / t he or et ic al c on tr ib ut io ns t hr ee p ha se s of e nt re pr en eu ri al d ya d fo rm at io n (p re co nd iti on s, c on di tio ns to b ui ld e xc ha ng e st ru ct ur e, a nd in te gr at io n an d co nt ro l) ; fi rm s ar e go ve rn ed b y so ci al n or m s of tr us t a nd re ci pr oc ity . in si gh ts o n: p ro ce ss es a nd s tr uc tu re o f s us ta in ed d ya di c in te rfi rm ex ch an ge , n et w or k as a lte rn at iv e to v er tic al in te gr at io n fo r e nt re pr en eu ri al fir m s, a nd n et w or ks a s ba se s fo r fi rm g ro w th . c on si st en t w ith s tr at eg ic in te rd ep en de nc e an d so ci al s tr uc tu ra l t he or ie s, so ci al n et w or k af fe ct s ne w a lli an ce s by g iv in g in fo rm at io n to fi rm s on ca pa bi lit ie s an d re lia bi lit y of p ot en tia l p ar tn er s. sh ow s im po rt an ce o f s oc ia l n et w or k in a lli an ce fo rm at io n, w hi ch p ro vi de s br id ge b et w ee n ne tw or k an d re so ur ce in te rd ep en de nc e th eo ri es . d if fic ul t m ar ke t c on di tio ns a nd ri sk y fir m s tr at eg ie s in cr ea se ra te o f al lia nc e fo rm at io n. t op m an ag em en t’s c ha ra ct er is tic s af fe ct a lli an ce fo rm at io n. e xt en ds re so ur ce -b as ed v ie w to is su e of a lli an ce fo rm at io n. n et w or k fo rm at io n an d in du st ry g ro w th a re im pa ct ed b y de ve lo pm en t a nd nu rt ur -i ng s oc ia l c ap ita l. c on tr ib ut es to c om pa ri so n of s oc ia l c ap ita l a nd s oc ia l n et w or k th eo ri es in e xp la in -i ng n et w or k fo rm at io n. s tr uc tu re h ol es s ho ul d be g iv en m or e at te nt io n in m ar ke t t ra ns ac tio ns ra th er th an fi rm s’ c oo pe ra tiv e re la tio ns hi ps . a ls o in di ca te s in te rfi rm c ol la bo ra tio n re qu ir es a na ly si s of ne tw or k as a w ho le . ta bl e 1: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e m pi ri ca l i nt er fir m n et w or k st ud ie s volume 30, number 1 71 a ut ho r( s) / y ea r u zz i ( 19 97 ) m ad ha va n, k ok a, & pr es co tt (1 99 8) pr ov an & se ba st ia n (1 99 8) w al ke r, k og ut & s ha n (1 99 7) c on ce pt ua l pe rs pe ct iv e st ru ct ur al e vo lu tio na l st ru ct ur al e vo lu tio na l m ot iv at io na l t he or y ba se (s ) e m be dd ed ne ss u nc le ar n et w or k so ci al c ap ita l so ci al n et w or k ty pe s of ne tw or ks l o g a lli an ce pg n pg n (i m pl ic it) h or iz on ta l u nc le ar l ev el o f an al ys is n et w or k r el at io na l n et w or k n et w or k k ey fi nd in gs / t he or et ic al c on tr ib ut io ns e m be dd ed ne ss is lo gi c of e xc ha ng e th at a id s ec on om ie s of ti m e, in te gr at iv e ag re em en t, pa re to im pr ov em en t i n al lo ca tiv e ef fic ie nc y, a nd co m pl ex a da pt at io n, b ut a ls o ha s ne ga tiv e ef fe ct s. o ff er s ex pl an at io n of li nk s be tw ee n so ci al s tr uc tu re , d ec is io n m ak in g, a nd ec on om ic o ut co m es in a o rg an iz at io na l n et w or k. p ro po se s fr am ew or k to ex pl ai n ho w p ro pe rt ie s of e m be dd ed ne ss v ar y w ith q ua lit y of s oc ia l t ie s, st ru ct ur e of o rg an iz at io na l n et w or k, a nd fi rm ’s p os iti on in n et w or k. sh ow s in du st ry e ve nt s m ay b e cl as si fie d as re in fo rc in g or lo os en in g th e st ru ct ur e of th e ne tw or k. d ev el op s a m od el to e xp la in h ow in du st ry n et w or ks e vo lv e ov er ti m e in re sp on se to s pe ci fic e ve nt s. n et w or k ef fe ct iv en es s is n eg at iv el y re la te d to in te gr at io n of fu ll ne tw or ks . it is p os iti ve ly re la te d to in te gr at io n am on g sm al l c liq ue s of a ge nc ie s w he n cl iq ue s ha d ov er la pp in g lin ks th ro ug h re ci pr oc at ed re fe rr al s an d ca se co or di na tio n. sh ow s va lu e of s tu dy in g ne tw or k cl iq ue s tr uc tu re , e xp la in s ou tc om es (s uc h as n et w or k ef fe ct iv en es s) , a nd p oi nt s to n ee d to c on si de r n et w or ks an d ne tw or k st ru ct ur e in m ic ro an al yt ic w ay . n et w or k fo rm at io n an d in du st ry g ro w th a re im pa ct ed b y de ve lo pm en t a nd nu rt ur -i ng s oc ia l c ap ita l. c on tr ib ut es to c om pa ri so n of s oc ia l c ap ita l a nd s oc ia l n et w or k th eo ri es in e xp la in in g ne tw or k fo rm at io n. s tr uc tu re h ol es s ho ul d be g iv en m or e at te nt io n in m ar ke t t ra ns ac tio ns ra th er th an fi rm s’ c oo pe ra tiv e re la tio ns hi ps . a ls o in di ca te s in te rfi rm c ol la bo ra tio n re qu ir es a na ly si s of ne tw or k as a w ho le . ta bl e 1: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e m pi ri ca l i nt er fir m n et w or k st ud ie s 72 journal of business strategies a ut ho r( s) / y ea r g ul at i & w es tp ha l (1 99 9) g ul at i & g ar gi ul o (1 99 9) b au m , c al ab re se , & s ilv er m an (2 00 0) r ow le y, b eh re ns , & k ra ck ha rd t (2 00 0) c on ce pt ua l pe rs pe ct iv e e vo lu tio na l st ru ct ru al e vo lu tio na l r el at io na l st ru ct ur al r el at io na l t he or y ba se (s ) u nc le ar e m be dd ed ne ss st ru ct ur at io n (i m pl ic it) u nc le ar e m be dd ed ne ss so ci al c ap ita l ty pe s of ne tw or ks b oa rd in te rl oc k jo in t ve nt ur es a lli an ce s pg n s a lli an ce a lli an ce h or iz on ta l v er tic al a lli an ce l ev el o f an al ys is r el at io na l r el at io na l n et w or k n et w or k r el at io na l k ey fi nd in gs / t he or et ic al c on tr ib ut io ns c e o -b oa rd re la tio ns hi ps w ith in de pe nd en t b oa rd c on tr ol re du ce li ke lih oo d of a lli -a nc e fo rm at io n by p ro m ot in g di st ru st b et w ee n fir m le ad er s, w hi le c e o -b oa rd c oo pe ra tio n pr om ot es a lli an ce fo rm at io n by e nh an ci ng tr us t. a ls o, d ir ec t i nt er lo ck ti e ef fe ct s ar e am pl ifi ed b y ne tw or k tie s an d in di re ct tie s im pa ct fi rm a ct io n. g oe s be yo nd fo cu s on c on te nt a nd e ff ec ts o f d ya di c tie s. s ug ge st s in di re ct tie s, in w hi ch p ar tn er s to a n in te rl oc k tie a re e m be dd ed , m ay p os iti ve ly a nd ne ga tiv el y im pa ct in te ro rg an iz at io na l a ct io n. pr ob ab ili ty o f n ew a lli an ce b et w ee n or ga ni za tio ns in cr ea se s w ith th ei r in te rd ep en de nc e, p ri or m ut ua l a lli an ce s, a nd c om m on th ir d pa rt ie s, a nd th e jo in t c en tr al ity in th e al lia nc e ne tw or k. d iff er en tia tio n of e m er gi ng ne tw or k st ru ct ur e lim its e ff ec ts o f i nt er de pe nd en ce a nd e nh an ce s ef fe ct o f jo in t c en tr al ity o n ne w a lli an ce fo rm at io n. so ci al s tr uc tu re s ha pe s or ga ni za tio na l a ct io n, w hi ch s ub se qu en tly a ff ec ts so ci al s tr uc tu re . a lli an ce c om po si tio n im pa ct s fir m p er fo rm an ce . e nr ic he s lit er at ur e, b y ex am in in g ve rt ic al , h or iz on ta l, up st re am a nd do w ns tr ea m a lli an ce a nd e ff ec ts o f n et w or k co m po si tio n (e .g ., si ze , ef fic ie nc y, a lli an ce w ith ri va ls , a nd fi rm a ge s) . in g en er al , w ea k tie s an d st ro ng ti es p os iti ve ly a ff ec t fi rm s’ p er fo rm an ce an d ef fe ct s of re la tio na l e m be dd ed ne ss d ep en d on s tr uc tu ra l e m be dd ed ne ss an d en vi ro nm en ta l c on te xt . st ro ng a nd w ea k tie s ar e im po rt an t t o fir m s fo r d iff er en t p ur po se s, in di ff er en t c on di tio ns , i nd us tr ia l c on te xt s, a nd ti m es . a ls o, re la tio na l a nd st ru ct ur al e m be dde dn es s ca n on ly b e un de rs to od w ith re fe re nc e to e ac h ot he r. ta bl e 1: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e m pi ri ca l i nt er fir m n et w or k st ud ie s volume 30, number 1 73 a ut ho r( s) / y ea r st ev en so n & g re en be rg (2 00 0) k ha nn a & r iv ki n (2 00 1) l ee , l ee , & pe nn in gs (2 00 1) c on ce pt ua l pe rs pe ct iv e e vo lu tio na l in te ra ct io na l m ot iv at io na l m ot iv at io na l t he or y ba se (s ) so ci al m ov em en t tr an sa ct io n co st ec on om ic s (t c e ) r b v so ci al c ap ita l ty pe s of ne tw or ks u nc le ar b us in es s gr ou p u nc le ar l ev el o f an al ys is fi rm n et w or k fi rm k ey fi nd in gs / t he or et ic al c on tr ib ut io ns st ra te gi es fi rm s us e to im pa ct g ov er nm en t p ol ic y, u se a b ro ke r t o re ac h ag re em en t, or fo rm a c oa lit io n w ith o th er o rg an iz at io ns to s ha pe go ve rn m en t d ec is io ns d ep en d on s oc ia l c on te xt . e ve n pe ri ph er al a ct or s ca n af fe ct p ol ic y if th ey u se a d ir ec tc on ta ct s tr at eg y an d th e po lit ic al op po rt un ity s tr uc tu re is fa vo ra bl e. a pp lie s so ci al m ov em en t t he or y, w hi ch , u nl ik e so ci al n et w or k th eo ry , m ak es a llo w an ce fo r a ct or m ov em en ts . a ls o, s yn th es iz es m or e m ac ro so ci al le ve ls o f o rg an iz at io na l a na ly si s w ith m or e m ic ro le ve l a ct io ns o f in di vi du al s. fo cu se s on th e ec on om ie s of th ir te en c ou nt ri es : a rg en tin a, b ra zi l, c hi le , in di a, in do ne si a, is ra el , m ex ic o, p er u, th e ph ili pp in es , s ou th k or ea , ta iw an , t ha ila nd , a nd t ur ke y. b us in es s gr ou ps a ff ec t t he e co no m ic pe rf or m an ce in 1 2 of th e m ar ke ts . i n ot he r w or ds , t he g ro up a ffi lia tio n im pa ct p er fo rm an ce . i n ad di -t io n, th e an al ys is p ro vi de s no s up po rt fo r t he vi ew th at g ro up s ar e pr im ar ily re sp on se s to c ap ita l m ar ke t i m pe rf ec tio ns , no r f or th e vi ew fo r r en tse ek in g be ha vi or . in di ca te s th at g ro up s ex is t f or d if fe re nt re as on s an d pe rf or m d if fe re nt fu nc tio ns in e ac h in di vi du al in st itu tio na l s et tin g. in te rn al c ap ab ili tie s ar e im po rt an t p re di ct or s of fi rm p er fo rm an ce . n ot a ll in di ct or s of e xt er na l n et w or k pr ed ic t s ta rt -u p fir m s’ p er fo rm an ce . s ev er al in te ra ct io ns b etw ee n in te rn al c ap ab ili tie s an d ex te rn al n et w or ks a ls o em er ge . su gg es ts in te gr at in g vi ew s of r b v (o n fir m c ap ab ili tie s) a nd s oc ia l c ap ita l (o n ex te rn al n et w or ks ) t o pr ed ic t fi rm s’ p er fo rm an ce . ta bl e 1: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e m pi ri ca l i nt er fir m n et w or k st ud ie s 74 journal of business strategies r in dfl ei sc h & m oo rm an (2 00 1) st ru ct ur al in te ra ct io na l so ci al n et w or k n ew pr od uc t al lia nc e h or iz on ta l v er tic al r el at io na l h or iz on ta l a lli an ce s te nd to h av e lo w er le ve ls o f r el at io na l e m be dd ed ne ss an d hi gh er le ve l o f k no w le dg e re du nd an cy th an v er tic al a lli an ce s. e m be dd ed ne ss e le va te s ac qu is iti on a nd u til iz at io n of in fo rm at io n. r ed un da nc y re du ce s ac qu is iti on b ut e nh an ce s ut ili za tio n of in fo rm at io n. c ha lle ng es v ie w o n so ci al n et w or ks b as ed o n g ra no ve tte r’ s w or k. f or ex am pl e, in di vi du al s w ith c lo se ti es a re a ss um ed to s ha re b ot h hi gh le ve ls of re la tio na l e m be dd ed ne ss a nd in fo rm at io n re du nd an cy . f in di ng s su gg es t as su m pt io n do es n ot h ol d fo r i nt er or ga ni za tio na l r el at io ns hi ps . a ut ho r( s) / y ea r c on ce pt ua l pe rs pe ct iv e t he or y ba se (s ) ty pe s of ne tw or ks l ev el o f an al ys is k ey fi nd in gs / t he or et ic al c on tr ib ut io ns k ok a & pr es co tt (2 00 2) fr el s, s he rv an i, & s ri as ta va (2 00 3) b ra df or d, st ri ng fe llo w , & w ei tz (2 00 4) m ot iv at io na l st ru ct ur al in te ra ct io na l so ci al c ap ita l u nc le ar u nc le ar a lli an ce h or iz on ta l u nc le ar fi rm n et w or ks r el at io na l su pp or ts h yp ot he se s th at s oc ia l c ap ita l i s a th re e di m en si on al c on st ru ct . c on si de rs th e co ns tr uc t v al id ity a nd c on tin ge nt n at ur e of s oc ia l c ap ita l. su gg es ts th at s oc ia l c ap ita l s ho ul d be v ie w ed te rm s of th e di ff er en t in fo rm at io n vo lu m e, in fo rm at io n di ve rs ity , a nd in fo rm at io n ri ch ne ss av ai la bl e to fi rm s. v al ue a dd ed b y th e th re e ne tw or ks is p os iti ve ly re la te d w ith re so ur ce s al lo ca te d to c om pe tin g pr od uc t b y bu si ne ss c us to m er s. t he th re e ne tw or ks m ed ia te th e re la tio ns hi p be tw ee n pr od uc t p er fo rm an ce a nd re so ur ce al lo ca tio n. r efi ne th e no tio n of m ar ke t b as ed a ss et s. p ro po se in te gr at ed n et w or k m od el of d iff er en t t yp es o f n et w or ks , e xt en d co nc ep tu al iz at io ns o f i nn ov at io n di ff us io n, c od iff us io n, a do pt io n, a nd in tr ao rg an iz at io n ad op tio n. n eg at iv e ef fe ct s of in te rp er so na l a nd ta sk c on fli ct o n ne tw or k ou tc om es ca n be re du ce d by c on fli ct m an ag em en t. h ow ev er , e ff ec tiv en es s of u si ng di ff er en t c on fli ct m an ag em en t a pp ro ac h di ff er s. e xt en ds id ea s on c on fli ct in c ha nn el re la tio ns hi ps b y co ns id er in g ef fe ct iv en es s of c on fli ct m an ag em en t. a ls o ex pl ai n ho w ty pe s of c on fli ct an d co nfl ic t m an ag em en t a ff ec t n et w or k ou tc om es . ta bl e 1: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e m pi ri ca l i nt er fir m n et w or k st ud ie s volume 30, number 1 75 po w el l e t a l. (2 00 5) e vo lu tio na l u nc le ar h or iz on ta l n et w or k a s or ga ni za tio ns in cr ea se th ei r c ol la bo ra tio n an d di ve rs if y th ei r n ew tie s to o th er s, s ub -n et w or ks (c ha ra ct er iz ed b y m ul tip le , i nd ep en de nt pa th w ay s) fo rm . s uc h st ru ctu ra l c ha ng es , i n tu rn , m ay c ha ng e ch oi ce s an d op po rt un iti es a va ila bl e fo r t he fi rm a nd , t hu s, re in fo rc e an a tta ch m en t. su gg es ts th at n ei th er m on ey n or m ar ke t c an d om in at e a fie ld ’s n et w or k ev ol ut io n. in st ea d, o rg an iz at io ns w ith d iv er se p or tf ol io s of w el lco nn ec te d co lla bo ra to rs a re in th e m os t c oh es iv e an d ce nt ra l p os iti on s an d ha ve th e po w er to s ha pe th e fie ld ’s e vo lu tio n. a ut ho r( s) / y ea r c on ce pt ua l pe rs pe ct iv e t he or y ba se (s ) ty pe s of ne tw or ks l ev el o f an al ys is k ey fi nd in gs / t he or et ic al c on tr ib ut io ns z ah ee r & b el l (2 00 5) k ha nn a & r iv ki n (2 00 6) st ru ct ur al r el at io na l st ru ct ur al r b v so ci al c ap ita l so ci al n et w or k pg n in dir ec t a nd dir ec t e qu ity ho ldi ng s d ire cto r int erl oc ks f am ily co nn ec tio ns fi rm n et w or ks fi rm s’ in no va tiv e ca pa bi lit ie s an d ne tw or k st ru ct ur es e nh an ce p er fo rm an ce , bu t e ff ec t o f s tr uc tu ra l h ol es o n pe rf or m an ce is g re at er fo r i nn ov at iv e fir m s. fi rm s w ith s up er io r n et w or ks c an e xp lo it th ei r c ap ab ili tie s to im pr ov e pe rf or m an ce . c ha lle ng es n et w or k st ud y vi ew th at fi rm s au to m at ic al ly b en efi t f ro m po si tio ns th ey o cc up y. s ho w s fir m s w el len do w ed w ith in te rn al c ap ab ili tie s ar e be tte r a bl e to e xp lo it fa vo ra bl e ne tw or k st ru ct ur e an d ne tw or k cl os ur e do es n ot a lw ay s im pa ct fi rm p er fo rm an ce (a s c ol em an a rg ue d) . o ve rl ap in o w ne rs , i nd ir ec t e qu ity h ol di ng s an d di re ct or in te rl oc ks a re st ro ng g ro up b ou nd ar y de lin ea to rs , w hi ch is n ot th e ca se fo r f am ily co nn ec tio ns a nd d ir ec t e qu ity h ol di ng s. d is tin gu is h di ff er en t t ie s an d th ei r u se in te rm s of d efi ni ng g ro up bo un da ri es . ta bl e 1: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e m pi ri ca l i nt er fir m n et w or k st ud ie s 76 journal of business strategies b el l & z ah ee r (2 00 7) l uo & h as sa n (2 00 9) sw am in at ha n & m or rm an (2 00 9) in te ra ct io na l in te ra ct io na l st ru ct ur al o rg an iz at io na l le ar ni ng k no w le dg e m an ag em en t n et w or k (i m pl ic it) so ci al n et w or k so ci al n et w or k na o go ve rn an ce ne tw or k (im pli cit ) pg n (e. g., eq uit y ho ldi ng al lia nc e; im pli cit ) u nc le ar a lli an ce pg n r el at io na l fi rm r el at io na l n et w or k in st itu tio na l l ev el ti es a re v al ua bl e in k no w le dg e tr an sf er , i f t he y ar e ge og ra ph ic al ly p ro xi m at e. o rg an iz at io na l l ev el ti es fa il to tr an sf er kn ow le dg e, re ga rd le ss o f g eo gr ap hi c lo ca tio n. in di vi du al le ve l f ri en ds hi p tie s ar e su pe ri or c on du its fo r k no w le dg e flo w a nd s pa n ge og ra ph ic h ol es . sh ow s di ff er en t t yp es o f t ie s ac ro ss o rg an iz at io ns d if fe r i n pr op en si ty to tr an sm it kn ow le dg e w he n th ey a re g eo gr ap hi ca lly p ro xi m at e or d is ta nt . n et w or ki ng p ro m ot es k no w le dg e cr ea tio n bu t t oo m uc h ne tw or ki ng em be dd ed ne ss le ad s to d im in is he d re tu rn s. n et w or ki ng d is pa ri ty a ls o ha s ne ga tiv e im pa ct . c om pe tit iv e en vi ro nm en t a nd te ch no lo gi ca l t ur bu le nc e im pa ct n et w or ki ng d is pa ri ty a nd m ar ke tin g kn ow le dg e le ar ni ng . t hi s is be ca us e in m or e co m pe tit iv e an d tu rbu le nt m ar ke ts , b ro ke ra ge o pp or tu ni tie s of fe re d by c om pl em en ta ry k no w le dg e ba se s w ou ld b e ev en g re at er . o ff er s in si gh ts o n in flu en ce o f i nt er na l s oc ia l a ct or s (t op m an ag em en t) a nd de ba te o n re la tiv e be ne fit s of w ea k so ci al n et w or ks . a rg ue th at n et w or ki ng st re ng th m ay h av e m or e co m pl ic at ed e ff ec ts th an u su al ly e xp ec te d. r el at io ns hi p is in ve rt ed u -s ha pe (n ei th er to o st ro ng n or to o w ea k tie s ar e op tim al ). a ls o, n ot e ne tw or k ef -f ec ts m ay d ep en d on m ar ke t c on di tio ns . m ar ke tin g al lia nc es c re at e va lu e fo r fi rm in a nn ou nc em en t p er io d ev en t w in do w . n et w or k ef fic ie nc y an d ne tw or k de ns ity h av e st ro ng es t p os iti ve im pa ct w he n th ey a re m od er at e. n et w or k re pu ta tio n an d ne tw or k ce nt ra lit y ha ve n o ef fe ct . i n ad di tio n, re la tio na l n et w or k ch ar ac te ri st ic s ha ve g re at er ro le th an s iz e or s ta tu s be ne fit s. m ar ke tin g al lia nc e ca pa bi lit y, w hi ch re fle ct s a fir m ’s a bi lit y to m an ag e a ne tw or k of p re vi ou s m ar ke tin g al lia nc es , h as a po si tiv e im pa ct o n va lu e cr ea tio n. in di ca te s th e ro le o f r el at io na l n et w or k ch ar ac te ri st ic s. a ut ho r( s) / y ea r c on ce pt ua l pe rs pe ct iv e t he or y ba se (s ) ty pe s of ne tw or ks l ev el o f an al ys is k ey fi nd in gs / t he or et ic al c on tr ib ut io ns ta bl e 1: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e m pi ri ca l i nt er fir m n et w or k st ud ie s volume 30, number 1 77 b el lo , k at si ke as , & r ob so n (2 01 0) k um ar , h ei de , & w at hn e (2 01 1) in te ra ct io na l st ru ct ur al a cc om m od at iv e re sp on se b eh av io rs u nc le ar a lli an ce v er tic al ne tw or ks fi rm r el at io na l fi rm r el at io na l e xa m in es a fi rm ’s p er fo rm an ce in a n in te rn at io na l m ar ke tin g al lia nc e w he n it re sp on ds to a s el fse rv in g pa rt ne r’ s ex pl oi tiv e be ha vi or . t he au th or s fo un d th at a fi rm ’s p ay of f f ro m a cc om m od at io n de pe nd s on it s ap pr oa ch to m on ito ri ng , e ith er e m pl oy in g ov er t s ur ve ill an ce o r r el yi ng o n its p ar tn er ’s s el fco nt ro l. fo r i ns ta nc e, o ve rt s ur ve ill an ce c an u nd er m in e ac co m m od at io ns ’ a bi lit y to c on vi nc e a se lfi sh p ar tn er th at c oo pe ra tio n is be ne fic ia l a nd n ot in co ns is te nt w ith it s se lf -i nt er es t. e xa m in es h ow m an uf ac tu re ’s g ov er na nc e of a n ex te rn al s up pl ie r r el at io ns hi p af fe ct s its p er fo rm an ce to w ar ds a d ow ns tr ea m re ta il cu st om er . f or in st an ce , th e au th or s fo un d th at a m an uf ac tu re ’s re lia nc e on s up pl ie r n or m s an d in ce nt iv es p ro m ot es p er fo rm an ce . h ow ev er , i nt er na l i nc en tiv es w ea ke n th e ef fe ct o f e xt er na l n or m s, a nd in te rn al n or m s w ea ke n th e ef fe ct o f e xt er na l in ce nt iv es . a ut ho r( s) / y ea r c on ce pt ua l pe rs pe ct iv e t he or y ba se (s ) ty pe s of ne tw or ks l ev el o f an al ys is k ey fi nd in gs / t he or et ic al c on tr ib ut io ns ta bl e 1: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e m pi ri ca l i nt er fir m n et w or k st ud ie s 78 journal of business strategies b en so n (1 97 5) c oo k (1 97 7) fo m br un (1 98 2) in te ra ct io na l in te ra ct io na l st ru ct ur al is t in st itu tio na l e xc ha ng e th eo ry u nc le ar r el at io na l r el at io na l m ul tile ve l fo cu se s on e nv ir on m en ta l f or ce s an d co nd iti on s th at im pa ct n et w or k re la tio ns . e nv ir on m en ta l d im en si on s in cl ud e re so ur ce c on ce nt ra tio n, p ow er c on ce nt ra tio n, n et w or k au to no m y, e nv ir on m en ta l d om in an ce , r es ou rc e ab un da nc e, a nd e nv ir on m en t n et w or k co nt ro l m ec ha ni sm s. p ro po se s fo ur g en er al s tr at eg ie s fo r c ha ng in g ne tw or k re la tio ns : co op er at iv e, d is ru pt iv e, m an ip ul at iv e, a nd a ut ho ri ta tiv e st ra te gi es . a ls o id en tifi es fo ur di m en si on s of in te ro rg an iz at io na l e qu ili br iu m : d om ai n co ns en su s, id eo lo gi ca l c on se ns us , po si tiv e ev al ua tio n, a nd w or k co or di na tio n. a rg ue s no o ne th eo re tic al p er sp ec tiv e w ill e na bl e sc ho la rs to c om pl et el y ex pl ai n or ga ni za tio n in te ra ct io n (n et w or ks ). e ve ry th eo ry h as s co pe re st ri ct io ns . m aj or c on tr ib ut io n is to p re se nt a n ex te ns io n of e xc ha ng e th eo ry fo r a na ly si s of in te ro rg an iz at io na l r el at io ns . i n do in g so , t he or et ic al fr am ew or k fo cu se s on e ff ec ts o f p ow er o n ex ch an ge re la tio ns a m on g or ga ni za tio ns . a ls o of fe rs d efi ni tio ns a nd p ro po si tio ns a nd d is cu ss es li nk ag e be tw ee n di ff er en t t yp es o f e xc ha ng e ne tw or ks a nd m ar ke t s tr uc tu re . fi na lly , r ev ie w s cr iti ci sm s of e xc ha ng e an al ys is o f i nt er or ga ni za tio na l r el at io ns a nd d is cu ss es fu tu re d ir ec tio ns fo r re se ar ch . a rg ue s re se ar ch er s sh ou ld id en tif y ty pe s of n et w or ks (e .g ., at tr ib ut e ne tw or ks a nd tr an sa ct io na l n et w or ks ). id en tifi es th re e ki nd s of s tr at eg ie s fo r n et w or k re se ar ch (n od al , dy ad ic , a nd tr ia di c) . n od al a pp ro ac he s ar e gr ou nd ed in c ro ss -s ec tio na l c om pa ri so n of a s et of in di vi du al a ct or s. d ya di c ap pr oa ch es fo cu s on re la tio ns hi p am on g pa ir s an d ar e gr ou nd ed in in fo rm at io n ab ou t t he w ho le n et w or k in te rm s of p ai r d is ta nc e. t ri ad ic a pp ro ac he s ex pl or e al l p os si bl e tr ia ds in th e ne tw or k an d re ly o n th e de gr ee o f b al an ce in th e ne tw or k. a ls o di sc us se s st re ng th a nd w ea kn es s of n et w or k re se ar ch a nd a pp lic at io n of th re e re se ar ch ap pr oa ch es . m aj or c on tr ib ut io n is to la y ou t k ey m et ho do lo gi ca l i ss ue s av ai la bl e fo r re se ar ch er s w ho w is h to u se a n et w or k ap pr oa ch to o rg an iz at io na l a na ly si s. a ut ho r( s) / y ea r r es ea rc h pe rs pe ct iv e t he or et ic al b as e l ev el o f an al ys is k ey c on tr ib ut io ns ta bl e 2: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e xa m pl es o f c on ce pt ua l r es ea rc h on i nt er fir m n et w or ks volume 30, number 1 79 t ho re lli (1 98 6) po w el l (1 99 0) ia co bu cc i & h op ki ns (1 99 2) a nd er so n, h ak an ss on & j oh an so n (1 99 4) u nc le ar u nc le ar u nc le ar in te ra ct io na l n et w or k th eo ry e m be dd ed ne ss (i m pl ic it) u nc le ar e m be dd ed ne ss & so ci al e xc ha ng e n et w or k n et w or k r el at io na l & n et w or k r el at io na l & o rg an iza tio na l su m m ar iz es s tr at eg ic is su es in vo lv in g ne tw or ks : ( 1) tu rn ke y co nt ra ct s an d “s ys te m se lli ng ”, (2 ) b ar te r a nd re ci pr oc al tr ad in g, (3 ) m ak ele as e or b uy d ec is io n, (4 ) s pl it or un if y so ur ci ng , ( 5) tr an sa ct io ns b et w ee n fir m ’s d iv is io ns , ( 6) c ar te ls , ( 7) i nt er lo ck in g di re ct or at es , ( 8) jo in t v en tu re s, m er ge rs , a nd a cq ui si tio ns , ( 9) d iv er si fic at io n, (1 0) in te rn at io na liz at io n, a nd (1 1) v er tic al in te gr at io n. n ot es s tr at eg ic im pl ic at io ns o f n et w or k pa ra di gm in m ar ke tin g (d is tr ib ut io n ch an ne ls ) a nd o th er fi el ds . a rg ue s th at re la tio na l o r n et w or k fo rm s of o rg an iz at io n ar e an id en tifi ab le fo rm o f e co no m ic ch an ge u nd er c er ta in c ir cu m st an ce s. t he s al ie nt fe at ur es o f t hr ee m od es o f o rg an iz at io n (m ar ke t, hi er ar ch y, a nd n et w or ks ) a re id en tifi ed a nd c om pa re d. t he lo gi c of n et w or k fo rm s is e xp lo re d sy st em at ic al ly . e m ph as iz es th e im po rt an ce o f s oc ia l r el at io ns a nd e xp la in s th e tr an sf or m at io n of an e xc ha ng e dy ad ic re la tio ns hi p to a s et o f s ta bl e, m ul tid im en si on al , m ul til ay er ed in te ro rg an iz at io na l n et w or ks . t he a ut ho r p ro po se s th re e st ag es o f e nt re pr en eu ri al n et w or ki ng ac tiv ity w hi ch a re u se d to s ec ur e th e cr iti ca l e co no m ic a nd n on -e co no m ic re so ur ce s ne ed ed to s ta rt a b us in es s. 1 . f oc us o n es se nt ia l d ya ds , 2 . t ra ns fe r d ya di c tie s to s oc io ec on om ic ex ch an ge ti es a nd 3 . l ay er th e in iti al e xc ha ng e re la tio ns hi p w ith a dd iti on al b us in es s fu nc tio ns , a ct iv iti es , a nd le ve ls o f e xc ha ng e (f ro m p er so na l e xc ha ng e to o rg an iz at io na l ex ch an ge ). pr ov id es c on ce pt ua l d ev el op m en t o f d ya di c bu si ne ss re la tio ns hi ps th at c ap tu re s th e em be dd ed c on te xt a nd fo rm ul at es b us in es s ne tw or k co ns tr uc ts fr om fo ca l fi rm ’s p er sp ec tiv e an d its p ar tn er s’ p er sp ec tiv e. in th e ar tic le , t he a ut ho rs ’ c on ce pt ua liz e th e bu si ne ss n et w or k as s et s of c on ne ct ed re la tio ns hi ps . a ut ho r( s) / y ea r r es ea rc h pe rs pe ct iv e t he or et ic al b as e l ev el o f an al ys is k ey c on tr ib ut io ns ta bl e 2: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e xa m pl es o f c on ce pt ua l r es ea rc h on i nt er fir m n et w or ks 80 journal of business strategies jo ne s, h es te rl y & b or ga tti (1 99 7) a ch ro l (1 99 7) d ah ab , g en tr y & s oh i (1 99 7) po do ln y & pa ge (1 99 8) sy do w & w in de le r (1 99 8) in te ra ct io na l & m ot iv at io na l st ru ct ur al st ru ct ur al e vo lu tio na l st ru ct ur al tr an sa ct io n co st ec on om ic s & so ci al n et w or k th eo ri es u nc le ar in st itu tio na l u nc le ar st ru ct ur at io n th eo ry n et w or k o rg an iz atio na l n et w or k n et w or k n et w or k & or ga ni za tio na l in te gr at es tr an sa ct io n co st th eo ry a nd s oc ia l n et w or k th eo ri es . c la im s ne tw or k fo rm o f go ve rn an ce is a re sp on se to e xc ha ng e co nd iti on s of a ss et s pe ci fic ity , d em an d un ce rt ai nt y, ta sk c om pl ex ity , a nd fr eq ue nc y. t he se e xc ha ng e co nd iti on s dr iv e fir m s to w ar d em be dd in g th ei r t ra ns ac tio ns a nd le t t he m u se s oc ia l m ec ha ni sm s to c oo rd in at e an d sa fe gu ar d ex ch an ge s. w he n al l o f t he se c on di tio ns a re in p la ce , n et w or k go ve rn an ce fo rm h as ad va nt ag es o ve r b ot h hi er ar ch y an d m ar ke t s ol ut io ns . s ho w s ho w e m be dd ed ne ss p ro vi de s fo un da tio n fo r fi rm s to c oo rd in at e an d sa fe gu ar d ex ch an ge in n et w or k go ve rn an ce . a na ly ze s th e ev ol ut io n of th e ne tw or k or ga ni za tio n an d ex pl or es th e ch ar ac te ri st ic s of fo ur ty pe s of n et w or k or ga ni za tio ns , i nc lu di ng th e in te rn al m ar ke t n et w or k, th e ve rt ic al m ar ke t ne tw or k, th e in te rm ar ke t n et w or k, a nd th e op po rt un ity n et w or k. su gg es ts c ha nn el s in tr an si tio na l e co no m ie s m ay b e co nt ro lle d by g ro up s or n et w or ks of p eo pl e w ith m ut ua l i nt er es t ( in te re st d om in at io n) . e xa m in es in te re st d om in at io n by m an ag er s, c om m un is t c ad re s, a nd o th er p ar ty e lit e in tw o tr an sf or m in g ec on om ie s an d de sc ri be s ho w c om m an d ec on om ie s m ig ht b e co nd uc tiv e to in te re st d om in at io n fo r m ar ke tin g ch an ne ls . p re se nt s pr op os iti on s of h ow p ol iti ca l, so ci al , a nd e co no m ic fa ct or s th at s us ta in in te re st d om in at io n. e xa m pl es fr om h un gr y an d ta jik is ta n ar e us ed to p ro vi de co nt ex t f or th e di sc us si on . r ev ie w s lit er at ur e of n et w or k or ga ni za tio ns a nd fo cu se s on v ar ia tio n cr os sin du st ry a nd cr os spo pu la tio n. e xp la in s w hy o rg an iz at io ns d o no t a do pt n et w or k ap pr oa ch es . f in al ly , ca lls fo r a tte nt io n to s uc ce ss a nd fa ilu re o f n et w or k fo rm o f o rg an iz at io n. a pp lie s g id de n’ s st ru ct ur at io n th eo ry to a na ly ze n et w or k pr oc es se s. d efi ne s in te rfir m ne tw or k an d th en m ov es to o rg an iz at io na l n et w or k pr ac tic es . s tr es se s ho w s tr uc tu re o f si gn ifi ca tio n, d om in at io n, a nd le gi tim at io n sh ap e ne tw or k pr oc es se s an d ho w s tr uc tu re is cr ea te d un de r a us pi ce s of n et w or k ef fe ct iv en es s. a ut ho r( s) / y ea r r es ea rc h pe rs pe ct iv e t he or et ic al b as e l ev el o f an al ys is k ey c on tr ib ut io ns ta bl e 2: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e xa m pl es o f c on ce pt ua l r es ea rc h on i nt er fir m n et w or ks volume 30, number 1 81 a ch ro l & k ot le r ( 19 99 ) l in (1 99 9) d ac in , v en tr es ca & b ea l (1 99 9) g ul at i, n oh ri a & z ah ee r (2 00 0) st ru ct ur al m ot iv at io na l u nc le ar st ru ct ur al e m be dd ed ne ss & th eo ry o f n et w or ks (i m -p lic it) so ci al c ap ita l e m be dd ed ne ss so ci al c ap ita l (i m pl ic it) n et w or k r el at io na l & n et w or k u nc le ar / or ga ni za tio na l, re la tio na l, & n et w or k o rg an iz atio na l, re la tio na l, & n et w or k d efi ne s an d di st in gu is he s fo ur ty pe s of n et w or k or ga ni za tio ns , i nc lu di ng in te rn al ne tw or ks , v er tic al n et w or ks , i nt er -m ar ke t n et w or ks , a nd o pp or tu ni ty n et w or ks . m os t im po rt an tly , e xp la in s ro le o f m ar ke tin g in d iff er en t t yp es o f n et w or k or ga ni za tio ns a nd th e lim ita tio ns o f n et w or k or ga ni za tio ns . a na ly ze s th e ev ol ut io n of th e ne tw or k or ga ni za tio n an d ex pl or es th e ch ar ac te ri st ic s of fo ur ty pe s of n et w or k or ga ni za tio ns , i nc lu di ng th e in te rn al m ar ke t n et w or k, th e ve rt ic al m ar ke t ne tw or k, th e in te rm ar ke t n et w or k, a nd th e op po rt un ity n et w or k. r ev ie w s re se ar ch o n em be dd ed ne ss a nd c on tr ib ut e to u nd er st an di ng e m be dd ed ne ss o f or ga ni za tio ns . c ov er s re se ar ch o n ec on om ic s oc io lo gy , n et w or k th eo ri es o f a lli an ce , or ga ni za tio ns a nd s tr at eg y, s oc ia l c ap ita l, an d ne tw or k th eo ry a nd o rg an iz at io ns , a nd n et w or k th eo ry a nd c ul tu ra l s oc io lo gy . m ai nl y fo cu se s on c on ce pt ua liz at io n of e m be dd ed ne ss . pr es en ts in te gr at ed fr am ew or k th at c on si de rs s ou rc es , m ec ha ni sm s, o ut co m es , a nd s tr at eg ic im pl ic at io ns o f e m be dd ed ne ss . a ls o, c om m en ts o n fu tu re re se ar ch a nd is su es re la te d to ne tw or ks a nd m et ho do lo gy . n ot es th at s tr at eg ic n et w or ks e nc om pa ss in te ro rg an iz at io na l t ie s (e .g ., st ra te gi c al lia nc es , jo in t v en tu re s, lo ng -t er m , b uy er -s up pl ie r p ar tn er sh ip s, a nd m an y ot he r t ie s. a rg ue s th at re la tio ns hi ps in w hi ch fi rm s ar e em be dd ed s ha pe th ei r c on du ct a nd p er fo rm an ce . id en tifi es fiv e ar ea s of s tr at eg y re se ar ch th at m ay in vo lv e st ra te gi c ne tw or ks : ( 1) in du st ry s tr uc tu re , (2 ) p os iti on in g in a n in du st ry , ( 3) in im ita bl e fir m re so ur ce s an d ca pa bi lit ie s, (4 ) c on tr ac tin g an d co or di na tio n co st , a nd (5 ) d yn am ic n et w or k co ns tr ai nt s an d be ne fit s. d is cu ss es s tr at eg ic ne tw or ks ’ p ot en tia l p os iti ve (e .g ., in fo rm at io n ac ce ss , r es ou rc es , m ar ke ts , t ec hn ol og ie s, a nd sc op e ec on om ic s po si tiv e, r is k sh ar in g, a nd o ut so ur ci ng ) a nd n eg at iv e ef fe ct s. a ut ho r( s) / y ea r r es ea rc h pe rs pe ct iv e t he or et ic al b as e l ev el o f an al ys is k ey c on tr ib ut io ns ta bl e 2: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e xa m pl es o f c on ce pt ua l r es ea rc h on i nt er fir m n et w or ks 82 journal of business strategies d as & t en g (2 00 0) d as & t en g (2 00 2) b or ga tii & fo st er (2 00 3) pe ng (2 00 3) m ot iv at io na l & ev ol ut io na l in te ra ct io na l u nc le ar e vo lu tio na l r es ou rc eba se d th eo ry so ci al e xc ha ng e so ci al c ap ita l, ne tw or k, & di ff us io n th eo ri es in st itu tio na l, re so ur ce -b as ed , & ne tw or k th eo ri es o rg an iz atio na l r el at io na l a ll, b ut pr im ar -i ly or ga ni za tio na l & re la tio na l fi rm r ev ie w re so ur ce -b as ed th eo ry o f s tr at eg ic a lli an ce li te ra tu re , a nd s yn th es iz es th e fin di ng s. pr op os es fo ur m aj or a sp ec ts o f s tr at eg ic a lli an ce s: ra tio na le , f or m at io n, s tr uc tu ra l pr ef er en ce s, a nd p er fo rm an ce . n ot es re so ur ce -b as ed v ie w s ug ge st s th at th e ra tio na le fo r al lia nc es is th e va lu e cr ea tio n an d re so ur ce s ch ar ac te ri st ic s, s uc h as im pe rf ec t m ob ili ty , fa ci lit at e al lia nc e fo rm at io n. id en tifi es re so ur ce c ha ra ct er is tic s, d is cu ss es a ty po lo gy o f al lia nc e an d st ru ct ur e pr ef er en ce s fo r a lli an ce s tr uc tu re s, a nd u se s a se t o f p ro po si tio ns to in di ca te fu tu re re se ar ch d ir ec tio ns . d ev el op s a so ci al e xc ha ng e pe rs pe ct iv e of a lli an ce c on st el la tio ns (m ul tifir m a lli an ce s) , w hi ch e m ph as iz es ro le o f e xc ha ng e. a ls o, d is cu ss es th re e so ci al c on tr ol m ec ha ni sm s, (e .g ., re ci pr oc ity , s oc ia l s an ct io ns , m ac ro cu ltu re ) fo r m iti ga tin g di ffi cu lti es o f m an ag in g co ns te lla tio ns . p ro po se s ty po lo gy o f c on st el la tio ns b as ed o n di m en si on s of e xc ha ng e. c on tr ib ut es to a lli an ce li te ra tu re th at is la rg el y ba se d on a n ex ch an ge p ro ce ss , b ut w hi ch h as be en c en te re d on in te rp er so na l r el at io ns . r ev ie w s an d de ve lo ps ty po lo gy a nd d im en si on s of n et w or k st ud ie s in o rg an iz at io na l re se ar ch . e xt en ds li te ra tu re o n ho w o rg an iz at io ns m ak e st ra te gi c ch oi ce s du ri ng in st itu tio na l tr an si tio ns . i ts th re e pr im ar y co nt ri bu tio ns a re to (1 ) h ig hl ig ht in st itu tio na l c ha ng e, (2 ) de ve lo p tw oph as e m od el , f oc us in g on l on gi tu di na l p ro ce ss to m ov e fr om re la tio ns hi pba se d, p er so na liz ed tr an sa ct io n st ru ct ur e re qu ir in g ne tw or k ce nt er ed s tr at eg ie s to a ru le ba se d, im pe rs on al e xc ha ng e m od el th at e m ph as iz es m ar ke tce nt er ed s tr at eg y, a nd (3 ) e xt en d w or k of in st itu tio na l b as ed v ie w o f s tr at eg y ch oi ce . c au tio ns th at n ot a ll ne tw or ks a re th e sa m e an d fir m s ca n pr ac tic e bo th n et w or k a nd m ar ke tba se d st ra te gi es , w hi ch a re n ot m ut ua lly e xc lu si ve . c ul tu ra l d iff er en ce m ay a ls o in te ra ct w ith in st itu tio na l c ha ng e. a ut ho r( s) / y ea r r es ea rc h pe rs pe ct iv e t he or et ic al b as e l ev el o f an al ys is k ey c on tr ib ut io ns ta bl e 2: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e xa m pl es o f c on ce pt ua l r es ea rc h on i nt er fir m n et w or ks volume 30, number 1 83 b ra ss e t a l. (2 00 4) b et ts & s to ud er (2 00 4) c ur ra h & w ri gl ey (2 00 4) u nc le ar u nc le ar in te ra ct io na l u nc le ar u nc le ar o rg an iz at io na l le ar ni ng / kn ow le dg e m an ag em en t fi rm & re la tio na l o rg an iza tio na l, re la tio na l, & n et w or k r el at io na l & o rg an iza tio na l r ev ie w s an te ce de nt s an d co ns eq ue nc es o f n et w or ks b y le ve ls o f a na ly si s (i nt er pe rs on al le ve l, gr ou p le ve l, in te ro rg an iz at io na l l ev el ) a nd , o n ea ch le ve l, su gg es ts a re as th at h av e be en o ve rl oo ke d by re se ar ch er s. r ev ie w s m aj or n et w or k or ga ni za tio n re se ar ch a nd n ot es th at a lth ou gh m uc h is w ri tte n on n ot io n of “ ne tw or k or ga ni za tio ns ,” m os t a rt ic le s ar e th eo re tic al a nd ra re ly u se w el les ta bl is he d ne tw or k an al yt ic al te ch ni qu es . s ug ge st s th at n ot io n of n et w or k or ga ni za tio n is st ill d ev el op in g an d do es n ot h av e a cl ea r m ea ni ng . c ri tiq ue s us e of n et w or k an al ys is a nd co nc ep t o f n et w or k or ga ni za tio n, w hi ch h av e lit tle o ve rl ap in th e lit er at ur e. a pp lie s “c om pe te nc e ba se d” v ie w o f t he fi rm to e m er gi ng tr an sn at io na l c or po ra te (t n c ) re ta ili ng in du st ry . a na ly ze s ge og ra ph ic im pa ct o f o rg an iz at io na l l ea rn in g an d in ve st ig at es ad ap ta tio n am on g re ta il t n c s, to ra is e aw ar en es s of th ei r c on ce pt ua l i m po rt an ce . u se s co nc ep t o f i nt er -fi rm , i nt ra -fi rm , a nd e xt ra -fi rm re la tio na l n et w or k to s he d lig ht o n na tu re of e m be dd ed ne ss . o ff er s m or e de ta il by fo cu si ng o n in te rp la y be tw ee n ex tr afir m n et w or ks of s to re -b as ed le ar ni ng a nd in tr afir m n et w or ks o f k no w le dg e ex ch an ge a nd o rg an iz at io na l ad ap ta tio n. a ut ho r( s) / y ea r r es ea rc h pe rs pe ct iv e t he or et ic al b as e l ev el o f an al ys is k ey c on tr ib ut io ns ta bl e 2: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e xa m pl es o f c on ce pt ua l r es ea rc h on i nt er fir m n et w or ks 84 journal of business strategies pe ng & z ho u (2 00 5) e vo lu tio na l n et w or k th eo ry r el at io na l e xa m in es h ow n et w or k st ra te gi es e vo lv e w ith in st itu tio na l t ra ns iti on s. a rg ue s th at w hi le ce rt ai n ne tw or k st ra te gi es a re b ec om in g le ss im po rt an t, ot he r n et w or k st ra te gi es m ay b ec om e m or e cr uc ia l. sp ec ifi ca lly , w ea k tie s tr at eg ie s m ay d om in at e ne tw or k st ra te gy c ho ic es a s tr an si tio n ev ol ve s. in st ea d of b ei ng p ha se d ou t, st ro ng ti es m ay b e tr an sf or m ed in to w ea k tie s. a rg ue th at p ol iti ca l a nd le ga l f or ce s m ay s ha pe th e co nt en t o f d iff er en t n et w or ks th at fo cu s on b us in es sto -g ov er nm en t a nd b us in es sto -b us in es s tie s. s up po rt s id ea th at b us in es s ne tw or ks in a si a dr iv en b y im pa ct o f i ns tit ut io na l c ha ng e. n ot es th at th e di ff er en ce s be tw ee n fir m s in d ev el op ed a nd e m er gi ng e co no m ie s is n ot th at fo rm al , d o no t u se n et w or k st ra te gi es an d th e la tte r o nl y us e ne tw or k st ra te gi es . a ut ho r( s) / y ea r r es ea rc h pe rs pe ct iv e t he or et ic al b as e l ev el o f an al ys is k ey c on tr ib ut io ns l av ie (2 00 6) pr ov an & k en is (2 00 7) e vo lu tio na l st ru ct ur al e m be dd ed ne ss n et w or k th eo ry o rg an iz atio na l, re la tio na l, & n et w or k n et w or k st re ss es th eo ry d ev el op m en t r at he r t ha n lo gi ca l p os iti vi sm . c on tr ib ut es to a d eb at e fr om di ff er en t t he or et ic al v ie w s. f in al ly , i t o ff er s a dy na m ic s ta bi lit y ap pr oa ch to a na ly ze n et w or k re se ar ch . a ut ho rs s ee o rg an iz at io na l n et w or ks a s co m pl ex a da pt iv e sy st em th at e xh ib its b ot h pe rs is te nc e an d ch an ge . pr ov id es ra tio na le fo r s tu dy in g ne tw or k go ve rn an ce , i ts ro le , a nd it s im pa ct o n ne tw or k ef fe ct iv en es s. p ro po se s th re e ba si c fo rm s of n et w or k go ve rn an ce (n a o m od el , l ea d or ga ni za tio na l g ov er ne d ne tw or ks , a nd p ar tic ip an t g ov er ne d ne tw or ks ). a ls o di sc us se s te ns io ns in e ac h go ve rn an ce fo rm a nd h ow to m an ag e th em . l av ie (2 00 6) m ot iv at io na l r es ou rc eba se d vi ew fi rm & re la tio na l o ff er s sy st em at ic th eo re tic al a na ly si s of c om pe tit iv e ad va nt ag e of fi rm a lli an ce s an d in te gr at es a nd e xt en ds re la tio na l v ie w /s oc ia l n et w or k th eo ri es w ith tr ad iti on al re so ur ce ba se d vi ew (r b v ) w ith a re fo rm ul at ed v er si on th at s ho ul d be ta ke n in to a cc ou nt in n et w or k lit er at ur e. c on tr ib ut es to e xt en si on o f r b v a nd fi rm s’ c om pe tit iv e ad va nt ag e in n et w or ke d en vi ro nm en ts . a ut ho r r ev ea ls h ow a fi rm c an e xt ra ct v al ue fr om re so ur ce s th at a re n ot fu lly ow ne d or c on tr ol le d by it s in te rn al o rg an iz at io n. t o do s o, h e de ve lo ps m od el th at a llo w s fo r es tim at in g di ff er en t t yp es o f e co no m ic re nt th at fi rm c an g en er at e by re ly in g on re so ur ce s ac ro ss it s ne tw or k of a lli an ce s. it id en tifi es fi rm -s pe ci fic , r el at io nsp ec ifi c an d pa rt ne rsp ec ifi c fa ct or s. f in al ly , i t c al ls fo r i nt eg ra tio n of r b v a nd n et w or k th eo ri es . ta bl e 2: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e xa m pl es o f c on ce pt ua l r es ea rc h on i nt er fir m n et w or ks volume 30, number 1 85 pr ov an , f is h, & s yd ow (2 00 7) d ac in , o liv er , & r oy (2 00 7) pe te rs , g as se nh ei m er & j oh ns to n (2 00 9) st ru ct ur al m ot iv at io na l in te ra ct io na l n et w or k th eo ri es in st itu tio na l o rg an iz at io na l le ar ni ng & st ru ct ur at io n th eo ry n et w or k fi rm o rg an iz atio na l & re la tio na l m ai nl y fo cu se s on in te ro rg an iz at io na l n et w or ks a t t he n et w or k le ve l r at he r t ha n at or ga ni za tio na l o r r el at io na l l ev el o f a na ly si s. a rg ue s th at w e ne ed to e xa m in e w ho le ne tw or k, to fu rt he r u nd er st an d is su es s uc h as h ow n et w or ks e vo lv e, a re g ov er ne d, a nd h ow ne tw or k ou tc om es m ig ht b e ge ne ra te d. f or in st an ce , s tu dy in g th e w ho le n et w or k w ou ld h el p sh ed li gh t o n ho w m ul til at er al c ol la bo ra tio n im pa ct s ov er al l b us in es s cl im at e in a n in du st ry or re gi on . s ug ge st s re se ar ch er s an d pr ac tit io ne rs s ho ul d ha ve p er sp ec tiv es th at g o be yo nd pe rf or m an ce o f i nd iv id ua l o rg an iz at io ns . a ls o no te s th at s tu dy in g w ho le n et w or k m ay re ve al im pl ic at io ns fo r i ts m em be rs , e .g ., st ag e of n et w or k ev ol ut io n m ay e xp la in h ow in di vi du al s re ac h th ei r g oa ls . a gu es le gi tim ac y ga in ed v ia p ar tic ip at io n in s tr at eg ic a lli an ce c an h av e a m aj or im pa ct o n fir m p er fo rm an ce . s ug ge st s al lia nc es s er ve im po rt an t f un ct io ns fo r fi rm s. p ro po se s fiv e ty pe s of le gi tim ac y as so ci at ed w ith a lli an ce s (m ar ke t, re la tio na l, so ci al , i nv es tm en t, an d le gi tim ac y) . o ff er s pr op os iti on s to e xp la in w he n fir m s ar e m os t l ik el y to e nt er in to a lli an ce s fo r l eg iti m ac y pu rp os es a nd h ow le gi tim at in g ro le o f a lli an ce s co nt ri bu te s to fi rm a nd al lia nc e pe rf or m an ce . m os t i m po rt an tly , s up po rt s id ea th at le gi tim at io n m ay b e an im po rt an t ro le fo r a lli an ce s an d ex te nd s al lia nc e lit er at ur e fr om in st itu tio na l p er sp ec tiv e. a rg ue s th at th e ne w m ar ke tin g lo gi c re qu ir es m or e re fin em en t a nd e xp lic itn es s in ne tw or ki ng li te ra tu re . a dd re ss es th is n ee d by e xp lo ri ng h ow v al ue c re at io n in m ar ke tin g re lie s on o rg an iz at io na l l ea rn in g. u se s st ru ct ur at io n th eo ry to e xp la in re la tio ns hi p be tw ee n or ga ni za tio na l a nd in di vi du al le ar ni ng . e xp lo re s th re e fa ce ts o f s tr uc tu ra tio na l p ro ce ss o f or ga ni za tio na l l ea rn in g: (1 ) s tr uc tu ra l p ro pe rt ie s th at e na bl e an d co ns tr ai n le ar ni ng p ro ce ss es , (2 ) w ay s th at in di vi du al s ca rr y ou t l ea rn in g pr ac tic e, (3 ) s oc ia l p ro ce ss in w hi ch le ar ni ng pr ac tic es a re e m be dd ed . i llu st ra te s pr oc es s w ith e xa m pl es o f t yp ic al n et w or k re la tio ns hi p in co ns tr uc tio n in du st ry a nd h ig hl ig ht s ro le o f m ar ke tin g in e nh an ci ng k no w le dg e m an ag em en t, or ga ni za tio na l l ea rn in g, a nd v al ue c re at io n. a ut ho r( s) / y ea r r es ea rc h pe rs pe ct iv e t he or et ic al b as e l ev el o f an al ys is k ey c on tr ib ut io ns ta bl e 2: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e xa m pl es o f c on ce pt ua l r es ea rc h on i nt er fir m n et w or ks 86 journal of business strategies g an es an , g eo rg e, j ap , pa lm at ie r, & w ei tz (2 00 9) m cg ui re & d ow (2 00 9) st ru ct ur al st ru ct ur al k no w le dg e m an ag em en t & ne tw or k th eo ri es (i m pl ic it) u nc le ar fi rm & re la tio na l n et w or k d is cu ss es h ow re ce nt tr en ds a nd c ha ng es in re ta ile r s up pl y ch ai n m an ag em en t i m pa ct fir m p er fo rm an ce . p ro po se th re e di re ct io ns in w hi ch re ta ile rs le ve ra ge u ps tr ea m a nd do w ns tr ea m re la tio ns hi ps in s up pl y ch ai n to c re at e pe rf or m an ce o ut co m es fo r b ra nd s, re pu ta tio n, re ve nu es , i nn ov at io n, a nd lo ng te rm p ro sp ec ts (s ou rc in g pr ac tic es o n w or ld w id e, m ul tic ha nn el , a nd n at ur e of in te rfi rm ti es b as es ). r ev ie w s m aj or th eo re tic al a nd e m pi ri ca l w or k on v er tic al a nd h or iz on ta l j ap an es e k ei re ts u. d is cu ss es h is to ry , c ha ra ct er s, a nd c ha ng es fo r e ac h ty pe o f k ei re ts u in p os t19 92 p er io d. su gg es ts fu tu re re se ar ch a nd im pl ic at io ns . a ut ho r( s) / y ea r r es ea rc h pe rs pe ct iv e t he or et ic al b as e l ev el o f an al ys is k ey c on tr ib ut io ns ta bl e 2: s um m ar y of s el ec te d e xa m pl es o f c on ce pt ua l r es ea rc h on i nt er fir m n et w or ks volume 30, number 1 87 references achrol, r. s. (1997). changes in the theory of interorganizational relations in marketing: toward a network paradigm. journal of the academy of marketing science, 25 (1), 56-71. achrol, r. s., & kotler, p. (1999). marketing in the network economy. the journal of marketing, 63, 146-163. baker, w. e., faulkner, r. r., & fisher, g. a. (1998). hazard of the market: the continuity and dissolution of interorganizational marketing relationships. american sociological review, 63(2), 147-177. bell, g. g., & zaheer, a. (2007). geography, networks and knowledge flow. organization science, 18(6), 955-972. bell, d. c., katsikeas, c. s., & robson, m. j. (2010). does accommodating a selfserving partner in an international marketing alliance pay off? journal of marketing, 74(nov), 77-93. bensen, k. j. (1975). the interorganizational network as a political economy. administrative science quarterly, 20(2), 229-249. borgatti, s. p., & foster, p. c. (2003). the network paradigm in organizational research: a review and typology. journal of management, 29(6), 991-1013. bourdieu, p. (1983). the forms of capital, in soziale ungleichheiten (soziale welt, sonderheft 2), ed. reinhard kreckel, 183-98, goettingen: otto schartz & co. bourdieu, p. (1986), the forms of capital. in: richardson, j. g. ed. handbook of theory and research for the sociology of education. new york: greenwood press. brass, d., galaskeiwicz, j. greve, h. r., & tsai, w. (2004). taking stock of networks and organizations: a multilevel perspective. academy of management journal, 47(6), 795-817. burt, r.s. (1997). the contingent value of social capital. administrative science quarterly, 42, 339-365. chaskin, r. j., brown, p., venkatesh, s., & vidal, a. (2001). building community capacity. new york: aldine de gruyter. coase, r. (1937). the nature of the firm. economica, 4(16), 386-405. 88 journal of business strategies contractor, f. j., & lorange, p. (1988). cooperative strategies in international business. oxford, uk: elsevier science, ltd. cook, k. s. (1977). exchange and power in networks of interorganizational relations. the sociological quarterly, 18(1), special issue, 62-82. coleman, j. s. (1988). social capital in the creation of human capital. american journal of sociology, 94, s95-s120. dacin, m. t., oliver, c., & roy, j-p. (2007). the legitimacy of strategic alliances: an institutional perspective. strategic management journal, 28, 169-187. dahab, d .j., gentry, j. w., & sohi, r. s. (1996). interest domination as a framework for exploring channel changes in transforming economies. journal of macromarketing, 16(2), 8-23. das, t. k., & teng, b-s. (2000). a resource-based theory of strategic alliance. journal of management, 26(1), 31-61. das, t. k., & teng, b-s. (2002). alliance constellations: a social exchange perspective. the academy of management review, 27(3), 445-456. dimaggio, p. j,. & powell, w. w. (1983). the iron cage revisited: institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. american sociological review, 48, 147-160. dyer, j. h. & nobeoka, k. (2000). creating and managing a high performance knowledge sharing network: the toyota case. strategic management journal, 21, 345-67. eccles, r. g., & crane, d. b. (1988). doing deals: investment banks at work. boston: harvard business school press. eisenhardt, k. m., & schoonhoven, c. b. (1996). resource based view of strategic alliance formation: strategic and social effects in entrepreneurial firms. organization science, 7(2), 136-150. fabrizio, c. (2011). contractual networks, interfirm cooperation and economics growt., cheltenham, uk: edward elgar publishing, inc. flint, g. d., & fleet, d. d. (2011). the competitive cohort: an extension of strategic understanding. journal of business strategies, 28(2), 97-122. fombrun, c. j. (1982). strategies for network research in organizations. the academy of management review, 7(2), 280-291. volume 30, number 1 89 frels, j. k., shervani, t. & srivastava, r. k. (2003). the intergrated networks model: explaining resource allocation in network markets. journal of marketing, 67(1), 29-45. ganesan, s., george, m., jap, s., palmatier, r.w., & weitz, b. (2009). supply chain management and retailer performance: emerging trends, issues, and implications for research and practice. journal of retailing, 85(1), 84-94. gerlach, m. l. (1992). alliance capitalism: the social organization of japanese business. berkeley, ca: university of california press. giddens, a. (1984). the constitution of society. outline of the theory of structuration. cambridge: polity. graddy, e. a., & chen, b. (2006). influences on the size and scope of networks for social service delivery. journal of public administration research and theory, 16, 533–552. granovetter, m. (1973). the strength of weak ties. american journal of sociology, 78(6), 1360-1390. granovetter, m. (1983). the strength of weak ties: a network theory revisited, in social structure and network analysis, p.v. mardsen and nan lin (eds), 201-233, beverly hills, ca: sage publications. gu, f. f., hung, k., & tse, d. k. (2008). when does guanxi matter? issues of capitalization and its dark sides. journal of marketing, 72(4), 12-28. gulati, r. (1993). the dynamics of alliance formation. unpublished doctoral dissertation, harvard university. gulati, r. (1999). network location and learning: the influence of network resources and firm capabilities on alliance formation. strategic management journal, 20(5), 397-420. gulati, r., & garguilo, m. (1999). where do interorganizational networks come from? american journal of sociology, 104(5), 1439-93. gulati, r., & westphal, j. d. (1999). cooperate or controlling? the effects of ceoboard relations and the content of interlocks on the formation of joint ventures. administrative science quarterly, 44, 473-506. gulati, r., nohria, n., & zaheer, a. (2000). strategic networks. strategic management journal, 21, 203-205. http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/polity_%28publisher%29 90 journal of business strategies gulati, r., dialdin, d. a., & wang, l. (2002). organizational networks. in j. a. c. baum (ed.), the blackwell companion to organizations: 281-303. malden, ma: blackwell. holmes, r. m., bromiley, p., devers, c. e., holcomb, t. r., & mcguire, j. b. (2011). management theory applications of prospect theory: accomplishments, challenges, and opportunities. journal of management, 37(4), 1069-1107. human, s. e., & provan, k. g. (2000). legitimacy building in the evolution of small-firm networks: a comparative study of success and demise. administrative science quarterly, 45, 327–65. iacobucci, d. (1996). networks in marketing. thousand oaks, ca: sage publications. ingram, p., & baum, j. a. c. (1997). chain affiliation and the failure of manhattan hotels, 1998-1980. administrative science quarterly, 42, 68-102. inzerilli, g. (1990). the italian perspective: flexible organization and social management. international studies of management and organization, 20, 6–21. jones, c., & defillippi, r. j. (1996). back to the future in film: combining industry and self-knowledge to meet career challenges of the 21st century. academy of management executive, 10(4), 89–104. jones, c., hesterly, w. s., & borgatti, s. p. (1997). a general theory of network governance: exchange conditions and social mechanism. the academy of management review, 22(4), 911-945. keister, l. a. (1998). engineering growth: business group structure and firm performance in china’s transitional economy. american journal of sociology, 104, 404-40. khanna, t., & rivkin, j. w. (2006). interorganizational ties and business group boundaries evidence from an emerging economy. organization science, 17(3), 333-352. kogut, b. (1988). joint ventures: theoretical and empirical perspectives. strategic management journal, 9(4), 319-332. khoja, f. (2010). the triad: organizational cultural values, practices and strong social intra-firm networks. journal of business strategies, 27(2), 205-228. volume 30, number 1 91 koka, b. r., & prescott, j. e. (2002). strategic alliance as social capital: a multidimensional view. strategic management journal, 23, 795-816. koza, m. p., & lewin, a.y. (1999). the coevolution of network alliances: a longitudinal analysis of an international professional service network. organization science 10, 638–53. kumar, a, heide, j. b., & wathne, k. h. (2011). performance implications of mismatched governance regimes across external and internal relationships. journal of marketing, 75(march), 1-17. larson, a. (1992). network dyads in entrepreneurial settings: a study of the governance of exchange processes. administrative science quarterly, 397, 76-104. larson, a., & starr, j. a. (1993). a network model of organization formation. enterpreneurship theory and practice, winter, 1042-2578. lavie, d. (2006). the competitive advantage of interconnected firms: an extension of the resource based view. academy of management review, 31(3), 638-658. lazerson, m. (1995). a new phoenix? modern putting-out in the modena knitwear industry. administrative science quarterly, 40, 34–59. lee, c., lee, k., & pennings, h. m. (2001). internal capabilities, external networks, and performance: a study on technology-based ventures. strategic management review, 22, 615-640. lee, s., kroll, m. j., & walters, b. a. (2011). stages of corporate governance in transition economies. journal of business strategies, 28(2), 151-176. liao, y. c. (2010). internal capabilities, external network position, and knowledge creation. doctoral dissertation, rensselaer polytechnic institute, 2010. lin, n. (1999). building a network theory of social capital. connections, 22(1), 28-51. liu, y., atinc, g., & kroll, m. (2011). the unique nature of chinese corporate governance practices. journal of business strategies, 28(1), 29-58. lusch, r. f., & brown, j. r. (1996). interdependency, contracting, and relational behavior in marketing channels. journal of marketing, 60(october), 19-38. madhavan, r., koka, b. r., & prescott, j. e. (1998). networks in transitions: how industry events (re)shape interfirm relationships. strategic management journal, 19(5), 439-459. 92 journal of business strategies mariotti, f. (2011). knowledge mediation and overlapping in interfirm networks. journal of knowledge management, 15(6), 875-899. mariti, p. & similey, r. h. (1983). co-operative agreements and the organization of industry. the journal of industrial economics, 16(4), 437-451. mcevily, b., & zaheer, a. (2004). architects of trust: the role of network facilitators in geographical clusters. in trust and distrust in organizations, ed. r. kramer and k. cook, 189-213. new york: russell sage foundation. mcguire, j., & dow, s. (2009). japanese keiretsu: past, present, future. asia pacific journal of management, 26, 333-351. morgan, r. e. (2004). market-based organizational learning – theoretical reflections and conceptual insights. journal of marketing management, 20, 67-103. nygaard a. & dahlstrom, r. (2002). role stress and effectiveness in horizontal alliances. the journal of marketing, 66(2), 61-82. osborn, r. n., & baughn, c. c. (1990). forms of interorganizational governance for multinational alliances. academy of management journal, 3, 503-519. peng, m. w. (2003). institutional transitions and strategic choice. the academy of management review, 28(2), 275-296. peng, m.w., & zhou, j. q. (2005). how network strategies and institutional transitions evolve in asia. asia pacific journal of management, 22, 321-336. peters, l. d., gassenheimer, j. b., & johnston, w. j. (2009). marketing and the structuration of organizational learning. marketing theory, 9, 341-368. pfeffer, j., & nowak, p. (1976). joint ventures and interorganizational interdependence. administrative science quarterly, 21(3), 398-418. pisano, g. p. (1989). using equity participation to support exchange: evidence from the biotechnology industry. journal of law, economics and organization, 5(1), 109–126. podolny, j. m, & page, k. l. (1998). network forms organization. annual review sociology, 24, 57-76. porter, m., & fuller, m. b. (1986). coalitions and global strategy. in michael porter, ed. competition in global industries, 315-344, boston: hbs press. volume 30, number 1 93 portes, a. (1998). social capital: its origins and applications in modern sociology. annual review of sociology, 24, 1-24. powell, w. w. (1990). neither market or hierarchy: network forms of organization. research in organizational behavior, 12, 295. provan, k. g., isett, k. r., & milward, h. b. (2004). cooperation and compromise: a network response to conflicting institutional pressures in community mental health. nonprofit and voluntary sector quarterly, 33, 489-514. provan, k.g., & kennis, p. (2007). modes of network governance: structure, management, and effectiveness. journal of public administration research and theory, august, 1-24. provan, k.g., & sebastian, j.g. (1998). network within networks: service link overlap, organizational cliques and network effectiveness. the academy of management review, 41(4), 453-463. putnam, r. d. (2000). bowling lane: the collapse and revival of american community. new york: simon & schuster. reve, t., & stern, l. w. (1979). interorganizational relations in marketing channels. the academy of management review, 4(3), 405-16. rindfleisch, a., & moorman, c. (2001). the acquisition and utilization of information in new product alliances: a strength of ties perspective. journal of marketing, 65, 1-18. rowley, t., behrens, d., & krackhardt, d. (2000). redundant governance structures: an analysis of structural and relational embeddedness in the steel and semiconductor industries. strategic management journal, 21, 369-386. scott r.w. (1987). the adolescence of institutional theory. administrative science quarterly, 32, 493-511. snow, c. c., miles, r.e., & coleman, h.j., jr. (1992). managing 21st century network organizations. organizational dynamics, 21(winter), 5-20. stigler, g. j. (1951). the division of labor is limited by the extent of the market. journal of political economy, 59(3), 185-93. swaminathan, v., & moorman, c. (2009), “marketing alliances, firm networks, and firm value creation. journal of marketing, 73, 52-69. 94 journal of business strategies sydow, j., & windeler, a. (1998). organizing and evaluating interfirm networks: a structurationist perspective on network processes and effectiveness. organization science, 9(3), 265-283. teisman, g. r., & klijn, e. h. (2002). partnership arrangements: governmental rhetoric or governance scheme? public administration review, 62, 197-205. thorelli, h. b. (1986). networks: between markets and hierarchies. strategic management journal, 7, 37-51. uzzi, b. (1996). the sources and consequences of embeddedness for the economic performance of organizations: the network effects. american sociological review, 61, 674-698. uzzi, b. (1997). social structure and competition in interfirm networks: the paradox of embeddedness. administrative science quarterly, 42, 35-76. uzzi, b. (1999). embeddedness in the making financial capital: how social relations and networks benefit firms seeking financing. american sociological review, 64(4), 481-505. venkatraman, n., & lee, c. (2004). preferential linkage and network evolution: a conceptual model and empirical test in the u.s. video game sector. academy of management journal, 47, 876-892. walker, o. c., jr. (1972). the effects of learning on bargaining behavior. in 1971 combined proceedings, f. c. allvine, ed. chicago: american marketing association, 1, 94-99. walker g., kogut, b., & shan, w. (1997). social capital, structure holes and the formation of an industry network. organization science, 8(2), 109-125. weiner, b. j., & alexander, j. a. (1998). the challenges of governing public-private community health partnerships. health care management review, 23(2), 39-55. westbrock, b. (2010). natural concentration in industrial research collaboration. the rand journal of economics, 41(2), 351-371. williamson, o. e. (1975). market and hierarchies: analysis of antitrust implications. london, uk: the free press. williamson, o. e. (1985). the economic institutions of capitalism: firms, markets, relational contracting. new york: free press. volume 30, number 1 95 zaheer, a., & bell, g.g. (2005). benefiting from network position: firm capabilities, structural holes, and performance. strategic management journal, 26, 809-82. biographical sketch of authors dr. jie g. fowler is assistant professor of marketing at valdosta state university. she received her ph.d in marketing from the university of nebraska-lincoln. her recent work focuses on social networks, beauty appeals in advertising, and family dynamics/relationships in the marketplace. her research appears in journal of macromarketing and advances in consumer research. dr. timothy h. reisenwitz is professor of marketing at valdosta state university. he received his dba in marketing from cleveland state university. his work examines social media, generational cohorts, and academic dishonesty. his research appears in the international journal of internet marketing and advertising, journal of consumer marketing, marketing management journal, journal of college teaching & learning, and academy of educational leadership journal. volume 32, number 1 21 active waiting as business strategy: learning from the serengeti plains c. w. von bergen southeastern oklahoma state university • durant, oklahoma martin s. bressler southeastern oklahoma state university • durant, oklahoma abstract fast decision making, a propensity for action, and getting things done appear to be highly valued by both practitioners and academics in the united states. under such monikers as exhibiting initiative, being proactive, walking the talk, and taking charge, getting things done is widely lauded and promoted. as a result, most managers are content to deal with day-to-day operational activities that require immediate attention, daily routines, and superficial behaviors rather than addressing important issues requiring reflection, systematic planning, creative thinking—and above all— time. to address this often unproductive busyness the authors propose active waiting which involves the recognition that not all problems are open to a quick fix and that sometimes waiting can be a valuable option. however, waiting does not have to be passive. the authors recommend that managers act like the skilled, veteran lions of the serengeti plains and adopt active waiting in order to be able to seize the opportune moment in pursuit of effective business strategy. this paper offers a sixstep process to help leaders integrate active waiting into their supervision style and concludes with recommendations for managers. keywords: business strategy, active waiting, second-mover advantage introduction “every morning in africa, a gazelle wakes up. it knows it must run faster than the fastest lion or it will be killed. every morning a lion wakes up. it knows it must outrun the slowest gazelle or it will starve to death. it doesn’t matter whether you are a lion or a gazelle. when the sun comes up, you better start running” (friedman, 2005, p. 114). the above quote by thomas friedman reminds us that organizations are competing for their very survival and that the quickest, swiftest, and fastest continue to live another day while those left behind become food for the lion. fast action enables both people and organizations to survive and flourish. however, while running is im22 journal of business strategies portant for lions, lions also need to be cautious in doing so. younger lions lacking in experience, will instinctively chase targets often resulting in failure. successful hunters surprise their victims after carefully scanning the horizon and patiently waiting with focused attention for just the right circumstances before taking action (stander & albon, 1993). the key to the lion’s survival is not only size and strength, but also cleverness in knowing when and how to attack their prey. even when hungry, lions will forego a meal rather than hazard a hasty and uncontrolled attack (haas, 2013). the serengeti plains of africa provide us with an important lesson regarding business strategy. that lesson features an overemphasis on quick decision making and speed of action that in many instances at the expense of reflective thinking, thoughtfulness, and resourcefulness demonstrated by the lions’ successful hunting strategy. both the academic and practitioner literature in the united states emphasize the importance of quick decision making and fast action. taking action—the practitioner’s perspective the emphasis on swift action has become so entrenched in management thinking that fastcompany, and their magazine is now a popular read for many business managers. the bias for action has also been underscored by many practitioneroriented books. for example, eccles and nohria (1992), in their book beyond the hype wrote that “management was, is, and always will be the same thing: the art of getting things done…. and to get things done, managers must act themselves and mobilise collective action on the part of others” (p. 32). further, kelley (1998) emphasized initiative along with other proactive behaviors as the explanation that distinguishes top performing employees from average employees in his book how to be a star at work. in addition, bruch and ghoshal (2004) stated in their book a bias for action, that management is essentially the art of doing and getting things done. renowned management guru and former chairman of general electric jack welch, said that “an organization’s ability to learn, and translate that leaping into action rapidly, is the greatest competitive advantage” (welch, n. d.). we are reminded that relentless execution is central to achieving superior business performance (bruch & ghoshal, 2010), and we generally respect individuals who make decisions quickly and even refer to them as “decisive”—a highly valued quality (greenberg, 2011). in their book in search of excellence (1982) peters and waterman pointed to “a bias for action” (p. 119) as an important attribute of excellent companies that supports and strengthens all other qualities. additionally, peters and waterman prescribed “ready, fire, aim” (p. 119) as the means to build an action orientation. volume 32, number 1 23 these books and others provide motivating accounts of organizational heroes who achieve significant success by emphasizing action and speed while at the same time implying that those slow to act are modern-day dinosaurs destined for extinction. the importance of action is even celebrated in motivational posters such as “the essence of survival” from friedman’s 2005 bestseller the world is flat and his accompanying words in the introduction of this paper. from another perspective, the term “analysis paralysis” or “paralysis of analysis” refers negatively to a situation where a person or an organization continues to rework or refine analyses, calculations, or computations, thus extending the decision making process and taking more time than reasonable and necessary, and in some instances with the result being no action taken (langley, 1995). because over the past decade the organizations’ ability to gather, store, access, and analyze data has grown exponentially, too much analysis is becoming an increasing problem (shah, horne, & capellá, 2012). taking action—the academic perspective additionally, the academic literature reports and promotes the importance of fast decision making and taking action. a great deal of research addresses proactive issues (parker & collins, 2010), actively adjusting to new job conditions (ashford & black, 1996), using initiative (den hartog & belschak, 2007), communication to positively change the organization (lepine & van dyne, 1998), promoting critical issues to leaders (dutton & ashford, 1993), taking charge to effect change (morrison & phelps, 1999), self-initiated role expansions (parker, wall, & jackson, 1997), the need for employees to be self-starting (campbell, 2000; ibarra, 2003), and the importance of network building (morrison, 2002). from another perspective keinan and bereby-meyer (2012) observed the danger in avoiding taking action rather than taking action in areas such as dodging cancer screenings (howard & huang, 2012) or not saving for retirement (kogut & dahan, 2012), as well as other researchers have investigated the dangers of inaction including the status quo bias, which is the tendency for people to prefer the current situation rather than consider similar or possibly better options (kahneman, knetsch, & thaler, 1991). despite different terminology and theoretical foundations, these concepts involve an action mindset or in other words, “making things happen.” procrastinators are typically labeled lazy, indolent, and unambitious—pejorative words in achievement-oriented societies (knaus, 1973). desimone (1993), however, reported that many pre-industrialized societies did not have words compa24 journal of business strategies rable to today’s notion of procrastination. similar words or constructs have existed throughout history, although with different, and usually less negative, connotations. the term procrastination comes directly from the latin verb procrastinare, meaning quite literally, to put off or postpone until another day (desimone, 1993). this actually is a compilation of two words—pro, a common adverb implying forward motion, and crastinus, meaning “belonging to tomorrow.” the combined word was used numerous times in latin texts and seemed to reflect the notion that deferred judgment may be necessary and prudent, such as when it is best to wait the enemy out and demonstrate patience in military conflict (ferrari et al., 1995). furthermore, the oxford english dictionary (oed, 1989) lists the earliest known english usage of the word procrastination as occurring in 1548 in edward hall’s chronicle: the union of two noble and illustrious families of lancestre and yorke. according to the oed, the word procrastination was in common usage by the early 1600s and notes that the term was used several times in this work and apparently without disparaging connotations, reflecting more of the concept of “informed delay” or “wisely chosen restraint” popular in roman accounts (ferrari, 2001, p. 30). the negative moral connotations of the term did not seem to emerge until the mid-18th century, at approximately the time of the industrial revolution. perhaps to the ancients, procrastination involved a sophisticated, astute decision regarding when not to act. this paper examines such an interpretation as well as questioning the implicit expectation that managers must do everything quickly, must be permanently active, and must not hesitate to take immediate action. active waiting as described in the successful lion hunts noted earlier in this paper is offered as an alternative approach. active waiting the nature of a manager’s job typically leaves little room for reflection, resulting in supervisors who might ignore or postpone dealing with the organization’s most crucial issues since such matters usually require a “big picture” perspective— which means reflection, systematic planning, or creative thinking, and—above all— time. managers often spend much of their time addressing trivial operational issues that require their energy, time, and focus but are insignificant in the grand scheme of things. daily routines, superficial behaviors, or poorly prioritized tasks act like leeches on managers’ capacities—making unproductive busyness perhaps the most critical behavioral problem in companies (bruch & ghoshal, 2010). american fast-action culture calls for easy answers and quick solutions devolume 32, number 1 25 mand managers determine what is wrong and act quickly to resolve the situation. the abundance of technology and the “instant gratification” technological advancements typically bring (samuelson, 1995) increases the need for quick solutions. managers will often jump to a conclusion and then try to implement the solution they reached. this course of action causes managers to limit their search, not consider all alternatives, and pay enough attention to people who would be affected by the decision, not realizing that decisions often fail because of these reasons (nutt, 1999). fast action is most often favored, even in situations where there is no real time pressure. there seems to be a strong inclination to move forward and a fear of being seen as an indecisive manager. even when managers know that making decisions this way is foolhardy, the pressure for hasty solutions often wins out (nutt, 1999). the virtue of patience organizations tend to be dominated by cultures of frenzy and unreflected activity (gosling & mintzberg, 2003). energized action is necessary, but that does not mean being hyperactive or continuously implementing change. taking time for reflection, seriously reviewing and questioning projects are neither the usual practice nor well received in many organizations. rarely do firms question such values. that is what makes the international federation of red cross and red crescent societies, headquartered in geneva, switzerland so unique. executives there worried that it was drifting too far toward a fast-action culture. it realized that it must act quickly in responding to disasters everywhere—earthquakes, wars, floods and famines—but it also saw the need to engage in the slower, more delicate task of building a capacity for action that was careful, thoughtful, and tailored to local conditions and needs. what was needed was an approach where reflective thinking meets practical doing (gosling & mintzberg, 2003). active waiting, or what the center for advanced health refers to as “watchful waiting”, is a common practice in the health care profession. doctors believe that for certain medical conditions the preferred strategy is to delay treatment while monitoring progress of the illness. in fact, in many instances, such as aching muscles or a child’s ear infection, the illness may be minor and go away on its’ own. using the “watchful waiting” approach, doctors can often better determine the best approach to treating the illness (http:www.cfah.org). active waiting is recommended to encourage the necessary management reflection,. it is a process in which individuals intentionally hold back from impetuously diving into making irreversible commitments of resources (minniti, 2006). 26 journal of business strategies this, however, takes patience. it is often hard for individuals to believe that they will get more done by starting out slowly, patiently, planfully (i.e., by waiting around), but the patience of active waiting is essential for slowing and preparing the mind, which otherwise races on to the next crisis. therefore, “active waiting is less a matter of time management than of emotional management” (boice, 2000, p. 108). leveraging the second-mover advantage many business strategists advocate the value of “first-mover advantage”, being first to market with an innovative new product or technology. other strategy analysts support another school of thought that proposes “second-mover advantage” in which organizations and companies that are followers benefit by learning from first-movers mistakes. these “second movers” in many cases are then able to surpass those companies that rushed to be first in the market. henricks (2009) cites several companies that benefitted from second-mover advantage. for example, voodoo tiki tequila, a high-end tequila liquor challenged the category market leader, patron spirits company. patron’s strategy was based on educating and convincing consumers to switch from drinking vodka to instead drinking tequila. second-mover tiki voodoo tequila did not have to spend the time, effort, and money educating consumers as patron had already taken on that task. instead, tiki instead chose to make significant improvements to packaging. while patron uses a traditional style mexican packaging, tiki uses bottles made from hand-blown glass with a tiki inside the bottle. in addition, each bottle is numbered, giving the impression of a limited series collection. consumers now willingly pay more for a perceived premium, high-end tequila liquor product. henricks (2009) points to other examples of successful second-movers including southwest airlines, which learned from earlier entrants in the economy segment of the airline industry. in addition, google gained considerable knowledge from the experience of previous search engine companies (e.g., webcrawler and lycos). although nokia and ericsson were the early entrants in the cell phone industry, today, companies like samsung and apple tower over the market. active waiting allows the second-mover to take advantage of the market leader’s mistakes or lack of follow-through. in some instances, the market leader might lack intellectual property protection or channels of distribution. in other examples, high costs associated with research and development or market introduction could leave the company in a financially weakened position. in addition, the first-mover might have introduced their product before all the product errors were identified and corrected. volume 32, number 1 27 other examples can also be found where second-mover companies benefitted by active waiting: target stores learned from walmart and amd computer acquired important information from observing intel. the real test however is profitability. rasmusen and yoon (2012) found that when second-movers possess better business or product knowledge, the company can employ second-mover advantage resulting in greater profits. what about the strategic importance of speed? gamble, thompson, and peteraf (2013) reported that mobile phone usage around the world did not immediately take off. in fact, it took ten years for the industry to grow from 10 million users to 100 million users worldwide! similarly, it took nearly ten years for broadband home usage to reach 100 million users around the globe. gamble et al. (2013) also remind us that the market penetration curve for many business opportunities is much longer than many businesses estimate. many additional companies could likely benefit from an active waiting strategy and take better advantage of business opportunities within the market penetration curve. putting active waiting into practice the authors propose a six-step process to implement an active waiting strategy. this approach calls for managers to be doubtful, generate alternatives, assess the alternatives, be flexible, implement slowly, and then take action. this six-step procedure is illustrated in figure 1 and is discussed below. figure 1 the six-step process of active waiting 28 journal of business strategies be doubtful people and organizations both appear to be culturally eager to praise the power of conviction. self-confident persons demonstrate sureness in their ability to make decisions, organize and execute action plans, perform new tasks, and offer opinions (mayo, kakarika, pastor, & brutus, 2012). self-confident leaders are also more likely to be assertive and decisive, which gains others’ confidence in decisions which is crucial for their effective implementation. moreover, kirkpatrick and locke (1991) identified self-confidence as one of six key leadership traits. if leaders are not sure of what decision to make, or express a high degree of doubt, then followers are less likely to trust those leaders and be committed to their vision. such confidence, in fact overconfidence, seems to be central to human nature (kahneman, 2011). individuals are often confident even when they are wrong, and an objective observer is more likely to detect their errors than the person who is wrong. people often have excessive confidence in what they believe they know, and an apparent inability to acknowledge the full extent of their ignorance and the uncertainty of the world they live in. they are prone to overestimate how much they understand about the world and their high subjective confidence is not to be trusted as an indicator of accuracy. individuals also tend to exaggerate their ability to forecast the future, which fosters optimistic overconfidence (kahneman, 2011). nevertheless, some degree of uncertainty may be useful. bandura and locke (2003) reported “in preparing for challenging endeavors, some self-doubt about one’s performance efficacy provides incentives to acquire the knowledge and skills needed to master the challenges’’ (p. 96) and chamorro-premuzic (2012) indicated that being somewhat unsure may be helpful and serve as a catalyst for beneficial change. woodman, akehurst, hardy, and beattie (2010) also found that a decrease in self-confidence resulted in significant improvement in performance from practice to competition in a sports-related activity. gladwell (2013) indicated that “[d]oubt was creative because it allowed for alternative ways to see the world, and seeing alternatives could steer people out of intractable circles and self-feeding despondency. doubt, in fact, could motivate: freedom from ideological constraints opened up political strategies, and accepting the limits of what one could know liberated agents from their dependence on the belief that one had to know everything before acting, that conviction was a precondition for action.” doubt may help prevent what barker (1993) describes as “paradigm paralysis” when it is assumed there is only one way to do something. this condition actually can prevent managers from exploring and considering other options. volume 32, number 1 29 generate alternatives the second step in the process involves developing alternate courses of action in response to an opportunity or threat. management experts often cite the failure to consider alternatives as a key reason why managers sometimes make poor decisions (bazerman & moore, 2008). almost every discussion of effective decision making calls for developing multiple options. the rejected possibilities are not wasted, however, as they assist in confirming the value of a preferred course of action and frequently offers the means to improve it. different choices allow managers in decision-making roles to combine the best features of various options to make a superior one, and to make a comparison with a preferred action to demonstrate its merits. nutt (1999), however, reported that managers produced several courses of action in less than 20 percent of their decisions. when multiple options were developed, success rates jumped from 56 percent to 70 percent. multiple ideas provide another way to increase one’s chance of success but developing several possibilities is time consuming and to save time, the practice is often ignored. moreover, some managers are used to seeing the world from a single perspective due to their “managerial mind-set” and find it difficult to view problems from a fresh perspective. according to best-selling management author peter senge (2006), humans are trapped within our personal mental models of the world—that is, our ideas about what is important and how the world works. generating creative alternatives to solve problems and take advantage of opportunities may require that we abandon our existing mind-sets and develop new ones—something that usually is difficult to do. managers today are encouraged to set aside their traditional paradigms of management decision making and generate creative alternatives. this new approach is reflected in the interest and growth in the work of authors such as senge (2006) and de bono (1968), who have popularized management techniques for stimulating problem solving and creative thinking. more recently gladwell (2013) noted that creativity develops from embracing chaos and releasing control. gladwell (2013) also noted that famed economist albert hirschman even criticized organizations like the world bank for trying to remove obstacles and secure economic and infrastructural stability in developing countries. for hirschman, obstacles cause frustration and anxiety, which in turn spur motivation. this chaotic unpredictability serves as the motor of creative energy—getting the rug pulled out from under us knocks us into a free fall that builds more momentum than standing securely on our feet. 30 journal of business strategies assess alternatives once managers have developed a set of alternatives, they must evaluate the advantages and disadvantages of each alternative (russo & schoemaker, 1992). the key to a good assessment of the alternatives is to define the opportunity or threat exactly and then specify the criteria that should influence the selection of alternatives for responding to the problem or opportunity. one reason for bad decisions is that managers often fail to specify the criteria that are important in reaching a decision (bazerman & moore, 2008). in general, successful managers use four criteria to evaluate the pros and cons of alternative courses of action (jones & george, 2011). often times a manager must consider these four criteria simultaneously: 1. legality: managers must ensure that a possible course of action will not violate any domestic or international laws or government regulations. 2. ethicalness: managers must ensure that a possible course of action is ethical and will not unnecessarily harm any stakeholder group. many decisions managers make may help some organizational stakeholders and harm others. when examining alternative courses of action, managers need to be clear about the potential effects of their decisions. 3. economic feasibility: managers must decide whether the alternatives are economically feasible-that is, whether they can be accomplished given the organization’s performance goals. typically managers perform a cost-benefit analysis of the various alternatives to determine which one will have the best net financial payoff. 4. practicality: managers must decide whether they have the capabilities and resources required to implement the alternative, and they must be sure the alternative will not threaten the attainment of other organizational goals. at first glance an alternative might seem economically superior to other alternatives; but if managers realize it is likely to threaten other important projects, they might decide it is not practical after all. some of the worst managerial decisions can be traced to poor assessment of the alternatives, such as the decision to launch the challenger space shuttle. in that particular case, the desire of nasa and morton thiokol managers to demonstrate to the public the success of the u.s. space program in order to ensure future funding (economic feasibility) conflicted with the need to ensure the safety of the astronauts (ethicalness). managers deemed the economic criterion more important and decided to launch the space shuttle even though there were unanswered questions about volume 32, number 1 31 safety. tragically, some of the same decision-making problems that resulted in the challenger tragedy led to the demise of the columbia space shuttle 17 years later, killing all seven astronauts on board (berger, 2004). in both the challenger and the columbia disasters, safety questions were raised before the shuttles were launched; safety concerns took second place to budgets, economic feasibility, and schedules; top decision makers seemed to ignore or downplay the inputs of those with relevant technical expertise; and speaking up was discouraged (glanz & schwartz, 2003). rather than making safety a top priority, decision makers seemed overly concerned with keeping on schedule and within budget (wald & schwartz, 2003). be flexible centuries ago playwright and keen observer of human behavior william shakespeare noted in the merchant of venice (1596) that “thus hath the candle singed the moth” (act 2 scene 9) meaning that just as a moth is attracted to a flame that leads it to make a fatal mistake, so too are people irresistibly and dangerously tempted by situations that often lead to disaster. similarly, in business a firm’s steadfast commitment to a long-term view of what it should be doing and where it should be going, often touted as a powerful tool for improving corporate performance, can be problematic when such attraction leads to tunnel vision, a narrow concentration, and missing the big picture. for example, sull (2004) details how microsoft’s fixation on mission statements related to pcs blinded them to opportunities and threats presented by the explosive growth of the internet. organizations must be careful to avoid such a “moth-to-candle syndrome” that can lead to its demise. rather than getting too focused on clear, long-term visions that can distract firms from emerging situations in the present, companies may want to consider softening such single-mindedness. indeed, sull (2005) tells leaders to “avoid marching headlong toward a well-defined future and instead articulate a fuzzy vision. ... a fuzzy vision works because it provides a general direction and sets aspirations without prematurely locking the company into a specific course of action” (p. 124). such a vision contributes to a company’s situational awareness—the ability to identify, process, and comprehend the critical elements of information about what is happening around it (united states coast guard, n. d.)—and can act as a corrective measure when organizations fixate on and become preoccupied with one aspiration often losing the ability to detect other important environmental information. fuzzy visions can motivate employers to explicitly consider alternatives and options because the flexible perspective inherent in such mission statements can promote 32 journal of business strategies greater functional dissent and other forms of constructive conflict. such flexibility is particularly important in rapidly changing environments, including emerging markets, technology intensive industries where change is often revolutionary rather than evolutionary, and fields where different industries are converging (e.g., information technology and entertainment). implement slowly the fifth step calls for measured, deliberate action. there is a saying in martial arts: you have to go slow to go fast. the idea is that individuals have to be relaxed and calm to move as quickly as they are capable of doing. famous movie character, ferris bueller, voiced a similar theme when he said, “life moves pretty fast. if you don’t stop and look around once in a while, you could miss it” (hughes, 1987). more formally, nobel laureate daniel kahneman (2011) summarized the research literature on decision-making and problem solving and described mental life by the metaphor of two agents, called system 1 and system 2, which respectively produce fast and slow thinking. system 1 is generally automatic, affective, and heuristic-based, and relies on mental “shortcuts.” it quickly proposes intuitive answers to problems as they arise. system 2, which corresponds closely with controlled processes, is slow, effortful, conscious, rule-based, and also can be employed to monitor the quality of the answer provided by system 1. if system 2 is convinced that our intuition is wrong, then it is capable of correcting or overriding the automatic judgments. system 2 takes over when things get difficult. each system impacts the other because individuals have only so much attentional focus. if system 2 is engaged then system 1 may be negatively impacted. intense focusing on a task can make people miss stimuli that normally attract attention. system 1 thinking can also negatively impact system 2 thinking. in a business context bruch and ghoshal (2002) noted that frequently there is an astonishing amount of fast-moving activity in organizations that allows almost no time for reflection. such unproductive busyness characteristic of system 1 thinking, and what bruch and ghoshal (2002) call “active nonaction,” can be a hazard for managers and organizations since fully 90% of managers squander their time in all sorts of ineffective activities. what is needed is more system 2 thinking or what bruch and ghoshal (2002) refer to as concentrated attention—the ability to zero in on a goal and see the task through to completion which seem to define what they call purposeful managers. volume 32, number 1 33 such attention requires that purposeful managers choose not to respond immediately to every issue that comes their way or get sidetracked from their goals by distractions like email, meeting, setbacks, and unforeseen demands. such system 2 thinking involves carefully weighing options before selecting a course of action. moreover, because purposeful managers commit only one or two key projects, they can devote their full attention to the projects they believe in. purposeful managers manage time carefully and some refuse to respond to phone calls or visitors outside certain periods of the day. other such managers build “think time” into their schedules. one executive, bruch and ghoshal (2002) observed, frequently arrived at the office at 6:00 a.m. to think about issues before his colleagues showed up. this executive said, “in the busiest times, i slow (italics ours) down and take time off to reflect on what i actually want to achieve and sort what’s important from irrelevant noise. then i focus on doing what is most important” (bruch & ghoshal, 2002, p. 68). sometimes it is important to slow down and let an individual’s system 2 take control, which is often associated with the subjective experience of agency, choice, and concentration. this involves active waiting. while the one minute manager (blanchard & johnson, 1981) focused on quick action was a best seller some years ago, more and more discussion is today being focused on reflection and moving forward slowly (honoré, 2004). take action the final step in the six-step strategy is to take action. this final step calls for applying the selected alternative and carrying out the decision. in taking action it may be fitting to consider various mental shortcuts that frequently sabotage managerial judgment and action. hammond, keeney, and raiffa (1998, 1999) and kahneman, slovic, and tversky (1982) have identified several key psychological traps that managers should be alert to and compensate for them when taking action. an example of this would be the status quo bias—the tendency to stick to the current state. by being aware of the role that this bias plays in their own lives, individuals can take actions to reduce the influence of this bias in their decision making. to avoid this error managers should 1) ask if the status quo really serves their objectives, 2) ask if they would choose the status quo if it were not the status quo, and 3) downplay the effort or cost of switching from the status quo. like college students who mistakenly think that in a multiple-choice test, they should always stick with their first answer, rather than changing it (benjamin, cavell, & shallenberger, 1984), managers likewise often misguidedly stay with 34 journal of business strategies those options that first come to mind. they often fail even to think through the possible implications of information that would be harder to get. to minimize the distortion caused by variations in “recallability,” managers must take a very disciplined approach to making forecasts and judging probabilities and should 1) carefully examine all assumptions to ensure they are not unduly influenced by their memory and improperly give more weight to recent events, 2) get actual statistics whenever possible, and avoid being guided by impressions and dramatic events, and 3) try and recall instances of events that are not so memorable. summary and conclusion this paper focuses on the potential benefits of waiting strategically. to some degree this is in response to what the authors consider as an overemphasis on swift action, execution, and doing. while the “ready, fire, aim” concept is about velocity and the profound benefits of moving from ideas into action—from thinking into doing—at the fastest possible speed, it is essential to realize that such an approach may do more harm than good since such a strategy may cause individuals to completely miss the target if activities are undertaken with reckless abandon and bolting into action before due diligence is exercised. managers are encouraged to heed the words of noted financier, warren buffet (n. d.), who said “i insist on a lot of time being spent, almost every day, to just sit and think. that is very uncommon in american business. i read and think. so i do more reading and thinking, and make less impulse decisions than most people in business.” we offer active waiting as an alternative to the cultural and business demands for quick action. today’s fast-paced modern life, in many ways, has encouraged people to demand things immediately and to be impatient. people eat fast food, use high speed internet, and command that their emails be answered within an hour. active waiting, on the other hand, allows managers time for additional study, research and testing, consulting advisors, and thoughtful deliberation—in a word patience. although some situations require a rapid response, emergencies for example, most day-to-day decisions managers make in the course of their duties allow more time to pause and consider possible courses of action. patience is not only a virtue, but can also be considered essential to sound management. the authors find numerous examples of the importance of patience (active waiting) in business, perhaps none more significant than a study by baumann (2010) that found a firm can improve performance through moderate patience, allowing for some additional exploration of other possibilities. volume 32, number 1 35 rasmusen and yoon (2012), henricks (2009), and birger (2006) support the advantages of active waiting. companies ranging from southwest airlines to lowe’s home improvement stores benefited from being second-movers in their respective industries, resulting in better market positions and stronger financial performance. a famous quote by sun tzu in the art of war (goodreads.com) states “if you wait patiently by the river, the body of your enemy will float by”. like the lion waiting for the perfect time to strike its prey, smart managers and organizations need to take the time to thoroughly evaluate their environment, resisting the urge to act too quickly. as the authors present in this paper, many types of organizations find active waiting the best approach in their industry. the question then, is when will your company management adopt an active waiting strategy? references amsel, a. (1992). frustration theory: many years later. psychological bulletin, 112, 396-399. ashford, s. j., & black, j. s. (1996). proactivity during organizational entry: the role of desire for control. journal of applied psychology, 81, 199-214. bandura, a., & locke, e. a. (2003). negative self-efficacy and goal effects revisited. journal of applied psychology, 88(1), 87-99. barker, j. (1993). paradigms: the business of discovering the future. new york: harper business. baumann, o. (2010). search, failure, and the value of moderate patience. retrieved at http://www.sbr-online.de/pdfarchive/einzelne_pdf/sbr_2010_july_234-259.pdf barratt, e. s., & patton, j. h. (1983). impulsivity: cognitive, behavioral, and psychophysiological correlates. in m. zuckerman (ed.), biological bases of sensation seeking, impulsivity, and anxiety (pp. 77-116). hillside, nj: lawrence erlbaum associates. bazerman, m. h., & moore, d. a. (2008). judgment in managerial decision making (7th ed.).new york: wiley. benjamin, l. t., cavell, t. a., & shallenberger, w. r. (1984). teaching of psychology, 11(3), 133-141. berger, b. (2004, january 26). nasa: one year after columbia—bush’s new vision changes agency’s course midstream, space news business report, retrieved at http://www. space.com/spacenews/businessmonday_040126.html birger, j. (2006). second-mover advantage. fortune, 153(5), 20-21. 36 journal of business strategies blanchard, k., & johnson, s. (1981). the one minute manager. new york: the william morrow company, inc. boice, r. (2000). advice for new faculty members. needham heights, ma: allyn and bacon. briñoll, p., petty, r. e., & tormala, z. l. (2006). the malleable meaning of subjective ease. psychological science, 17(3), 200-206. bruch, h., & ghoshal, s. (2002). beware the busy manager. harvard business review, 80(2), 63-69. bruch, h., & ghoshal, s. (2004). a bias for action: how effective managers harness their willpower, achieve results, and stop wasting time. boston: harvard business school press. bruch, h., & ghoshal, s. (2010). think again: management is the art of doing and getting done. business strategy review, 21(2), 70-75. buffet, w. (n. d.). warren buffet quotes. retrieved at http://www.goodreads.com/ author/quotes/756.warren_buffett campbell, d. j. (2000). the proactive employee: managing workplace initiative. academy of management executive, 14, 52-66. center for advanced health “what is watchful waiting?” retrived at http://www. cfah.org/prepared-patient/make-good-treatment-decisions/ chabris, c. f., & simons, d. j. (2009). the invisible gorilla: how our intuitions deceive us. new york: crown publishing. chamorro-premuzic, t. (2012). less-confident people are more successful. retrieved from http://blogs.hbr.org/2012/07/less-confident-people-are-more-su/ den hartog, d. n., & belschak, f. d. (2007). commitment, affect and initiative at work. journal of occupational and organizational psychology, 80, 601-622. de bono, e. (1968). lateral thinking. london: penguin. desimone, p. (1993). linguistic assumptions in scientific language. contemporary psychodynamics: theory, research & application, 1, 8-17. dutton, j. e., & ashford, s. j. (1993). selling issues to top management. academy of management review, 18, 397-428. eccles, r. g., & nohria, n. (1992). beyond the hype. boston: harvard business school press. ferrari, j. r. (2001). getting things done on time: conquering procrastination. in c. r. snyder, coping with stress: effective people and processes (pp. 30-46). new york: oxford university press. ferrari, j. r., johnson, j. l., & mccown, w. g. (1995). procrastination and task avoidance: theory, research, and treatment. new york: plenum press. volume 32, number 1 37 freud, s. (1959). collected papers, vol. 4. new york: basic books. friedman, t. l. (2005). the world is flat. new york: farrar, straus and giroux. gamble, j., thompson, a., & peteraf, m. (2013). essentials of strategic management, the quest for competitive advantage (3rd ed.). new york: irwin/mcgraw-hill. gladwell, m. (2013). the gift of doubt: albert o. hirschman and the power of failure. the new yorker. retrieved at http://www.newyorker.com/arts/critics/ books/2013/ 06/24/130 624crbo_books_gladwell?currentpage=all glanz, j., & schwartz, j. (2003, september 26). dogged engineer’s effort to assess shuttle damage. the new york times, p. a1. gollwitzer, p. m. (1996). the volitional benefits of planning. in p. m. gollwitzer & j. a. bargh (eds.), the psychology of action: linking cognition and motivation to behavior (pp. 287-312). new york: guilford. gosling, j., & mintzberg, h. (2003, november). the five minds of a manager. harvard business review, 1-9. greenberg, j. (2011). behavior in organizations (10th ed.). upper saddle river, nj: prenticehall. haas, r. b. (2013). masters of their universe: business (and life) secrets taught by four-legged professors. minneapolis, mn: langdon street press. hammond, j. s., keeney, r. l., & raiffa, h. (1998). the hidden traps in decision making. harvard business review, 76(5), 47-48, 50. hammond, j. s., keeney, r. l., & raiffa, h. (1999). smart choices: a practical guide to making better decisions. boston: harvard business press. henricks, m. (2009, june). when second really is the best. entrepreneur, 71-77. honoré, c. (2004). in praise of slow: how a worldwide movement is challenging the cult of speed. new york: harpercollins publishers. howard, d. h., & huang, y. (2012). serious health events and discontinuation of routine cancer screening. medical decision making, 32, 627-635. hughes, j. (director) (1987). ferris bueller’s day off (movie). paramount pictures. ibarra, h. (2003). working identity: unconventional strategies for reinventing your career. cambridge, ma: harvard business school press. jones, g. r., & george, j. m. (2011). contemporary management (seventh ed.). new york: mcgraw-hill/irwin. kahneman, d. p. (2011). thinking, fast and slow. new york: farrar, straus, and giroux. kahneman, d. p., knetsch, j. l., & thaler, r. h. (1991). anomalies: the endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias. the journal of economic perspectives kahneman, d. p. slovic, p., & tversky, a. (eds.). (1982). judgment under uncertainty: heuristics and biases. new york: cambridge university press. 38 journal of business strategies keinan, r., & bereby-meyer, y. (2012). “leaving it to chance”—passive risk taking in everyday life. judgment and decision making, 7(6), 705-715. kelley, r. e. (1998). how to be a star at work: 9 breakthrough strategies you need to succeed. new york: times books. kirkpatrick, s. a., & locke, e. a. (1991). leadership: do traits matter? academy of management executive, 5(2), 48-60. klein, g. (2007). performing a project premortem. harvard business review, 85(9), 18-19. knaus, w. (1973). overcoming procrastination. rational living, 8, 2-7. kogut, t., & dahan, m. (2012). do you look forward to retirement? motivational biases in pension decisions. judgment and decision making, 7, 282-291. langer, e. j. (1989). mindfulness. new york: perscus books. langley, a. (1995). between “paralysis by analysis” and “extinction by instinct.” sloan management review, 36(3), 63-76. lawson, r. (1965). frustration: the development of a scientific concept. new york: macmillan. lepine, j. a., & van dyne, l. (1998). predicting voice behavior in work groups. journal of applied psychology, 83, 853-868. loewenstein, g., & elster, j. (1992). choice over time. new york: sage. marrow, a. j., bowers, d. f., & seashore, s. e. (1967). management by participation. new york: harper and row. mayo, m., kakarika, a. m., pastor, j. c., & brutus, s. (2012). aligning or inflating your leadership self-image? a longitudinal study of responses to peer feedback in mba teams. academy of management learning & education, 11(4), 631-652). minniti, m. (2006). entrepreneurship. westport, cn: greenwood publishing group. mischel, w. (1974). processes in delay gratification. in l. berkowitz (ed.), advances in experimental social psychology, vol. 7 (pp. 249-292). new york: academic press. morrison, e. w. (2002). newcomers’ relationships: the role of social networks during socialization. academy of management journal, 45, 1149-1160. morrison, e. w., & phelps, c. c. (1999). taking charge at work: extrarole efforts to initiate workplace change. academy of management journal, 42, 403-419. nutt, p. c. (1999). surprising but true: half the decisions in organizations fail. academy of management executive, 13 (4), 75-90. oxford english dictionary (2nd ed.). (1989). j. simpson & e. weiner (eds.). oxford: oxford university press. volume 32, number 1 39 parker, s. k., & collins, c. g. (2010). taking stock: integrating and differentiating multiple proactive behaviors. journal of management, 36(3), 633-662. parker, s. k., wall, t. d., & jackson, p. r. (1997). “that’s not my job”: developing flexible employee work orientations. academy of management journal, 40, 899-929. peters, t. j., & waterman, r. h. j. (1982). in search of excellence: lessons from america’s best-run companies. new york: harpertrade. rasmusen, e., & yoon, y. (2012). first versus second mover advantage with information asymmetry about the profitability of new markets. journal of industrial economics, 60(3), 374-405. read, j. d. (1995). the availability heuristic in person identification: the sometimes misleading consequences of enhanced contextual information. applied cognitive psychology, 9(2), 91-121. rogers, w. (n. d.). will rogers legacy: remembering that old cowboy. retrieved at http://www.parks.ca.gov/?page_id=23998 russo, j. e., & schoemaker, p. j. h. (1992). decision traps: ten barriers to brilliant decision-making and how to overcome them. samuelson, r. j. (1995). the good life and its discontents: the american dream in the age of entitlement, 1945-1995. new york: times books. senge, p. m. (2006). the fifth discipline: the art & practice of the learning organization. new york: currency. shah, s., horne, a., & capellá, j. (2012). good data won’t guarantee good decisions. harvard business review, 90(4), 23-25. shakespeare, w. (1596). the merchant of venice. retrieved from http://www.opensource shakespeare.org/views/plays/playmenu.php?workid=merchantvenice stander, p. e., & albon, s. d. (1993). hunting success of lions in a semi-arid environment. symposia of the zoological society of london, 65, 127-143. sull, d. n. (2004). look out for the tunnel vision trap. retrieved from http://www.ft.com/cms/s/2/e0bcb1ac-e576-11d8-bfd2-00000e2511c8. html#axzz2hthbw1xb sull, d. n. (2005). strategy as active waiting. harvard business review, 83(9), 120-129. sun tzu. (n. d.). sun tzu quotes. retrieved at https://www.goodreads.com/ quotes/803224-if-you-wait-patiently-by-the-river-the-body-of united states coast guard. (n. d.). situational awareness. retrieved from http://www.uscg.mil/auxiliary/training/tct/chap5.pdf vanderbilt, t. (n. d.). tom vanderbilt reviews the invisible gorilla. retrieved at http://www.amazon.com/the-invisible-gorilla-intuitions-deceive/dp/0307459667 40 journal of business strategies wald, m. l., & schwartz, j. (2003, august 28). nasa chief promises a shift in attitude. the new york times, p. a23. welch, j. (n. d.). retrieved from http://www.brainyquote.com/quotes/quotes/j/jackwelch 173305.html woodman, t., akehurst, s., hardy, l., & beattie, s. (2010). self-confidence and performance: a little self-doubt helps. psychology of sport and exercise, 11(6), 467-470. brief biographical sketch of authors c.w. von bergen is professor of management and the john massey endowed chair in management at southeastern oklahoma state university. dr. von bergen has authored more than 100 articles for a wide variety of academic journals, focusing on the fields of human resources, employee relations, and organizational behavior issues. martin s. bressler is professor of management & marketing and the john massey endowed chair in entrepreneurship at southeastern oklahoma state university. dr. bressler is a fulbright scholar and served as resource panel expert to the 1995 white house conference on small business. dr. bressler has authored many articles, focusing primarily on small business and entrepreneurship. the urge to merge: the role of governance structures in mergers and acquisitions catherine m. daily purdue university west lafayette, in dan r. dalton indiana university bloomington, in abstract the 1990s have witnessed merger and acquisition activity which rivals that of the 1980s "merger mania." as firms continue to consolidate either within industries or across industries it is appropriate to investigate those a!,pects of a target firm which might attract a bidder. the board of directors, a central decision-making body in the corporation, may provide insights into this process. this study investigates the relationship between board composition and size and the incidence of a firm being targeted for a merger or acquisition. results of a logistic regression analysis of a matched set of target firms and firms not targeted for merger or acquisition reveal that target firms have higher proportions of independent outside directors and more total numbers of directors. moreover, we find that target firms have greater exposure to institutional investors. introduction mergers and acquisitions continue to dominate the corporate landscape. recent mega-mergers and acquisitions within industries such as upjohn co. with pharmacia ab and chase manhattan with chemical bank, as well as those across industries such as walt disney co. with capital cities/abc, are some evidence that the "merger mania" of the 1980s has not subsided (business week, 1995; u.s. news & world report, 1995). a growing body of research focuses on the motives which drive merger and acquisition activity (e.g., amihud & lev, 1978; eckbo, 1983; lubatkin, 1983; roll, 1986). thus far, however, this research has not yet provided consensus regarding the motives of bidder firms (e.g., haunschild, 1993). an enhanced appreciation for those elements of a target firm which are attractive to a bidder firm will enable both researchers and practitioners to gain a more comprehensive understanding of the likelihood of any given firm being targeted as a merger or acquisition candidate. 152 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 the structure of firms' board of directors may provide insight into the attractiveness of a target firm. the board of directors is central to a decision to engage in merger or acquisition activity. ultimate approval of major strategic moves lies with firms' board of directors (d' aventi & kesner, 1993; paul, 1995). some observers have noted that board activity may be greatest during strategic shifts such as a merger or acquisition (lorsch & maciver, 1989; zald, 1969). while the board of directors is clearly central to merger and acquisition activity, we still know very little about its role (see e.g., d' aveni & kesner, 1993; gibbs, 1993; haunschild, 1993; walsh & kosnik, 1993 for notable exceptions). the vast majority of mergers and acquisitions research has focused on firms' management, not their boards of directors. this study expands cufrent research by focusing on target firms' board composition and size. one reason bidder firms may target another firm is because they expect little resistance from the target firm's board of directors (d' aveni & kesner, 1993). firms dominated by outside directors, for example, may prove quite open to negotiations should the proposed deal be valuable from a shareholder perspective. boards dominated by target firm management may be expected to strongly resist a merger or acquisition due to fears of job loss. we examine the extent to which board composition discriminates between those firms engaging in merger and acquisition activity as compared to those firms not targeted by bidder firms. we also consider the impact of board size. it may be that target firms are characterized by smaller boards, leaving fewer numbers of individuals with which bidder firms must negotiate. alternatively, larger boards may be attractive to bidder firms due to the scope of linkages to a target firms' task environment. target firms and the board of directors there is considerable consensus in the conceptual literature that boards of directors can be most appropriately configured with a preponderance of outside directors (e.g., zahra & pearce, 1989). the rationale for this preference is the expectation that outsiders, non-management directors, bring an objectivity to their role as directors not provided by insiders. this objectivity is expected to directly benefit the shareholders whom directors serve (nussbaum & dobrzynski, 1987). we recognize that there are several potential benefits to inside directors, such as their superior level of firm specific knowledge (baysinger & hoskisson, 1990; fama, 1980; fama & jensen, 1983). additionally, inside directors have been found to be effective in ceo compensation decisions (boyd, 1994). as will be developed, however, inside directors may be subject to conflicts of interest which complicate their ability to objectively evaluate a merger or acquisition opportunity (johnson & siegel, 1987). while outsider dominated boards may effectively mitigate potential conflicts of interest that insiders face fall 1996 daily & dalton: the urge to merge 153 in this situation (e.g., fama, 1980; mizruchi, 1983), jauch, martin and osborn (1981) provide compelling evidence that insiders may experience some difficulty in separating the threat of job loss as a result of a merger or acquisition from their fiduciary responsibility to shareholders. recently researchers have begun investigating distinctions among outside directors. it may be that differing levels of objectivity can be expected across different categories of outside directors (e.g., daily & dalton, 1994; kosnik, 1987). independent outside directors (hereafter referred to as outside directors) are recognized as those directors whose association to the firm is strictly a function of their role as directors. these directors are believed to be best positioned to provide objective service to the firm. affiliated directors maintain personal or professional relationships with either the firm or firm management. these affiliations may impede the ability of the directors to be objective in their service to the firm and the firm's shareholders (e.g., daily & dalton, 1994). board composition may yield insights into directors' predispositions regarding resisting a merger or acquisition (gibbs, 1993; johnson & siegel, 1987; zalecki, 1993), as it has been identified as one of several dimensions of the balance of power in an organization (finkelstein, 1992). target firm inside directors, for example, may resist merger and acquisition opportunities due to the increased likelihood of job loss or a dramatic redefinition of job responsibilities (e.g., gutknecht & keys, 1993; jensen & ruback, 1983; morek, shleifer & vishny, 1988; walsh, 1988, 1989; walsh & ellwood, 1991). inside directors' fears are apparently well-founded. both corporate raiders and academics have commented that a primary motive in acquiring a firm is to increase firm value by replacing ineffective managers (fama & jensen, 1983; herman & lowenstein, 1988; leahn, 1988; jensen & meckling, 1976; pickens, 1986). outside directors, due to their independence from firm management; may be able to effectively control behaviors which conflict with shareholder interests (fama & jensen, 1983). moreover, we might expect outside directors to be responsive to organizational moves which benefit firm shareholders. as a consequence of their perceived ability to control managerial opportunism and an expectation that they will have a strong shareholder orientation, target firms with outsider dominated boards may be more attractive to bidder firms than boards with alternative board configurations (e.g., d' aveni & kesner, 1993). research by brickley and james (1987) suggests that board composition may be a significant factor in the merger and acquisition process. they found that the proportion of outside directors was significantly lower on boards of banks in states that restrict banking acquisitions as compared to those states without such restrictions. based on their findings, brickley and james concluded that outside directors play a major role in evaluating takeover proposals. accordingly, we hypothesize: hypothesis 1: target firms will be characterized by greater proportions of outside directors than non-target firms. 154 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 due to the sophisticated financing requirements and legal maneuverings inherent in the merger and acquisition process, it may be that target firms with higher proportions of outside directors who are lawyers and investment bankers may facilitate a merger or acquisition (e.g., d' aveni & kesner, 1993; kesner, shapiro & sharma, 1994; lofthouse, 1984). bidder firms may perceive that targets with strong legal and financial representation are best able to appreciate the intricacies involved in a merger or acquisition, especially from the shareholder perspective. accordingly, we hypothesize: hypothesis 2: target firms will be characterized by greater proportions of directors who are lawyers and investment bankers than non-target firms. finally, the size of the board may impact the attractiveness of a target firm. consistent with the resource function of boards (e.g., pfeffer & salancik, 1978), large board size may be some indication of the variety of external constituents with which the firm must work (e.g., chaganti, mahajan & sharma, 1985; pfeffer, 1972). in this view, directors provide critical linkages to the external environment which may enable the firm to more effectively manage its interdependencies, as well as provide access to important firm resources (e.g., pfeffer & salancik, 1978; provan, 1980; stearns & mizruchi, 1993). directors with these linkages and interdependencies may be perceived as a critical component of a successful merger or acquisition. while a larger board may enable the firm to more effectively address a broader range of constituents, it may also be less manageable from a control perspective (chaganti et ai., 1985). moreover, a larger board is likely to be more heterogeneous than a smaller board, perhaps increasing the difficulty of reaching consensus when faced with a decision to engage in a merger or acquisition. rather than serving as a means to enhance the assimilation of a target firm with the bidder, a larger board may be perceived as an obstacle due to the potential for many differing interests which must be effectively addressed in the negotiation process. smaller boards, then, may prove more attractive to bidder firms than larger boards. based on the lack of consistency regarding the anticipated impact of board size we hypothesize: hypothesis 3a: target firms ~vill have greater total numbers of directors than non-target firms. hypothesis 3b: target firms will have fewer total numbers of directors than noll-target firms. fall 1996 daily & dalton: the urge to merge methods 155 this sample consists of 55 finns engaging in a merger or acquisition during the years 1987-1992 and a matched pair of 55 control firms. target firms were selected from the list of top 100 announced deals reported annually by mergers and acquisitions. in order to ensure data availability only those firms which were publicly-traded at the time of the acquisition or merger and involved in a "traditional" merger or acquisition (i.e., one finn acquires another finn) were included (haunschild, 1993: 573; see also datta, 1991). also, firms operating in regulated environments (e.g., utilities, railroads, airlines) and banks and financial institutions were excluded (flagg, giroux & wiggins, 1991; healy, palepu & ruback, 1992; hennalin & weisbach, 1988). we relied on ward's business directory of us. private and public companies to generate a set of publicly-traded control finns by matching targets on the basis of four-digit sic codes and finn size (e.g., daily & dalton, 1994; hambrick & 0' aveni, 1992; kesner & johnson, 1990). target finns with no comparable match listed in wards business directory of us. private and public companies were excluded. logistic regression analysis confirmed that matched finns did not significantly differ from target finns on the basis of finn size, as measured by the natural logarithm of sales, assets, and number of fulltime employees. variables the dependent variable is dichotomous; either the finn was the target of a merger or acquisition (coded as i) or not targeted (coded as 0) during the focal year. the three independent variables include: total number of directors, proportion of outside directors (directors with no discernible tie to the firm or its management other than in their service as directors) and the proportion of outside directors who are lawyers or investment bankers. these data were collected from corporate proxy statements. several control variables are appropriate for inclusion in these analyses. researchers have long speculated about the liabilities of newness and size (stinchcombe, 1965). younger finns may be more likely to fail as a result of environmental pressures or organizational factors and may possess fewer resources than more established finns (e.g., van de ven, hudson & schroeder, 1984), limiting their ability to protect themselves from a merger or acquisition. larger finns typically have greater resources available which might discourage bidders from pursuing a target due to the prohibitively high costs of financing a large transaction (morek et al, 1988) and the ability to effectively resist a bidder (holl & pickering, 1988). finn age is computed from the time the finn was founded. finn size is the natural logarithm of sales revenues. these data were collected from wards business directory of us. private and public companies. we also control for finn perfonnance in these analyses. there is some evidence that firms with abnormally low performance are more likely to become 156 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no.2 targets (e.g., asquith, 1983; bartley & boardman, 1986; bradley, desai & kim, 1983; hasbrouck, 1985). perfonnance may indicate the availability of resources which may be needed to resist a bidder (d' aveni & kesner, 1993). relying on guidance from flagg et al. (1991) three categories of performance indicators are included in these analyses: profitability (return on assets), liquidity (current ratio), and leverage (debt-to-equity ratio). all financial data were collected from corporate annual reports, moody's industrial manual, and moody's over-the-counter manual. equity holdings may also impact the incidence of being targeted for a merger or acquisition. institutional holdings and large block holdings have been the subject of previous investigation in corporate restructuring (e.g., bethel & liebeskind, 1993; johnson, hoskisson & hitt, 1993). their anticipated impact, however, is unclear. bidding firms may be attracted to target firms with significant institutional holdings expecting institutions to sell their holdings to the highest bidder (e.g., buchholtz & ribbens, 1994; palmieri, 1986). alternatively, institutions may support incumbent firm management (0' aveni & kesner, 1993; ikenberry & lakonishok, 1993). similar rationale would apply for large block holders (individuals holding five percent or more of firm's stock). institutional holdings are measured as the percentage of firms' stock held by institutional investors. large block holders are captured as the percentage of firms' stock held by five percent or greater equity holders. these data were collectcd from standard & poor's corporation security owner's stock guide and corporate proxy statements. analyses given the dichotomous nature of the dependent variable we rely on logistic regression analysis (likelihood ratio method). this method combines aspects of hierarchical multiple regression and discriminant function analysis. results table i provides thc descriptive statistics and inter-item correlations for the study variables. results of the logistic regression analysis are reported in table 2. the baseline hit-rate for these analyses is 50 percent; half of the firms were targeted, half were not. in the first step the financial, firm size, and firm age control variables were included in the analyses. as demonstrated in table 2, these variables do not result in a significantly improved model (58.18 percent hit-rate) as compared to the baseline model. while three of these five variables are independently significant, this information must be interpreted cautiously given a non-significant model. at the next step the stock holding control variables were added. inclusion of these variables results in an improved model, as demonstrated by the improvement chi-square (65.45 percent hit-rate). based on the logistic coefficients we can determine that this improvement is a function of significantly greater "i1 table 1 ~ ...... descriptive statistics and inter-item correlations '-0'-0 01 variable mean s.d. (i) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (i) finn size 6.55 1.39 (2) finn age 58.97 40.32 .37*** t;:, l.:l ~ (3) profitability .04 .11 .24* .23* r<> (4) liquidity 2.31 1.50 -.39*** -.11 -.18 ~........... c:. (5) leverage 37.67 158.12 -.19 .05 .15 .24* ;::.. ~ (6) institutional holdings 46.70 19.90 .24* .16 .24* -.07 -.10 '"c::: (7) large block holdings 27.62 24.87 -.30*** -.18 -.05 -.10 .00 -.49*** ~'"..... c:. (8) outside director proportion .26 .is .21* .22* -.01 -.05 -.05 .28** -.31 *** ~ (9) lawyer/banker proportion .14 .13 -.19 -.22* -.08 .00 -.07 .15 .08 -.25** ~ '" (10) total directors 10.37 3.45 .59*** .33*** .07 -.24* -.18 .16 -.20* .25** -.17 *p < .05 **p < .01 ***p < .001 -vi -.l 158 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no.2 table 2 logistic regression analysis of target and nontarget firms coefficients se logmodel improvement sig. hit-rate likelihood chi-square chi.square baseline 152.49 50.00% ~ 147.35 5.14 5.14 .399 58.18% firm size , -.50* .24 firm age profitability , -4.80* 2.22 liquidity• -.29* .17 leverage ~ 136.72 10.63 10.63 .005 64.45% institutional holdings , 5.16*** 1.58 large block holdings lrl!...ilij;! 128.13 8.59 8.59 .035 70.00% outside director proportion• -2.21* 1.34 lawyerlban ker proportion total directors . .17* .08 • indicates variable was a significant indicator in the step in which it was entered. *p < .05 **p < .01 ***p < .001 fall 1996 daily & dalton: the urge to merge 159 exposure to institutional holdings for target firms, as compared to those firms not targeted. the final step includes the board composition and size variables. this model results in a significant improvement chi-square and a 70 percent hitrate. it is possible to directly address the research hypotheses based on the logistic coefficients. as demonstrated in table 2, hypotheses 1 and 3a are supported. target firms have significantly higher proportions of outside directors than do those firms not targeted. also, target finn boards are larger than those of non-target firms, lending support to the resource view. hypothesis two was not supported. there is no statistically significant difference in the proportion of lawyers and investment bankers serving target firms as compared to those firms not targeted. in sum, these analyses demonstrate that target firms have higher proportions of outside directors, larger numbers of directors, and greater exposure to institutional investors. discussion these findings demonstrate the importance of the outside director in mergers and acquisitions. those firms with higher proportions of outside directors are apparently more attractive to bidder firms than are firms with lower proportions of outside directors. these results may suggest that outside directors are perceived by bidder firms as being more amenable to a potential merger or acquisition; le., they are more willing to "make a deal." perhaps those directors with no personal or professional ties to the firm are able to evaluate merger and acquisition opportunities based on a return-to-shareholder analysis which is not complicated with the concerns of inside directors for job security or the concerns of affiliated directors for the potential loss of business relationships. an alternative view, however, is that outside directors are willing to "make a deal," but that the deal does not serve target firm shareholders as well as more director resistance to the merger/acquisition proposition. attractiveness to the acquiring firm may be largely dependent on consummating a deal which best serves the interests of the bidding firm's shareholders. perhaps the anticipated resistance by inside and affiliated directors makes a target firm less at· tractive to a bidding firm, but that this resistance serves to increase the purchase price an outcome which is clearly attractive to target finn shareholders, but not to the bidding firm shareholders (jarrell et ai., 1988). we would note, however, that target firms' board of directors have apparently been responsible to their shareholders in merger and acquisition situations. prior research has demonstrated that excess returns, premiums averaging approximately 30 percent, are realized primarily by target firm shareholders; this same benefit is not shared by bidding firm shareholders (jarrell, brickley & netter, 1988; jarrell & poulsen, 1989; jensen & ruback, 1983; zalecki, 1993). the finding that larger boards are more attractive to bidder firms may indicate the importance of the director's resource role. these analyses may sug160 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 gest that bidder firms appreciate the linkages that directors provide to firms' external environment. given the increasing complexity of the business environment, greater numbers of directors may indicate a convenient means for gaining access to those resources most crucial for the effective functioning of the business. access to these resources may prove critical to the long-term success of the merger or acquisition. this resource role is particularly important in light of past research which has demonstrated that financial benefits to the acquiring firm may not be immediately apparent at the time of the bid (jarrell et al., 1988). it may be that bidder firms see the long-term potential of directors and that this dominates any short-term loss. an interesting finding of this study is that the presence of lawyers and investment bankers does not differentiate between target and non-target firms. past research has suggested that lawyers, in particular, would be particularly useful in negotiating a merger or acquisition agreement (e.g., d' aveni & kesner, 1993). lawyers and investment bankers arguably possess the specialized knowledge often needed in both structuring and completing a merger or acquisition agreement. it may be, however, that no statistically significant differences were found because the complexity of the environments in which most firms operate require the presence of these specialized directors. perhaps lawyers and investment bankers are a necessity on today's corporate boards. alternatively, it may be that bidder firms view target firm lawyers and investment bankers as one more impediment in successfully negotiating a deal. bidder firms may view their own legal and financial counsel as the only beneficial counsel in this domain. these results also have interesting implications regarding the role of institutional investors. institutional investors have been the target of some criticism for reportedly supporting management, not shareholders, in the case of a conflict between management and shareholder interests (e.g., graves, 1988; lipton, 1987; mieher, 1993). these results would seem to indicate the opposite; larger percentages of institutional holdings are positively associated with being targeted. as with outside directors, institutions may be perceived by bidder firms as being open to objectively reviewing the benefits to shareholders of a potential merger or acquisition. institutions are apparently not as loyal to firm management as some critics have charged (e.g., thompson, 1994). as with outside directors, however, there is the concern over whose shareholders most directly benefit from a merger/acquisition. implications for practice and research the competitive environment in which firms operate today requires organizational leaders to constantly monitor means for gaining competitive advantage. the mergers and acquisitions environment makes this task challenging. mergers and acquisitions are extending beyond consolidations across industries and are increasingly within industry consolidations (e.g., business week, 1995; fall 1996 daily & dalton: the urge to merge 161 us. news & world report, 1995). with much of recent merger and acquisition activity being driven by a desire to control distribution networks, firms missing the opportunity to benefit from industry consolidation are likely to be confronted by issues of organizational survival (us. news & world report, 1995; wysocki, 1995). "big is better" is back with a vengeance (us. news & world report, 1995: 46). with the acceleration of merger and acquisition activity, managers may benefit from guidance on those elements of a firm's governance structure which are discussed in this study. knowledge of the types of board configurations which attract a bidder firm may assist firm management in appropriately structuring their own board of directors and in assessing the viability of potential targets. this would be especially important for those firms seeking a "strategic" merger or acquisition, for example, in order to remain competitive in a rapidly changing environment. moreover, understanding the role of boards of directors in this arena is potentially time and resource saving given the recent trend toward using the proxy system to unseat unfriendly directors (lipin, 1995). proxy contests can consume a considerable amount of time and financial resources. perhaps careful attention to the composition and size of potential target firm boards will provide bidding firms with valuable information regarding anticipated resistance to a proposed deal, as well as the type of resources available once the deal is consummated. careful attention to ways in which the composition and size of a target firm's board may either save resources or provide future resources to the bidder firm may be a step toward improving the returns to bidder firm shareholders. the results of this study, coupled with the consistency of merger and acquisition activity, would suggest the need for further attention to these important governance issues. references amihud. y., and b. lev. "risk reduction as a managerial motive for conglomerate mergers." bell journal of economics 12 (1978): 605-617. asquith, p. "merger bids, uncertainty, and stockholder returns." journal of financial economics 11 (1983): 51-83. bartley, 1. and c. boardman. "the replacement-cost adjusted valuation ratio as a discriminator among takeover target firms." journal of economics and business 38(1), (1986): 41-55. baysinger, b. and r. e. hoskisson. "the composition of boards of directors and strategic control: effects on corporate strategy." academy of management review 15 (1990): 72-87. 162 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 bethel, j. e. and j. liebeskind. 'the effects of ownership structure on corporate restructuring." strategic management journal 14 (1983): 15-31. "big!" u.s. news & world report (september ii, 1995): 46-48. boyd, b. k. "board control and ceo compensation." strategic management journal 15 (1994): 335-344. bradley, m., a. desai and e. h. kim. "the rationale behind interfirm tender offers: information or synergy?" journal of financial economics ii (1983): 183-206. brickley, j. a. and c. m. james. "the takeover market, corporate board composition, and ownership structure: the case of banking." journal of law and economics 30 (1987): 161-180. buchholtz, a. k. and b. a. ribbens. "role of chief executive officers in takeover resistance: effects of ceo incentives and individual characteristics." academy of management journal 37 (1994): 554-579. chaganti, r. s., v. mahajan and s. sharma. "corporate board size, composition, and corporate failures in retailing industry." journal of management studies 22 (1985): 400-417. daily, c. m. and d. r. dalton. "bankruptcy and corporate governance: the impact of board composition and structure." academy of management journal 37 (1994): 1603-1617. datta, d. k. "organizational fit and acquisition performance: effects of post-acquisition integration." strategic management journal 12 (1991): 281-297. d' aveni, r. a. and i. f. kesner. "top managerial prestige, power and tender offer response: a study of elite social networks and target firm cooperation during takeovers." organization science 4 (1993): 123-151. eckbo, e. h. "horizontal mergers, collusion, and stockholder wealth." journal of financial economics 11 (1983): 241-274. fama, e. f. "agency problems and the theory of the firm." journal of political economy 88 (1980): 288-307. fama, e. f. and m. c. jensen. "separation of ownership and control." journal of law and economics 26 (1983): 301-325. finkelstein, s. "power in top management teams: dimensions, measurement, and validation." academy of management journal 35 (1992): 439-450. flagg, j. c., g. a. giroux and c. e. wiggins. "predicting corporate bankruptcy using failing firms." review of financial economics 1 (1991): 67-78. fall 1996 daily & dalton: the urge to merge 163 gibbs, p. a. "determinants of corporate restructuring: the relative importance of corporate governance, takeover threat, and free cash flow." strategic management journal 14 (1993): 51-68. graves, s. b. "institutional ownership and corporate r&d in the computer industry." academy of management journal 31 (1988): 417-428. gutknecht, j. e. and j. b. keys. "mergers, acquisitions and takeovers: maintaining morale of survivors and protecting employees." acagemy of management exes;utive 7(3), (1993): 26-36. hambrick, d. c. and r. a. d' aveni. "top team deterioration as part of the downward spiral of large corporate bankruptcies." manas-ement science 38 (1992): 14451466. hasbrouck, j. 'the characteristics of takeover targets and other measures." journal of banking and finance 9 (1985): 351-362. haunschild, p. r. "interorganizational imitation: the impact of interlocks on corporate acquisition activity." administrative science ouarterly 38 (1993): 564-592. healy, p. m., k. g. palepu and r. s. ruback. "does corporate performance improve after mergers?" journal of financial economics 31 (1992): 135-175. hermalin, b. e. and m. s. weisbach. "the determinants of board composition." rand journal of economics 9 (1988): 589-606. herman, e. s. and l. lowenstein. "the efficiency effects of hostile takeovers." in knights. raiders. and targets. eds. j. c. coffee, l. lowenstein and r. roseackerman. new york: oxford university press, ]983. holl, p. and 1. f. pickering. "the determinants and effects of actual, abandoned and contested mergers." managerial and decision economics 9 (1988): 1-19. leahn, c. "kahn on icahn." fortune (february 29, 1988): 54-58. ikenberry, d. and j. lakonishok. "corporate governance through the proxy contest: evidence and implications." journal of business 66 (t 993): 405-435. jarrell, g. a., j. a. brickley and j. netter. "the market for corporate control: the empirical evidence since 1980." journal of economic perspectives (winter, 1988): 4968. jarrell. g. a. and a. b. poulsen. "the returns to acquiring firms in tender offers: evidence from three decades." financial management (autumn, ] 983): 12-19. jauch, l. r., t. n. martin and r. n. osborn. "top management under fire." journal of business strategy 1(4), (1981): 33-41. 164 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no.2 jensen, m. c. and w. h. meckling. "theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure." journal of financial economics 3 (1976): 305-360. jensen, m. c. and r. s. ruback. "the market for corporate control: the scientific evidence." journal of financial economics 11 (1983): 5-50. johnson, r. a., r. e. hoskisson and m. a. hitt. "board of director involvement in restructuring: the effects of board versus managerial controls and characteristics." strategic management journal 14 (1993): 33-50. johnson, 1. 1. and m. siegel. "corporate mergers: redefining the role of target directors." university of pennsylvania law review 136 (1987): 315-416. kesner, 1. f. and r. b. johnson. "an investigation of the relationship between board composition and stockholder suits." strategic management journal 11 (1990): 327336. kesner, 1. f., d. l. shapiro and a. sharma. "brokering mergers: an agency theory perspective on the role of representatives." academy of management journal 37 (1994): 703-721. kosnik, r. d...greenmail: a study of board performance in corporate governance." administrative science quarterly 32 (1987): 163-185. "land of the giants." business week (september 11, 1995): 34-35. lipin, s. "more potent weapons dwell in takeover arsenal." the wall street journal (september 9, 1995): cl, c12. lipton, m. "corporate governance in the age of finance corporatism." university of pennsylvania law review 136 (1987): 1-72. lofthouse, s. "strategy and tactics for resisting take-over." long range planning 17(4), (1984): 38·50. lorsch, j. w. and e. maciver. pawns or potentates: the reality of america's corporate boards. boston: harvard business school press. 1989. lubatkin. m. "mergers and the performance of the acquiring firm." academy of management journal 8 (1983): 218-225. mieher, s. "weak force, shareholder activism, despite hoopla, leaves most ceos unscathed; only big, famous companies draw consistent scrutiny of institutional owners a case study in mississippi." the wall street journal (may 24, 1993): ai. mizruchi, m. s. "who controls whom? an examination of the relation between management and boards of directors in large american corporations." academy of management review 8 (1983): 426·435. fall 1996 daily & dalton: the urge to merge 165 morck, r, a. shleifer and r w. vishny. "characteristics of hostile and friendly takeovers." in corporate takeovers: causes and consequences. ed. a. j. auerbach. chicago: university of chicago press, 1988. nussbaum, b. and j. h. dobrzynski. "the battle for corporate control." business week (may 18, 1987): 102-109. palmieri, f. w. "fiduciary responsibilities under erisa in corporate takeovers." journal of comorate taxation 13(2), (1986): 127-142. paul, c. e. "scouting the m&a landscape for quality targets." merger & acquisitions (marchiapril, 1995): 20-26. pfeffer, j. "size and composition of corporate boards of directors: the organization and its environment." administrative science ouarterly 17 (1972): 218-228. pfeffer, j. "size, composition, and function of hospital boards of directors: a study of organization-environment linkage." administrative science ouarterly 18 (1973): 349-364. pfeffer, j. and g. r salancik. the external control of organizations: a resource depend'ence perspective. new york: harper & row, 1978. pickens, t. b. "professions of a short-termer." harvard business review 64(3), (1986): 75-79. provan, k. g. "board power and organizational effectiveness among human service agencies." academy of management journal 23 (1980): 221-236. roll, r. "the hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers." journal of business 59 (1986): 197-216. stearns, l. b. and m. s. mizruchi. "board composition and corporate financing: the impact of financial institution representation on borrowing." academy of management journal 36 (1993): 603-618. stinchcombe, a. "social structure and organizations." in handbook of organizations. ed. j. g. march. chicago: rand mcnally, 1965. thompson, l. m. "a corporate governance committee of the board." directors & boards (summer, 1994): 37-39. van de ven, a. h., r. hudson and d. m. schroeder. "designing new business startups: entrepreneurial, organizational, and ecological considerations." journal of management 10 (1984): 87-107. walsh, j. p. ''top management turnover following mergers and acquisitions." strategic management journal 9 (1988): 173-183. 166 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 2 walsh, j. p. "doing a deal: merger and acquisition negotiations and their impact upon target company top management turnover." strategic management journal 10 (1989): 307-322. walsh, j. p. and j. w. ellwood. "mergers, acquisitions, and the pruning of managerial deadwood." strategic management journal 12 (1991): 201-217. walsh, j. p. and r. d. kosnik. "corporate raiders and their disciplinary role in the market for corporate control." academy of management journal 36 (1993): 671-700. wysocki, b. "improved distribution, not better production is key goal in mergers." the wall street journal, (august 29, 1995): al-a2. zahra, s. a. and j. a. pearce. "boards of directors and corporate financial performance: a review and integrative model." journal of management 15 (1989): 291-334. zald, m. n. "the power and functions of boards of directors: a theoretical synthesis." american journal of sociology 75 (1969): 97-111. zalecki, p. h. "the corporate governance roles of the inside and the outside directors." university of toledo law review 24 (1993): 831-858. catherine m. daily is an assistant professor of management in the krannert graduate school of management, purdue university. she received her ph.d. degree in strategic management from the graduate school of business, indiana university. her research interests include corporate governance, strategic leadership, the dynamics of business failure, ownership structures, and research methods. dan r. dalton is the samuel and pauline glaubinger chair and associate dean of the graduate school of business, indiana university. he received his ph.d. degree from university of california. his research interests include corporate governance, managerial ethics, corporate social resonsibility, and research methods. the urge to merge: the role of governance structures in mergers and acquisitions millennials’ strategic decision making through the lens of corporate social responsibility and financial management reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 1 journal of business strategies doi:10.54155/jbs.38.2.125-146 millennials’ strategic decision making through the lens of corporate social responsibility and financial management mark reavisa, kuldeep singhb, jack tuccic a finance department, university of central oklahoma, edmond, ok 73034. mreavis1@uco.edu (corresponding author). b department of management and marketing, arkansas tech university, russellville, ar 72801. ksingh1@atu.edu. c william m. lemley endowed chair, department of management and marketing, arkansas tech university, russellville, ar 72801. jtucci@atu.edu. key words corporate social responsibility; millennials; strategic decision making, aacsb; stakeholder theory abstract corporate social responsibility (csr) is the touchstone for millennials when looking at the means for making their world a better place. higher education’s focus on csr has allowed millennials to focus their decision-making using a csr/stakeholder approach to financial management decisions. millennials’ support for a csr/stakeholder approach has grown as they have been completing college. the csr/stakeholder approach has increased partly due to social awareness created by curricula that highlights areas of social and environmental inequality. this csr/stakeholder approach has recently emerged as a bona fide strategic management option globally. this paper extends csr research by evaluating millennial financial decisions and the resulting competitive company performance in a widely used business simulation. proactive university equality initiatives, resulting in curriculum changes, reinforce millennials’ ethos of social and environmental sustainability. as millennials will soon take the reins of industry, the results of their ethos will significantly influence society. this work is licensed under a creative commons attribution-noncommercial 4.0 international license. copyright (c) 2021 mark reavis, kuldeep singh, jack tucci. mailto:mreavis1@uco.edu mailto:ksingh1@atu.edu mailto:jtucci@atu.edu https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/4.0/ https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc/4.0/ 126 reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 1. introduction the advancement of both individuals and society is strategically accomplished through education. advancement is further reinforced by institutions of higher learning and by their governing accrediting bodies through accreditation requirements or initiatives. the association to advance collegiate schools of business (aacsb) (the world’s leading business accrediting body) nearly three decades ago, put as one of its required standards the subject of business ethics. many business schools implemented a required ethics course(s), or infused ethics in several required courses. by 2020, the aacsb “standard 9” required that each institution shall have “engagement and social impact” and must have measures in place which specifically address corporate social responsibility (csr). csr is an active component in the education of the students through “hands-on” community projects as service-learning initiatives (stonkute et al., 2018; larran et al., 2018). “service learning” is a common means to meet the standard 9 through a minimum number of hours of service, or award diploma citations/notations to the student who maintain a specified level of participation (miftachal et al., 2018). the question remains: “does the curriculum engaged by a college of business have an influence on business students?” a secondary question closely related is: “do the students engaged by this curriculum have changed social norms?” millennials perceive an ethical duty to reengineer society and become change agents (howe & strauss, 2000). nevertheless, a research question begs to be answered: “will millennials make strategic decisions with a csr focus or a profit focus?” the term 'millennial' as used in this research refers not only to a generation of young people by age, but also to their worldview and society's perception of them (ohio university, 2020). by age, this generation was born approximately 1982-2000. this is the sample boundary used in this study. millennial’s worldview is much more social-oriented than their parents or grandparents. they are activists and seek to make the world a better place. society regards this generation as special and as having a capacity for greatness (howe & strauss, 2000). this generation is inherently different than their predecessors. "the millennial future is what america is destined to become" (howe & strauss, 2000, p. 367). reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 127 2. the model the aacsb is global accrediting body and as such many international schools of business incorporate csr (ferrell et al., 2016; prutina, 2016; serban, 2015). curriculum changes are being made to benefit society through the efforts of students, business schools, and in the long-term, business (horng et al., 2019). the ability to manage companies while improving societal imbalances is paramount and it has shifted the focus from a stockholder approach to a stakeholder approach in response to these societal changes (reavis et al., 2017; elalfy, 2020). global business school accreditation standards (aacsb) have aided business schools in transitioning to a csr curriculum from an ethics focused curriculum. aacsb standards recognize the shift of business practices from a stockholder to stakeholder approach (reavis & orr, 2021). the aacsb standards provide encouragement/guidance to business schools/students to teach/learn how businesses can be successful and effect positive social change. this paradigm shift is ultimately focused on movement toward a sustainability ethos of decision making, based on ethical behavior and social responsibility. the model in figure 1 is depicted with these drivers of the change, ethical behavior and csr, providing upward force. this force more than supports changes in thought, it is a driving force for societal evolution of thought about people, profit, and planet. this model contends that this evolution of thought is times based; however, this change will accelerate when the current millennials emerge in the “c” level suite. the efforts of aacsb to require csr in the early 2000’s as reflected by service-learning initiatives, the natural outcome is the emerging sustainability model and certified type b corporations. universities have spent countless person-hours modifying business education which warrants a review of the results of these changes in the curriculum. if the curriculum is truly impactful, then the predictions by the brookings institute bear closer watch (winograd & heis, 2018). earlier studies analyzed and discovered that millennials have a stakeholder preference over a stockholder approach and indicate that csr decisions stem from a values proposition (ferrell et al., 2016; serban, 2015). a further study also found that a student’s chosen major had an influence on their decision making; those with a qualitative, organizational behavioral approach preferring a stakeholder approach (reavis & tucci, 2020). in comparison, students who majored in 128 reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 quantitative studies in business, finance, economics, and accounting, still leaned towards a stakeholder approach but less so than their organizational behavior focused counterparts. 3. literature review stockholder and stakeholder theory: contrasting perspectives smith and ronnegard in 2016 posited that stockholders must be held in the highest regard in all business decisions because they risked personal capital for the profits of invested business. they drew their philosophy from adam smith’s writing in wealth of nations, that laid the foundational concepts of stockholder’s risk. following that thought, stockholder theory contends that it is the “individual risk taker” who has the right to engage in socially responsible actions of their own choosing. this approach was strongly supported by milton friedman (1970). smith and friedman acknowledge that a business cannot pursue profits at any cost, but must deal with “externalities” or rules, and quantifiable analysis supports their position (lopez et al., 2007). in impactors sustainability corporate social responsibility (csr) ethics figure 1. evolution towards sustainability: the efficacy of change in accreditation standards reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 129 contrast, those who argue in favor of csr argue that there are benefits to the stakeholder approach (aquilera et al., 2007). the stanford research institute defines “stakeholder” as "groups without whose support the organization would cease to exist" (freeman, 1983). stakeholder theory as championed by freeman, 1983, came to be defined simply as interconnectedness. symbiotic relationships in society between individuals and corporations explain why companies engaged in csr to increase employee affective commitment (prutina, 2016). stakeholders include employees, suppliers, vendors, customers, creditors, government entities, resource communities, etc. (post et al., 2002). stakeholders are affected by the business’ operations and the business is obligated to provide value to these various stakeholders to some degree at the expense of stockholders (rausch, 2011). measures and methods of the stakeholder approach and sustainability the balanced scorecard approach is a method of quantifying the results of business decisions in various identified areas in a semi-holistic approach. the scorecard is used by a wide range of entities, from business to government to military to nonprofits and is a planning and management tool that aligns activities with organizational goals and missions (cokins, 2013). the balanced scorecard institute (bsi) helps organizations develop a scorecard for their organization through the development of a framework of nine steps organized around four core components: customers/ stakeholders, financial/ stewardship, internal processes, and organizational capacity (“nine steps to success”, 2017). the triple bottom line (tbl), another approach to measuring csr, was mainstreamed by john elkington’s book (1997) cannibals with forks: the triple bottom line of 21st century business. the key aspect is the sustainability of the business through performance in financial, social, and environmental areas (slaper & hall, 2011). the concept is simple; along with the profit-making operational decisions of a company, there are two other operational areas to address: people and planet. these three combined provide the basis for the 3p model. while there is still not a universal tbl that fully addresses sustainability, companies are finding that it is useful in showcasing their corporate social responsibility initiatives (slaper & hall, 2011). wilburn & wilburn (2015) advise that a 2010 study showed companies that have proof of positive csr programs enjoyed higher sales among global customers that were willing to pay more for their products. 130 reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 a certified b corp is a company that has been certified by the independent, non-profit organization b lab founded in 2006 by three entrepreneurs (honeyman, 2015). their mission was to create a corporate entity that was both about maximizing wealth and positively impacting society and the environment through sustainability initiatives. a certified b corp must establish the public benefit they are pursuing. (b lab, 2017). it could be a specific public benefit that addresses such social issues as unemployment, nutrition, or education. a certified b corp must assess their overall social and environmental impact using an accepted third-party standard for their industry. b lab specifically directs that the company’s benefit director has a duty to consider the impact of business decisions on a variety of stakeholders. a study in 2015 of the forty-five original certified b corp companies found that all made progress toward their stated goals, were profitable, and had published annual reports for greater transparency (wilburn & wilburn, 2015). these founding certified b corp companies were all from canada and the united states (wilburn & wilburn, 2015). as of march 2019, there were over 2,500 certified b-corps in 50 countries (b lab, 2019). more importantly to drive home the point; there has been a not insignificant increase of nearly 50% in both b corp companies and countries utilizing this form of incorporating in the last year alone. the csr movement is growing internationally (ferrell et al., 2016). in 2020 there were 3,585 companies in 74 countries that are utilizing the b corp form of incorporation. this upturn in csr – sustainability focus reflects the growing awareness and acceptability that there is a growing stakeholder perspective. as of 2019, thirty-four states and the district of columbia have enacted benefit corporation legislation (benefit corporation, 2019). this legally allows the designated company to operate in a manner that does not require the company to pursue maximization of stockholder wealth at the expense of public benefit (el khatib, 2015). unlike traditional for-profit corporations, benefit corporations (which are still in the business to make a profit) cannot be held accountable for business practices by stockholders unless there is a question of the company pursuing its stated benefit goals (hacker, 2016). the very existence of the various measures and methods employed to demonstrate any stakeholder approach to corporate governance begins to create an illusion for consumers that a company is more socially responsible than other, more traditional, for-profit corporations. this perspective bias reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 131 theoretically creates an unfair advantage much to the detriment of a traditional company. ‘greenwashing’ is defined as “use of a public-relations-enhancing social purpose to fritter away money without oversight” (solomon, 2015). hacker (2016) and el khatib (2015) both refer to greenwashing as using the labels that convey to the consumer the company is engaged in a public benefit when in actuality it is just a complex marketing ploy and there is no substantive effort by the company or results from efforts to actually pursue the stated public benefit. csr and sustainability internationally in addition to the expansion of b lab to certify companies globally, other countries have taken legal steps to require corporations to engage in csr. in 2013, india passed the indian companies act 2013, an amendment to india’s laws governing corporations. this act included a specific requirement for indian companies to spend at least 2% of their average earnings on csr activities. to be required to comply with this new law, a company in india must meet certain revenue and/or asset thresholds. to comply, a company may spend its earnings on such issues as hunger, poverty, education, child mortality, or maternal health (hiralal, 2015). in 2015, italy became the first foreign nation to make benefit corporations legal entities; similar legislation is also being advocated in australia, argentina, chile, colombia and canada (benefit corporation, 2019). future leadership and the millennial perspective this literature review has so far described relevant theory and practice with regard to csr. the results of this study add to the existing body of knowledge by providing evidence of millennials’ philosophy and attitudes on csr reflected in their financial decisions while participating in a strategic business simulation. the 18-year period between 1982 and the year 2000 is the most commonly accepted period where the millennial generation fits in most published estimates (mcglone et al., 2011). this generation is critical to our future economy as they play an important role in csr because they will significantly influence society toward a more stakeholder-centered approach. millennials are optimistic, cooperative, and more importantly civic minded. they “will demand that employers make good on fair play on pay and benefits will be at issue” (howe & strauss, 2000). millennials will not only demand changes in the workplace that focus on their needs but also tend to seek out 132 reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 and buy “products that combine their focus on family….and community approval” (howe & strauss, 2000). millennials are activists. they will seek to influence community, political, economic, and environmental issues (howe & strauss, 2000). this leads us to the assumption that sustainability through corporate csr efforts will be the “natural” outcome of this generations’ influence and future leadership. millennials are largely misunderstood in the workplace today. they are often viewed as lazy, entitled, and never satisfied (roker, 2017). millennials have a different self-perception. they view themselves as ambitious, innovative, connected, and expressive. millennials are “looking for things to support because we want to feel like we’re making a change in the world” (roker, 2017). for millennials, actions are important. they seek to reward or punish corporations based on csr involvement (mcglone et al., 2011). millennials also perceive that doing good is not enough, that authentic leadership is critical (kim et al., 2018). it is not doing good for external measures; it is doing good because it is what the organization is at its core. this is an effort to prevent the greenwashing evidenced by firms who in times past “were not fully committed to the ethos of sustainability and lacked authenticity” (tucci et al., 2015). millennials have become the largest generation in the u.s. labor force making up 35% of the total u.s. labor force (arkansas business, 2018). over half of the workforce will be composed of millennials by 2025. they already seek change in society and soon they will have achieved critical mass and its associated power to effect change. this current age grouping seeks to advance societal welfare over individual success (winograd & hais, 2014). however, these demanded changes are not balanced. prutina (2016) identified that as individuals rise in position and authority and are engaged in csr, organizational commitment increases. what remains to be seen, is why is this phenomenon increasing? this study contends curricula and culture have coincided. this paper reinforces that this rise of millennials and the make-up of the future corporate leadership class illuminates the force behind the change. with the move towards csr, the gender leadership ratio is changing simultaneously. women see both a higher level of organizational commitment and commitment to their personal values than men as they rise within the organization (aggarwal et al., 2018). as the baby-boomers age, turnover reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 133 increases, and women ascend the corporate ladder into executive leadership, the expected change will be increased csr efforts and commitments to that as a bona-fide strategy. the corresponding lower likelihood of being replaced as a corporate leader in uncertain times will entrench these new leaders into the social fabric of these corporations (cooper, 2017). evolutionary factors such as increases in board diversity and changes in strategy are becoming the norm (rao & tilt, 2016) (marques-mendes & santos, 2016). the research question a review of the literature firmly establishes that a stakeholder approach is the “preferred” approach of millennials. nevertheless, the question addressed by this study is, “given the opportunity, would millennials in a capstone competitive simulation use a stakeholder approach (csr focus) strategy when financial performance is the measure of success?” the syllabus provided to these students clearly stated that a basket of financial measures would be used to determine their grade as this part of the course. csr does help the students overall scores to a point, however, just like investments in r&d, and marketing/advertising, there are diminishing rates of return once optimal levels of investment have been reached. students were aware that excessive investment in csr is detrimental to their overall score. 4. methodology millennial students were selected for this study as appropriate to test the prediction that they would have a greater propensity to seek the common good, be more socially conscious, and take a more active role in society and politics that clearly follows the concepts of sustainability empowered by csr than previous generations. in previous studies it has been shown that millennials’ do have a heightened sense of csr as reflected in a philosophy of “better for the common good” by business students attending a senior level business class (reavis, et al., 2017; reavis & orr, 2021). what has not been analyzed are the decision behaviors of millennials in operational decision making and if those decisions reflect their stated values. the assignment used to test the research question is a commonly used business simulation called glo-bus (glo-bus.com). in the simulation, students are assigned to teams of two to four individuals. these teams compete not only against their classmates, but also against teams from other business schools around the world. typically, about 3,800 teams compete in this 134 reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 simulation that lasts approximately 10 to 12 weeks. the simulation allows each team to manage a company that produces two products, an action camera and a flying drone. the products are hypothetically made in east-asia and are marketed around the world. there is a combination of decisions to manage both products’ design, finance, manufacturing, quality control, operations/production, human resources, as well as the marketing and distribution. ancillary to direct operational decisions; each team must also decide whether they want to engage in csrc (corporate social responsibility and citizenship) by investments in charitable contributions, environmental sustainability through the use of a “renewable energy program,” an on-site child-care facility and an on-site employee cafeteria, improved working conditions through increased lighting and ventilation, and the implementation of a supplier code of conduct requiring all suppliers to follow an ethical code of conduct. the ancillary decisions are the focus of the research to determine if millennials will in fact engage in csr decisions given the pressure to maximize profits in a financially competitive simulation. students in the capstone business policy class are randomly assigned to glo-bus teams prior to the beginning of the semester. when the semester begins, the students must first read the participants guide that is a 32-page pdf document explaining each of the key areas in which decisions must be made, how they are made, and the potential costs and benefits of each of those decisions. three weeks into the course, each team takes control of the company in the simulation. it is assumed in the simulation that the companies are already in production and previously had five years of profitability. all teams start with exactly the same financial standing and market share. the students get two practice decision cycles to manipulate the simulation decision matrix and compare notes from simulation generated competitive intelligence reports. after the two practice years are completed, the following week, the simulation is reset back to year five and students operate the company making decisions for years 6 through 14 (there is a year 15, but due to time constraints, it is not required). students are coached in the first week of school to pick a strategy and stick with that strategy for the long term since it has been proven in earlier classes that randomly making decisions leads to early failure. if students choose a lowcost strategy, all decisions should be made to minimize un-needed / excessive reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 135 expenditures. if they choose a differentiation strategy, they must make decisions that enhance the features and benefits of the product, making their products stand out from competitors’ offerings. the third strategy is a bestcost strategy where they try to apply both a low cost and a differentiation strategy to satisfy customers’ needs at an affordable price. there are two optional areas for students to invest profits. the first is research and development (r&d). research and development does not have an immediate payback but does have high return over time in direct portion to how much they invested up to a point and then the return is diminishing. research and development and the delayed return on investment is not the subject of this paper. investment in csrc initiatives has immediate payback but has escalating diminishing returns once an investment plateau has been reached. often students do not fully understand foreign labor and 12-hour work days nor lack of access to food during work hours nor readily available child-care for manufacturing facilities. lack of employee benefits in these forms for foreign workers is discussed in lecture as the course progresses and is covered in the text. to test our research question, we looked at the 2018 academic year and selected the students who met our definition of millennial in a senior business policy (strategic management) class. students in business policy are required to be graduating seniors in their last semester and past performance for these students has been satisfactory. the business college that hosts the simulation typically places very high in the global competition (at least three to four teams out of 12 teams score in top 100), and just the year before data was collected (2017) two students won recognition as best performance in competition with 3800 other teams worldwide. students falling outside of the 1982 to 2000 birth years were not used in the analysis. the students selected for this study have been exposed to csr topics and theory in several other classes before participating in the glo-bus simulation. we used an academic year format (five course sections) since a great majority contained students who we knew to fit the millennial definition. in previous csr studies, using different data, millennial students have shown to favor a stakeholder approach over a stockholder approach to corporate governance (see figure 2). 42.81% of millennial students in the previous study “strongly support” a stakeholder approach to corporate governance. when added to the ‘leans towards stakeholder approach’ amount of 21.57%, 64.38% 136 reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 of millennials identify as stakeholder oriented. in comparison, only 18.63% (the total of both ‘strongly support’ and ‘lean towards’) of millennials’ share milton friedman’s stockholder approach to corporate governance. those that were neutral, not preferring either the stakeholder or stockholder approach, represented 16.99% of the sample. as a research team we also considered other variables from the course data obtained from the simulation: leadership skills, collaboration & teamwork, analytical skills, operation management, marketing management, human resources management, and strategic analysis & planning. however, only financial management and csr were found to have any significant statistical relationships. the financial performance variable data was based on the company's eps, roe, credit rating, and stock price performances, whereas the csr variable data was based on the percentage of company revenues spent on the six corporate social responsibility initiatives. 5. analysis and results the students from five different sections in the 2018 academic year enrolled in a business policy class participating in the glo-bus simulation in 2018 were selected for this study. the original sample had 138 respondents. eight students were eliminated from the data because they did not fall within the age range definition of millennial and another 10 were eliminated due to missing or incomplete values. a final sample of 120 students was used for our study. table 1 shows the descriptive statistics of all the variables in this study. the 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 -2 -1 0 1 2 p e rc e n ta g e rating purel stakeholder perspective neutral perspective stockholder perspective figure 2. student philosophy by rating (reavis & tucci, 2020) reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 137 mean score on financial management was 50.76, with a standard deviation of 18.56. on the other hand, the mean score on csr was 53.58, with a standard deviation of 25.99. a correlation analysis was performed to examine the relationship between financial management and csr and the result is tabulated in table 2. the correlation result shows that financial management and csr are significantly negatively associated with each other. table 1. descriptive statistics of variables within study table 2. correlation table of financial management and csr score in the study variable csr financial management -0.213* significance (2-tailed) 0.019 note: correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed) to further analyze the relationship between financial management and csr, we performed a cluster analysis on financial management in relationship to csr scores. the goal of cluster analysis is to divide the data into meaningful subgroups when there is no knowledge about the composition and/or number of the subgroups (fraley & raftery, 1998). there is no exact formula on the number of clusters, but the decision can be made based on a rule of thumb. for example, lehmann (1979) suggested that the number of clusters based on sample size (n) should be between n/30 and n/60. in this study, the sample size was 120, so the range of the number of clusters based on the above guidelines is between 2 and 4. we decided to use a four-cluster solution shown in table 3 in this study as four-cluster solution provided more insight as compared to a two or three cluster solution without increasing the complexity. the cluster analysis suggests that cluster 2 has the highest mean of 73, whereas cluster 4 has the lowest cluster mean of 23. in order to examine the differences across four groups, one-way analysis of variance (anova) was used to test for the differences in mean score on csr among four clusters. the results of anova are shown in table 4, and variable response mean standard deviation financial management 120 50.76 18.56 csr 120 53.58 25.99 138 reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 table 3. cluster solution on financial management in relation to csr investment 1 (medium) 2 (high) 3 (low) 4 (lowest) cluster mean 55.37 73.28 39.04 22.73 sample size 41 32 25 22 table 4. one-way anova results (dependent variable = csr) note: significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed) the results indicate that the proposed model is significant (f=3.011, and pvalue=0.033) and we can infer that there is a significant difference among four clusters on the mean csr score. also, the mean score on csr for all four clusters is shown in figure 3. the mean plot indicates cluster 3 has the highest score among all clusters on csr, whereas the cluster 1 has lowest score on csr. the mean score of csr plot also suggests that cluster 3 and 4 score high on csr in comparison to cluster 1 and 2. the data indicates that there tends to be a bi-polar split in the distribution of students use of stakeholder theory as measured by our study. there is a strong association between the lower financial performance score and a higher csr score as associated with preferences towards stakeholder theory. conversely, there is a less strong relationship between higher financial performance and a stakeholder approach to decision making by millennials in this study, especially in cluster 3. further analysis of cluster 4 revealed that some students in this cluster were deficient in their financial decision-making and only moderately investing in csr. students in cluster 4 typically made strategic errors early in the competition that minimized the financial health of their company. the students are aware of the costs for every decision they make. decisions are not made in a vacuum, but with a financial overview of their competitors’ investments (competitive intelligence report), including their csr activities. sum of squares df mean square f sig. between groups 5807.760 3 1935.920 3.011 0.033* within groups 74577.407 116 642.909 total 80385.167 119 reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 139 finally, we conducted the fisher’s lsd post-hoc test to identify the differences among clusters on csr. the result of fisher’s lsd is shown in table 5. the post-hoc test reveals that there is significant difference on mean csr score between cluster 1 and 3. similarly, the results also indicate that there is significant difference on mean csr score between cluster 2 and 3. the results of the statistical analysis supports that students do engage in a stakeholder model of decision-making and that decision-making had a direct financial impact on their teams’ performance. the analysis further indicates that the higher the score in the csr values, the lower the financial performance by that team. this indicates that the business students in this study are willing to forgo profits to maximize stakeholder values in making strategic/financial decisions. interestingly, what several students wrote in the required final paper for the course “what i learned in this class,” was the repeated expression “at the outset, our strategy was designed to make a difference in the world.” the decision to engage in csr was a conscious decision from the outset for them. csr and investment in csr is clearly covered in the simulation instructions and the pros and cons of said investments. the simulation awards teams who lead the industry in csr, even though their financial performance lags those with a more “balanced management portfolio.” the balance being that you have the appropriate dollars invested in csr activities, just as you would at setting employee salaries (which the students are also required to do). this simulation is done over a nine-week period with approximately 50 decisions 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 1 2 3 4 m e an o f c s r cluster number of case figure 3. mean plot of csr 140 reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 table 5. multiple comparison (fisher’s lsd post-hoc test) (i) cluster number (j) cluster number mean difference (i-j) std. error sig. 95% confidence interval lower bound upper bound 1 2 2.36 5.981 0.694 -9.49 14.21 3 -16.150* 6.434 0.013 -28.89 -3.41 4 -6.754 6.701 0.316 -20.03 6.52 2 1 -2.36 5.981 0.694 -14.21 9.49 3 -18.510* 6.768 0.007 -31.92 -5.1 4 -9.114 7.022 0.197 -23.02 4.8 note: significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed) required weekly with a “competitive intelligence report” to determine optimal/competitive positions. limitations the use of the terms csr, stakeholder theory, and stockholder theory as used in this study have become commonplace, at times probably misused or misunderstood, and issues of construct validity may give rise to error in differences in either interpretation or definition by either researchers or respondents. a second limitation is the geographic region from which a majority of the respondents have historically been limited in their desire for mobility and exposure to other belief models limited. to overcome this second limitation, further studies of millennials in other geographic regions could be tested to minimize this potential limitation. further study of millennials as they age, marry, work, and support themselves financially could result in changes to the conclusions of their generational philosophy as a whole. a third limitation was that for cluster groups one and two in this study, it might be observed by them that they did not perceive the exercise as an opportunity for engaging in csr, or did not understand that this opportunity for csr engagement was a risk worth taking during this exercise. 6. conclusions millennials mostly prefer a stakeholder approach as postulated by howe and strauss (2000). this study extends earlier research findings, which illustrate that millennial students prefer a stakeholder approach, by illustrating a negative reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 141 financial consequence exists as behavior follows stakeholder preference. nevertheless, millennials do prefer csr as a tool in their decision-making process across the population even by those who do not use it as a primary referent when making decisions. all groups did engage in csr activities, but groups three and four at a much higher rate. we believe that even groups one and two will increase over time due to accreditation requirements, curriculum changes, and the very nature of the teaching materials and cases available to professors in aacsb accredited business schools. the results of this study give colleges of business institutional support that integrating csr activities and goals into the curriculum does have an impact that supports corporate social responsibility as per the aacsb “standard 9.” business students use csr as a tool in strategic decision-making. this is evidence of the associated increase in commitment to organizational change as millennials advance to the c level suite within organizations as postulated by aggarwal, dhaliwal, & nobi (2018) and prutina (2016). the analysis presented herein indicates that as more millennials ascend to leadership positions in authority, there should be a corresponding change from a stockholder to stakeholder approach in corporate governance. if financial performance is the same for real world corporations as it is in glo-bus, millennials’ stakeholder approach to corporate governance will result in decreased financial performance for firms. the millennial generation supports social accountability as evidenced by their decision-making. the millennial generation supports the common good over financial profit. this study lends support to the predictions by howe & strauss (2000) that as millennials continue to enter the c-level suite, they will lead significant cultural and strategic changes. they will impact the fabric of commercial, political, educational, and religious institutions. as their actions follow their philosophy, significant changes in society will occur. 142 reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 references aacsb. (2020). standard 9 and societal and engagement impact arkansas state legislature. (2013). arkansas benefit corporation act, ark. stat. ann.§§ 4-36-101-401. retrieved from http://www.arkleg.state.ar.us/assembly/2013/2013r/pages/billinformat ion.aspx?measureno=hb1510 aggarwal, a., dhaliwal, r., & nobi, k. (2018). impact of structural empowerment on organizational commitment: the mediating role of women’s psychological empowerment. vision, 22(3), 284-294. https://doi.org/10.1177/0972262918786049 aguilera-caracuel, j., guerrero-villegas, j., garcía-sánchez, e. (2017). european journal of management and business economics, 26(3), 329-346. https://doi.org/10.1108/ejmbe-10-2017-019 arkansas business (2018). millennials constitute 35% of u.s. labor force. retrieved from http://www.arkansasbusiness.com/article/122227/millennials...t=dailyreport&utm_campaign=newsletter&enews_zone=3818 b lab (2017). b corporation. retrieved from www.bcorporation.net b lab (2019). b corporation. retrieved from www.bcorporation.net b lab (2021). b corporation. retrieved from www.bcorporation.net benefit corporation (2019). state by state status of legislation. retrieved from http://benefitcorp.net/policymakers/state-by-statestatus. benefit corporation (2019). international legislation. retrieved from http://benefitcorp.net/international-legislation. benioff, m. (2016). from cbs this morning june 1, 2016. chalmers, a., & van den broek, o. (2019). financial volatility and public scrutiny as institutional determinants of financial industry firms' csr. business and politics, 21(2), 240-266. https://doi.org/10.1017/bap.2018.28 cokins, g. (2013). kite with a broken string – the balanced scorecard. balanced scorecard institute. retrieved from http://www.balancedscorecard.org/resources/articles-white-papers cooper, e., (2017). corporate social responsibility, gender, and ceo turnover, managerial finance, 43(5) 528-544. https://doi.org/10.1108/mf02-2016-0049 elalfy, a., palaschuk, n., el-bassiouny, d., wilson, j., & weber, o. (2020). scoping the evolution of corporate social responsibility (csr) research in the sustainable development goals (sdgs) era. sustainability, 12(14). https://doi.org/10.3390/su12145544 http://www.arkleg.state.ar.us/assembly/2013/2013r/pages/billinformation.aspx?measureno=hb1510 http://www.arkleg.state.ar.us/assembly/2013/2013r/pages/billinformation.aspx?measureno=hb1510 https://doi.org/10.1177/0972262918786049 https://doi.org/10.1177/0972262918786049 https://doi.org/10.1108/ejmbe-10-2017-019 http://www.arkansasbusiness.com/article/122227/millennials...t=daily-report&utm_campaign=newsletter&enews_zone=3818 http://www.arkansasbusiness.com/article/122227/millennials...t=daily-report&utm_campaign=newsletter&enews_zone=3818 file://///winfscommon/common/cbed/jbs/manuscripts/copyediting/38-2/5473%20-%20reavis/www.bcorporation.net file://///winfscommon/common/cbed/jbs/manuscripts/copyediting/38-2/5473%20-%20reavis/www.bcorporation.net file://///winfscommon/common/cbed/jbs/manuscripts/copyediting/38-2/5473%20-%20reavis/www.bcorporation.net https://doi.org/10.1017/bap.2018.28 http://www.balancedscorecard.org/resources/articles-white-papers https://doi.org/10.1108/mf-02-2016-0049 https://doi.org/10.1108/mf-02-2016-0049 https://doi.org/10.3390/su12145544 reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 143 el khatib, k. (2015). the harms of the benefit corporation. american university law review, 65(1), 151-189. https://digitalcommons.wcl.american.edu/aulr/vol65/iss1/3 elkington, j. (1997). cannibals with forks: the triple bottom line of the 21st century business. gabriola island, bc: new society publishers. ferrell, o., thorne, d., & ferrell, l. (2016). business and society: a strategic approach to social responsibility & ethics. chicago business press, 5th ed. fraley, c., & raftery, a. (1998). how many clusters? which clustering method? answers via model-based cluster analysis. the computer journal, 41(8), 578-588. https://doi.org/10.1093/comjnl/41.8.578 freeman, r. e. (1983). stockholders and stakeholders: a new perspective on corporate governance. california management review, 25(3), 88. https://doi.org/10.2307/41165018 friedman, m (1970). the social responsibility of business is to increase its profits. the new york times. gilbert, j. (2010). tedxphilly jay coen gilbert on better businesses. retrieved from https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=mgnz-w9p5fu glo-bus.com, (2021). an online business strategy simulation. retrieved from glo-bus.com hacker, m. a. (2016). “profit, people, planet" perverted: holding benefit corporations accountable to intended beneficiaries. boston college law review, 57(5), 1747-1780. harrison, virginia. (2019). “it’s a delicate dance”: understanding csr relationships from the nonprofit perspective. journal of communication management, 23(2), 142-158. https://doi.org/10.1108/jcom-10-20180100 honeyman, r. (2015). a look at the history of the b corp movement. retrieved from http://www.triplepundit.com/2014/08/fascinating-lookhistory-b-corp-movement/. hiralal, m. (2015). india: corporate social responsibility – indian companies act 2013. retrieved from http://www.mondaq.com/india/x/366528/corporate+governance/cor porate+social+responsibility+indian+companies+act+2013 horng, j., hsu, h., chang-yen, t. (2019). learning corporate ethics and social responsibility: developing an influential curriculum for undergraduate tourism and hospitality students, journal of hospitality, leisure, sports and tourism education, 24, 100-109. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhlste.2019.01.003 https://digitalcommons.wcl.american.edu/aulr/vol65/iss1/3 https://doi.org/10.1093/comjnl/41.8.578 https://doi.org/10.2307/41165018 https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=mgnz-w9p5fu https://doi.org/10.1108/jcom-10-2018-0100 https://doi.org/10.1108/jcom-10-2018-0100 http://www.mondaq.com/india/x/366528/corporate+governance/corporate+social+responsibility+indian+companies+act+2013 http://www.mondaq.com/india/x/366528/corporate+governance/corporate+social+responsibility+indian+companies+act+2013 https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jhlste.2019.01.003 144 reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 howe, n. & strauss, w. (2000). millennials rising: the next great generation. new york: vintage books. kim, b., nurunnabi, m., kim, t., & kim, t., (2018) doing good is not enough, you should have been authentic: organizational identification, authentic leadership, and csr. sustainability, 10(6), 20-26 larrán, m., andrades, j., herrera, j, (2018). an examination of attitudes and perceptions of spanish business and accounting students toward corporate social responsibility and sustainability themes. revista de contabilidad, 21(2), 196-205. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rcsar.2018.02.001 lehmann, d. r. (1979). market research and analysis. homewood, il: r. d. irwin. lopez, m., garcia, a., rodriguez, l. (2007). sustainable development and corporate performance: a study based on the dow jones sustainability index. journal of business ethics, 75, 285-300. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-006-9253-8 marques-mendes a. & santos, m. (2016) strategic csr: an integrative model for analysis. social responsibility journal, 12(2), 363-381. mcglone, t., spain, j., & mcglone, v (2011). corporate social responsibility and the millennials. journal of education for business, 86(4), 195-200. https://doi.org/10.1080/08832323.2010.502912 miftachul, h., mulyadi, d., hananto, a., nasrul, h., kamarul, s. (2018). empowering corporate social responsibility (csr): insights from service learning. social responsibility journal, 14(4), 875-894. http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/srj-04-2017-0078 nine steps to success. (2017). balanced scorecard institute retrieved from http://www.balancedscorecard.org/resources/the-nine-steps-tosuccess ohio university (2020). why corporate social responsibility is important. onlinemasters.ohio.edu/blog/why-corporate-social-responsibility-mattersin-todays-society/ february 6th porter, m., & kramer, m. (2011). creating shared value. harvard business review. post, j., preston, l., & sachs, s. (2002). redefining the corporation: stakeholder management and organizational wealth. stanford, ca: stanford university. prutina, zana (2016). the effect of corporate social responsibility on organizational commitment. journal of contemporary management issues, 21, 227-248. rao, k. & tilt c. (2016). board composition and corporate social responsibility: the role of diversity, gender, strategy and decision making. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.rcsar.2018.02.001 https://doi.org/10.1007/s10551-006-9253-8 https://doi.org/10.1080/08832323.2010.502912 http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/srj-04-2017-0078 http://www.balancedscorecard.org/resources/the-nine-steps-to-success http://www.balancedscorecard.org/resources/the-nine-steps-to-success reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 145 journal of business ethics, 138(2), 327-347. https://www.jstor.org/stable/24755872 reavis, m. & orr, d. (2021). the journey of american capitalism: from stockholders to stakeholders. american journal of management, 21(4), 1-15. https://doi.org/10.33423/ajm.v21i4.4553 reavis, m., tucci, j., & st. pierre, g. (2017). corporate social responsibility and millennials’ stakeholder approach. journal of leadership, accountability and ethics, 14(4), 74-83. https://doi.org/10.33423/jlae.v14i4.1488 reavis, m. r., tucci, j.e., (2020). sustainability effort acceleration as measured by increased propensity of corporate social responsibility. journal of management and sustainability, 10(2) 121-134. doi: 10.5539/jms.v10n2p121 roker, a. (2017). millennial misconceptions-how they are changing the workplace. today. new york city, ny: national broadcast corporation. rausch, a. (2011). reconstruction of decision-making behavior in stockholder and stakeholder theory: implications for management accounting systems. review of managerial science, 5(2-3), 137-169. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11846-010-0053-2 serban, a. (2105). how personal values influence romanian csr manager’s involvement in csr campaigns. management dynamics in the knowledge economy, 3(4), 729-748. slaper, t. & hall t. (2011). the triple bottom line: what is it and how does it work? indiana business review, 86(1). smith, n., & rönnegard, d. (2016). stockholder primacy, corporate social responsibility, and the role of business schools. journal of business ethics, 134(3), 463-478. https://www.jstor.org/stable/24703783 solomon, s. (2015). idealism that may leave stockholders wishing for pragmatism. the new york times. retrieved from https://www.nytimes.com/2015/10/14/business/dealbook/laureateeducation-for-profit-school-public-benefit.html?_r=0 starbucks 2012 annual meeting (2013). starbucks annual meeting, retrieved from https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=hoibhe0i22e&t=9s stonkutė, e., vveinhardt, j., sroka, w. (2018). training the csr sensitive mind-set: the integration of csr into the training of business administration professionals, sustainability, 10(3), 754. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10030754 triple bottom line (2009). the economist. retrieved from http://www.economist.com/node/14301663. https://www.jstor.org/stable/24755872 https://doi.org/10.33423/ajm.v21i4.4553 https://doi.org/10.33423/jlae.v14i4.1488 file://///winfscommon/common/cbed/jbs/manuscripts/copyediting/38-2/5473%20-%20reavis/10.5539/jms.v10n2p121 https://doi.org/10.1007/s11846-010-0053-2 https://www.jstor.org/stable/24703783 https://www.nytimes.com/2015/10/14/business/dealbook/laureate-education-for-profit-school-public-benefit.html?_r=0 https://www.nytimes.com/2015/10/14/business/dealbook/laureate-education-for-profit-school-public-benefit.html?_r=0 https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=hoibhe0i22e&t=9s https://doi.org/10.3390/su10030754 146 reavis et al. / journal of business strategies (2021) 38: 125-146 tucci, j., shin, s., & benefield, m. (2015). logistics sustainability? long term technology investments and integration. journal of management and sustainability, 5. doi:10.5539/jms.v5n2p48 wilburn, k. & wilburn, r. (2015). evaluating csr accomplishments of founding certified b corps. journal of global responsibility, 6(2), 262-280. https://doi.org/10.1108/jgr-07-2015-0010 winograd, m. & hais, m. (2014). how millennials could upend wall street and corporate america. the brookings institution. washington, dc. file://///winfscommon/common/cbed/jbs/manuscripts/copyediting/38-2/5473%20-%20reavis/10.5539/jms.v5n2p48 https://doi.org/10.1108/jgr-07-2015-0010 volume 35, number 2 29 religiosity and corporate illegal activity joseph e. coombs virginia commonwealth university • richmond, va k. matthew gilley st. mary’s university • san antonio, tx joseph p. o’connor recently retired from the university of texas at el paso • el paso, tx timothy e. thorley dixie high school • st. george, ut curtis l. wesley ii university of houston • houston, tx abstract this paper explores the effects of regional religiosity on the illegal financial actions of business executives. in particular, we examine the extent to which agency and institutional theories may be used to explain fraudulent financial reporting and stock options backdating. our findings indicate that religiosity has a negative influence on illegal corporate activity but that this relationship is primarily limited to stock options backdating. board size and independence are also shown to moderate the relationship between religiosity and illegal corporate activity. these results provide support for an institutional theory perspective on mitigating executive opportunism. keywords: corporate fraud; executive compensation; financial reporting; institutional norms; religiosity; stock options backdating introduction agency theory is the primary theoretic lens through which executive compensation and corporate governance issues are examined (dalton, hitt, certo, & dalton, 2007; devers, cannella, reilly, & yoder, 2007; eisenhardt, 1989). this continues despite growing evidence that agency theory prescriptions may inadvertently contribute to the agency problems they were designed to solve (dalton et al., 2007; devers et al., 2007) such as financial fraud (e.g., ndofor, wesley, & priem, 2015; o’connor, priem, coombs, & gilley, 2006) and stock option backdating (heron and lie, 2007; lie, 2005). one possible way to address these issues is to follow eisenhardt’s recommendation that researchers, “use agency theory with complementary theories” (eisenhardt, 1989, p. 71) because agency theory ignores organizational complexity. we 30 journal of business strategies follow this recommendation and offer institutional theory as an important compliment to agency theory when studying certain agency problems. institutions provide society with rules and standards that influence individuals and organizations, and hence, economic activity (hitt, ahlstrom, dacin, levitas, & svobodina, 2004; north, 1990; scott, 2001). institutions affect individuals’ and firms’ strategic choices (hitt et al., 2004; peng, 2003) partly because they define acceptable behaviors within a society (dimaggio & powell, 1983; north, 1990; scott, 2001). one institutional dimension of particular importance to executives and organizations is the normative dimension. normative institutions introduce values and norms into social life that “define legitimate means to pursue valued ends” (scott, 2001, p. 64). in particular, normative institutions not only define socially acceptable goals such as making a profit, but they also specify acceptable rules for meeting those goals (blake & davis, 1964). in our context, we examine how one particular normative institution, religion, influences the likelihood of socially unacceptable actions such as corporate illegal activity. the purpose of our research, then, is to integrate agency and institutional theories and demonstrate how they may act together to explain corporate illegal activity. in doing so, we make several contributions to the literature. first, we respond to eisenhardt (1989) by integrating agency and institutional theories to explain corporate illegal activity. consistent with warnings that agents may look for new ways to increase their personal gain when old ways are monitored and controlled (dow, 1987; ghoshal & moran, 1996), executives at many organizations have engaged in illegal actions. agency theory prescriptions have not only failed to mitigate these actions, but may have actually contributed to them (dalton et al., 2007; devers et al., 2007). we posit that pressure from normative institutions may help to mitigate these actions. second, we develop theory to help understand how normative institutions influence social actors to not engage in corporate illegal activity. more specifically, we explain how religiosity in the geographic region in which an organization is headquartered creates social norms of honesty and risk aversion in which executives live and make decisions (cialdini & goldstein, 2004; halek & eisenhauer, 2001; kohlberg, 1984; sunstein, 1996). lastly, we extend recent work relating religiosity with legal accounting tactics such as earnings management (callen, morel, & richardson, 2011; mcguire, omer, & sharp, 2012) and financial restatements (dyreng, mayew, & williams, 2012), as well as investment and growth rates (hilary and hui, 2009) by examining the relationship between religiosity and corporate illegal activity. volume 35, number 2 31 literature review religiosity as a normative institution religion has been defined as shared beliefs, ideologies, and behaviors based on faith in a higher power, or supernatural forces (iannaccone 1998). religiosity is often used in the social sciences to represent the measurable behaviors, affect, and cognitions of respondents that are related to religion (mcguire et al., 2012). consistent with the view that normative institutions define socially acceptable goals and specify acceptable rules for meeting those goals (blake & davis, 1964), religious norms provide individuals guidelines for what constitutes ethical action (mcguire et al., 2012; weaver & agle, 2002). within organizations, religiosity may influence honesty and risk aversion, two individual characteristics likely associated with the likelihood to commit illegal (dishonest and risky) acts. recent research suggests religiosity, while not consistently associated with honesty (weaver & agle, 2002), remains the best predictor of attitudes about honesty (katz, santman, & lonero, 1994). this relationship may stem from both a direct and an indirect relationship between religiosity and honesty. for example, perrin (2000) reported that students were more likely to be honest if they were more religious, as evidenced by church attendance, involvement in religious activities, and belief in life after death, suggesting a direct relationship between religiosity and honesty. this relationship may be indirect as well, however. according to dyreng and colleagues (2012), religious reminders such as “what would jesus do?” bracelets and religious bumper stickers in more highly religious geographic areas provide a consistent reminder of the region’s moral code. additionally, mazar, amir, & ariely (2008) demonstrated that religious reminders such as reciting the ten commandments tend to curb dishonest reporting that would have led to personal financial gain even for individuals not explicitly associated with any religious group. further evidence at the organization level suggests religiosity is associated with employees’ honesty in terms of their willingness to voluntarily disclose bad news rather than hide it (dyreng et al., 2012). religious individuals are also typically associated with risk aversion more so than are those who are non-religious (diaz, 2000; dohmen, falk, huffman, sunde, schupp, & wagner, 2011; hilary & hui, 2009; liu, 2010; miller, 2000; miller & hoffman, 1995). much like the relationship between religiosity and honesty, the relationship between religiosity and risk aversion does not necessarily suggest religious individuals are more risk averse but that the relationship is driven by the social aspect 32 journal of business strategies of religion (noussair, trautmann, van de kuilen, & vellekoop, 2013). evidence for this relationship also exists at the organization level. hilary and hui (2009) found that organizations are more conservative in choosing investments when located in a more religious geographic area. additionally, dyreng and colleagues (2012) report that religious adherence is associated with a lower risk of voluntary, rather than forced, financial restatement. the authors of each of these papers suggest their findings provide evidence of social norms influencing corporate decision-making. religious norms and the organization while religiosity is measured at the individual level, there is reason to conclude that individual religiosity can influence decisions at the organization level. religious norms of the population located around an organization’s headquarters are one aspect of the social environment in which organization decisions are made (cialdini & goldstein 2004; dyreng et al., 2012; kohlberg, 1984; sunstein, 1996). even when managers themselves are not religious, the likelihood of interacting with religious individuals exposes managers to religious social norms and increases the likelihood that managers are influenced by these norms (kennedy & lawton, 1998). as evidence of this relationship, welch, tittle, and petee (1991) found that religious social norms in a community can cause individual adherence to these social norms. more specifically, welch and colleagues (1991) demonstrated both individual and community religiosity influenced whether an individual would evade taxes or use employer equipment for personal gain. religiosity and financial reporting in some cases, managers manipulate earnings to bolster their own financial rewards, or to create a false sense of security for key stakeholders regarding the company’s finances. in a study looking at both religiosity and other cultural variables, callen and colleagues (2011) found that earnings management is unrelated to both religious affiliation and religiosity, as measured by attendance and self-ratings of religious conviction and importance. however, other cultural variables, individualism and uncertainty avoidance, had a relationship with earnings management. these variables were examined at the national level, so it is possible that differences in religiosity within a particular country may relate to earnings management. in a working paper, grullon, kanatas, and weston (2014) found that organizations in areas with a higher level of per capita adherents to an organized religion were less likely to be the targets of class action lawsuits, engage in forms of options backdating volume 35, number 2 33 that are not illegal per se, and manipulate their earnings. however, as they note, their rather coarse-grained measure of religiosity presents limitations. mcguire and colleagues (2012) found that social norms created or influenced by religion help to reduce financial reporting irregularities, especially when other control mechanisms are less effective. as with other studies, these results may suggest that the manager making a decision does not have to be particularly religious in order to be influenced by the religious practices, attachment, and affiliation in the region in which he or she works. dyreng and colleagues (2012) examined different aspects of financial reporting and found similar results. more specifically, they determined that non-forced restatements, made necessary by inappropriate reporting or omissions, are less likely in more religious areas. they also found that firms located in more religious areas do not delay or avoid reporting bad news as much as firms located in less religious areas. whether these reporting practices reflect the values adopted by executives because of the area in which they work, or represent a response to social norms and pressures from stakeholders, is unclear. corporate illegal behavior there is an extensive body of work on corporate illegal activity, which we define as deliberate actions taken by executives to misrepresent their firm’s operations and financial activities for monetary gain. this definition covers issues such as fraudulent financial reporting (arthaud-day, certo, dalton, & dalton, 2006; harris & bromiley, 2007; ndofor et al., 2015; o’connor et al., 2006; zhang, bartol, smith, pfarrer, & khanin, 2008) and stock option backdating (aboody & kasznik, 2000; heron & lie, 2007; lie, 2005). harris and bromiley (2007) reported that fraudulent financial reporting increased when stock options made up a higher percentage of total compensation. ndofor and colleagues (2015) describe how industry and firm level complexity are associated with fraud, while ceo stock options increase the likelihood of fraud in association with high industry complexity. o’connor and colleagues (2006) found that fraudulent financial reporting and stock option grants were related when boards of directors also held options. according to zhang and colleagues (2008), fraudulent financial reporting is more likely to occur when ceos hold greater amounts of “out of the money” options. a common thread amongst these studies is that ceo stock options are associated with fraudulent financial reporting. for agency theorists, this is problematic, as stock options are the primary mechanism used to reduce opportunistic behavior by aligning the interests of agents and principals (eisenhardt, 1989; fama & jensen, 1983; jensen & meckling, 1976). 34 journal of business strategies stock option backdating occurs when stock option grant dates are changed (1) with the benefit of hindsight to a past date when the stock price was appreciably lower and (2) without notifying or obtaining approval from principals (lie, 2005). because most stock option plans limit the number of shares awarded annually, and because options are typically granted “at the money” (the price of the firm’s common stock on the day the options are granted), backdating provides an illegal and “covert method of maximizing the option component value of executives’ compensation” (heron & lie, 2007, p. 274). researchers have provided substantial evidence that backdating is widespread (aboody & kasznik, 2000; heron & lie, 2007, 2009; heron, lie, & perry, 2007; lie, 2005; narayanan, schipani, & seyhun, 2007; narayanan & seyhun, 2008) and, despite regulatory changes, continues to be a significant issue. specifically, researchers estimate that the enhanced regulations instituted through the sarbanesoxley act of 2002 (sox) have reduced backdating events by only half (heron and lie, 2009), and that 20 percent of stock grants do not conform to sox’s reporting requirements (narayanan & seyhun, 2008). consistent with their expectation, aboody and kasznik (2000) reported changes in stock prices and analyst earnings forecasts around option awards consistent with stock option backdating. heron and lie (2007) reported that stock returns are abnormally negative before option grants and abnormally positive afterward options grants in a large sample of public firms, suggesting backdating is widespread. in a subsequent study, heron and lie (2009) provided evidence that from 1996-2005, 13.6% of all option grants to top executives were backdated or manipulated. narayanan and colleagues (2007) calculated an average loss to shareholders of about 8% in firms where executive stock options were backdated. lastly, narayanan and seyhun (2008) report evidence of both stock option backdating and forward dating. perhaps even more problematic for agency theorists, stock option backdating results suggest executives are manipulating the very mechanism designed to reduce their opportunistic behavior (eisenhardt, 1989; fama & jensen, 1983; jensen & meckling, 1976). hypothesis development we theorize that religious social norms affect corporate illegal activity through their influence on executive decision-making. the primary focus of previous corporate illegal activity research has been on how firm financial reports and stock options have been manipulated to the benefit of executives. a primary focus of a second research stream examined how religiosity influenced several accounting volume 35, number 2 35 tactics legally used to benefit organizations. religiosity can also be examined in terms of its relationship with corporate illegal activity, which is the purpose of the current study. religious individuals within a particular geographic area interact with employees and executives from local firms, and in doing so, expose these organization members to religious social norms prevalent in the area (kennedy and lawton, 1998). we posit that religious social norms such as honesty (dyreng et al., 2012; mazar et al., 2008) and risk aversion (diaz, 2000; dyreng et al., 2012; hilary & hui, 2009; miller, 2000; miller & hoffman, 1995) influence accounting tactics such that the likelihood of using these tactics is lower in areas with higher religiosity. to the extent that religious social norms are prevalent in the community, we expect executives to be influenced by these norms when considering whether to take illegal actions. more specifically, when located in a community with higher religiosity, we expect executives to adhere to the accompanying religious social norms and be more honest and risk averse. executives in more religious communities are less likely to commit illegal acts because other executives or employees, similarly influenced by religious social norms, are likely to view such actions as unethical (mcguire et al., 2012). taken together, these arguments suggest executives in organizations headquartered in more religious communities will be less likely to commit illegal acts. more specifically, we propose: hypothesis 1: regional religiosity negatively affects corporate illegal activity. board of director size as a moderator agency theory suggests that boards of directors can be important monitors of the agent-principle relationship (fama, 1980; fama & jensen, 1983; jensen & meckling, 1976). there remains uncertainty, however, amongst research as to whether larger or smaller boards are more effective monitors of management actions (williams, fadil, & armstrong, 2005). from an agency perspective, there are several reasons larger boards may be better monitors than smaller boards. first, larger boards have more specialized human capital than smaller boards and may, therefore, be better able to process larger quantities of information more quickly, thus decreasing information asymmetries between management and shareholders (amason & sapienza, 1997; williams et al., 2005). larger boards may also be able to form and use more committees with which to monitor management (pearce & zahra, 1992; zahra & pearce, 1989). additionally, larger boards likely have more independent board members with which to monitor the executives. in addition, larger boards 36 journal of business strategies are better able to constrain executives’ internal political coalitions (ocasio, 1994; williams et al., 2005). multiple political coalitions are more easily formed in larger boards, and these coalitions may be more effective in confronting political coalitions within the executive ranks (ocasio, 1994). lastly, larger boards may be more likely to be represented by members of the community who are of a religious orientation, thus affecting executive decision-making. these arguments suggest that executives who are not sufficiently influenced to avoid illegal acts by religious social norms may be further influenced to avoid such actions by larger boards. in other words, we expect that board size and regional religiosity interact such that the negative effects of religiosity on illegal activity are enhanced when a company’s board is larger. therefore, we propose: hypothesis 2: board size moderates the effects of religiosity on corporate illegal activity, such that the negative relationship between religiosity and corporate illegal activity will be stronger in organizations with a larger board of directors. percentage of outsiders on the board as a moderator in addition to board size, agency theory suggests boards with a higher percentage of outsiders can better monitor executive actions (mizruchi, 1983; zahra & pearce, 1989). the belief is that outside directors, as a result of their independence from management, will produce superior firm performance (dalton, daily, ellstrand, & johnson, 1998). ezzamel and watson (1993) provide support for this perspective with their finding that board outsiders were associated with greater firm profitability. other researchers, such as baysinger and butler (1985) and pearce and zahra (1992), have also reported results consistent with outside board members’ ability to monitor management and deliver greater firm performance. this research suggests that when executives are not sufficiently influenced to avoid illegal acts by religious social norms, more independent boards may further influence executives to avoid such actions. thus: hypothesis 3: board independence moderates the relationship between religiosity and corporate illegal activity, such that the negative effects of religiosity on corporate illegal activity will be stronger in organizations with more independent boards. volume 35, number 2 37 methodology sample selection our sample contains firms that have been involved in illegal corporate activity, including reporting fraudulent financial results and backdating stock options. these illegal acts are relatively rare, making random sampling inappropriate, necessitating use a matched pair design (o’connor et al., 2006). consistent with o’connor and colleagues (2006), to identify firms that had fraudulently inflated financial results, we reviewed 12,222 articles using the proquest® newspapers database of over 550 newspapers and searched for variations of the word “restate” in the text of fulltext articles. to identify firms with specific instances of backdating, we used the wall street journal online options scorecard. janney and gove (2011) used the full database to study relationships between corporate social responsibility and stock option backdating. to ensure firms in our sample were unambiguously involved with backdating, firms had to meet one of three criteria: (1) the firm admitted that certain historical stock option grants were found to differ from the recorded grant dates, or (2) the firm restated financial results for costs related to backdating, or (3) the firm settled backdating charges with the federal government. the backdating firms included in this sample had at least one instance of backdating. next, to provide a comparison group (non-restating and backdating firms), we developed a matched-sample design (denis, hanouna, & sarin, 2006; harris & bromiley, 2007; o’connor et al., 2006) by closely matching each firm that had committed an illegal act with a similar firm based on five criteria. all matched firms (1) are publicly traded, (2) are based in the u.s. as of the year corresponding to the backdating, (3) share four-digit standard industry classification codes (sic), (4) have similar net sales, and (5) have similar net incomes. our review of proquest® articles identified 103 firms that met our criteria, and we were able to identify close matches for 65 firms. our review of the the wall street journal online options scorecard included fourteen backdating firms that we dropped because the necessary financial data were unavailable or they were headquartered outside of the u.s., leaving 82 firms for our analyses. thus, the final sample included 65 firms that had been forced to restate their financial reports and 82 backdating firms. including the matched firms, our sample totals 294 firms, of which 130 make up the forced restatement group and 164 are in the backdating group. 38 journal of business strategies because the exact date of each instance of illegal activity is typically not identifiable, we incorporate a one-year lag in our models. thus, if a firm was investigated for backdating or restated earnings in year t, data for all independent and control variables were collected for year t-1 (except for value of exercisable options, discussed below, which were collected for year t). this lag structure is appropriate since ceo compensation (including stock options) is determined annually and is influenced by firm performance in the prior year (coombs & gilley, 2005). the data sources for all variables are the wall street journal online options scorecard, the proquest® newspapers database, compustat, execucomp, and the sec’s edgar database. dependent variables the dependent variable is corporate illegal activity, which is a binary variable coded as 1 if the firm committed an illegal activity (either backdating or forced restatements) and 0 if the firm did not. a binary variable is used because whether a firm committed an illegal act is a dichotomous phenomenon and because assigning a specific dollar amount for the financial consequences of these illegal acts requires consideration of numerous arbitrary factors. control variables twelve control variables are used in the analyses. executives in larger firms may be more likely to commit illegal acts because they may face more pressure to suppress their values if they hinder organizational priorities (gabbioneta, greenwood, mazzola, & minoja, 2013). thus, we control for firm size using the natural logarithm of total sales. we control for the number of audit committee meetings held annually (o’connor et al., 2006), as the number of audit committee meetings may decrease the likelihood of illegal acts (ndofor et al., 2015; o’connor et al., 2006). ceo age is used as a control variable because of its relationship with both managerial risk propensity and moral judgment (zahra, priem, & rasheed, 2005) as well as its negative relationship with financial misconduct (o’connor et al., 2006). ceo age is measured in years. ceo cash compensation is measured as the sum of salary and bonus cash compensation. volume 35, number 2 39 higher ceo cash compensation might be expected to decrease ceo motivation to commit illegal acts (finkelstein and boyd, 1998; henderson and fredrickson, 1996). stock option grants are the very mechanism through which executives have enriched themselves, whether it is from fraudulent financial reporting or stock option backdating. we expect more option grants to increase the likelihood that executives will commit illegal acts. stock option grants are measured as the number of stock options the ceo received in the year of the organization’s illegal act. ceo tenure is associated with experience and power (shen, 2003) and is measured as the number of years the ceo has held that title at the focal firm. ceo duality is measured as 1 if the ceo is also the chair of the board of directors and 0 if the ceo is not, and it is considered a measure of ceo power (harris & bromiley, 2007). ceo ownership is measured as the percentage of stock owned by the ceo (zhang et al., 2008). we expect that when ceos have higher ownership they have less motivation to commit illegal acts. as harris and bromiley (2007) note, poor performance against historic company standards motivates executives to respond. as a result, self reference equals 1 where the firm’s return on assetst-1 minus its return on assetst-2 is positive and 0 if not (harris & bromiley, 2007). board of directors (bod) options is a binary variable reflecting the presence (1) or absence (0) of bod stock options. hambrick and jackson (2000) provided evidence that companies with directors who own company stock outperform other firms, suggesting these options may align board member interests with shareholder interests. moderators williams and colleagues (2005) recently argued that larger boards are better able to monitor executive actions because larger boards may process larger quantities of information more quickly, thus decreasing information asymmetries between management and shareholders. larger boards may also form and use more committees with which to monitor management, and they are better able to constrain executives’ political coalitions. board members are measured as the total number of board members for each firm. percentage of outsiders on the board (abrahamson & park, 1994) was measured as the number of outsiders divided by the total number of directors. 40 journal of business strategies independent variable religiosity is the independent variable in our analyses. to create our measure, we followed the process used by mcguire and colleagues (2012). we used a gallup organization database of over 610,000 interviews conducted nationwide on a range of religious characteristics and focused on three of religiosity’s distinct elements: cognitive, affective, and behavioral (parboteeah, hoegl, & cullen, 2008). consistent with mcguire and colleagues (2012), we used three poll questions that correspond with the three elements of religiosity: (1) are you affiliated with a particular religion (cognitive); (2) is religion important in your daily life (affective); and (3) do you attend religious services weekly (behavioral). data for these questions is available at the county level. we grouped counties into metropolitan statistical areas (msas) and aggregated scores for each question into an msa-level score. we then changed the scores for each question into z-scores and summed these results to create msalevel scores for religiosity. data analysis and results to test our hypotheses, we use logistic regression, which is appropriate for analyzing models with dichotomous dependent variables (hoetker, 2007). conditional logistic regression is typically used with dichotomous dependent variables when the sample follows a matched-pair design (agresti, 2002); however, it does not provide an intercept necessary for graphing interaction results. so to confirm our logistic regression results, we also tested our hypotheses with conditional logistic regression and found consistent results. we also follow hoetker’s (2007) and wiersema and bowen’s (2009) suggestions to report marginal effects when interpreting direct effects between independent variables and the dependent variable. consistent with sanders and hambrick (2007), we report one-tailed tests for our hypothesized interactions and two-tailed results for our control variables. lastly, all variables (except for binary variables) were mean centered before hypothesis testing. table i reports uncentered descriptive statistics and correlations for the variables. volume 35, number 2 41 table 1 correlation matrix table 1 (cont.) correlation matrix 42 journal of business strategies table 2 logistic regression results for religiosity and illegal financial activity (includes backdating and forced restatements) results for hypothesis 1 are shown in model 2 of table ii. hypothesis 1 argued that religiosity is negatively associated with corporate illegal activity. results from model 2 support the statistical significance of this relationship, although the relationship is weak. this result suggests that religiosity does have a weak but significant negative influence on illegal corporate activity. results for hypotheses 2 and 3 are shown in model 4 of table ii. hypothesis 2 argues that board size moderates the relationship between religiosity and corporate illegal activity, such that the negative relationship between religiosity and corporate illegal activity will be stronger in organizations with a larger board of directors. hypothesis 2 is not supported. the interaction between religiosity and board size is positive and our plot of these results confirms that larger boards actually increase the likelihood of backdating as the level of religiosity rises. hypothesis 3 stated that board independence moderates of the relationship between religiosity and corporate illegal activity, such that the negative relationship between volume 35, number 2 43 religiosity and corporate illegal activity will be stronger in organizations with more independent boards. our results provide support for hypothesis 3 and our plot of this relationship lends further support. figure 1 interaction between religiosity and board size figure 2 interaction between religiosity and outsider percentage to determine whether our results were consistent across different types of illegal acts, we also conducted the above analyses separately for only firms that restated financial results and for only firms where stock options were backdated. interestingly, for firms that restated their financials, there was no significant 44 journal of business strategies relationship between religiosity and restatements. further, the interaction of religiosity and board size was not significant. the interaction of religiosity and board outsider percentage, however, was negative and significant suggesting that religiosity can still influence restatements, and that the influence is enhanced by board independence. regarding firms where stock option backdating occurred, religiosity had a highly significant, negative influence, suggesting that religiosity by itself may serve to limit stock option backdating. further, the interaction between religiosity and board size is significant and positive as in our original set of analyses, suggesting that larger boards inhibit the influence of religiosity on stock option backdating. the interaction between religiosity and percentage of outsiders on the board is not significant, indicating that board independence does not enhance the effect of religiosity on stock option backdating. table 3 logistic regression results for religiosity and forced restatements volume 35, number 2 45 table 4 logistic regression results for religiosity and stock option backdating discussion our study was motivated by the desire to extend theory by integrating institutional theory (north, 1990; scott, 2001) with agency theory (fama & jensen, 1983; jensen & meckling, 1976) as suggested by eisenhardt (1989). in doing so, we introduced religiosity as a normative institutional construct that may reduce the likelihood of agent-based opportunism in the form of illegal corporate activity. we view illegal corporate activity as a form of opportunistic behavior that has been largely overlooked because research has focused on more easily observable forms of opportunism (dow, 1987; ghoshal & moran, 1996). we focus on forced financial restatements and stock option backdating as forms of illegal corporate activity because the sec has formally recognized these activities as fraudulent and because stock options have been viewed as aligning interests of agents and principals (eisenhardt, 1989). moreover, these forms of opportunism are less researched than 46 journal of business strategies other forms, such as excessive compensation. our research makes three specific contributions of interest to institutional and agency theory researchers. first, we take up eisenhardt’s (1989) call to integrate agency theory with other complementary theories by introducing institutional theory to explain how corporate illegal activity may be reduced. corporate illegal activity is particularly important to understand, as it may reflect executives’ attempts to increase their personal gain to offset compensation reductions resulting from increased monitoring in other areas (dow, 1987; ghoshal & moran, 1996). eisenhardt’s (1989) suggestion to draw from other theories is particularly timely because agency theory prescriptions to mitigate opportunism appear to have increased other forms of opportunism (dalton et al., 2007; devers et al., 2007). we posit that pressure from normative institutions may help to mitigate these new forms of opportunism. second, we develop theory to clarify how normative institutions may influence social actors such as executives to not engage in corporate illegal activity. more specifically, we introduce religiosity as a normative institutional concept and explain how the level of religiosity in the geographic region around an organization’s headquarters forms social norms of honesty and risk aversion in which executives live and make decisions (cialdini & goldstein, 2004; halek & eisenhauer, 2001; kohlberg, 1984; sunstein, 1996). additionally, we explain how institutional norms are transferred from the social to the organizational level and discuss how these institutional norms interact with board of director variables to influence corporate illegal activity. finally, we extend recent work relating religiosity with legal accounting tactics such as earnings management (callen et al., 2011; mcguire et al., 2012), voluntary financial restatements (dyreng et al., 2012), and investment and growth rates (hilary & hui, 2009) to the realm of illegal corporate activity. we also extend recent work on corporate illegal activity by examining two forms of illegal activity (i.e., fraudulent restatements and stock option backdating). specifically, we investigate the direct effect of religiosity on corporate illegal activity as well as the interaction effects of board size and board independence. we formally hypothesized that religiosity would negatively affect illegal corporate activity. our results support this direct hypothesized relationship, particularly with regard to backdating. this result indicates that executives in firms located in more religious geographic areas are indeed influenced by the social norms of their environment. although both backdating and reporting fraudulent financials are illegal, there are clearly important differences in the underlying reasons they occur. volume 35, number 2 47 moreover, we hypothesized that board size moderates the relationship between religiosity and illegal corporate activity. our results did not support this hypothesis. in fact, larger boards actually increased the likelihood of illegal activity occurring. this result suggests that smaller boards may monitor executives more effectively with respect to these actions, perhaps because smaller boards encourage greater focus, engender member participation and cohesiveness, endure less social loafing, and encourage genuine debate among board members (firstenberg & malkiel, 1994; lipton & lorsch, 1992; williams et al., 2005). they may also be more homogenous and easier to coordinate with regard to executive control mechanisms. subsequent analyses show that this relationship is entirely associated with stock option backdating and not fraudulent financial reporting, further demonstrating underlying differences between these illegal activities. we also hypothesized that board independence would moderate the relationship between religiosity and illegal corporate behavior. our results support this hypothesis, as the relationship between religiosity and illegal activity becomes stronger as board independence increases. once more, subsequent analyses clarify this relationship. it is actually only for firms restating fraudulent financials that this relationship holds. once more, a difference between the two forms of illegal activity is evident. implications our results indicate that eisenhardt (1989) was correct when she suggested that agency theory might fruitfully be combined with other theories to explain organizational phenomena. we integrate institutional theory with agency theory and demonstrate that social norms associated with religiosity can influence executive decisions to act illegally. this is a key finding, as some scholars (e.g., ghoshal & moran, 1996) suggest that when some forms of opportunism are closely monitored, agents react by searching for other opportunities, even if they involve illegal actions. our findings are consistent with institutional theory in that social norms can influence executive decision-making (north, 1990; scott, 2001). for practitioners, our results have important implications. considerable effort has gone into finding ways to keep executives from acting opportunistically. these efforts have primarily been aimed at aligning the interests of executives and shareholders through stock options and similar tools. our findings suggest that those efforts may yield unintended consequences by inducing executives to game compensation systems. 48 journal of business strategies limitations and future research as with any study, ours has limitations that provide future research opportunities. first, our study focused on illegal corporate activity in the form of fraudulent financial reporting and stock option backdating. scholars may consider whether other forms of opportunism are being used by executives and whether agency theory alone can explain these activities or if additional theories may be required. scholars may also consider whether opportunism is even more multifaceted. it may be that there are different forms of opportunism that require different actions be taken to limit their damage. a second limitation of our study was its focus on a single institutional measure (religiosity) and a limited number of board characteristics (board size and board independence). institutions are not limited to those that are social in nature. scholars may consider whether regulative and cultural-cognitive institutions may have as much of an effect on illegal corporate activity as do normative institutions. additionally, other board and ceo characteristics such as power are ripe areas to be integrated with other theories. in particular, an examination of ceo religiosity and its influence on behaviors may yield interesting results. finally, our study focuses only on the ceo. evidence suggests, however, that in many cases of illegal activity, other executives such as the cfo and coo are involved. there is also evidence in testimony to the securities and exchange commission that managers below the executive rank have benefitted from and been involved in illegal activities. research to help scholars better understand these actions would be beneficial. conclusion to date, scholars still understand too little regarding illegal corporate activity, despite its continued occurrence. our study demonstrates that religiosity directly influences illegal corporate activity, but that this influence holds for stock option backdating and not fraudulent financial reporting. we further argued and found support for the moderating effect of board characteristics, though these relationships depend on the type of illegal activity examined. our study confirms that corporate illegality is highly complex and that additional measures are necessary to prevent its occurrence. we hope that our research stimulates development in agency theory regarding how different forms of opportunism can be curtailed. we also hope that our research stimulates the integration of other theories with agency theory to provide a more complete understanding of how opportunism can be mitigated. volume 35, number 2 49 references aboody, d., & kasznik, r. (2000). ceo stock option awards and the timing of corporate voluntary disclosures. journal of accounting and economics, 29, 73100. abrahamson, e., & park, c. (1994). concealment of organisational outcomes: an agency theory perspective. academy of management journal, 5: 1302-1334. agresti, a. 2002. categorical data analysis (2nd ed.). hoboken, nj: wiley. amason, a. c., & sapienza, h. j. (1997). the effects of top management team size and interaction norms on cognitive and affective conflict. journal of management, 23, 495-516. arthaud-day, m., certo, s. t., dalton, c. m., & dalton, d. r. (2006). a changing of the guard: executive and director turnover following corporate financial restatements. academy of management journal, 49, 1119-1136. baysinger, b. d., & butler, h. h. (1985). corporate governance and the board of directors: performance effects of changes in board composition. journal of law, economics, and organization, 1, 101-124. blake, j., & davis, k. (1964). norms, values, and sanctions. in handbook of modern sociology, farris, r. e. l. jr., (ed.). chicago: rand mcnally, 456-484. callen, j. l., morel, m., & richardson g. (2011). do culture and religion mitigate earnings management? evidence from a cross-country analysis. international journal of disclosure and governance, 8, 103-121. cialdini, r. b., & goldstein, n. j. (2004). social influence: compliance and conformity. annual review of psychology, 55, 591-621. coombs, j. e., & gilley, k. m. (2005). stakeholder management as a predictor of ceo compensation: main effects and interactions with financial performance. strategic management journal, 26, 827-840. dalton, d. r., daily, c. m., ellstrand, a. e., & johnson, j. l. (1998). meta-analytic reviews of board composition, leadership structure, and financial performance. strategic management journal, 19, 269-290. dalton, d. r., hitt, m. a., certo, t. s., & dalton, c. m. (2007). the fundamental agency problem and its mitigation: independence, equity, and the market for corporate control. academy of management annals, 1, 1-64. denis, d. j., hanouna, p., & sarin, a. (2006). is there a dark side to incentive compensation? journal of corporate finance, 12, 467-488. 50 journal of business strategies devers, c. e., cannella, a. a., reilly, g. p., & yoder, m. e. (2007). executive compensation: a multidisciplinary review of recent developments. journal of management, 33, 1016-1072. diaz, j. (2000). religion and gambling in sin-city: a statistical analysis of the relationship between religion and gambling patterns in las vegas residents. the social science journal, 37, 453-458. dimaggio, p. j., & powell, w. w. (1983). the iron cage revisited: institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. american sociological review, 48, 147-160. dohmen, t., falk, a., huffman, d., sunde, u., schupp, j., & wagner, g. g. (2011). individual risk attitudes: measurement, determinants and behavioral consequences. journal of the european economic association, 9, 522-550. dow, g. k. (1987). the function of authority in transaction cost economics. journal of economic behavior and organization 8, 13-38. dyreng, s. d., mayew, w. j., & williams, c. d. (2012). religious social norms and corporate financial reporting. journal of business finance and accounting, 39, 845-875. eisenhardt, k. m. (1989). agency theory: an assessment and review. academy of management review, 14, 57-74. ezzamel, m. a., & watson, r. (1993). organizational form, ownership structure, and corporate performance: a contextual empirical analysis of uk companies. british journal of management, 4(3), 161-176. fama, e. f. (1980). agency problems and the theory of the firm. journal of political economy, 88, 288-307. fama, e. f., & jensen, m. c. (1983). separation of ownership and control. journal of law and economics, 26, 301-325. finkelstein, s., & boyd, b. k. (1998). how much does the ceo matter: the role of managerial discretion in the setting of ceo compensation. academy of management journal, 41, 179-199. firstenberg, p. b., & malkiel, b. g. (1994). the twenty-first century board-room: who will be in charge? sloan management review, 36, 27-35. gabbioneta, c., greenwood, r., mazzola, p., & minoja, m. (2013). the influence of the institutional context on corporate illegality. accounting, organizations and society, 38, 484-504. ghoshal, s., & moran, p. (1996). bad for practice: a critique of the transaction cost theory. academy of management review, 21, 13-47. volume 35, number 2 51 grullon, g., kanatas, g., & weston, j. religion and corporate (mis)behavior. unpublished working paper. rice university. halek, m., & eisenhauer, j. (2011). demography of risk aversion. journal of risk and insurance, 68, 1-24. hambrick, d. c., & jackson, e. m. (2000). outside directors with a stake: the linchpin in improving governance. california management review, 42, 108127. harris, j., & bromiley, p. (2007). incentives to cheat: the influence of executive compensation and firm performance on financial misrepresentation. organization science, 18, 350-367. henderson, a. d., & fredrickson, j. w. (1996). information-processing demands as a determinant of ceo compensation. academy of management journal, 39, 575-606. heron, r. a., & lie, e. (2007). does backdating explain the stock price pattern around executive stock option grants? journal of financial economics, 83, 271295. heron, r. a., & lie, e. (2009). what fraction of stock option grants to top executives have been backdated or manipulated? management science, 55, 513-525. heron, r. a., lie, e., & perry, t. (2007). on the use (and abuse) of stock option grants. financial analyst journal, 63, 17-27. hilary, g., & hui, k. w. (2009). does religion matter in corporate decision making in america? journal of financial economics, 93, 455-473. hitt, m. a., ahlstrom, d., dacin, m. t., levitas, e., & svobodina, l. (2004). the institutional effects on strategic alliance partner selection in transition economies: china vs. russia. organization science, 15, 173-185. hoetker, g. (2007). the use of logit and probit models in strategic management research: critical issues. strategic management journal, 28, 331-343. iannaccone, l. r. (1998). introduction to the economics of religion. journal of economic literature, 36, 1465-1495. janney, j. j., & gove, s. (2011). reputation and corporate social responsibility aberrations, trends, and hypocrisy: reactions to firm choices in the stock option backdating scandal. journal of management studies, 48, 1562-1585. jensen, m. c., & meckling, w. h. (1976). theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs, and ownership structure. journal of financial economics, 3, 305360. katz, r. c., santman, j., & lonero, p. (1994). findings on the revised morally debatable behaviors scale. journal of psychology, 128(1), 15-21. 52 journal of business strategies kennedy, e. j., & lawton, l. (1998). religiousness and business ethics. journal of business ethics, 17, 163-175 kohlberg, l. (1984). essays on moral development vol. 2, the psychology of moral development. san francisco, ca: harper and row. lie, e. (2005). on the timing of ceo stock option awards. management science, 51, 802-812. lipton, m., & lorsch, j. w. (1992). a modest proposal for improved corporate governance. business lawyer, 48, 59-77 liu, e. y. (2010). are risk-taking persons less religious? risk preference, religious affiliation, and religious participation in taiwan. journal for the scientific study of religion, 49, 172-178. mazar, n., amir, o., & ariely, d. (2008). the dishonesty of honest people: a theory of self-concept maintenance. journal of marketing research, 45, 633-644. mcguire, s. t., omer, t. c., & sharp, n. y. (2012). the impact of religion on financial reporting irregularities. the accounting review, 87, 645-673. miller, a. (2000). going to hell in asia: the relationship between risk and religion in a cross-cultural setting. review of religious research, 40, 5-18. miller, a. s., & hoffman, j. p. (1995). risk and religion: an explanation of gender differences in religiosity. journal for the scientific study of religion, 34, 63-75. mizruchi, m. s. (1983). who controls whom? an examination of the relation between management and board of directors in large american corporations. academy of management journal, 8, 426-435. narayanan, m. p., schipani, c. a., & seyhun, h. n. (2007). the economic impact of backdating of executive stock options. michigan law review, 105, 1597-1641. narayanan, m. p., & seyhun, h. n. (2008). the dating game: do managers designate option grant dates to increase their compensation? the review of financial studies, 21, 1907-1945. ndofor, h. a., wesley, c., & priem, r. l. (2015). providing ceos with opportunities to cheat. journal of management, 41, 1774-1797. north, d. (1990). institutions, institutional change and economic performance. cambridge, uk: cambridge university press. noussair, c. n., trautmann, s. t., van de kuilen, g., & vellekoop, n. (2013). risk aversion and religion. journal of risk and uncertainty, 47, 165-183. ocasio, w. (1994). political dynamics and the circulation of power: ceo succession in u.s. industrial corporations, 1960-1990. administrative science quarterly, 39, 285-312. volume 35, number 2 53 o’connor, j. p., priem, r. l., coombs, j. e., & gilley, k. m. (2006). do ceo stock options prevent or promote corporate accounting irregularities? academy of management journal, 49, 483-500. parboteeah, k. p., hoegl, m., & cullen, j. b. (2008). ethics and religion: an empirical test of a multidimensional model. journal of business ethics, 80, 387-398. pearce, j. a., & zahra, s. a. (1992). board composition from a strategic contingency perspective. journal of management studies, 29, 411-438. peng, m. w. (2003). institutional transitions and strategic choices. academy of management review, 28, 275-296. perrin, r. d. (2000). religiosity and honesty: continuing the search for the consequential dimension. review of religious research, 41, 534-544. sanders, w. g., & hambrick, d. c. (2007). swinging for the fences: the effects of ceo stock options on company risk taking and performance. academy of management journal, 50, 1055-1078. scott, w. r. (2001). institutions and organizations. thousand oaks, ca: sage. shen, w. (2003). the dynamics of the ceo-board relationship: an evolutionary perspective. academy of management review, 28, 466-476. sunstein, c. r. (1996). social norms and social rules. columbia law review, 96, 903-968. weaver, g. r., & agle, b. r. (2002). religiosity and ethical behavior in organizations: a symbolic interactionist perspective. academy of management review, 27, 7797. welch, m. r., tittle, c. r., & petee, t. (1991). religion and deviance among adult catholics: a test of the “moral communities” hypothesis. journal for the scientific study of religion, 30, 159-172. wiersema, m. f., & bowen, h. p. (2009). the use of limited dependent variable techniques in strategy research: issues and methods. strategic management journal, 30, 679-692. williams, r. j., fadil, p. a, & armstrong, r. w. (2005). top management team tenure and corporate illegal activity: the moderating influence of board size. journal of managerial issues, 17, 479-493. zahra, s. a., & pearce, j. a. (1989). boards of directors and corporate financial performance: a review and integrative model. journal of management, 15, 291334. zahra, s. a., priem, r. l., & rasheed, a. a. (2005). the antecedents and consequences of top management fraud. journal of management, 31, 803-828. 54 journal of business strategies zhang, x., bartol, k. m., smith, k. g., pfarrer, m. d., & khanin, d. m. (2008). ceos on the edge: earnings manipulation and stock-based incentive misalignment. academy of management journal, 51, 241-258. brief biographical sketch of authors joseph e. coombs is an associate professor of management and academic director for entrepreneurship programs in the school of business at virginia commonwealth university where he teaches courses in entrepreneurship and strategic management. he received his doctorate from temple university. he has held faculty positions at rutgers university, james madison university, the university of richmond, and texas a&m university. k. matthew gilley holds the bill greehey chair in ethics and corporate social responsibility in the greehey school of business at st. mary’s university. he holds a doctorate in strategic management from the university of texas at arlington. his primary teaching and research interests are in the areas of ethical leadership, corporate responsibility, and bridging academic research and practice. joe o’connor recently retired from the marketing and management department after 11 years at the university of texas at el paso. dr. o’connor earned his ph.d. in management science in 2005 from the university of wisconsin – milwaukee. prior to joining academia, he spent 25 years as a senior leader in human resources for major corporations, as well as serving eight years on active duty with the united states army. tim thorley has a master’s degree in management from virginia commonwealth university and teaches financial literacy at dixie high school in st. george, utah. when he is not teaching, tim is busy with his kids, reading, and working in his garden. dr. curtis wesley is an assistant professor of strategy and entrepreneurship at the university of houston c.t. bauer college of business. his primary areas of interest are the positive organizational scholarship in corporate governance and entrepreneurship. he serves on the editorial board of the journal of management and has published in a variety of management outlets including the journal of management, strategic entrepreneurship journal, and business ethics quarterly. 66 journal of business strategies status incongruence in supervisor-subordinate dyads—the effects on subordinate job satisfaction and creative performance carliss d. miller sam houston state university • huntsville, tx orlando c. richard university of massachusetts – amherst • amherst, ma abstract extant research on status incongruence has begun to explore the resulting tensions it may engender between supervisor and subordinate, yet it excludes the role of other demographic factors beyond age which influence status perceptions. we draw on role congruity theory to examine how organizational culture influences whether supervisor-subordinate dyadic status incongruence has a negative or positive impact on subordinate job satisfaction and creative performance. we find that status incongruence reduces job satisfaction when supervisor-subordinate dyads work in a hierarchical organizational culture (i.e. low clan organizational culture), and job satisfaction increases for supervisor-subordinate dyads that work in a clan organizational culture (i.e. high clan organizational culture). furthermore, these effects on job satisfaction ultimately impacted subordinate creative job performance, supporting a moderated-mediation model. implications for future research on status incongruence are discussed. keywords: status incongruence, organizational culture, job satisfaction, creative job performance, role congruity theory, supervisor-subordinate dyads introduction status incongruence depicts a circumstance in which traditional status characteristics (e.g., age, work experience, organizational tenure) associated with leader roles and subordinate roles are reversed (hirschfeld & thomas, 2011; jarmon, 1976; perry, kulik, & zhou, 1999). traditional hierarchical norms depict supervisors as being the older, wiser, and more educated leader (collins, hair, & rocco, 2009), whereas in instances of status incongruence, the subordinate may be older and have more work experience or organizational tenure (triana, richard, & yücel, 2017). with the generational shifts in the labor market, organizations have a greater likelihood of status incongruence between supervisors and subordinates (collins et al., 2009), and it is important to investigate how status incongruence volume 37, number 2 67 impacts employee subjective states which are suggested to affect employee creativity (brief & weiss, 2002). for example, in a large company, it would not be an uncommon notion for an employee to manage someone 10-15 years older (knight, 2015). the supervisor-subordinate age difference dynamic (considering age as a status characteristic) has been well established in the literature (collins et al., 2009; kunze & menges, 2017; perry et al., 1999), but less is known about the additive effects of multiple instances of status incongruence where the supervisor is younger, less experienced, less tenured, and less educated (see lucas, 2017 for an example). in this scenario, employees may feel more qualified than their supervisor, and this feeling may greatly affect the employees’ level of job satisfaction (smith, 2013) and other subsequent effects. research suggests that status incongruence can result in tensions between subordinates and supervisors (collins et al., 2009; hirsch, 1990; shellenbarger & hymowitz, 1994). collins and colleagues (2009) reported that elder subordinates had low expectations of a younger supervisor, and they argue that low expectancy results in low support from the subordinate. other studies have shown that younger supervisors are reluctant to give directives to subordinates who are of the same age as their parents or grandparents (hirsch, 1990), and that elder employees also do not like to take orders from supervisors who are their children’s and grandchildren’s ages (hirsch, 1990; shellenbarger & hymowitz, 1994). perry et al. (1999) explain that younger supervisors managing older subordinates may contradict age norms because older employees typically manage younger employees. their research has documented well the tensions that status incongruence may engender between supervisor and subordinate. however, they only analyzed the impact of age difference, thereby negating the role of other factors influencing status. in this manuscript, we aim to build on the current literature on status incongruence by investigating the effects of incongruence on multiple characteristics (i.e. age, work experience, education, and organizational tenure), versus focusing on a single status characteristic. specifically, adopting triana, richard, and yucel’s (2017) characterization, status incongruence includes situations where the subordinate is not only potentially older than the supervisor, but also has possibly more education than the supervisor, has more work experience and/or has more organizational tenure than the supervisor. when there is no status incongruence, we would have status congruence, which refers to a situation where the supervisor is older, has more organizational tenure, work experience, and education than the subordinate. in this circumstance, the two members of the dyad are involved in a relationship which is congruent with traditional social status characteristics, and 68 journal of business strategies where role congruity theory (eagly & johannesen-schmidt, 2001; eagly & karau, 2002; eagly, karau, & johnson, 1992) would predict no reduction in subordinate affect (i.e., job satisfaction). as the workplace becomes more generationally diverse, it is necessary for researchers and managers alike to know what to expect from this diversity so they can better manage it. as the status incongruence phenomenon may or may not, in isolation, impact subordinate attitudes about their job situation or their ability to perform creatively, we consider the role that organizational context plays. specifically, we set out to explore how status incongruence affects subordinate overall job satisfaction, particularly when the organizational culture (de)emphasizes power differentials and hierarchy. organizational culture is defined as the pattern of shared values, beliefs, and assumptions that provide behavioral norms and social cues for organizational members, serving as an organizational control mechanism (deshpande and webster, 1989; perrone, zaheer, & mcevily, 2003). williams and o’reilly (1998) put forth that organizational culture acts as a powerful mechanism to manage differences, and it can encourage either solidarity or divisiveness. research supports the notion that organizational culture makes organizational identity salient for employees and encourages diverse members to base their social categorizations on common interests with the organization rather than on status characteristics (chatman, polzer, barsade, & neale, 1998). therefore, we examine whether status incongruence will have more negative (or positive) effects on subordinate job satisfaction when hierarchical status is (de)emphasized. we argue that job satisfaction is critical when managing across generations, as is the influence of organizational culture—the more employees feel valued in their working environment, they stand a greater likelihood of being satisfied with their jobs (delcampo, 2011; westerman & yamamura, 2007) despite the existence of status incongruence. because increased job satisfaction facilitates job performance (bowling, khazon, meyer, & burrus, 2015; wright, cropanzano, & bonett, 2007), we also examine under what organizational culture conditions that status incongruence effects on job satisfaction ultimately increase or decrease the creative aspect of subordinate job performance. our focus on creativity is justified due to the concern that status incongruence episodes may impede creative performance when influenced by the dissatisfaction that one may have with their job situation. furthermore, the possibility that a subordinate may express higher job satisfaction and thereby realize a creative performance advantage from being in a status incongruent situation, has not yet been acknowledged in the relational demography literature. for example, the literature on volume 37, number 2 69 teams would suggest that dyadic dissimilarity and even status incongruence–within the appropriate context–may also yield enhanced information sharing, creativity, and improved problem-solving capabilities (gilson, lim, luciano, & choi, 2013; homan, van knippenberg, van kleef, & de dreu, 2007; van knippenberg, de dreu, & homan, 2004; van knippenberg & schippers, 2007). therefore, we examine whether a high clan organizational culture—an environment that encourages employees to view coworkers and supervisors as an extended family of cohesiveness (ouchi, 1980; perrone, zaheer, & mcevily, 2003)—may create a positive context where subordinates working in status incongruent dyads actually express more job satisfaction, and therefore improve their subsequent creative performance. in summary, we explore relational demography within supervisor-subordinate dyads to understand subordinates’ states of affect, as well as behavioral reactions to status incongruence. figure 1 the conceptual model of the hypothesized of effects of supervisorsubordinate status incongruence on creative performance via job satisfaction when moderated by organizational culture our conceptualization offers a key organizational contextual factor, organizational culture, as a relevant contingency condition, through which job satisfaction mediates the relationship between status incongruence and subordinate creative job performance. we test the predictions of our theoretical model by conducting a field study using a sample of 178 supervisor-subordinate dyads, and we offer implications for future research and practice. 70 journal of business strategies theory and hypotheses status incongruence in supervisor-subordinate dyads according to eagly and karau’s (2002) role congruity theory, an impending situation for prejudice arises when social perceivers hold beliefs and expectations about individuals based on the status cues of certain demographic characteristics that may contrast with hierarchical norms related to age, education, or experience. these status characteristics (e.g. age, education, and/or experience) are often considered legitimizing status signals congruent with certain leadership positions and visible roles in organizations. in situations where employees see themselves as the leader prototype more so than the individuals leading them, perceptual inconsistency has been formed based on the employees’ beliefs and role expectations. the perceptual inconsistency of role expectations versus reality can lower employees’ selfevaluation (diekman & hirnisey, 2007; koenig, eagly, mitchell, & ristikari, 2011). perceived incongruity between employees’ status affiliations and the expected role for themselves and their leaders can lead to attitudes that are less positive toward the individuals who occupy a high-stakes role, such as in a supervisory role or leadership position. the perceived incongruity can lead to a form of prejudice where an older, more educated and more tenured subordinate may perceive a supervisor less qualified for the leadership role than themselves (monzani, hernandez bark, van dick, & peiró, 2015). in sum, role incongruity increases the likelihood that a supervisor with lower status characteristics (e.g. on the basis of age, education, and/ or experience) comparative to a subordinate may be perceived as less competent by the subordinate, which leads to the plausibility of negative subordinate responses to the job situation. a pertinent example of such a phenomenon is the prejudice toward leaders perceived as younger than their subordinates, which is derived from the incongruity that many people perceive between the characteristics of age and the requirements of leader roles, for example, older age should equate to leadership. based on role congruity theory, prejudice toward such leaders consists of two types of disadvantage—biased perceptions of leadership ability and fitting the leadership prototype (eagly & karau, 2002). first, drawing from the descriptive aspect of the age role, is the perception of younger leaders as possessing less leadership ability than their elder counterparts. second, deriving from the injunctive aspect of the age role is the less advantageous evaluation of behavior that fulfills the prescriptions of a leader role when this behavior is enacted by a younger leader compared to an elder employee. volume 37, number 2 71 the first type of disadvantage stems from social perceivers’ combining of the descriptive aspects of the leader roles. this blending produces the perception that younger and less tenured employees possess less agency and more communion, and therefore are less qualified for leadership, especially for executive roles (diekman & hirnisey, 2007). these two forms of disadvantages would lead to consequences such as less favorable attitudes toward younger and less tenured leaders, greater difficulty in younger and less tenured individuals attaining leadership roles, and greater difficulty in being recognized as effective in these roles (diekman & hirnisey, 2007). the above-mentioned discrepancy in status may have important effects on individual behaviors and outcomes. status incongruence refers to a situation where traditional status characteristics associated with the leader and subordinate roles appear to be reversed (triana et al., 2017). it is a relationship where lower-ranked individuals (e.g. a subordinate) possess more prestige-based status characteristics than do their high-ranked counterpart (e.g. a supervisor). nevertheless, following the trends of demographic changes and generational shifts in the workplace, it is not uncommon for older workers to report to younger supervisors (cappeli & novelli, 2010; kunze & menges, 2017). the pre-established patterns of behavior were well settled and accounted for over the past two decades, with studies elucidating how elder employees are reluctant to take instructions from supervisors who are younger than they are (hirsch, 1990; shellenbarger & hymowitz, 1994). in the same vein, sometimes younger supervisors are uncomfortable giving orders to subordinates who are older than they are (hirsch, 1990). conversely, status incongruence research which looked at status as embedded in age found that older workers expect less from younger supervisors than do younger workers (collins et al., 2009) still, findings about the impact of status incongruence on individual outcomes and behavior has been divided; evidence on age status incongruence in work dyads shows that tension is a probable outcome of status incongruence, whereas other studies have found more positive outcomes. for instance, perry et al (1999) found some evidence that age status incongruence may have serious implications in dyadic relationships. elder subordinates working under younger supervisors are more likely to engage in work change behavior, or adaptive behavior as a result of negative work affect (perry et al., 1999). they are also likely to exhibit positive conduct, such as citizenship behaviors, both towards other individuals and towards their organizations. one possible explanation may reside in the fact that elder employees engross in more citizenship when the organizational culture promotes inclusiveness. in sum, the perceived congruence between an individual’s status and role expectations results in attitudes that may be less positive toward their job situation 72 journal of business strategies when they are supervised by someone with lower status characteristics. if the individual’s self-concept is embedded in role congruence, then status incongruence withing the supervisor-subordinate dyad may be personally threatening and an impediment to the indivduals’s creative job performance (tierney & farmer, 2002). we argue that the saliency of status incongruence effects is dependent upon the organizational context, specifically the organizational culture in which the incongruence resides, as well as the performane nature of the job. the moderating role of clan organizational culture given that organizational culture is a control mechanism guiding behavior for organizational members, it creates a context which either elevates or buffers the likely tensions between dissimilar or status incongruent supervisor-subordinate dyads (deshpande & webster, 1989; perrone, zaheer, & mcevily, 2003; williams & o’reilly, 1998), depending on the type of culture (richard & miller, 2013). a clan-based organizational culture encourages employees to minimize the salience of individual differences between organizational members, and align more with the shared values, beliefs, and behavioral norms of the organization (chatman, polzer, barsade, & neale, 1998). organizational culture typologies vary along the cooperation and interdependence dimensions of human interaction (chatman & barsade, 1995; mcmillan-capehart, 2005; richard, kochan, & mcmillan-capehart, 2002). within the competing values framework (deshpande & webster, 1989; deshpande, farley, & webster, 2000), the dominant attributes that distinguish organizational culture types are considered and are operationalized across two dimensions: formal-informal organizational processes, and internal-external focus. for the purposes of our study, we will focus on the dimension of formal-informal organizational processes, operationalized as clan organizational culture (i.e. high clan culture) and hierarchical organizational culture (i.e. low clan culture), given that both organizational cultures are internally focused. clan organizational culture and hierarchical organizational cultures are antipodes. the clan organizational culture is considered a friendly place to work due to its informal governance. it emphasizes the development of human resources, employee participation in decision-making, teamwork, and cohesiveness, whereas the hierarchical organizational culture emphasizes formalization and mechanistic governance that reduce flexibility and variety, and thus may hamper the advantages of diversity/dissimilarity (richard & miller, 2013). employees working in clan volume 37, number 2 73 organizational cultures are largely influenced by internalized values and goals rather than by formal rules to determine appropriate action and behaviors due to a heavy emphasis on socialization (ouchi, 1980; perrone, zaheer, & mcevily, 2003). according to kerr and slocum (1987), a clan organizational culture is essentially characterized by long socialization processes, high commitment from organizational members, peer pressure to conform to expected behavioral norms, and the importance of supervisors functioning as mentors for social cues. for status incongruence in supervisor-subordinate dyads to yield positive outcomes, there necessitates a context that emphasizes cohesiveness, participation, and teamwork (dwyer, richard, & chadwick, 2003; pless & maak, 2004; richard, kochan, & mcmillan-capehart, 2002). for instance, a group atmosphere that encourages freedom of expression should facilitate openness among status incongruent supervisor-subordinate dyads (swann, polzer, seyle, & ko, 2004). this openness should lead to reduced conflict and tension, and instead create more positive outcomes, such as job satisfaction. per mcmillan and colleagues (2012), an “organizational culture based on hierarchies relies on the use of legitimate authority to achieve performance goals” (p. 312), to which job satisfaction has an important relationship (bowling, khazon, meyer, & burrus, 2015; wright et al. 2007). the consideration of legitimate authority is problematic in status incongruent supervisor-subordinate dyads because although the younger, less tenured, or less educated supervisor has positional power, the subordinate may be less willing to show deference, particularly in a hierarchical organizational culture (i.e. low clan organizational culture). hierarchical organizational cultures emphasize stability, structure, greater formalization, and are less concerned with creating and maintaining supportive relationships among organizational members (mcmillan et al., 2012). with more focus on employee control, monitoring, implementing rules and standard operating procedures (mcmillan et al., 2012; ouchi & price, 1993), this heightened attention from a lower status supervisor may create greater tension and lower job satisfaction for higher status subordinates because the expectations associated with the status characteristics conflict with the positional expectations (collins et al., 2009; hirsch, 1990; perry et al., 1999; shellenbarger & hymowitz, 1994). thus, we argue that subordinates in status incongruent dyads will likely experience greater job satisfaction in a clan organizational culture (i.e. high clan organizational culture) than in a hierarchical organizational culture (i.e. low clan organizational culture). hypothesis 1: dyadic status incongruence is negatively related to subordinate job satisfaction when clan organizational culture is low (i.e., 74 journal of business strategies hierarchical culture is high), and positively related to subordinate job satisfaction when clan organizational culture is high. the mediating role of job satisfaction previous research has consistently shown that job satisfaction increases employee job performance (franke & park, 2006; judge, thorese, bono, & patton, 2001; morrisson, 1997; petty, mcgee, & cavender, 1984). job satisfaction may increase individual performance because “people who evaluate an attitude-object favorable, tend to engage in behaviors that foster or support it, and people who evaluate an attitude object unfavorable tend to engage in behaviors that hinder or oppose it” (eagly & chaiken, 1993: 12). for example, keaveney and nelson (1993) found that job satisfaction increases job performance, arguing that such individuals intrinsically satisfied with their job may have a higher motivation orientation to perform better. furthermore, when studying the effects of job satisfaction and organizational commitment, shore and martin (1989) found that job satisfaction explained more incremental variance in the supervisor-rated measures of job performance. in addition, job satisfaction has been shown to be a mediator between a host of organizational factors and employee job performance (crede, chernyshenko, stark, dalal, & bashshur, 2007; yousef, 2000, 2002). one salient aspect of job performance, the creative component, has recently gained much attention in the literature (shalley, gilson & blum, 2009, tierney & farmer, 2002, zhang & bartol, 2010). we define creative job performance as the deliberate creation, promotion and actualization of novel ideas within one’s job function, work group, and organization, for the sake of the same job function, work group, and organization (janssen & van yperen, 2004; kanter, 1988; scott & bruce, 1994; west & farr, 1989). to encourage more creative performance, organizations have moved away from seniority-based compensation and promotion plans to meritbased plans to encourage competition and creative performance, giving younger and less tenured employees an opportunity to pursue leadership roles and stretch assignments that may have previously been out of reach. young, “fresh blood” may be less experienced, but they can also come with fresh ideas and more innovation. their lack of experience is viewed as an advantage, as they are considered not to be tainted with the notion of doing things the way they have always been done. this perspective is likely beneficial for supervisor creative performance; however the creative outcomes for the subordinates may be overlooked, as well as the implications of additive status incongruence between subordinates and their supervisors. volume 37, number 2 75 as we have argued above, low job satisfaction is a possible outcome for subordinates in status incongruent dyads, depending on the organizational culture. a potential symptom of job satisfaction is the status threat employees may experience due to the status differences with their supervisor. status threats may cause some individuals to behave in assertive, competitive ways towards their supervisors in order to defend their status (tiedens & fragale, 2003; lee, choi & kim, 2018) which can undermine the subordinate’s ability to perform creatively (lee et al., 2018). individuals processing the implications for experiencing multiple status differences with their supervisor takes extra mental energy which impedes one’s ability to think and perform creatively and innovatively. in a recent study by lee, choi, and kim (2018), the authors argue that status conflict—”disputes over the relative status positions of people in the social hierarchy of their group”—can hinder team creativity (p. 187). although status conflict is a different construct from status incongruence, our operationalization of status incongruence implies there is a felt conflict for the individual who is likely to feel more threatened by the lack of status congruence (i.e. the subordinate), thus impacting job satisfaction. because job satisfaction has been shown to be a key mediator in the organizational behavior domain, we examine whether it behaves as a mediator of the status incongruence to subordinate’s creative job performance relationship across high and low clan organizational culture. hypothesis 2: the negative (positive) effect of status incongruence on subordinate job satisfaction when clan organizational culture is low (high) will reduce (increase) supervisor-rated creative job performance. methods sample our data collection effort targeted both working professionals enrolled in a graduate program at a major university in the united states as well as their supervisors. the working professionals received a survey and subsequently invited their respective supervisors to respond to another survey; each supervisor responded to one survey as participants were from multiple organizations. this central aspect of our study design allowed us to collect data from the participants’ direct supervisor to increase the external validity of our research (rosnow & rosenthal, 2008), as well as to reduce the likelihood of common source bias. all survey respondents answered of their own will and the responses were 76 journal of business strategies kept confidential. the surveys were collected online using survey monkey to ensure the highest possible response rate. to guarantee the authenticity of the data collected, the supervisors could opt to provide their contact information for the researchers to conduct random checks for true submissions. responding students were granted extra credit for completing the employee survey, and additional extra credit if the supervisor completed the supervisor survey, which included an introductory note explaining the nature, purpose and procedure of the study. this was followed by a questionnaire which instructed the respondents how to answer the questions in the survey. in the employee survey, demographic data, as well as key measures including dyadic tenure (experience in years with the current supervisor) and job satisfaction were collected. the supervisor survey–collected one month after all subordinate surveys were turned in–inquired about the demographics of the supervisor as well as a request to rate the subordinate’s creative job performance. at the end of this process, both surveys were matched by means of an identification number provided by the subordinate participant to ensure proper matching of the subordinate and supervisor surveys, and to maintain confidentiality of the data (tepper & taylor, 2003). the initial response rate was 100%; however more than half (55%) did not yield a fully completed survey from their supervisor. in all, 178 dyadic pairs (matched employee and supervisor surveys) were collected, resulting in a final sample from various industries. such industries include service (42.7%), wholesale (3.5%), manufacturing (17.8%), government and education (12.9%), retail (7.7%), healthcare (6.9%), and other (8.4%). women represent 38.2% of the respondents, and the age range was between 18 and 59 years old. table 1 offers summary statistics and correlations between the variables of interest. dependent variable creative job performance (cjp) (supervisor-reported). the subordinate’s creative job performance was collected from the immediate supervisor. the measure was adopted from janssen and van yperen (2004) and consisted of nine items measured on a five-point likert scale with a coefficient alpha of .93. a sample item is, “creating new ideas for improvements.” volume 37, number 2 77 independent variables status incongruence (between subordinate and supervisor). consistent with previous status incongruence measures in the literature (jarmon, 1976; lundberg, kristenson, and starrin, 2009; perry et al., 1999; triana et al., 2017), we first determined whether there was a status incongruence between the supervisor and subordinate on the basis of age, education, work experience, and organizational tenure. employee education was measured on the employee survey in a question that asked them to rate their highest education degree received. the same question was asked in the supervisor survey to determined supervisor education. education was coded (1 = high school, 2 = associate degree, 3 = bachelor’s degree, 4 = graduate degree). both work experience and organizational tenure were measured in number of years and collected directly from the designated employee and the employee’s supervisor. consistent with triana, richard, and yucel (2017), we calculated the supervisor credentials (age, education, work experience, or organizational tenure) and then subtracted the subordinate credentials for each variable. this resulted in four calculations: one for age, one for education, one for work experience, and one for organizational tenure. if the result is negative, that means the subordinate has higher credentials than the supervisor on that variable (e.g. older age, higher educational attainment, more work experience, greater organizational tenure). then, following jarmon (1976), we dummy coded each of the four resulting calculations (i.e. 1 = high status incongruence or 0 = low status incongruence) to create four indicators of status incongruence. finally, we added these four incongruence indicators together to create an overall measure of status incongruence between the supervisor and subordinate, with values ranging from 0 to 4. mediator job satisfaction. we utilized three items from cammann, fichman. jenkins, and klesh (1983). a sample item is “in general, you are satisfied with your job.” measured on a sevenpoint likert type scale, the coefficient alpha is .84. 78 journal of business strategies moderator clan organizational culture (subordinate-reported). to measure clan organizational culture employees responded to a four-item scale adapted from the competing values framework scale developed by quinn and colleagues (cameron & quinn, 1999; quinn, 1988; quinn & rohrbaugh, 1983; quinn & spreitzer, 1991) and further validated by other researchers (howard, 1998; quinn & sprietzer, 1991). items were measured on a five-point likert scale where 1 = strongly disagree and 5 = strongly agree. items were: 1) my company is a very personal place. it is like an extended family, 2) the head of my company is generally considered to be a mentor, sage, or a father or mother figure, 3) the glue that holds my company together is loyalty and tradition, 4) my company emphasizes human resources. high cohesion is important. cronbach’s alpha for this measure was .80. control variable subordinate respondents provided information on our control variable, dyad tenure, which was number of years working under the direction of the supervisor (also collected from supervisor as validity check). descriptive statistics (means, standard deviations, and correlations) for all variables are shown in table 1. table 1 means, standard deviations, and correlations 25 table 1 means, standard deviations, and correlations variables m sd 1 2 3 4 5 1. dyad tenure 1.89 1.57 2. status incongruence .66 .73 .25** 3. clan culture 3.34 .90 .13 -.07 4. job satisfaction 3.88 .84 .02 -.10 .50** 5. creative job performance 3.50 .80 .29** .13 .10 .14 note: n = 178; ** p < .05; two-tailed volume 37, number 2 79 results before testing the hypotheses, we first evaluated the distinctiveness of the key constructs. because there were several scales assessed from the subordinate respondents, we conducted a confirmatory factor analysis (cfa) with amos 24.0 of the two subordinate-rated variables: clan organizational culture (4 items) and job satisfaction (3 items). the results showed that the hypothesized two-factor model provided an adequate fit to the data (χ2 = 27.81, p = .01, df = 13, cfi = .971). this model was significantly better than a one factor model (χ2 = 145.52, p = .000, df = 14, cfi = .744) that did not have acceptable fit. we then estimated our models using ordinary least squares regression and used the process macro in spss 24 (models 1 and 7) by hayes (2012) to test our moderation and moderated-mediation hypotheses table 2 regression tables for effects on job satisfaction and creative job performance (cjp) hypothesis 1 suggests that the relationship between status incongruence and job satisfaction is negative when clan culture is low and positive when clan culture is high. in model 4 of table 2, a significant interaction effect emerges (∆r2 = 5.04%) for job satisfaction (ß = .287, p = .0004), lending support for h1. we suggested status incongruence would be negatively (positively) related to job satisfaction when clan culture was low (high). figure 2 depicts a significant and negative slope when clan culture is low (-3.68; p = .0003) and a significant and positive slope when clan culture is high (2.65; p = .009). 26 table 2 regression tables for effects on job satisfaction and creative job performance (cjp) variable tested job satisfaction cjp model 1 model 2 model 3 model 4 model 5 constant 3.86*** 3.91** 2.39*** 3.92*** 2.71*** (.10) (.11) (.23) (.86) (.28) 1. dyad tenure .01 .03 -.02 .02 .14*** (.04) (.04) (.04) (.04) (.04) 2. status incongruence -.12 -.06 -.10 .08 (.09) (.08) (.08) (.08) 3. clan culture .47*** .44 (.06) (.06) 4. status incongruence x clan culture h1 .29*** (.08) 5. job satisfaction h2 .14* (.07) r-square .00 .01 .25 .30 .11 the coefficients and standard error (in parenthesis) are reported; n = 178 *** p < .001, ** p < .01, * p < .05 80 journal of business strategies figure 2 three-way interaction between status incongruence and clan culture on job satisfaction we used the bootstrapping approach to confirm mediation effects for our moderated-mediation hypotheses (h2) (preacher, rucker, & hayes, 2007). we ran our analysis using 5,000 bootstraps. hypothesis 2 predicts the conditional indirect effect of status incongruence on creative job performance via job satisfaction will be negative (positive) in low (high) clan cultures. as predicted, table 3 reports 95% bootstrapping confidence intervals showing the indirect effects. status incongruence effects on our creative job performance (via a decrease in job satisfaction) are negative under low clan culture conditions (table 3) (effect = -.0486, boot llci = -.1302 and boot ulci = -.0071) and positive under high clan culture conditions (effect = .0217, boot llci = .0018 and boot ulci = .0629) supporting h2. 29 figure 2 three-way interaction between status incongruence and clan culture on job satisfaction 3 3.2 3.4 3.6 3.8 4 4.2 4.4 4.6 4.8 5 low status incongruence high status incongruence jo b sa tis fa ct io n low clan organizational culture high clan organizational culture volume 37, number 2 81 table 3 moderated-mediation results. bootstrapped condtional indirect effects of job satisfaction on supervisor-rated creative job performance discussion our study’s aim was to investigate how multiple characteristics of status incongruence affect subordinate affect (i.e. job satisfaction), and ultimately, subordinate creative job performance across clan versus hierarchical organizational culture types. we found that in hierarchical organizations, typified by a low clan organizational culture, status incongruence leads to lower (overall) job satisfaction, but it increases job satisfaction in organizations with high clan cultures. additionally, such status incongruence impacts subordinates’ creative job performance as a result of the interplay between status incongruence and organizational culture. limitations and future research although the study and its design rely on multi-sourced data which signals great confidence in our findings, we offer a few limitations that may inform future research. first, our study may produce restricted findings because of its use of a cross-sectional design (i.e., we collected data related to organizational culture and job satisfaction at the same time), thereby limiting the extent of our inference for causality. our design did, however, put variables under scrutiny which are trait-based (i.e, status incongruence) and not state-based, suggesting characters, behaviors and feelings that are consistent and long-lasting. these differ from psychological states, which are temporary behaviors or feelings that depend on a person’s situation and motives (mehroof & griffiths, 2010). furthermore, we were able to collect creative performance from the supervisor at a 1-month period later than the subordinate, offering some longitudinal tenets. to curb potential doubts about cross-sectional design, future studies may consider a longitudinal design to show the robustness of our trait-based cross-sectional design. 27 table 3 moderated-mediation results. bootstrapped conditional indirect effects of job satisfaction on supervisor rated creative job performance dependent variable: creative job performance mediator-job satisfaction moderator-clan culture effect boot se bootllci bootulci low -.05 .03 -.13 -.01 high .02 .02 .00 .06 note: n = 178. bootstrap sample size = 5,000 82 journal of business strategies an additional potential limitation of our study is a monocultural source of data as we only sampled participants from the united states. despite the deliberate nature of this choice to show that there is variance among individuals’ perception of the importance of status in role congruity, such a sample may spark skepticism about the generalizability of the perception of status by the participants in our study. future research may want to test the influence of organizational culture types on the outcomes of status incongruence in other countries beyond the u.s. to test the generalizability of our findings. contributions the extant literature concerning role congruity and status incongruence has been helpful in predicting the interpersonal dynamics that affect supervisor and subordinate relationships; however, the literature has not directly addressed the influence of organizations and organizational context in shaping supervisorsubordinate relations. we understand anecdotally and empirically that status incongruence between a supervisor and subordinate may result in some interpersonal tension that could stifle the subordinate’s job satisfaction and ability to perform creatively; however, our results provide evidence that the culture of the organization can exacerbate or lessen the negative implications of those tensions. our study complements the literature by specifying the type of organizational culture that would most likely foster greater job satisfaction and creative performance relative to the effects of supervisor-subordinate status incongruence. we show that clan organizational culture can indeed foster positive effects of status incongruence on subordinates’ job satisfaction and creativity. furthermore, while previous studies have shown that age is one factor that creates incongruence in supervisor-subordinate relationships, we follow the work of recent studies to show how multiple characteristics of status together affect the perceptions of roles and positions within dyads. our findings show that status incongruence should simultaneously consider additional characteristics including age (i.e. education, work experience, and organizational tenure), and thereby reconcile the literature to show that the effects of status incongruence have more theoretical and empirical precision when it is considered multidimensionally. conclusion this paper draws on a multidimensional conceptualization of status incongruence to explore when and how it affects subordinate’s job satisfaction and volume 37, number 2 83 creative performance. we provide evidence of the importance of organizational culture in shaping how both supervisor and subordinate may respond to situations when lower status individuals are conferred positional power. our results show that status incongruence decreases job satisfaction in a hierarchical organizational while it increases job satisfaction for dyads that work in a clan organizational culture, and that these ultimately impact subordinate creative job performance. these findings invite us to rethink the way we currently see status incongruent dyads by pointing to a more key part played by organizations in shaping how such incongruence affects individuals, dyads, and organizations. references brief, a. p., & weiss, h. m. (2002). organizational behavior: affect in the workplace. annual review of psychology, 53(1), 279-307. bowling, n., khazon, s., meyer, r., & burrus, c. (2015). situational strength as a moderator of the relationship between job satisfaction and job performance: a meta-analytic examination. journal of business & psychology, 30(1), 89-104. doi:10.1007/s10869-013-9340-7 cameron, k.s. & quinn, r.e. (1999). diagnosing and changing organizational culture. reading, mass.: addison-wesley. cammann, c., fichman, m., jenkins, d. g., jr., & klesh, j. r. (1983). assessing the attitudes and perceptions of organizational members. in s. e. seashore, e. e. lawler, p. h. mirvis, & c. cammann (eds.), assessing organizational change (pp. 711-738). new york: wiley. cappeli, p., & novelli, b. (2010). managing the older worker: how to prepare for the new organizational order. cambridge: harvard business press. chatman, j. a., & barsade, s. g. (1995). personality, organizational culture, and cooperation: evidence from a business simulation. administrative science quarterly, 423-443. chatman, j. a., polzer, j. t., barsade, s. g., & neale, m. a. (1998). being different yet feeling similar: the influence of demographic composition and organizational culture on work processes and outcomes. administrative science quarterly, 749-780. collins, m. h., hair jr, j. f., & rocco, t. s. (2009). the older‐worker‐younger‐ supervisor dyad: a test of the reverse pygmalion effect. human resource development quarterly, 20(1), 21-41. 84 journal of business strategies crede, m., chernyshenko, o. s., stark, s., dalal, r. s., & bashshur, m. (2007). job satisfaction as mediator: an assessment of job satisfaction’s position within the nomological network. journal of occupational and organizational psychology, 80(3), 515-538. delcampo, r. g. (2011). managing the multi-generational workforce: from the gi generation to the millennials. farnham, surrey: routledge. deshpande, r., & webster jr, f. e. (1989). organizational culture and marketing: defining the research agenda. the journal of marketing, 3-15. deshpande, r., farley, j. u., & webster, f. e. (2000). triad lessons: generalizing results on high performance firms in five business-to-business markets. international journal of research in marketing, 17(4), 353-362. diekman, a. b., & hirnisey, l. (2007). the effect of context on the silver ceiling: a role congruity perspective on prejudiced responses. personality and social psychology bulletin, 33(10), 1353-1366. dwyer, s., richard, o. c., & chadwick, k. (2003). gender diversity in management and firm performance: the influence of growth orientation and organizational culture. journal of business research, 56(12), 1009-1019. eagly, a. h., & chaiken, s. (1993). the psychology of attitudes. harcourt brace jovanovich college publishers. eagly, a. h., & johannesen‐schmidt, m. c. (2001). the leadership styles of women and men. journal of social issues, 57(4), 781-797. eagly, a. h., & karau, s. j. (2002). role congruity theory of prejudice toward female leaders. psychological review, 109(3), 573. eagly, a. h., karau, s. j., & johnson, b. t. (1992). gender and leadership style among school principals: a meta-analysis. educational administration quarterly, 28(1), 76-102. franke, g. r., & park, j. e. (2006). salesperson adaptive selling behavior and customer orientation: a meta-analysis. journal of marketing research, 43(4), 693-702. gilson, l. l., lim, h. s., luciano, m. m., & choi, j. n. (2013). unpacking the cross‐ level effects of tenure diversity, explicit knowledge, and knowledge sharing on individual creativity. journal of occupational and organizational psychology, 86(2), 203-222. hayes, a. f. (2012). process: a versatile computational tool for observed variable mediation, moderation, and conditional process modeling [white paper]. retrieved from http://www.afhayes.com/public/ process2012.pdf volume 37, number 2 85 hirsch j. s. (1990, february 26). older workers chafe under young managers. wall street journal, p. b1. hirschfeld, r. r., & thomas, c. h. (2011). age‐and gender‐based role incongruence: implications for knowledge mastery and observed leadership potential among personnel in a leadership development program. personnel psychology, 64(3), 661-692. homan, a. c., van knippenberg, d., van kleef, g. a., & de dreu, c. k. (2007). bridging faultlines by valuing diversity: diversity beliefs, information elaboration, and performance in diverse work groups. journal of applied psychology, 92(5), 1189-99. howard. l.w. (1998). validating the competing values model as a representation of organization cultures. the international journal of organizational analysis, 6(3), 231-80. janssen, o., & van yperen, n. w. (2004). employees’ goal orientations, the quality of leader-member exchange, and the outcomes of job performance and job satisfaction. academy of management journal, 47(3), 368-384. jarmon, c. (1976). education as a dimension of status incongruence between parents and the self-perceptions of college students. sociology of education, 49, 218222. judge, t. a., thoresen, c. j., bono, j. e., & patton, g. k. (2001). the job satisfaction– job performance relationship: a qualitative and quantitative review. kanter, r. (1988). when a thousand flowers bloom: structural, collective, and social conditions for innovation in organizations. in b. m. staw & l. l. cummings (eds.), research in organizational behavior, (vol. 10, pp. 169–211). greenwich, ct: jai press. keaveney, s. m., & nelson, j. e. (1993). coping with organizational role stress: intrinsic motivational orientation, perceived role benefits, and psychological withdrawal. journal of the academy of marketing science, 21(2), 113-124. kerr, j., & slocum, j. w. (1987). managing corporate culture through reward systems. the academy of management executive, 1(2), 99-107. knight, r. (2015). when your boss is younger than you. harvard business review digital articles, 2-6. koenig, a. m., eagly, a. h., mitchell, a. a., & ristikari, t. (2011). are leader stereotypes masculine? a meta-analysis of three research paradigms. psychological bulletin, 137(4), 616-642. doi:10.1037/a0023557 86 journal of business strategies kunze, f., & menges, j. i. (2017). younger supervisors, older subordinates: an organizational‐level study of age differences, emotions, and performance. journal of organizational behavior, 38(4), 461–486. https://doi.org/10.1002/job.2129 lawrence, b. s. (1996). organizational age norms: why is it so hard to know one when you see one? the gerontologist, 36(2), 209-220. lee, h. w., choi, j. n., & kim, s. (2018). does gender diversity help teams constructively manage status conflict? an evolutionary perspective of status conflict, team psychological safety, and team creativity. organizational behavior and human decision processes, 144, 187–199. https://doi.org/10.1016/j. obhdp.2017.09.005 lucas, s. (2017, september). new employee promoted over longer term employees: is this fair, legal, and good for employee morale to promote a new employee? retrieved from https://www.thebalance.com/new-employeepromoted-over-longer-term-employees-1919142 lundberg, j., kristenson, m., & starrin, b. (2009). status incongruence revisited: associations with shame and mental wellbeing. sociology of health & illness, 31(4), 478-493. mcmillan-capehart, a. (2005). a configurational framework for diversity: socialization and culture. personnel review, 34(4), 488-503. mcmillan, a., chen, h., richard, o. c., & bhuian, s. n. (2012). a mediation model of task conflict in vertical dyads: linking organizational culture, subordinate values, and subordinate outcomes. international journal of conflict management, 23(3), 307-332. mehroof, m., & griffiths, m. d. (2010). online gaming addiction: the role of sensation seeking, self-control, neuroticism, aggression, state anxiety, and trait anxiety. cyberpsychology, behavior and social networking, 13(3), 313–316. https://doi.org/10.1089/cyber.2009.0229 monzani, l., bark, a. s. h., van dick, r., & peiró, j. m. (2015). the synergistic effect of prototypicality and authenticity in the relation between leaders’ biological gender and their organizational identification. journal of business ethics, 132(4), 737-752. morrison, k. a. (1997). how franchise job satisfaction and personality affects performance, organizational commitment, franchisor relations, and intention to remain. journal of small business management, 35(3), 39-67. ouchi, w. g., & price, r. l. (1993). hierarchies, clans, and theory z: a new perspective on organization development. organizational dynamics, 21(4), 62-70. volume 37, number 2 87 ouchi, william g. (1980). markets, bureaucracies, and clans. administrative science quarterly, 25, 12941. perrone, v., zaheer, a., & mcevily, b. (2003). free to be trusted? organizational constraints on trust in boundary spanners. organization science, 14(4): 422439. perry, e. l., kulik, c. t., & zhou, j. (1999). a closer look at the effects of subordinate– supervisor age differences. journal of organizational behavior, 20(3), 341-357. petty, m. m., mcgee, g. w., & cavender, j. w. (1984). a meta-analysis of the relationships between individual job satisfaction and individual performance. academy of management review, 9(4), 712-721. pless, n., & maak, t. (2004). building an inclusive diversity culture: principles, processes and practice. journal of business ethics, 54(2), 129-147. preacher, k. j., rucker, d. d., & hayes, a. f. (2007). addressing moderated mediation hypotheses: theory, methods, and prescriptions. multivariate behavioral research, 42(1), 185-227. quinn, r. e. (1988). beyond rational management: mastering the paradoxes and competing demands of high performance. jossey-bass. quinn, r. e., & rohrbaugh, j. (1983). a spatial model of effectiveness criteria: towards a competing values approach to organizational analysis. management science, 29(3), 363-377. quinn, r. e., & spreitzer, g. m. (1991). the psychometrics of the competing values culture instrument and an analysis of the impact of organizational culture on quality of life. emerald. richard, o. c., & miller, c. d. (2013). considering diversity as a source of competitive advantage in organizations. the oxford handbook of diversity and work, 239-250. richard, o. c., kochan, t. a., & mcmillan-capehart, a. (2002). the impact of visible diversity on organizational effectiveness: disclosing the contents in pandora’s black box. journal of business and management, 8(3), 265. rosnow, r. l., & rosenthal, r. (2008). assessing the effect size of outcome research. in a. m. nezu & c. m. nezu (eds.), evidence-based outcome research: a practical guide to conducting randomized controlled trials for psychosocial interventions (pp. 379–401). new york, ny: oxford university press. scott, s. g., & bruce, r. a. (1994). determinants of innovative behavior: a path model of individual innovation in the workplace. academy of management journal, 37(3), 580-607. 88 journal of business strategies shalley, c. e., gilson, l. l., & blum, t. c. (2009). interactive effects of growth need strength, work context, and job complexity on self-reported creative performance. academy of management journal, 52(3), 489-505. shellenbarger, s., & hymowitz, c. (1994, june 13). over the hill? as population ages, older workers clash with younger bosses. wall street journal, p. a1. shore, l. m., & martin, h. j. (1989). job satisfaction and organizational commitment in relation to work performance and turnover intentions. human relations, 42(7), 625-638. smith, j. (2013). when you’re more qualified than the boss. forbes.com 22. business source complete, ebscohost (accessed january 5, 2018). swann, w. b., polzer, j. t., seyle, d. c., & ko, s. j. (2004). finding value in diversity: verification of personal and social self-views in diverse groups. academy of management review, 29(1), 9-27. tepper, b. j., & taylor, e. c. (2003). relationships among supervisors’ and subordinates’ procedural justice perceptions and organizational citizenship behaviors. academy of management journal, 46(1), 97-105. tiedens, l. z., & fragale, a. r. (2003). power moves: complementarity in dominant and submissive nonverbal behavior. journal of personality and social psychology, 84(3), 558–568. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.84.3.558 tierney, p., & farmer, s. m. (2002). creative self-efficacy: its potential antecedents and relationship to creative performance. academy of management journal, 45(6), 1137-1148. triana, m. d. c., richard, o. c., & yücel, i̇. (2017). status incongruence and supervisor gender as moderators of the transformational leadership to subordinate affective organizational commitment relationship. personnel psychology, 70(2), 429-467. van knippenberg, d., & schippers, m. c. (2007). work group diversity. annual review of psychology., 58, 515-541. doi: 10.1146/annurev.psych.58.110405.085546 van knippenberg, d., de dreu, c. w., & homan, a. c. (2004). work group diversity and group performance: an integrative model and research agenda. journal of applied psychology, 89(6), 1008-1022. doi:10.1037/0021-9010.89.6.1008 west, m. a., & farr, j. l. (1989). innovation at work: psychological perspectives. social behaviour, 4(1), 15–30. westerman, j. w., & yamamura, j. h. (2007). generational preferences for work environment fit: effects on employee outcomes. career development international, 12(2), 150-161. volume 37, number 2 89 williams, k., & o’reilly iii, c. (1998). forty years of diversity research: a review. in b. m. staw & l. l. cummings (eds.), research in organizational behavior, 20: 77-140. greenwich: jai press. wright, t. a., cropanzano, r., & bonett, d. g. (2007). the moderating role of employee positive well-being on the relation between job satisfaction and job performance. journal of occupational health psychology, 12(2), 93–104. yousef, d. a. (2000). organizational commitment: a mediator of the relationships of leadership behavior with job satisfaction and performance in a non-western country. journal of managerial psychology, 15(1), 6-24. yousef, d. a. (2002). job satisfaction as a mediator of the relationship between role stressors and organizational commitment: a study from an arabic cultural perspective. journal of managerial psychology, 17(4), 250-266. zhang, x., & bartol, k. m. (2010). the influence of creative process engagement on employee creative performance and overall job performance: a curvilinear assessment. journal of applied psychology, 95(5), 862. zhou, j., & hoever, i. j. (2014). research on workplace creativity: a review and redirection. annual review of organizational psychology and organizational behavior, 1, 333-359. brief biographical sketch of authors carliss d. miller is an assistant professor of management in the college of business administration at sam houston state university where she currently teaches organizational behavior, human resource management, and the mba seminar in team leadership. her primary research interests include workplace diversity, leader-follower relationships, and workplace deviance. dr. miller holds a ph.d. in international management studies from the university of texas at dallas, specializing in organizational behavior and human resource management. orlando c. richard (ph.d. from university of kentucky) is the dean’s research professor at the university of massachusetts amherst. the majority of his research studies fall under the domain of demographic diversity (both visible and nonvisible attributes) and seeks to move the field forward in understanding the complexities in how it relates to organizational processes and outcomes. strategic planning emphasis and planning satisfaction in small firms: an emprircal investigation javad kargar john a. parnell north carolina central university durham, nc abstract most empirical studies examining strategic planning effectiveness have focused on its impact on financial performance. however, solid empirically-based conclusions concerning the usefulness of strategic planning have not yet emerged. the present study takes an alternative perspective, examining two dimensions of executive satisfaction with strategic planning. results support a link between seven strategic planning characteristics and planning satisfaction among small firms. introduction according to a recent business week (1992:60) special edition, "change can [no longer] be an occasional episode in the life of a corporation. companies with rigid structures will be swept away. corporate cultures that can adapt will survive and thrive... " flexibility-as well as the related constructs of speed, adaptability, and change-has been touted as a key tenet of the "paradigm for the postmodern manager" (byrne, 1992:62). to yield positive results, change and flexibility necessitate prior effective strategic planning. however, researchers have not yet conclusively determined why some planning efforts are more successful than others in meeting this challenge. the present study examines the relationship between various facets of strategic planning and performance in small community banks. drawing on the planning literature, this article suggests that planning-performance research on small firms can produce meaningful results. strategic planning and performance over the past decade, researchers have investigated the effects of formal strategic planning on financial performance in small firms. many have concluded that there is no consistent association between the strategic planning process and performance (cappel, 1990; greenley, 1986; leontiades & tezel, 1980; orpen, 1985; robinson & pearce, 1983). in response to studies highlighting the impact of strategic planning on firm performance (karger & malik, 1975; rhyne, 1986; sapp & seiler, 1981; welch, 1984), recent research has 2 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 1 seen a greater emphasis on the strategic process rather than only on the strategy content that hofer (1975) proposed in his early study. steiner (1979) provided a thorough conceptualization of strategic planning. according to steiner, planning is an attitude and a process concerned with the future consequences of current decisions. formal strategic planning links short, intermediate, and long-range plans. strategic planning does not attempt to make future decisions or even forecast future events. it need not replace managerial intuition and judgment with massive, detailed sets of plans. steiner argued for the importance of strategic planning, providing keen insight into overcoming the barriers and biases associated with planning failures. however, research by steiner and others is founded in the critical assumption that planning is important. but the debate rages on in the literature. the key question remains: is there really a link between planning and performance? the literature is inundated with the apparent advantages of planning, most notably its ability to improve the fit between the organization and its external environment (godiwalla, meinhart, & warde, 1981). others have argued that planning aids in the identification of future marketing threats and opportunities, elicits an objective view of managerial problems, creates a {ramework for internal communication, promotes forward thinking, and encourages a favorable attitude to change (hausler, 1968; loasby, 1967; stern, 1966; wilson, 1979). further, there are intrinsic benefits that accrue as a result of the planning process, including the positive effects of planning on local employment and the economy (greenley, 1986). langley (1988) also provided support for the benefits of planning, identifying four roles of formal strategic planning. in the public relations role, formal strategic planning is intended to impress or influence outsiders. the information role provides input for management decisions. the group therapy role is intended to increase organizational commitment through the involvement of people at all levels of the organization in strategic planning. finally, the direction and control role is fulfilled when plans serve to guide future decisions and activities toward some consistent ends. according to roach and allen (1983), the strategic planning process is the product of the best minds inside and outside the corporation. the process considers future implications of current decisions, adjusts plans to the emerging business environment, manages the business analytically, and links, directs, and controls complex enterprises through a practical, working management system. this process plays a vital role in firm performance (roach & allen, 1983). cartwright (1987) suggested that effective planning is not as rational and analytical as it has been portrayed in the literature. he argues for the lost art (rather than science) of planning. he contends that planning is both (1) a generic activity whose success determinants are partially independent of the area in which it is applied, and (2) an area where judgment, intuition, and creativity are still important. spring 1996 kargar & parnell: strategic planning in small firms 3 robinson and pearce (1984) argued that fonnal strategic planning is a conceptual activity suited solely to larger finns and therefore has no effect on the financial perfonnance of small finns. wortman (1986) reviewed a set of small business planning-perfonnance studies in the context of a broad survey of the methodologies employed in the small business literature. wortman developed typologies but did not focus on the particular issue of the effect of fonnal strategic planning on small finn perfonnance. however, he clearly addressed the need for continued refinement in planning-perfonnance relationships and recommended the use of sophisticated statistical techniques for addressing such substantive research questions. greenley (1986) agreed with robinson and pearce and others to follow (cartwright, 1987; langley, 1988; ramanujam & venkatraman, 1987), but provided an alternative perspective, suggesting that there may not even be a positive relationship between planning and perfonnance. specifically, greenley noted the face validity of the planning-perfonnance linkage, but reports that existing empirical data has not yet substantiated the relationship. ramanujam and venkatraman (1987) provided limited support for greenley's contention. however, their empirical analysis of high and low perfonning finns elicited significant differences between the groups that relate to the planning process. specifically, their research examined the quality of the planning. for example, high perfonning finns tend to commit resources to planning and promote line-staff cooperation substantially more than low perfonning finns. low perfonners may plan; they just may not plan effectively. pearce, freeman, and robinson (1987) examined the perceived substantive contributions of each of eighteen existing studies, concluding that empirical support for the nonnative suggestions that all small finns should engage in fonnal strategic planning has been inconsistent and often contradictory. in a similar vein, schwenk and shrader (1993) recently meta-analyzed fourteen studies on fonnal strategic planning and perfonnance in small finns. while they did not find that planning necessarily improves perfonnance, they argued against the assertion that strategic planning is only appropriate for large finns. as such, they concluded that strategic planning promotes long-range thinking, reduces the focus on operational details, and provides a structured means for identifying and evaluating strategic alternatives. since this was the first review that clearly demonstrated the planning-perfonnance link across studies, it strengthened the case for recommending the use of strategic planning in all finns, regardless of size. sinha (1990) appears to have empirically established some kind of a planning-perfonnance linkage. sinha examined 1087 decisions made by 129 fortune 500 finns between 1982 and 1986. he concluded that characteristics of the decisions accounted for 15 percent of the variance in data and therefore should be regarded as important detenninants of the contribution planning makes to decision making. however, sinha concedes that the quality of planning is critical to the relationship. 4 journal of business strategies planning and strategic change vol. 13, no.1 there are three frequently cited reasons why top managers pursue changes in strategy (parnell, 1994). first, a change in strategy may appear attractive because desired performance levels are not being attained by the organization. in many cases, top managers may believe that a change in strategy will improve the ability of the business to generate revenues or profits, increase market share, and/or improve return on assets or investment. many studies have concluded that declining profitability is the most common catalyst for strategic change (boeker, 1989; webb & dawson, 1991). second, an environmental shift may necessitate strategic change to maintain alignment. such shifts may result from changes in either the macroenvironment (e.g., new regulations, social forces, demographic changes, etc.) or the industry environment (e.g., new competitors, changes in competitor strategies, etc.). changes in competition and technology necessitate a change in the knowledge base within the organization if it is to survive (whipp, rosenfeld, & pettigrew, 1989). according to the population ecology perspective (hannan & freeman, 1977~ ulrich, 1987), the environment determines which organizations will survive and which ones will not. new firms better suited to the changing environment constantly replace existing ones. competitors constantly struggle for existence by seeking to procure additional resources. as such, strategic change can be seen as a means to access additional resources and survive in a turbulent environment (aldrich, mckelvey, & ulrich, 1984). third, strategic change can enhance effective resource utilization (barney, 1991; lado, boyd, & wright, 1992). proponents of the resource-based perspective have noted that competitive advantage often occurs from such organizational attributes as informational asymmetries (barney, 1986b), culture (barney, 1986a; fiol, 1991), resource accumulation (dierickx & cool, 1989), and the minimization of transaction costs (camerer & vepsalainen, 1988). hence, as organizational human and capital resources evolve, changes in strategy become necessary to fully utilize the resources available to the organization. resource shifts necessitating strategic change are more prevalent in some organizations than in others. researchers have found that organizational performance, age, and length of tenure of the founding entrepreneur influence the degree to which a founding strategy endures and thus, the prospects for strategic change (boeker, 1989). in fact, new ceos are often recruited to attempt strategic changes upon entering the organization (greiner & bhambri, 1989). benefits and costs of strategic change there are three potential benefits of strategic change that are commonly cited in the literature. first, strategic change can enhance the strategy-environment fit. for example, calingo (1989) found that the low cost leadership strategy was most successful in price sensitive markets, whereas the differentiaspring 1996 kargar & parnell: strategic planning in small finns 5 tion strategy was most successful when consumers perceived great differences among product offerings. second, strategic change can open new dimensions of competitive advantage previously untapped by competitors. these first mover advantages result from the willingness of an organization to enter a new market or develop a new product or service prior to the competition (gannon, smith & grimm, 1992; lieberman & montgomery, 1988; mascarenhas, 1992; wemerfelt & kamani, 1989). finally, strategic change can improve an organization's ability to adapt by forcing healthy changes within the business. the initial pain associated with change may be offset by the emergence of a lean, rejuvenated organization with a fresh focus on its goals and objectives. on the contrary, organizations that maintain strategic consistency over time may become stagnant, limiting the creativity and potential contributions of its members (grimm & smith, 1991; wiersema & bantel, 1992). regardless of the potential benefits, four potential costs that may be incurred as a result of strategic change have received considerable attention in the literature. first, strategic change increases perceived risks; a change in any key strategic, environmental, or organizational factor requires that the business develop a new "formula" for success suited to the change (gaertner, 1989; yoshihara, 1990). second, change can disrupt the strategy-culture alignment (green, 1988; scholz, 1987; schwartz & davis, 1981). although the organizational culture may be changed (saffold, 1988; schein, 1990) to reflect and support the change in strategy, the period of time required to do so is likely to take several years (lorenz, 1988; saffold, 1988; schein, 1985; scholes, 1991). third, measures required to implement a change in strategy may necessitate the outlays of capital (miles & snow, 1978). finally, strategic change may result in consumer confusion as they begin to alter their perceptions of the organization's products and services. even when strategic change results in a successful new product or service, there is no assurance that this success can be maintained. indeed, competitors may distort consumer perceptions and reap the benefits of the initial strategic change. for example, many consumer goods companies implement an "imitation strategy" (foxman, muehling & berger, 1990). as a result, many consumers purchase the imitation product thinking it is the original. if the consumer dislikes the product, this dissatisfaction can be transferred to the origina1. if the consumer likes the product, the consumer may realize that the product is an imitator and transfer the positive associations with the original product to that of the imitator. either scenario can prove costly to the originator (loken, ross & hinkle, 1986). constructs and propositions empirical studies in small firms have generally employed a single dimension measure such as the presence or absence of planning or its degree of 6 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. i formality to explain variations in organizational performance. such conceptualizations are inconsistent with the multidimensional view of planning systems that are being viewed as more important in the recent literature (e.g. dyson & foster, 1982; king, 1983; kukalis, 1991; lorange, 1979, 1980; rhyne, 1987; veliyath & shortell, 1993). although many strategic planning system characteristics have been suggested in the literature, no consensus has yet emerged. for example, ramanujam and venkatraman (1987) proposed six dimensions of planning systems: use of techniques, attention to internal facets, attention to external facets, functional coverage, resources provided for planning, and resistance to planning. in another attempt to categorize strategic planning, veliyath and shortell (1993) identified five dimensions for strategic planning systems: planning implementation, market research competence, key personnel involvement, staff planning assistance, and innovativeness of strategies. further, these studies focused on large firms. thus, an expanded conceptualization of the notion of small-firm strategic planning is germane. following recent work (ramanujam & venkatraman, 1987~ veliyath & shortell, 1993), the strategic planning system characteristics in the present study includes: (l) the degree of internal orientation of the system, (2) the degree of external orientation of the system, (3) the level of integration achieved within functional departments, (4) the extent of key personnel involvement in the planning process, and (5) the extent of use of analytical techniques in addressing strategic issues. these planning system attributes, in addition to being well-grounded in the existing literature (see table 1), also appear to be problem areas in strategic planning within the banking industry. 1\vo dimensions of planning satisfaction most researchers who have investigated small-firm strategic planning have used financial and marketing measures as indicators of performance. these performance measures are based on how a business has performed in the past, implicitly assuming that such success can be extrapolated into the future. however, financial superiority is only one element of organization performance. perhaps more attention should be attached to an organization's ability to adapt to changes that are occurring and will occur in its environment. a realistic model of organization performance must reflect a highly complex paradigm and requires more than a single criterion (brown & laverick, 1994). as such, the present study adopts a broader perspective, examining satisfaction with planning. specifically, two dimensions are examined: satisfaction with the concrete and financial outcomes believed to be associated with the planning process, and satisfaction with the contribution of strategic planning efforts to overall organizational effectiveness. the first dimension follows the tradition of earlier studies that sought to examine the impact of planning on financial performance. although perfonnance objectives were included in the goal attainment spring 1996 kargar & parnell: strategic planning in small finns 7 dimension, there is a clear distinction between achieving perfonnance goals and being a high-perfonnance organization. the second dimension reflects a goal-centered approach to assessing organizational effectiveness (cameron & whetten, 1983; ramanujam, venkatraman & camillus, 1986). the goal attainment measure is primarily concerned with the specific end results nonnally anticipated from a planning system. this view reflects king's (1983) suggested approach to the evaluation of planning and steiner's (1979) notion of measurement against purpose. table 1 characteristics of strategic planning systems characteristic description supporting literature hitt, ireland, & paba (1982); hitt, ireland. & stadler (1982); lorange (1980); snow & hrebiniak (1980); ramanjam et at. (1986); ramanjam & venkatraman (1987) andrews (1971); mcdaniel & kolari (1987); ramanjam et a1. (1986); snow & hrebiniak (l980); veliyath & shortell (1993) cartwright (1987); greenley (1986); ramanjam et al. (1986); roach & allen (1983); shank, niblock & sandal (1973) andrews (1971); camillius (1975); king & cleland (1978); langley (1988) govindrajan (1986); mowday et at. (1982); ramanjam & venkatraman (1987); steers (1977); veliyath & shortell (1993) fredrickson (1984); grant & king (1982); hax & majluf (1984); ramanjam & venkatraman (1987) the degree of emphasis placed on planning as a means of organizational control the extent of attention camillus & venkatraman (l984); devoted to an organization's grant & king (1982); king & recent history and current cleland (1978); lorange & situation, past performance, vancil (1977); steiner (1979); and analysis of strengths stevenson (1976) and weaknesses ability to obtain reliable and timely research information in order to learn about external environmental opportunities and threats. the extent of coverage given to different functional areas with a view to integrating different functional requirements into a general management perspective. the degree of involvement of top management, board members, line and staff managers in planning process. the extent of reliance on appropriate planning techniques in order to solve ill-structured strategic problems. the degree to which planning efforts emphasize new modes of thinking. focus on control key personnel involvement creativity in planning functional integration internal orientation external orientation use of analytical techniques 8 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 1 propositions almost all previous small-firm research has examined relationships between strategic planning and organization performance with unidimensional treatments. however, the issue becomes more complicated when both sets of variables are conceptualized in multidimensional terms, as some authors have recently argued (e.g. ramanujam et al., 1986; ramanujam & venkatraman, 1987). hence, a positive relationship between strategic planning and performance dimensions among small firms is expected. specifically, the present study posits two propositions: 1. increased emphasis placed on each of the seven planning characteristics will be positively associated with each of the two dimensions of planning satisfaction. 2. top executives of firms that place the greatest emphasis on all seven planning characteristics will report the greatest satisfaction with planning along the two dimensions. likewise, top executives of firms that place the least emphasis on all seven planning characteristics will report the lowest satisfaction with planning along the two dimensions. methodology, analysis, and findings sample sixty-nine u.s. commercial banks in the state of north carolina were examined, representing the entire population with fewer than $500 million in total deposits. all 69 banks are considered small banks by banking industry standards (robinson and pearce, 1983). surveys were sent to the senior executives (presidents and/or ceos) of all the 69 banks. to improve the response rate, the north carolina commissioner of banks asked that each bank president and/or ceo cooperate by completing a questionnaire that would be sent to them. forty-seven of the 69 banks completed and returned the research questionnaire for a response rate of 68 percent. forty-one of these banks were chosen for further analysis to eliminate banks less than five years old as well as those that did not provide complete information. these criteria ensured that sample would not be biased toward banks with inadequately developed strategic planning systems, reducing the effective response rate to 59 percent. north carolina's small community banks provide an excellent opportunity to apply evaluation processes that are normally employed to study strategic planning in small businesses because they historically have had broad powers to engage in various businesses traditionally not associated with commercial lending (north carolina banking commission, 1991). challenges requiring strategic management by small community banks go beyond establishing new branches and typically include introducing new products/services, offering competitive personalized services, meeting the needs of small businesses, and altering racial lending patterns. the relative stability of the north carolina comspring 1996 kargar & parnell: strategic planning in small firms 9 mercial banks in an industry under turmoil also provided for a strong population from which to draw the sample. further, there was only one bank failure each in 1991 and in 1993 in north carolina. strategic planning characteristics the specific strategic planning system characteristics are summarized in table 2 and based on five-point likert scales ranging from no emphasis (1) to great emphasis (5). internal orientation was measured through the perceived degree of attention devoted to customer services, efficiency of operations process, attracting and retaining high-quality employees, and analysis of financial strengths and weaknesses. external orientation was measured by four items relating to the analysis of investment and deposit opportunities, competition and market analysis. functional coverage was measured by ramanujam and venkatraman's (1987) four-item scale relating to the perceived degree of emphasis accorded to functional involvement, coordination, and integration in planning activity. key personnel involvement was measured by the degree of ceo, board member, and line manager involvement in the strategic planning process. creativity in planning is assessed by ramanujam and others nine-item scale addressing the firm's ability to anticipate surprises and crises, to adapt to unanticipated changes, and so forth. the control aspect was measured by ramanujam and others (1986) ten-item scale which addressed the degree of emphasis given to managerial motivation, upward and downward communication in the hierarchy, integration of operational areas, and the like. finally, the use of planning techniques was measured by the degree of emphasis devoted to the application of financial models, portfolio analysis, and forecasting analysis techniques. strategic planning satisfaction planning satisfaction was measured via the two aforementioned dimensions, hereafter abbreviated as financial performance (finance) and organizational effectiveness (orgeff). these dimensions were measured by an eight-item, two-factor scale (see table 3) based on prior'work by ramanujam and venkatraman (1987), including items addressing areas such as the prediction of future trends, improving short-term performance, improving long-term performance, evaluating alternatives, and enhancing management development. respondents were asked to indicate their yiews via a 5-point scale, ranging from much deterioration (1) to much improvement (5), on eight criteria as a primary goal. factor loadings (see tables 2 and 3) indicate that all the factors tapped characteristics measuring states of planning system and organization performance. factor loadings in each scale were above 0.50 and eigenvalues for each factor were well above 1.0. internal consistency of each scale was also assessed and judged strong using cronbach's alpha (cronbach, 1951; van de yen & ferry, 1980). these assessments provide adequate support for the reliability 10 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 1 of the measures employed. factor scores were computed for each planning system characteristic and planning satisfaction dimension to serve as composite measures for hypothesis testing. table 2 planning system characteristics and their factor loadings* factor loadine internal orientation (intnlx 1: alpha =0.79) customer services 0.57 efficiency of operating process 0.91 attracting and retaining high-quality employees 0.86 analysis of financial strengths and weakness 0.80 external orientation (extnlx1; alpha = 0.66) analysis of investment opportunities 0.75 analysis of deposits opportunities 0.87 analysis of competition 0.73 performing market research 0.71 functional coverage (funtnx1; alpha =0.75) marketing function 0.77 finance function 0.86 personnel function 0.77 operations function 0.72 involvement of key personnel (resrsx1; alpha = 0.51) time spent by the ceo in strategic planning 0.93 involvement of line managers in strategic planning 0.54 involvement of board members in strategic planning 0.77 use of planning techniques (techkx1; alpha =0.63) financial models 0.90 forecasting and trend analysis 0.86 portfolio analysis techniques 0.71 creativity in planning (creatx1; alpha = 0.85) ability to anticipate surprises, threats and crises 0.74 flexibility to adapt to unanticipated changes 0.70 value of a mechanism for identifying new business opportunities 0.53 role of identifying key problems 0.78 value as a basis for enhancing innovation 0.69 capacity to generate new ideas 0.68 formulating goals to be achieved in the bank's competitive environment 0.50 capacity to generate and evaluate a number of strategic alternatives 0.72 anticipating, avoiding, and removing barriers to strategy implementation 0.73 focus on control (contrx1; alpha =0.94) value as a tool for management control 0.66 ability to communicate top management's expectations down the line 0.81 value as a tool for managerial motivation 0.79 capacity to foster organizational learning 0.78 ability to communicate line management's concern to top management 0.84 value as a mechanism for integrating diverse functions and operations 0.60 spring 1996 kargar & parnell: strategic planning in small firms 11 table 2 planning system characteristics and their factor loadings cont'd* factor loadina: monitoring & controlling the implementation of the bank's strategy 0.90 using multiple financial & non-financial control measures 0.83 using control techniques for monitoring performance 0.89 having control systems to revise current plans 0.83 *all scales were (1-5) likert scales: no emphasis (1) to great emphasis (5) table 3 satisfaction with planning and their factor loadings dependent variables factor loadina:s finance orgeff .73 .59 .82 .84 .83 financial performance items: predictions of future trends enhancing management development improving short-term performance improving long-term performance direct impact on financial performance organizational effectiveness items: improving ability to evaluate alternatives .15 improving ability to avoid mistakes .27 improvement of budget process .38 *all scales were (1-5) likert scales: no emphasis, to great emphasis. .41 .37 .18 .15 .36 .85 .79 .68 table 4 presents correlations among the dimensions. each planning system characteristic positively and significantly correlates with only finance and orgeff (at the .05 percent level). these results are consistent with the conceptual literature from which dimensions were distilled. the presence of the expected bivariate relationships between the planning system characteristics and these two satisfaction dimensions is encouraging, but the main focus of this study is on the multivariate relationship between the planning characteristics and planning satisfaction. having established the existence of appropriate measurement scales, proposition testing can be pursued. the first proposition was strongly supported. emphasis on each of the seven planning characteristics was positively associated with both satisfaction dimensions. further, firm size (employes) was not significantly associated with any of the seven characteristics. the second proposition was partially supported. to examine which factors contributed to the greatest satisfaction in planning along both dimensions, the forty-one businesses were clustered on the seven planning emphases into three distinct groups (see table 5). the purpose of the cluster analysis was to identify several groups of organizations, each of which would contain businesses with similar emphases on the seven planning characteristics. although table 4: descriptive statistics and correlations ....... n extnlxl funtnxi resrsxi techkxi creatxl contrxi finance orgeffcorrelations: employes intnlx i employes ooסס.1 p--. intnlxi .0041 1.0000 p=a90 p--. extnlxi -.1873 .6147 p=.120 p=.ouo funtnxi -.1630 a739 p=.154 p=.ool resrsxl .0914 a594 p=.285 p=.ool techkxi .1252 .3292 p=.218 p=.018 creatxi -.2428 .5637 p=.063 p=.ooo contrxi -.1430 .6026 p=.186 p=.ooo finance -.2057 .3478 p=.099 p=.0l3 orgeff -.0716 .3056 p=.328 p=.026 1.000 p--. .7994 1.0000 p=.ooo p--. .3731 .4411 1.0000 p=.008 p=.002 p--. .2641 .3041 .2812 1.0000 p=.048 p=.027 p=.037 p--. .5416 a861 a654 .5391 1.0000 p= .000 p=.ool p=.ooi p=.ooo p-. .5054 a061 .6053 .5296 .8590 1.0000 p= .000 p=.004 p=.ooo p=.ooo p=.ooo p=. a393 .4872 .3529 .3952 .5863 .5768 1.0000 p=.002 p=.ool p=.0l2 p= .005 p=.ooo p=.ooo p--. .3125 .2700 .3360 .2702 .5901 .6272 .0000 p=.023 p=.044 p=.016 p=.044 p=.ooo p=.ooo p=.5oo 1.0000 p=. ~ $;;: :.i l::l~ ~ $;;: ""s· !li """" ~ ~ ~ ~' "" ~ ...... w z 9 ...... spring 1996 kargar & parnell: strategic planning in small firms 13 a variety of clustering methods could be applied, ward's algorithm was selected because of its tendency to cluster cases into groups of similar sizes, an aspect critical for small populations (barney & hoskisson, 1990; hair, anderson & tatham, 1987). the optimum solution contained three clusters of eight, eleven, and twenty-two businesses. table 5 planning system satisfaction means for each cluster cluster analysis variable employees intnlxl extnlxi funtnxi resrsxl techkxl creatxl contrxi finance orgeff cluster i cluster 2 (n=8, 19%) (n=ll, 27%) 235.38 592.64 0.37 ·0.32 0.72 1.28 0.87 -0.53 0.43 -0.20 0.38 -0.12 0.88 ·0.47 0.75 -0.46 0.73 -1.23 1.09 0.39 cluster 3 (n=22, 54%) 118.68 0.02 0.80 -0.05 -0.06 -0.08 -0.09 -0.04 0.35 -0.59 sig. level .178 .335 .035 .006 .375 .500 .009 .028 .000 .000 firms in the first cluster placed the greatest emphasis on six of the seven planning characteristics and also reported the greatest satisfaction with planning along both dimensions. firms in the second cluster placed the least emphasis on six of the seven characteristics, also reporting the least satisfaction with planning dimensions. significant differences among the clusters were found in four of the seven emphases and both planning satisfaction dimensions. external emphasis did not associate with the other six planning characteristics, suggesting that heavy external emphasis may be more associated with planning that does not lead to satisfaction with the process. conclusions and future directions taken together, it seems evident 'that the relationship between planning and performance in small firms bears significantly on strategic management research and practice, and that strategy scholars should not abandon this line of inquiry altogether. the planning literature appears to suggest two key themes: first, planning should be an integral part of the strategic management process. the benefits of planning can outweigh the costs. and most critically, one's competitors will likely enjoy the benefits of planning. therefore, to ignore planning is to relegate a source of competitive advantage to disadvantage. the second theme is perhaps most critical. effective planning-not just the process of planning-appears to be positively associated with performance. 14 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 1 in other words, organizations that plan effectively are more likely to achieve higher performance than those that do not. but the key here is effective planning; ineffective planning appears to have no predictable or consistent association with performance. going through the motions of planning provides no great insights or benefits; it may actually result in a depletion of resources and lower quality decisions. thus, a strong emphasis placed on planning is only justified when it is also focused on effective planning. future research may address five areas appropriate to this study. first, a longitudinal research design may improve the reliability of strategy measures and examine the long-term (le., beyond five years) effects of strategic planning. golden (1992) found that 58 percent of organizations he surveyed did not agree with the previously validated accounts of their organization's past strategies! hence, retrospective accounts of strategy and planning emphases may not always be valid. a longitudinal design would eliminate the reliance on ceos' perceptions of past strategy-a limitation of this exploratory study. second, future inquiries should expand the planning assessment process beyond the chief executive officer. although a high response may be more difficult when complete anonymity is not assured, a more accurate depiction of planning activity may be gleaned from surveying several managers within each organization in addition to the ceo. further, the validation of self-reported financial results with archival data would improve the validity of the study. third, additional industries may be examined. this study addressed only the banking industry. additional investigations should include those industries experiencing major macroenvironmental changes. in such industries, one may actually find a greater value in strategic planning activities. fourth, the identification of important planning characteristics should provide an impetus to further efforts at reconceptualizing planning in more realistic terms than the unidimensional treatments common in the previous smallfirm empirical research. similarly, the results support such a multidimensional treatment, which argues against the use of narrow conceptualizations of planning effectiveness in future studies. in general, these findings suggest the need for future research to explore not only the degree of emphasis and perceived effectiveness of various strategic planning dimensions but also the reasons for these choices. such research will help to provide a better understanding of why managers of small firms choose various strategic planning system approaches as well as how these approaches give rise to possible changes in organization strategy. finally, the present study involved a relatively small number of banks in the study. future investigations into process and content dimensions unique to small firm strategic planning process could focus on larger industries. spring 1996 kargar & parnell: strategic planning in small firms 15 references aldrich, h., b. mckelvey, and d. ulrich. "design strategy from the population perspective." journal of management 10 (1984): 67-86. andrews, k.r. the concept of cqrporate strategy. homewood, il: dow jones-irwin, 1971. barney, 1.b. "firm resources and sustained competitive advantage." jqurnal of management 17 (1991): 99-120. barney, lb. "organizational culture: can it be a source of sustained competitive advantage?" academy of management review 11 (1986a): 656-665. barney, j.b. "strategic factor markets: expectations, luck, and business strategy." m<.magement science 32 (1986b): 1231-1241. barney, j.b., and r.e. hoskisson. "strategic groups: untested assertions and research proposals." m<.magerial <.md decision economic§ 11 (1990): 167-198. boeker, w. "strategic change: the effects of founding and history." academy of mana~ment jqurnal 32 (1989): 489-515. brown, d.m., and s. laverick. "measuring corporate performance." long range planning 27 (1994): 89-98. business week. "managing change." business week 1992 spe.£ial boiju§ issue: r$}inventing america (1992): 60-74. byren, j.a. "paradigms for postmodern managers." busine§§ w$}ek 1992 special bonus issue: reinventing america (1992): 62-63. calingo, l.m.r. "environmental determinants of generic competitive strategies: preliminary evidence from structured content analysis of fortune and business week articles (1983-1984)." human relation§ 42 (1989): 353-369. camerer, c., and a. vepsalainen. "the economic efficiency of corporate culture." strategic management journal 9 (1988): 115-126. cameron, k. and d.a. whetten. org<.mizational effectivene§s: a compari'son qf multiple mod&b. new york: academic press, 1983. camillus, j.c. "evaluating the benefits of formal planning." l.qng, range planning 8 (1975): 3340. camillus, j.c., and n. venkatraman. "dimensions of strategic choice." planning review 12 (1984): 26-31. 16 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 1 cappel, s.d. strategic profiles and performance in service qrganizatioqs: examinin2 retail department. variety and general merchandise stores. unpublished doctoral dissertation, memphis state university, memphis, tennessee, 1990. cartwright, tj. "the lost art of planning." long range planning 20 (1987): 92-99. cronbach, lj. "coefficient alpha and the internal structure of tests." psychometrica 16 (1951): 297-334. dierickx, 1., and k. cool. "asset stock accumulation and sustainability of competitive advantage." management science 35 (1989): 1504-1511. dyson, rg., and mj. foster. "the relationship of participation and effectiveness in strategic planning." strategic mam!l~ement journal 3 (1982): 77-88. fiol, c.m. "managing culture as a competitive resource: an identity-based view of sustainable competitive advantage." journal of management 17 (1991): 191-211. foxman, e.r, d.d. muehling, and p.w berger. "an investigation of factors contributing to consumer brand confusion." journal of consumer affairs 24 (1990): 170189. fredrickson, j. w "the comprehensiveness of strategic decision process, extensions, observations, future directions." academy of management journal 27 (1984): 45-466. gaertner, k.n. "winning and losing: understanding managers' reactions to strategic change." human relations 42 (1989): 527-545. gannon, mj., k.g. smith, and c. grimm. "an organizational information-processing profile of first movers." journal of business research 25 (1992): 231-241. godiwalla, y.m., wa. meinhart, and w.a. warde. "general management and corporate strategy." managtfrial planning 30 (1981): 17-29. golden, b.r "the past is the past-or is it? the use of retrospective accounts as indicators of past strategy." academy of management journal 35 (1992): 848-860. govindrajan, v. "impact of participation in the budgetary process on managerial attitudes and performance: universalistic and contingency perspectives." decision sciences 7 (1986): 96-516. grant, j.h., and wr king. the logic of strategic planning. boston: little, brown & company, 1982. green, s. "strategy, organizational culture, and symbolism." long range planning 21 (1988): 121-129. greenley, g. "does strategic planning improve company performance?" long ram~e planning 19 (1986): 101-109. spring 1996 kargar & parnell: strategic planning in small firms 17 greiner, l.e., and a bhambri. "new ceo intervention and dynamics of deliberate strategic change." strategic mana~ment journal 10 (1989, summer): 67-86. grimm, em., and k.g. smith. "management and organizational change: a note on the railroad industry." strategic management journal 12 (1991): 557-562. hair, j.p., re. anderson, and rl. tatham. multivariate data analysis. new york: macmillan, 1967. hannan, m. and j. freeman. "the population ecology of organizations." americ;an journal of sodolqgy 82 (977): 929-964. hausler, j. "planning: a way of shaping the future." management international review 2 (1968): 12-21. hax, a.c., and n.s. majiuf. strategic management: an integrative approach. englewood cliffs, nj: prentice-hall, 1984. hitt, m.a, ra. ireland, and g.a. stadter. "functional importance and company performance: moderating effects of grand strategy and industry type." strategic management journal 3 (1982): 315-330. hofer, c.w. "toward a contingency theory of business strategy." acaql;idy of manal;!eident journal 18 (1975): 784-809. karger, d.w, and z.a. malik. "long range planning and organizational performance." long range planning 8 (1975): 60-64. king, wr "evaluating strategic planning systems." strategic management journal 4 (1983): 263-277. king, wr., and dj. cleland. strategic planning and policy. new york: van nostrand reinhold, 1978. kukalis, s. "determinants of strategic planning systems in large organizations: a contingency approach." journal of management studil;s 28 (1991): 143-60. lado, a, n. boyd, and p. wright. "a competency based model of sustained competitive advantage: toward a conceptual integration." journal of management 18 (1992): 77-91. langley, a. "the roles of formal strategic planning." long range planning 21 (1988): 40-50. leontiades, m., and a. tezel. "planning perceptions and planning results." strategic management journal i (1980): 65-75. lieberman, m.r, and d.b. montgomery. "first-mover advantages." strategic management journal 9 (1988): 41-58. 18 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 1 loasby, bj. "long-range formal planning in perspective." journal of management studies 4 (1967): 12-21. loken, 8., i. ross, and rl. hinkle. "consumer confusion of origin and brand similarity perceptions." journal of public policy and marketing 5 (1986): 195-211. lorange, p. "formal planning systems: their role in strategy implementation." in strategic management: a new view of business policy and planning. eds. d.e. schendel and c.w. hofer. boston: little brown & company, 1979. lorange, p. corporate planning: an executive view point. englewood cliffs, nj: prentice-hall, 1980. lorange, p., and r.f. vancil. strategic planning systems. englewood cliffs, nj: prentice-hall, 1977. lorenz, c. "why strategy has been put in the hands of line managers." financial ~ (may 18, 1988): 20. mascarenhas, b. "first mover effects in multiple dynamic markets." strategic management journal 13 (1992): 237-243. mcdaniel, s.w., and j.w. kolari. "marketing strategy implications of the miles and snow strategic typology." journal of marketing 51 (1987): 19-30. miles, re., and c.c. snow. organizational strategy, structure. and process. new york: west, 1978. mowday, rt., l.w. porter, and rm. steers. employee-organization linkages the psychology of commitment. absenteeism and turnover. new york: academic press, 1982. north carolina banking commission. state qf north carolina commissioner of banks 1991 annual report. raleigh, nc: 1991. orpen, c. "the effects of long-range planning on small business performance: a further examination." journal of small bu&iness management 1 (1985): 16-23. parnell, j.a. "strategic consistency versus flexibility: does strategic change really enhance performance?" american business review 12 (1994): 22-30. pearce, la., ii, e.b. freeman, and rb. robinson. 'the tenuous link between formal strategic planning and financial performance." academy of management review 12 (1987): 658-675. ramanujam, v., and n. venkatraman. "planning and performance: a new look at an old question." busi nes& horizons 30 (1987): 19-25. spring 1996 kargar & parnell: strategic planning in small finns 19 ramanujam, v., n. venkatraman, and j.e. camillus. "multi-objective assessment of effectiveness of strategic planning: a discriminant analysis approach." academy of mana2emept journal 29 (1986): 347-372. rhyne, l.c. "contrasting planning systems in high, medium and low performance companies." journal of mana2ement studies 24 (1987): 363-85. rhyne, l.c. 'the relationship of strategic planning to financial performance." strateiic mana2ement journal 7 (1986): 423-436. roach, j.d.c., and m.g. allen. "strengthening the strategic management process." in the strategic mana2ement handbook, 1983. robinson, r.b., and j.a. pearce. 'the impact of formalized strategic planning on financial performance in small organizations." strate2ic mana2ement journal 4 (1983): 197-207. saffold, g.s. iii. "culture, traits, strength, and organizational performance: moving beyond strong culture." academy of manaiement review 13 (1988): 546-558. sapp, r.w., and r.e. seiler. "the relationship between long-range planning and financial performance of u.s. commercial banks." management planning 29 (1981): 3236. schein, e.h. "organizational culture." american psychologist (feb. 1990): 109-119. schein, e.h. organizational culture. san francisco: jossey-bass, 1985. scholes, k. "the way to manage strategic change." accountancy 107 (1991): 98-99. scholz, e. "corporate culture and strategy-the problem of strategic fit." ~ range planning 20 (1987): 78-87. schwartz, h., and s. davis. "matching corporate culture and business strategy." organizational dynamics (summer, 1981): 475-493. schwenk, e.r., and c.b. shrader. "effects of formal strategic planning on financial performance in small firms: a meta-analysis." entrepreneurship theory and practice 17 (1993): 53-64. shank, j.k., e.j. niblock, and wt. sandall. "balance 'creativity' and 'practicality' in formal planning." harvard business review 51 (1973): 87-95. sinha, d.k. "the contribution of formal planning to decisions." strategic management journal 11 (1990): 479-492. snow, c.c., and l. hrebiniak. "strategy, distinctive competence, and organizational performance." administrative science quarterly 25 (1980): 317-35. 20 journal of business strategies vol. 13, no. 1 steers, rm. "antecedents and outcomes of organizational commitment." administrative science quart~rly 22 (1977): 46-56. steiner, g.a. strategic planning: what every manager must know. new york: free press, 1979. stem, m.e. marketing planning: a systems approach. new york: mcgraw-hill, 1966. stevenson, h.h. "defining corporate strengths and weaknesses." sloan management review 17 (1976): 51-68. ulrich, d. "the population perspective: review, critique, and relevance." human relations 40 (1987): 137-152. van de yen, a., and d. ferry. measuring and assessing organizations. new york: wiley, 1980. veliyath, r., and s.m. shortell. "strategic orientation, strategic planning system characteristics and performance." journal of management studies 30 (1993): 359-381. webb, j., and p. dawson. "measure for measure: strategic change in an electronic instruments corporation." journal of management studies 28 (1991): 191-206. welch, j.b. "strategic planning could improve your share price." long range planning 17 (1984): 144-147. wernerfelt, b., and a. karnani. "competitive strategy under uncertainty." strategic management journal 8 (1987): 187-194. whipp, r., r rosenfeld, and a. pettigrew. "managing strategic change in a mature business." lom: range planning 22 (1989): 92-99. wiersema, m.e, and k.a. bantel. "top management team demography and corporate strategic change." academy of management jqurnal 35 (1992): 91-121. wilson, rm.s. mana&\::l 25 34 13.0 university degree 29.6 during morning 5.9 % ~ ~ 35 49 25.1 graduate degree 8.0 at lunch 5.9 >::l '" 50 64 18.1 6. town of residence during afternoon 29.2 r<> 65 and over 10.7 primary 45.4 % during evening 8.6 v:>.... "l 2. gender secondary 23.1 saturdays 47.0 =:.... male 38.0% fringe 31.5 sundays 3.2 ~? female 62.0 7. town of work 11. mark-downs as a motivating ~3. marital status primary 37.6% factor to shop downtown married 58.2 % secondary 34.9 yes 64.4% ~ ~ not married 41.8 fringe 27.5 no 35.6 .... i tl 4. total household 8. primary downtown as a 12. the appealing word in "l yearly income (i,ooos) shopping destination visualizing downtown ~. ~ ;:: under $10 13.9 % yes 58.4 % parkade 58.0 % v:> $10 $19 10.7 no 41.6 mainstreet 42.0 .... i:l $20 $29 19.5 9. advertising media that .... ~ 1>0 $30 $39 19.6 attracts attention the ~. $40 $49 9.9 most to primary downtown '" $50 $59 13.2 direct mail 9.0% $60 $69 7.3 t.y. 23.4 $70 or over 4.9 radio 19.7 newspaper 42.0 billboards 5.9 vi vi 56 journal of business strategies vol 14, no. 1 used to capture each shopping area image dimension, especially in exploratory studies where no guiding framework is present. for this reason, the instrument was divided into four sections. the first section featured questions addressing the importance to consumers of the availability of various retail store types (e.g., drugstores, office supply stores, factory outlets) that may attract shoppers downtown. the second section addressed the importance to respondents of environmental issues like cultural activities, historical ambiance, or parking, which may stimulate downtown traffic when consumers are considering where or whether to shop. in each of these two sections, consumer beliefs were assessed using five-point likert-type scales, with (i) indicating "extremely unimportant" and (5) indicating "extremely important." the third section dealt with consumer perceptions of the quality of various aesthetic factors that may be associated with a downtown's retailing environment. again, consumer responses were measured along a fivepoint scale, but now (l) indicated "miserable" and (5) indicated "excellent." the instrument's final section measured demand-side related demographic characteristics of respondents and featured "yes-no" questions that permitted respondents to be classified into downtown shopper-nonshopper categories. to summarize the patterns of correlations existing among the questions, an exploratory factor analyses with varimax rotation was performed on 35 items measuring the importance of retail store-types. this analysis identified storctype subgroups viewed by this sample as similarly important in their ability to attract customers downtown. the roots criterion and scree test criteria were used in combination to determine the suitable number of factors to extract. that juncture on the scree plot with a large break in the plot of the eigen roots was assumed to be the point where factor extraction should stop with the additional provision that all eigenvalues be near or greater than one. this procedure revealed that 27 items loaded on seven retail store-type factors. eight items were dropped because of low loadings. based on the identity of the items loading on them, these factors were labeled as focused consumer needs stores, traditional retail format stores, women s wares stores, discount stores, specialty stores, discount stores, exotic stores, and gift stores, respectively. an identical scale building procedure was used with respect to the items measuring downtown environmental issues. two factors, labeled old fashioned values and activities and circumstances external to stores, were extracted. the first construct reflected circumstances relating to historical buildings, period images, artistic factors, and/or cultural activities that may be present downtowns. the lattcr factor encompassed considerations relating to the availability downtown of frec parking, special events, parks and picnic areas, and recreational activities. four factors were extracted from the final factor analysis, which was performed on fifteen items measuring perceptions of downtown trading area's aesthetic characteristics. the emergent factors were labeled as assortment and atmospheric presentation, appearance, quality transactions, and convenience, respectively. characteristics such as a downtown trading area's merchandise varispring 1997 rawwas & strutton: market-driven strategies 57 ety, window displays, layout, building facades, and quality of goods/services loaded on the assortment and atmospheric presentation factor. appearance reflected the cleanliness and attractiveness of a downtown trading area. a downtown's traffic flow patterns (e.g., straight vs. serpentine), parking accessibility, accessibility to disabled persons, and shopping hour convenience correlated highly, thus fashioning the convenience construct. finally, salesperson friendliness, safety, and general costs of a downtown's goods and services loaded together to form a quality transactions factor. table 2 summarizes the items, loadings, and coefficient alphas corresponding to each factor. analysis the hypotheses were tested using manova. the manova procedure used to test the second and third hypotheses also employed a covariate analysis, controlling for respondents' town of residence and of work. covariate analysis increases the power of a manova significance test to detect true differences in downtown shopper/nonshopper perceptions. removing the possible effects of residence and employment on respondents' perceptions of their downtown trading areas was desirable because those conditions might have biased the results. on the other hand, no strategic need existed to address these effects since neither retailers nor municipal planners can meaningfully influence any targeted consumer group's places of residence or employment. discriminant analysis was also used. using discriminant analysis in conjunction with manova facilitates insights into the direction and intensity of any significant relationships. while manova tests for significant differences from the null hypothesis of no differences in the demographic characteristics (or perceptions of what is important in a downtown shopping experience) of downtown shoppers/nonshoppers, discriminant analysis determines the weights of the combination of criterion variables that optimize departure from the null. examining each demographic or perceptual variable's contribution to the discriminant function facilitates a more precise interpretation of any differences in demographics or image perceptions across downtown shoppers and nonshoppers. results objective 1 manova was used to test the hypothesis concerned with whether consumers who shop or did not shop "downtown" would display significantly different demographic characteristics. demand characteristics included in the model were income, marital status, place of work, place of residence, age, gender, and education. manova revealed a significant overall difference in the demographic characteristics associated with downtown shoppers and nonshoppers. using discriminant analysis to determine the direction and intensity of the hypothesized relationships across the shopper categories was thus appropriate. 58 journal of business strategies table 2 vol. 14, no. 1 retail businesses that may attract customers to primary downtown (factor analysis) item factor loadings coefficient alpha 1. retail factors consumer needs stores financial services (e.g., stock brokers, banks) personal services (e.g., barbers, hair dressers, ins., medical, travel ins.) office supplies photo studios computers, electronics hardware furniture shoes men's, women's and children's traditional retail format stores box (limited-line) store (e.g., aldi) supermarket (e.g., hy vee) drugstores department store fast-food restaurants (e.g., mcdonald's) video sales and rentals women's wares stores women's wear women's accessories discount stores off-price store (e.g., tj maxx) factory outlet (e.g., galt sand, liz claiborne) large specialty store (e.g., the limited) specialty stores specialty food (e.g., coffees, fr~nch pastries, candies) specialty gifts (e.g., boutiques. lingerie) exotic stores hobby stores sports apparel luggage, executive gi fts jewelers gift stores cards and gifts children's clothes and gifts .711 .688 .676 .602 .578 .511 .503 .486 .738 .707 .675 .550 .534 .454 .776 .708 .853 .848 .727 .786 .709 .720 .577 .505 .479 .726 .634 .81 .77 .84 .84 .80 .66 .64 spring 1997 rawwas & strutton: market-driven strategies table 2 59 retail businesses that may attract customers to primary downtown (continued) item factor loadings coefficient alpha 2. non-retail factors old-fashioned values preservation of historic buildings a downtown that projects image (e.g., ethnic or time period) artistic environment (e.g., art studios, art galleries) cultural activities (e.g., live theater, musical performances) activities and circumstances external to stores free parking special events and festivals availability of parks and picnicking areas recreational activities (e.g., biking, water activities, movies) 3. aesthetic characteristics assortment and atmospheric presentation variety of stores window and in-store displays variety of goods/service store layout building facade quality of goods/service quality transactions friendliness of salespeople safety cost of goods/service convenience traffic flow (straight vs. serpentine main street) parking convenience store accessibility to handicapped patrons shopping hours appearance cleanliness attracti veness .82 .828 .815 .744 .722 .69 .734 .688 .744 .636 .88 .812 .763 .754 .751 .710 .603 .794 .743 .633 .66 .749 .687 .634 .355 .83 .886 .872 60 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 this analysis revealed that only one demographic variable, income, significantly discriminated between downtown shoppers and nonshoppers. consumers reporting higher incomes were significantly more likely to shop downtown. surprisingly, no other demand-related factor (e.g., marital status, place of work or residence, age, gender, and education) was significantly related to this sample's downtown shopping behaviors. one must conclude that the first hypothesis was not supported. mean values, canonical loadings, and multivariate and univariate significance tests associated with this analysis are reported in table 3. table 3 analysis of demographic differences means variable income status (dummy) workl (dummy) live2 (dummy) age work2 (dummy) sex (dummy) education livel (dummy) canonical loading .6451 .2605 .2360 .1782 .1273 .0997 .0512 .0362 .0052 f·test .022 .437 .398 .986 .393 .721 .583 .897 .750 shoppers 4.214 0.643 0.393 0.140 3.607 0.446 0.321 2.232 0.482 nonshoppers 3.235 0.568 0.314 0.216 3.372 0.412 0.373 2.255 0.451 multivariate chi-square chi-square significance percent of variance explained percent correctly classified analysis sample hold out sample 11.975 .0175 100% 66.36 % 54.81 % objective 2 the broad content of the propositions associated with the second research objective was illustrated in figure 1. mancova was used to test the second hypothesis that downtown shoppers and nonshoppers would exhibit significantly differing perceptions regarding what they view as important in a downtown shopping experience. after adjusting for the possible influence of work and residence, significant overall differences were revealed in the perceptions held by shoppers and nonshoppers. discriminant analysis again was used to determine spring 1997 rawwas & strutton: market-driven strategies 61 the direction and intensity of the univariate relationships across the downtown shopping/nonshopping groups. downtown shoppers were significantly more likely than nonshoppers to view the downtown presence of specialty stores as important. but nonshoppers were more likely to report that they felt the downtown presence of discount and traditional retail format stores was important. this implies the availability of these store types should increase the likelihood that downtown nonshoppers would alter their shopping behaviors. while downtown shoppers apparently seek more depth in product lines (availability), nonshoppers appear more interested in value and the width of product mix available. these latter properties are presumably more widely available in suburban retail settings. when evaluated against some rehabilitative efforts that have recently unfolded in a few midsized downtowns the strategic implications of these results are particularly evident. some cities have begun to revive their long-dormant downtown trading areas by offering deeper product lines. burlington, iowa, and stillwater, minnesota are each success stories in progress. each city has largely built its renewal around decisions to feature deep product lines of a single specialty product, antiques (business directory, 1995). one will recall from the demographic analysis that downtown shoppers generally enjoy higher incomes than nonshoppers. because shoppers are apparently more interested in the sorts of unique items that theoretically could be more widely available downtown as opposed to malls or shopping centers, these results imply that downtown nonshoppers can be expected to seek more value and assortment in downtown offerings. when compared with nonshoppers, downtown shoppers also felt that "oldfashioned values" were more important. since these downtown shoppers tended to have higher incomes it may be inferred that they are a bit more sophisticated or cultured than their nonshopping counterparts. consumers who shopped downtown may have elected to patronize the locale because they were more appreciative of the historic buildings, art, cultural activities, and generally erudite image that they perceived to be available there. downtown shoppers also assigned more favorable evaluations to various aspects of the downtown's aesthetic characteristics, (i.e., hypothesis 3). differences existed between the groups with respect to two factors: "quality transactions" and "assortment and atmospheric presentation." each factor captures a broad range of characteristics that may attract shoppers downtown. for instance, while each shopping group assigned above average ratings to the aesthetic factors, nonshoppers evaluated the friendliness of downtown sales staffs, safety, and considerations of cost less favorably than shoppers. downtown nonshoppers were also less favorably impressed with the variety of stores, window and point-of-purchase (pop) displays, variety of goods/services, store layouts, and quality of goods/services available downtown. to attract more nonshoppers downtown, retailers apparently should take action aimed at addressing these particular shortfalls. 62 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 because discriminant analysis generates a linear function based on the criterion variables best distinguishing shoppers from nonshoppers, the importance of each criterion in discriminating the groups is given by the relative size of the canonical loadings. in descending order, the downtown characteristics exerting the greatest influence on overall group differences were: "quality transactions," "old-fashioned values," "assortment & amospheric presentation," "discount stores," "specialty stores," and "traditional retail format stores." two of the first three factors are associated with a downtown's aesthetic characteristics. the overall size of the mean values associated with the retail and nonretail factors indicated that, regardless of their shopping behaviors, this sample believed most of the shopping area characteristics investigated were at least somewhat important. regardless of their shopping behaviors, those persons sampled also generally felt that the aesthetic characteristics of their downtown was at least fair. convenience was the sole exception to this trend. nonshoppers felt the level of "convenience" associated with a downtown shopping experience was relatively poor. again, the strategic implication is that downtown retailers should increase the convenience or perception of the convenience associated with a downtown shopping experience. such an action should entice more nonshoppers to venture downtown. given the absence of significant differences across the shopper groups with respect to the following dimensions, one may likewise conclude that non-retail factors such as "activities and circumstances external to stores" and aesthetic characteristics such as "convenience" and "appearance" are equally important to both groups. "appearance" was seen as particularly important by both shoppers and nonshoppers. the means, canonical loadings, and multivariate and univariate significance tests associated with this analysis are shown in table 4. strategic implications for years, retail strategists and public planners have too frequently shared an attitude of "why try to develop in an area that is more difficult to develop." but now, the easy, early pickings for retailers and urban planners are mostly gone. downtowns are usually situated in what should be economically viable locations, e.g., near a port, river, or transportation nexus. population density is another telling characteristic of downtowns. strategically speaking, downtowns simply have or are near too many people to be ignored. consequently, downtown retail centers clearly offer an attractive option retailers who could benefit from close proximity to population, tourism or entertainment centers, central business districts, or locale near the center of the logistical infrastructure. in the near term private and public developers are increasingly likely to realize that they have an implied responsibility to their city, society and selves to attempt to renew their downtown's well being. but the fact remains that retail trading areas situated in downtown locations generally cannot compete on an equivalent footing with malls. nor can they reasonably aspire to cultivate distribution structures that will allow spring 1997 rawwas & strutton: market-driven strategies table 4 63 analysis of factors that may attract customers to primary downtown controlling for place of residence and work 1. retail factors means* variable canonical loading f~test shoppers nonshoppers discount stores .333 .019 3.46 3.75 specialty stores -.305 .031 3.37 3.70 traditional retail format stores -.297 .036 3.80 3.59 women's wares stores -.110 .432 3.73 3.82 gift stores .097 .489 4.00 3.92 consumer needs stores .090 .520 3.66 3.61 exotic stores .067 .634 3.49 3.45 2. non-retail factors means* variable canonical loading f·test shoppers nonshoppers old-fashioned values .475 .001 3.57 3.16 activities & circumstances external to stores .201 .153 4.11 3.97 * "i" corresponds to "extremely unimportant," and "5" corresponds to "extremely important." 3. aesthetic characteristics means* variable canonical loading f·test shoppers nonshoppers quality transactions .536 assortment and atmospheric presentation .447 convenience .146 appearance -.089 overall manova f-test value * "i" corresponds to "miserable," and "5" corresponds to "excellent." .000 3.70 .002 3.44 .298 3.03 .525 3.67 .000 3.661 3.37 3.18 2.95 3.72 64 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 them to offer pricing levels more competitive than those already available in nationally prominent discount stores. this set of market characteristics provide a useful backdrop against which to interpret these results. apparently, these results suggest that for waning downtown retailing districts to approach their former vigor, they must develop a series of strategically compelling competitive advantages that provide reasons why more people would want to begin shopping there again. the findings imply that vibrant retailing activity in downtown retail trading areas will be reborn only when such locations boast sustainable competitive advantages (le., old fashioned values such as the preservation of older buildings) and occupy defensible niches (i.e., specialty stores such as antique or handicraft shops) that cannot be easily replicated elsewhere. these results also suggest that downtown business communities should capitalize on their heritage those aspects which make them unique. such an approach would give downtowns a distinct positioning advantage over faceless malls and look-alike suburban stores. the flow of this study's results (see figure 1) implies that two sets of decision criteria are likely used in most of consumers' patronage decisions: (l) those attributes that affect a downtown districts overall shopping image, and (2) those that affect a consumer's preference for particular retail outlets. thus, when individual retailers compete vigorously and do those things necessary to derive a desirable store image, they simultaneously bolster the image of their entire shopping area. thus, a spirit of "one for all and all for one" truly should prevail relative to downtown revitalization efforts. but this findings also imply that individual retailers cannot reasonably hope to revive the flagging fortunes of downtowns on their own. on their own, individual retailers cannot reasonably hope to effect "old-fashioned values" throughout an entire downtown. nor can they ensure that an ideal retailing mix is available throughout a downtown trading area. this is why an overarching strategic plan that incorporates the concurrent efforts of governmental and community activists should also be engaged. such efforts would complement the classic competitive tactics of retailers aimed at delivering for themselves a more auspicious retailing mix or set of atmospherics. the inner retailing cores of most midsized american cities have declined for many reasons. this urban decline thus represents a complicated problem. it is widely recognized that simple solutions to complex problems are rare. moreover, it is understood that successful urban revitalization will require enormous resources. the nature of this problem and scope of these resources suggests the burden of renewal efforts should be borne proportionately across the broad range of publics who affect or are affected by a given downtown's relative welfare. these publics include retailers, nonretailing businesspeople, entrepreneurs, community activists, and public servants. the cooperation and coordination of private and public sectors is undoubtedly crucial to the success of virtually all downtown renewal strategies. this implies that in the development of such strategies some overarching organizaspring 1997 rawwas & strutton: market-driven strategies 65 tional body should be established and assigned the responsibility of bridging the value gaps held by these disparate groups. this organization should also ensure that the efforts of the private and public sector are cohesively directed toward mutually acceptable outcomes. this could be achieved by forming private-public partnerships whose basic mission is to reinvent and reinvest in the downtown in question. based on these data, it is apparent that a planning commission representing private sector retailers and public sector government offices would do well to devise a plan that operationalizes two broad tasks: the establishment of specialty stores and the rejuvenation of what were termed old-fashioned values. this study further indicates that a coherent downtown redevelopment strategy must begin with a fundamental understanding of what the market in question seeks (or feels is absent) from their downtown shopping experiences. working together, relevant constituencies operating within the trading area could then strive to deliver to the market the features it has singled out as desirable. only downtown retailing attributes that are unique, or devised in such a way as to appear unique, within a relevant geographical market, will promote and support viable levels of business. in this study, the significance of the "old-fashioned values" construct implies that downtowns may be able to carve out a position of relative strength by doing business the old-fashioned way. by positioning downtown shopping experiences as being more like they once were, retail and public policy strategies apparently may be to cultivate a more viable future for downtowns. this would, by turns, require strategic goals based on exploiting downtowns' historic appearances, and on generally promoting downtowns as traditional social, cultural, and entertainment centers. in this regard, businesspeople would also do well to stress the community and cultural pride that derives naturally from a healthy downtown. a sense-of-place and an appreciation for history are likely to prove important to the future "self-concepts" of cities, given that virtually all american cities started as port or rail towns featuring vital downtowns. naturally, the "product offering" that is a downtown would have to be reformulated in ways consistent with these claims of old-fashioned values. retailers are clearly incapable of doing this alone. the results of this study also underscore the multidimensional nature of the opportunities currently enjoyed by downtown retailers. business strategists acting on behalf of downtown interests apparently can increase the vitality of their districts as shopping destinations by purposefully operating on selected aspects of the retail factors, nonretail factors, and aesthetic characteristics evaluated in this study. for example, government officials could endeavor to provide the sorts of incentives necessary to stimulate the private sector's retail development or the maintenance of the right mix of stores. the city would be responsible for providing technical information, assistance, incentives, and loans to encourage the necessary sorts of private property investments and improvements. innovative, nontraditional contributions to the development of the desired retailing mix could corne in the form of helping to solve regulatory or zoning problems, the forma66 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 tion of development organizations to support the project and in some cases functioning as owners or developers themselves. the public sector would also have to take actions that enhance public property, leading to improvements in the downtown's atmospheric presentation. these could include traditional activities such as streetscape or lighting improvements, and landscaping. community activists, on the other hand, certainly would have a critical role to play in the preservation of older buildings, the advancement or conservation of a compatible artistic environment, and the promotion of appropriate cultural activities. in this regard, community activists will always enjoy an advantage based in their intimate knowledge and understanding of what is unique in tenus of the artistic dimensions of their downtowns. these insights can help them promote the right types of historical development. retail strategists, of course, are largely responsible for insuring that quality transactions between stores and consumers transpire, that a suitable assortment of goods and services is available, and that a suitable atmosphere is developed. retailer associations might be used to initiate measures aimed at establishing specialty stores with a common theme. such stores could feature unique products or services that complement one another. retailers should also plan to improve product offerings, window displays, merchandising and marketing techniques. finally, the results associated with the model suggest that the success of downtown revitalization efforts may in large part depend on how effectively two economic standbys supply and demand are addressed. in this instance, however, the conventional relationship between these two elements ought to be reversed. specifically, the results imply that to revitalize downtown trading areas demand for retailer services should be established before~ is furnished. demand could be grown, for instance, by having chambers of commerce engage in strategic development aimed at attracting more and more high paying jobs downtown. this could be achieved by influencing state officials to offer incentives such as tax abatements to new businesses (including manufacturers). once consumer demand for retail services and products has been established in this manner, the supply of "appropriate" retailing services would likely expand as a natural consequence. at that point, the opportunity would emerge to fine tune the mix and number of specialty stores downtown, as would the opportunity to purposefully improve selected aspects of the public infrastructure of the downtown in question. infrastructure encompasses parking, lighting, street sidewalks, public restrooms, trees, parks, and so forth. with respect to these supply and demand issues, working agreements could be enjoined between all involved publics that penuit each party to concentrate on what it does best, thus allowing other publics to exercise their own distinctive strengths. these "strategic partnerships" should include the mayor, top government officials, public agencies, downtown resident associations, retail associations, and non-retailing businesses. various aspects of the downtown community spring 1997 rawwas & strutton: market-driven strategies 67 life, heritage and ideals, as well as land use and retail design issues ought to be deliberated (bramhall, 1992). working together in this fashion should allow natural synergies to develop. all the publics having a stake in a given downtown's welfare would do well to remember that they should hang together in these renewal efforts. otherwise, borrowing from the words of benjamin franklin, they will surely hang separately ("hang" as in watching the slow, inevitable strangulation of something that should be dear to them). these publics would then be left with little more than a doughnut hole in place of what used to be the lively center of their cities. limitations and future research these findings must be evaluated in light of certain limitations. any discussion derived from a single, cross-sectional study reporting consumer responses is less than completely generalizable. this shortfall can be addressed in part by investigating these same issues using different samples taken from other regions of the country, or by developing longitudinal studies of these same effects. this study is also limited in that issues such as land-use, technology, entertainment, employment patterns, or crime that also may influence consumers' downtown shopping behaviors are not considered. the possible influence of such factors on downtown revitalization efforts should be investigated in future research. references barrett, k. and r. greene. "return from the crypt." financial world 162,5 (1993): 5253. bearden, w.o. "determinant attributes of store patronage: downtown versus outlying shopping centers." journal of retailin~ 53,2 (1997): 15-22. bramhall, b. "building people power in three cities." plannin~ 58 (november 1992): 23-26. brown, s. "retail location theory: the legacy of harold hotehing." journal of retailing 65,4 (1989): 450-470. -----. "retail location at the micro-scale: inventory and prospect." service industries journal 14,4 (1994): 542-576. dabholkar, p.a., oj. thrope and j.o. rentz. "a measure of service quality for retail stores: scale and validation." journal of the academy of marketing science 24, 1 (1996): 3-16. 68 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 ettorre, b. "should businesses remain in the inner cities?" management review 84,5 (1995): 13-18. frieden, bj. and l.b. safalyn. downtown inc.: how america rebuilds cities. cambridge: mit press, 1989. heikkila, ej. and c. kantiotu. "calculating fiscal inputs where spatial efforts are present." regional science and urban economics 22, 3 (1992): 475-490. khermouch, g. "target hits bullseye." brandweek 36, 23 (1995): 22-26. leinenkugel, j. "urban revitalization: it's not just for large cities." executive speeches 9 (february/march, 1995): 12-16. lorch, bj. and m.j. smith. "pedestrian movement and the downtown enclosed shopping center." journal of the american planning association 59, 1 (1993): 75-86. newman, o. "defensible space a new physical planning tool for urban revitalization." journal of the american planning association 61, 2 (1995): 149-155. nevin, j.r. and mj. houston. "image as a component of attraction to intraurban shopping areas." journal of retailing 56, 1 (1980): 77-93. palma, d. "the top ten ways to revitalize your downtown." american city & country 23 (november, 1992): 48-55. porter, m.e. "the competitive advantage of the inner city." harvard business review (may/june, 1995): 55-71. robertson, k.a. "downtown redevelopment strategies in the united states: an end-ofthe-century assessment." journal of the american planning association 6 i, 4 (1995): 429-437. rooks, w.a. and j. weinroth. "an empirical confirmation of dual strategies used in marketing high-technology goods and services: the decision-supporting software example part one: theoretical, philosophical, and pragmatic foundations for the research." journal of professional services marketing 9, 1 (1993): 173-181. rogers, d. "surviving the supercenter's shadow." supermarket business 50, 1 (1995): 35-40. rybczynksi, w. "culture's urban fortunes." civilization (november/december, 1995): 33-35. schiller, r. "vitality and visibility: challenge to the town center." international journal of retail & distribution 22,6 (1994): 46-50. spring 1997 rawwas & strutton: market-driven strategies 69 smallwood, c. "a matter of pride." american city & country 12 (february, 1994): 4751. stanwood, pg. john donne and the theolo&y of lan&uage. columbia, mo: university of missouri press, 1991. statistical abstracts of the united states: the national data book. u.s. department of commerce. washington, dc: 1995. stone, n. "old problems, new solutions." harvard business review (may/june, 1995): 18. swan, c. "demography and the demand for housing a reinterpretation of the mankivweil demand variable." regional science & urban economics 25, i (1995): 41-58. tarricone, p. "a league of their own." civil engineering 5 (1994): 58-61. taubman, a.a. "challenging myths that plaque retail development." retail estate finance journal 25 (summer, 1987): 61-64. "the downtowns strike back: coexistence now the goal for city retail." chain store age executive 68, 11 (1992): 64-66. ''the ultimate sales & credit tool (1994-1995)." american business directories. omaha, ne: university of nebraska press, 1996. weisbrod, g.e., rj. parcells and c. kern. "a disaggregate model for predicting shopping area market attraction." journal of retailing 60, i (1984): 65-83. welch, j.l. and t.k. massey. "a data collection alternative for services professionals: the 'answer check.'" journal of professional services marketing 3,2 (1987): 35-45. wilson, m. "retail goes downtown: building stores in urban markets." chain store age executive 70, 9 (1994): 28-30. mohammed y.a. rawwas (ph.d., university of mississippi) is an assistant professor of marketing at the university of northern iowa. his primary research interests lie in the areas of international marketing and ethics. dr. rawwas's research has appeared in the journal of business ethics, journal of promotion management, marketing education review, journal of international consumer marketin& and the journal of business research, among others. david strutton (ph.d., university of mississippi) is the acadiana bottling professor of marketing and j. w. steen professor of business administration at the university of northern iowa. his research has appeared in the journal of advertisin& research, journal 70 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no. 1 of the academy of marketing science, journal of macromarketing, journal of personal selling & sales management, and the journal of business research, among others. strutton is co-author of marketing channels: a relationship management approach (richard d. irwin & co., 1996). the lights used to be brighter there: market-driven strategies for rehabilitating the retail trading areas of mid-sized cities toward a synthesis of the resource-based view and organizational economics in the context of grand strategies james g. combs university of mississippi university, ms david j. ketchen, jr. louisiana state university baton rouge, la abstract the resource-based view (rbv) and organizational economics (oe) are influential perspectives in the field ofstrategic management. in essence, the rbv is concerned with the creation and deployment of resources with certain qualities whereas oe is focused on efficiently monitoring operations. an important area of research where these approaches have both been employed is the choice of grand strategy. grand strategies are the alternative ways that firms can implement an expansion offirm scope, includingjor example, joint ventures and internal development. the rbv and oe can, because oftheir different emphases, lead managers toward different grand strategies. guided by prior research, this paper develops a model suggesting that firms will generally place their resource needs before monitoring considerations and that this choice brings about the best possible peiformance. propositions designed to guide subsequent empirical research are developed and implications for both theory and practice are discussed. introduction researchers have enlisted several theoretical perspectives to explain organizational actions and subsequent finn perfonnance (e.g., child, 1972; hannan & freeman, 1977; williamson, 1975; wemerfelt, 1984). in recent years, two of these perspectives, the resource-based view (rbv wemerfelt, 1984) and organizational economics (oehesterly, liebeskind & zenger, 1990) have been used to explain a wide variety of organizational actions including diversification (markides & williamson, 1996; teece, 1980), the evolution of competitive advantage (barnett, greve & park, 1995; mehra, 1996), international entry mode (anderson & coughlan, 1987; anderson & gatignon, 1986; oviatt & mcdougall, 1994), vertical integration (carney & gedajlovic, 1991; mahoney, 1992; mcwilliams & gray, 1995), and organizational structure (masten, 1984; russo, 1991). as several important attempts to integrate these perspectives attest, they do not consistently direct researchers and prac84 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 titioners toward similar conclusions (carney & gedajlovic, 1991; mahoney & pandian, 1992; mcwilliams & gray, 1995). in this paper, we examine one context grand strategies wherein prescriptions emanating from the rbv can contradict those from oe. defined as strategies that increase the scope of a firm (i.e., internal development, acquisition, joint venture, long-term contracting pearce, 1982), grand strategies can have a profound impact on organizational performance (koh & venkatraman, 1991; lamont & anderson, 1985; williamson, 1994). thus, in order to develop a better understanding of the relationship between grand strategies and performance, we work toward an integration of rbv and oe predictions in this context. according to the rbv, managers choose among alternative strategies based on the need to build strategically valuable resource stocks (dierickx & cool, 1989). grand strategies should be chosen to enable the firm to acquire and/or protect the unique and valuable resources needed to compete effectively (e.g., barney, 1991; wernerfelt, 1984). by contrast, oe states that managers respond to governance costs (mahoney, 1992). specifically, firms are thought to seek strategies that minimize the costs of negotiating and enforcing (i.e., governing) transactions across markets vis-a-vis internal hierarchies (williamson, 1975; 1985). also, the costs of monitoring and bonding agents (e.g., managers or cooperative partners) gives rise to agency costs, which are another form of governance costs the firm will wish to minimize (jensen & meckling, 1976). thus, grand strategies are chosen such that transaction and agency costs are minimized. the potentia] conflict between these two approaches emanates from the dual nature of the grand strategies. on one hand, grand strategies can be viewed as a tool to help the firm gain access to important resources that is, to overcome resource constraints (martin & justis, 1993; shane, 1996). alternatively, grand strategies can serve as a way to minimize the cost of negotiating with organizational participants and monitoring their behavior as the firm grows (lafontaine, 1992; williamson, 1991). in partial reconciliation of these dual purposes, mcwilliams and gray (1995) have argued that resource-scarce firms place their resource-based needs before governance cost considerations when choosing among alternative grand strategies. using their study as a point of departure, we build a model wherein we predict the preferred grand strategy for several resource stock-governance cost contingencies. in so doing, we explain how the variables offered by de play an important secondary role. an additional step is taken by combining the rbv and oe logic to predict performance. finally, we offer advice to managers for achieving competitive advantage as their resource and governance conditions change. literature review the rbv and oe differ considerably in terms of the factors believed to influence managerial action and the performance consequences of such actions. specifically, the rbv is concerned with how extant resource endowments can influence the firm's ability to grow. furthermore, the rbv draws a fall 1997 combs & ketchen: toward a synthesis 85 direct link between the deployment of resources and performance. in contrast, oe is centered on how managers minimize the costs of monitoring and controlling the firm's activities. the consequence of efficient governance is improved performance (hill & snell, 1988; williamson, 1994). resource-based view in a seminal work that laid the foundation for business-level strategic analysis, andrews (1965) painted a fairly balanced picture of how internal and external factors contribute to successful strategies. in the ensuing years, most research in strategic management centered on external forces; it is only in the last decade that scholars have begun to carefully examine how firm-level resource differences shape strategy and performance (barney, 1995). at the heart of the rbv of strategy is the notion that firms act to acquire "strategically valuable" resources that can be a source of a sustainable competitive advantage (i.e., superior long-term performance) forthe firm (barney, 1991; conner, 1991; peteraf, 1993). indeed, it is this link between the nature of certain resources and performance that sets the rbv apart from related theories such as resource dependency (pfeffer & salancik, 1982), which is primarily concerned with the firm's efforts to protect the flow of resources between the firm and its environment. much of the research using the rbv attempts to describe the characteristics of strategically valuable resources that will, over time, build a sustainable advantage. such resources must be: (1) valuable, meaning buyers are willing to purchase the resources' outputs at prices significantly above their costs, (2) rare, so that buyers cannot turn to competitors with the same (or substitute) resources, and (3) imperfectly imitable, meaning it would be difficult for competitors to either imitate or purchase the resources (barney, 1986a; 1991; lippman & rumelt, 1982; peteraf, 1993; reed & defillippi, 1990). some of the spegific resources that may meet these conditions are management teamwork (castanias & helfat, 1991; hambrick, 1987), culture (barney, 1986b), brand name capital (aaker, 1991), implementation of total quality management (powell, 1995), and trust (barney & hansen, 1994). firms in possession of strategically valuable resources are expected to achieve superior performance. that is, resource-based differences among firms can help explain performance differences because the set of products and services that can efficiently emerge from any unique configuration of resources is itself unique. performance differences emerge from buyer preferences, which generally favor the outputs (i.e., products and services) of some resource configurations more than others (barney, 1991; wernerfelt, 1984). in addition to the strategically valuable resources that underlie competitive advantage, firms must also have access to any "complementary" resources that are necessary to bring products or services to market (barney, 1995; teece, 1987). for example, a superior design is of little use without access to the manufacturing and distribution facilities necessary to reach buyers. when complemen86 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 tary resources are lacking, products cannot be provided to markets and returns to strategic resources cannot be realized (mahoney & pandian, 1992). thus, both strategic and complementary resources are important components of the firm's endowments (barney, 1995). because resources are closely linked to performance, managerial action is, according to the rbv, directed primarily toward building strategically valuable resources. however, these resources can take considerable time to develop (dierickx & cool, 1989). as penrose (1959) explained, the time it takes to hire and develop experienced and committed managers can slow organizational expansion; growth must be put on hold until a cadre of capable managers can emerge. other resource-building efforts such as the development of organizational routines (nelson & winter, 1982; shane, 1996), the building of a reputation (dierickx & cool, 1989) and access to a pool of capital (martin & justis, 1993) have also been shown to affect organizational growth rates. thus, resources can influence managerial action by compelling managers to find ways to delimit their resource-based constraints (mahoney & pandian, 1992). one common solution is to invoke a grand strategy that involves cooperation with an external organization so that the firm can grow with the aid of the other's resources (erramilli & rao, 1990; harrigan, 1985; ingham & thompson, 1994; teece, 1987). indeed, because firms can often perform activities in cooperation that neither could perform independently (erramilli & rao, 1990; hamel, 1991), resource sharing has become a primary explanation for many forms of cooperation (borys & jemison, 1989). organizational economics transaction cost economics and agency theory constitute the two major theories supporting oe (barney & ouchi, 1986; hesterly et ai., 1990). transaction cost asserts that firms choose strategy so that organizational activities are performed in the least cost environment hierarchy or market (i.e., whether to internalize a function or contract for it with an external actor williamson, 1975). transaction cost economics can trace its roots to the work of coase (1937). by recognizing the costs inherent in using markets to perform transactions, coase hypothesized that firms will grow until the marginal costs of organizing equals the marginal costs of contracting in markets. williamson (1975) extended this logic by articulating market and transaction specific variables that may influence a firm's choice between hierarchy and market. in general, as a firm becomes interdependent with another, it increases its exposure to potential opportunistic behavior on the part of the other firm. risk of opportunism is thus a cost that encourages firms to internalize activities otherwise performed by external organizations (williamson, 1975). for transaction cost economics, the pivotal variable affecting governance costs is the specificity of assets deployed in the performance of organizational activities (e.g., dyer, 1996; teece, 1980; 1987). asset specificity refers to the fa111997 combs & ketchen: toward a synthesis 87 difficulty of redeploying assets to alternative uses without sacrificing their productive value (williamson, 1991). essentially, because highly specific assets cannot be easily used for other purposes, they render those who have invested in them dependent on the participants charged with employing them. if participants take advahtage of the firm, expected profits from investments in specific assets would be lost. thus, if the firm must invest in specific assets, it will seek to control those resources as tightly as possible usually through direct ownership (anderson & gatignon, 1986; williamson, 1985; 1991). agency theory is the second dominant perspective comprising oe. it is focused on the relationship between principals and their agents to whom some decision making authority is delegated (eisenhardt, 1989; jensen & meckling, 1976). agency theory was developed in the 1960s and i970s by economists studying how groups could be efficiently monitored given group members' incentive to shirk (e.g., alchian & demsetz, 1972). because principals and agents are assumed to have divergent self-interests, the central premise of agency theory states that they will jointly minimize: (i) the principal's costs of monitoring the agent's actions, (2) any costs paid by the agent to ensure the principal's interests (i.e., bonding costs), and (3) any residual loss due to remaining divergence between their respective goals (jensen & meckling, 1976). a key agency variable is the task programmability of organizational participants' responsibilities (gomez-mejia & balkin, 1992; mahoney, 1992; stroh, brett, baumann & reilly, 1996). the cost of monitoring participants' behavior directly is lower when job tasks can be easily specified in advance. thus, hierarchical relationships between participants are likely when task programmability is high. in contrast, task ambiguity and other impediments to the gathering of meaningful information about participants' job performance such as geographic distance (e.g., brickley & dark, 1987) or cultural differences (e.g., roth & o'donnell, 1996) can raise the costs of monitoring within the hierarchy. in these conditions, it is often less costly to contract for products and services from agents outside the firm (e.g., lafontaine, 1992; mahoney, 1992). although they do not share the same academic legacy, the two theories that compose the oe perspective have some notable similarities. both possess an efficiency orientation that offers guidance for selecting among alternative grand strategies. moreover, as depicted in table i, they share many of the same assumptions and emphasize many of the same independent variables (hesterly et ai., 1990). indeed, mahoney (1992) showed that by including both ex ante information search and negotiation costs, as well as ex post monitoring, bonding, and adaptation costs, transaction cost simply encompasses a broader array of governance cost variables into its framework. hence, agency costs can be viewed as a sub-set of transaction costs. the theories' central differences are found in their units of analysis and dependent variables. transaction cost economics is generally used to analyze governance relationships between organizational units whereas agency 88 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 table 1 similarities and differences between the primary theories of organizational economicsl dimension focus unit of analysis dependent variable independent variables assumptions central governance costs transaction costs organizational boundary transaction organizational governance (i.e., market v. hierarchy) asset specificity uncertainty/complexity transaction frequency number of buyers/sellers self interest goal conflict bounded rationality information asymmetry efficiency motive ex ante: information search negotiation ex post: monitoring bonding maladaptation loss adaptation costs agency theory principalagent relationship contract agent governance (le., behavior-based v. outcome-based contracts) risk propensities uncertainty task programmability information asymmetry self interest goal conflict bounded rationality information asymmetry efficiency motive risk aversion ex post: monitoring bonding adaptation loss maladaptation loss i this table draws heavily from eisenhardt (1989), mahoney (1992), and williamson (1975; 1985). theory emphasizes the relation between the firm (as principal) and individual actors (as agents). as a result, transaction cost analysis economics is generally used to investigate grand strategies where key individual actors are sometimes difficult to isolate (e.g., acquisition, joint ventures) while agency theory is used to investigate strategies where principal-agent dyads are clear (e.g., long term contracts). because the grand strategies represent alternative ways to organize the firm's activities, both theories are needed to explain the choice of grand strategy along the entire range of alternatives. thus, following others who have drawn from the oe perspective (e.g., barney & ouchi, 1986; hesterly et al., 1990), we fall 1997 combs & ketchen: toward a synthesis 89 emphasize transaction cost economics' and agency theory's common concern for efficiency and treat them as complementary. toward an integration of perspectives in recent years, several articles have incorporated ideas from both the rbv and oe (e.g., bergh, 1995; carney & gedajlovic, 1991; conner, 1991; mahoney & pandian, 1992; mcwilliams & gray, 1995). broadly speaking, three identifiable patterns can be seen in the literature that help define how the rbv and oe approaches might be related. first, they can be viewed as independent explanations in which only one perspective is considered to explain a particular phenomenon with little consideration of the other. for example, much of the vertical integration literature (e.g., masten, 1984; monteverde & teece, 1992; walker & weber, 1984; see argyres, 1996 for a recent exception) and the international entry mode literature is grounded in oe (e.g., anderson & coughlan, 1987; anderson & gatignon, 19,86; see oviatt & mcdougall, 1994 for a recent exception), whereas the evolution of competitive advantage is usually grounded in the rbv (e.g., barnett, greve & park, 1995; levinthal & myatt, 1995). a second approach is to envision these perspectives as complementary, each offering insights that generally point managers and researchers in similar directions. the complementary view is, in part, found in the recognition that specific assets share an important quality with strategically valuable resources (e.g., amit & schoemaker, 1993; dyer, 1996). that is, specific assets are difficult to trade (chi, 1994), which is one of the conditions needed for a set of resources to meet the definition of strategically valuable (peteraf, 1993). this commonality explains why greater performance among firms with certain diversification postures can either be explained as the product of an efficient (i.e., governance cost minimizing) way to organize activities (e.g., hill, hitt & hoskisson, 1992; teece, 1980) or a strategy for exploiting strategically valuable resources in new markets (e.g. chatterjee & wernerfelt, 1991; markides & williamson, 1996; prahalad & hamel, 1990; robins & wiersema, 1995). in their examination of vertical integration, mcwilliams and gray (1995) have addressed a third view the relationship can be conflictive. this can occur when managerial action is directed toward delimiting resource constraints while governance conditions point elsewhere. grand strategies offer a context in which to study this managerial dilemma. grand strategies grand strategies refer to the alternative ways that firms can expand their scope (pearce, 1982). although each contains numerous variations, grand strategies can generally be categorized into four basic groups internal development, acquisition, joint venture, and long-term contracting (anderson & gatignon, 1986; erramilli & rao, 1990). firms engaged in internal development supply all 90 journal of business strategies vol 14, no.2 necessary resources and control operations by extending their hierarchy (barney, 1988; chatterjee, 1990). acquisitions involve the transfer of control from a previous set of owners to a new one (borys & jemison, 1989). a joint venture is a new organization is that is supported and controlled by two "parent" organizations (harrigan, 1985; koh & venkatraman, 1991). under long-term contracting, cooperating firms do not create a third entity. such arrangements are generally held together by the legal system (williamson, 1991), often with the aid of credible commitments by participants (teece, 1987). grand strategies are fundamental to business growth and have been studied in the context of diversification entry mode (e.g., chatterjee, 1990; yip, 1982), vertical integration (e.g., carney & gedajlovic, 1991; mcwilliams & gray, 1995), and geographic (primarily international) expansion (e.g., anderson & gatignon, 1986; hill, hwang & kim, 1990). as shown in table 2, the choice of grand strategy can reflect a response to either resource demands or governance conditions. thus, the grand strategies open a window into the potential conflict between the rbv and oe because they contain both a resource and a governance element. from the rbv, alternative expansion modes make different resource demands on the firm. internal development and acquisition demand that the firm supply all of the strategic and complementary resources needed to successfully implement an expansion effort (cf. barney, 1988; chatterjee, 1990). joint ventures and long-term contracts, in contrast, permit the firm to share its resource burden with external partners (borys & jemison, 1989; oviatt & mcdougall, 1994). thus, the latter offer means to overcome resource-based constraints to growth (erramilli & rao, 1990; ingham & thompson, 1?94; teece, 1987). grand strategies also serve as alternative arrangements for governance. that is, they are different methods for governing the behavior of organizational actors, each imbued with different governance cost incentives and penalties (e.g., anderson & gatignon, 1986; lafontaine, 1992; williamson, 1991; 1994). specifically, internal development and acquisition offer greater control over organizational participants because behavior can be monitored directly. the employment contract gives firms significant latitude to replace organizational participants who are not acting in the firm's best interests (williamson, 1991). when there are considerable incentives for an external partner to act opportunistically (e.g., because of the programmability of the work and/or specificity of assets involved), these grand strategies offer the tools to offset such risks. conditions that might foster opportunism among external partners are labeled here as high cost ofexternal governance. the behavioral controls offered by internal development and acquisitions, however, must be balanced against inefficiencies and inflexibility that can result from the larger bureaucracy created by these strategies (i.e., bureaucratic costsjones & hill, 1988; merton, 1945). long-term contracting and joint ventures, in contrast, can offer increased flexibility and efficiency because firms only pay for needed products or services. thus, when the risks of opportunistic behavior on fall 1997 combs & ketchen: toward a synthesis 91 table 2 grand strategies juxtaposed against resource-based and organizational economics criteria internal development acquisition joint venture long-term contracting pure market exchangel organizational economics criteria control flexibility [ mcwilliams & gray, 1995 • • ] high risk of opportunism low risk of opportunism [ . williamson, 1991 ] high low interorganizational interorganizational dependence dependence [ contractor & lorange, 1988 ] high control low control [ • anderson & gatignon, 1986 ] resource-based criteria high resource availability low resource availability [ ingham & thompson, 1994 ] high resource involvement low resource involvement [ erramilli & rao, 1990 ] internal external resource resource access access [ chatterjee, 1990 ] ·pure market exchange is not considered a grand strategy because the firm has not increased the scope of its operations. the part of an external partner is low, the firm will prefer to cooperate. these conditions are labeled here as low cost of external governance. propositions figure 1 presents a model that integrates the rbv and de in the context of grand strategy. in the model, strategy is influenced jointly by resource and governance conditions. the grand strategies, in turn, affect performance directly. 92 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 figure 1 an integrative model of grand strategy and performance resource stocks governance cost conditions } grandstrategy performance effects of resource stocks and governance cost conditions on strategy the potential conflict between the rbv and de occurs when the firm's resourceversus governance-based contingencies push the firm toward different grand strategies (cf. carney & gedajlovic, 1991; mcwilliams & gray, 1995). specifically, what is a firm to do when it does not have access to the resource stocks necessary to use the governance cost minimizing strategy? such firms either have to cooperate with an external firm that can help delimit resource constraints or forego expansion opportunities. because cooperative strategies such as joint ventures and long-term contracts best delimit resource constraints by permitting independent firms to cooperate, these will be preferred when resource stocks are insufficient to permit the firm to achieve its growth objective independently (ingham & thompson, 1994). resource constrained firms simply have no alternative but to grow through long-term contracting or joint ventures, even when these are not the most efficient governance arrangements (mcwilliams & gray, 1995). if the resource stocks that are missing can be furnished by an external partner with little risk of opportunism, then the firm will take advantage of this low cost of external governance situation by contracting. thus, it is predicted that: proposition 1: when firms possess insufficient resource stocks under low cost ofexternal governance, long-term contracts will be preferred. conversely, when needed resources cannot be easily contracted for without considerable exposure to potential opportunism, joint ventures become the only viable option. the governance costs of contracting can be high because the firm must expose its strategically valuable resources to the external firm in order to create a configuration of resources sufficient for existing opportunities. under a long-term contract, the firm risks creating a competitor if its partner can, over time, imitate the firm's strategically valuable resources. similarly, there is considerable risk that after highly specific investments have been made by the firm, the partner could demand to renegotiate their contract as a condition for continfall 1997 combs & ketchen: toward a synthesis 93 ued cooperation. the advantage of ajoint venture is that both firms must make a credible commitment to the venture (hennart, 1988; teece, 1987). because each partner must expose its resources to potential loss, gains from opportunistic behavior are reduced. accordingly, we expect: proposition 2: when firms possess insufficient resource stocks under high cost of external governance, joint ventures will be preferred. when firms possess adequate resource stocks, the need to use strategy for resource accumulation is eliminated. hence, strategic choices will reflect minimization of governance costs. as mc williams and gray (1995) pointed out, firms that possess a complete set of strategically valuable resources have an incentive to control these resources tightly through company ownership because they are the source of above average returns. thus, resource-abundant firms can be expected to grow primarily through the grand strategies of internal development and acquisition. however, if the strategically valuable resources must be combined with complementary resources that can be contracted for at competitive prices and with little risk of opportunism then there is room for cooperation (mahoney & pandian, 1992; teece, 1987). under these low costs of external governance conditions, there is no reason for the firm to endure the bureaucratic costs and loss of flexibility that may accompany the internal development or acquisition of complementary assets. for example, a clothing designer may earn higher returns and increase flexibility by contracting for manufacturing and distribution activities. thus, when strategically valuable resources are sufficient, but the cost of external governance remains low, we expect firms to contract for any activities that are not central to their competitive advantage. stated formally: proposition 3: when firms possess sufficient stocks ofstrategically valuable resources under low cost ofexternal governance, they will prefer internal development or acquisition for those activities that depend on strategically valuable resources and long-term contracts for activities that depend on complementary resources. occasions also exist in which complementary activities must be so tightly linked to strategically valuable activities that it would be difficult for them to be conducted in different firms because of the risk of opportunism (e.g., sales and manufacturing of industrial products anderson & coughlan, 1987). when the firm is relatively resource rich, it has no incentive to expose its anticipated income stream to opportunistic behavior from external firms (mcwilliams & gray, 1995) and will thus engage new opportunities through internal development or acquisition. stated formally: 94 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 proposition 4: when firms possess sufficient stocks ofstrategically valuable resources under high cost ofexternal governance, they will prefer internal development and/or acquisition. the four propositions above are visually depicted in figure 2. figure 2 proposed integration of resource stock and governance cost effects on grand strategy resource stocks sufficient insufficient high cost of external governance low internal development joint venture and/or acquisition internal development and/or acquisition long-term and contracting long-term contracting the distinction between internal development and acquisition depends on the firm's current configuration of resources (chatterjee, 1990; yip, 1982). if existing resource stocks can be employed in the new market, internal development is preferred. this might occur, for example, for brand extensions or geographic growth. however, if the configuration of resources needed to engage the target market differ considerably from existing resource stocks, acquisition is likely to be used to access needed resources. such would likely be the case for some types of diversification. thus, we offer the following corollaries to propositions 3 and 4: corollary 1: firms with sufficient stocks of strategically valuable resources will prefer internal development when the new activity is an extension of current resources. corollary 2: firms with sufficient stocks of strategically valuable resources will prefer acquisition when the new activity requires a new configuration of resources. fall 1997 combs & ketchen: toward a synthesis 95 grand strategy and performance because a distinguishing characteristic of strategic management research is its emphasis on performance (summer et ai., 1990; venkatraman & ramanujam, 1986), it is not enough to specify the influence ofresource stocks and governance costs on grand strategy. unless there are implications for performance, the value of matching strategy to resource and governance conditions is limited. above it was suggested that long-term competitive success rests first on the firm's capacity to access and exploit strategically valuable resources. it was predicted that when firms possess few of these resources, they will be prompted to engage in joint ventures and long-term contracting to gain the use of resources, even if governance cost conditions might predict otherwise. however, firms will still consider their governance cost conditions when selecting between joint ventures and long-term contracts. specifically, when high external governance costs conditions make cooperation potentially costly, firms will favor joint ventures. the expectation that governance cost will impact performance through strategy is based, in part. on the efficiency logic that underlies oe (barney & ouchi, 1986; hesterly et ai., 1990). that is, by responding appropriately to governance cost pressures, firms are selecting low cost alternatives. presumably, choosing the "correct" (i.e., low cost) strategy translates into better performance (hill & snell, 1988; williamson, 1994). taken together, we expect the following propositions to hold true: proposition 5: firms that engage in long-term contracting when their resource stocks are insufficient and their cost of external governance is low will perform better than firms that use other grand strategies under these conditions. proposition 6: firms that engage in joint ventures when their resource stocks are insufficient and their cost of external governance is high will perform better than firms that use other grand strategies under these conditions. when stocks of strategically valuable resources are sufficient, firms are expected to defer to oe concerns when selecting grand strategy. nevertheless, firms can increase their strategic flexibility and minimize bureaucratic costs by contracting for complementary activities when the cost of external governance is low. this additional efficiency should translate into improved performance. accordingly: proposition 7: firms that engage in the internal development or acquisition ofstrategically valuable resources and long-term contracting for complementary resources when resource stocks 96 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 are sufficient and the cost of external governance is low will perform better than firms that use other grand strategies under these conditions. the luxury of contracting complementary activities is not efficient when the costs of external governance are high. the risk of opportunistic behavior is simply too severe considering the firm can access au needed resources internally. thus, we expect that: proposition 8: firms that engage in internal development or acquisition when stocks ofstrategically valuable resources are sufficient and the cost of external governance is high will perform better than firms that use other grand strategies under these conditions. discussion several implications can be drawn for research and practice from our synthesis of rbv and oe insights into grand strategies. for researchers, it appears that both perspectives are needed to fully explain choices among grand strategies. if so, empirical investigations that recognize both perspectives should enjoy greater predictive power than existing models. for practitioners, this integration offers guidance for selecting among grand strategies. specifically. the trade-offs in responding to resource versus governance contingencies may have an impact on performance. below we suggest that the nature of this trade-off changes as the firm grows and matures. implications for research the logic developed above indicates that the relationship between resource stocks and grand strategy depends on governance costs and the relationship between governance costs and grand strategy depends on resource stocks. the implication is that prior research examining any of the grand strategies from one perspective without consideration ofthe other should be viewed cautiously. likewise, future scholars focused on either resource stocks or governance costs should include measures of the other, at least as control variables, or they will face the risk of having an underspecified empirical model. indeed. models that include both rbv and de variables should have enhanced predictive power because more fully specified models have greater potential to explain variance. increased predictive power is important to managers who need to better predict competitors' behavior and to researchers who wish to use these models to better understand the link between strategy and performance. although our solution to the conflict between the rbv and de in the context of grand strategies is consistent with each perspective's prior empirical fall 1997 combs & ketchen: toward a synthesis 97 results, little has been done empirically to compare the joint effects of resources and governance conditions on grand strategy. examining these relationships in more detail will be an important next step for future inquiry. in this paper, we have examined rbv and de prescriptions regarding grand strategies without challenging any of the fundamental assumptions that underlie either perspective. thus, another potentially fruitful avenue of research may be to relax key theoretical assumptions (barney, 1990). indeed, an important body of literature has emerged contradicting de assumptions concerning the rational self-interested behavior of organizational participants (e.g., donaldson, 1990; moran, 1996). this research argues that organizational participants are, as often as not, trustworthy. that is, participants will act according to generally accepted ethical principles even when it is not in their rational self-interest to do so (hosmer, 1995). extant research suggests that the need for formal governance arrangements are diminished when a climate of trust prevails (chiles & mcmackin, 1996; granovetter, 1985; duchi, 1980). moreover, because trust may diminish the need for expensive formal governance arrangements, it can be viewed as a strategically valuable resource (barney & hansen, 1994). although it may be difficult to tease out behaviors based in trust versus self-interest, such an effort might give researchers insight into the extent to which trust affects the choice of grand strategy. future research could also benefit from increased understanding of the social and psychological antecedents of trust (granovetter, 1985; mayer, davis & schoorman, 1995). managerial implications the ideas developed in this paper have important implications for managers as well. modern organizations are forced to confront a staggering array of challenges, including rapid advances in information technology (fulk & desanctis, 1995), the emergence of new organizational forms (miles & snow, 1994), and the globalization of many markets (chang, 1995). under such conditions, understanding the relationship between strategy and performance is of great practical interest. indeed, a well-constructed strategy is one of the few weapons managers have available to help ensure the viability of the organization. building on prior research, this paper suggests that managers give resource issues primacy over governance concerns in grand strategy decisions. this was based on evidence from the rbv suggesting that deployment of strategically valuable resources is central to performance. nevertheless, as the de perspective points out, there is an efficiency loss when firms must cooperate with others through, for example, a joint venture to gain access to valuable resources when governance conditions dictate otherwise. although accessing a partner's strategically valuable resources may enhance performance, the apparent loss of efficiency might be expected to reduce profits vis-a-vis a competitor owning all needed resources. in time, however, the firm possesses two avenues for recovering this efficiency loss. first, trust between the firm and its joint venture partner can be built, 98 journal of business strategies vol. 14, no.2 which may negate the need for formal hierarchical governance (barney & hansen, 1994). second, the firm could use the joint venture to, over time, develop its own endowments and either acquire or shutdown its joint venture operations (hamel, 1991). under either scenario, the firm suffers a small short-term inefficiency in order to capitalize on strategically valuable resources over the long-term. overall, managers are encouraged to view increased deployment of strategically valuable resources as sources of increased revenue. their second concern should be to manage these resources as efficiently as possible with an eye toward building future resources. managers must be aware that this prioritization may require short-term inefficiencies as a price for enhanced long-term performance. conclusion the rbv and oe are increasingly popular views of organizational action. in the context of grand strategies, these views do not always point managers in the same direction. we have taken a step toward reconciliation of these views and drawn a link between resourceversus governance-based antecedent conditions, strategy and performance. future inquiry into grand strategies may enjoy greater predictive power by recognizing the contributions of each perspective. more importantly, managers can use insights from both views to better understand potential trade-offs and their impact on firm performance. references aaker, d. (1991). mauaiini brand eqyity: cm:litalizini on the value of brand naml;<. new york: free press. alchian, a. a., & demsetz. h. (1972). production, information costs. and economic organization. aml;