A NOTE ON THE STRATEGIC USE OF SERVICE

Charles Hegji
Evan Moore

Auburn University - Montgomery
Montgomery, AL

Abstract

We develop a model ofoptimal service provision and pricing in which the level
ofservice is not viewed as a capacity choice. We study the provision o.fservices
in both a non-strategic setting, characterized by a monopoly, and in a strategic
setting, a differentiated price duopoly. We find that in both settings increased
services lead to increased prices. However, unlike other models, the strategic
setting results in greater services than the non-strategic case. Additionally, we
discuss the welfare effects for consumers and find that any gains in consumer
surplus from increased service provision in the strategic setting are more than
offco;et by the associated higher equilibrium prices.

A problem that has received attention in the literature is the level of customer
service provided by retailers. One vein of research has hnked the provision of
service by retailers to fair trade laws and resale price agreements between sellers.
This is exemplified by the work of Telser (1960, 1990) and that of Marvel and
McCafferty (1996). The argument is that since resale price agreements provide
price floors in the resale market, they prevent retailers from selling at low prices
to customers that have obtained product information from other sellers. Such
agreements, therefore, encourage the provision of service in the form ofadditional
product information by retailers. An implication of this reasoning is that higher
service levels are generally associated with higher retail prices.

An alternative strand of research has been to regard the level of service
provided by retailers as a strategic weapon. De Vany (1976), De Vany and
Saving (1983), Koenigsburg (1980), Kalai et al. (1992), Stidham (1992), Li
and Lee (1994), and I1makunnas (2002) adopt this approach. Earlier work in
this area centers on service level as the firm's primary choice variable. More
recent work, such as the papers of Stidham (1992), Li and Lee (1994), and
I1makunnas (2002), study the simultaneous use of price and service capacity
as strategic instruments. I1makunnas, for instance, develops a model of service
capacity choice in which firms, after choosing capacity, compete using price in
Bertrand fashion. In the Ilmakunnas model, capacity choices have a negative
impact on competitors, since added capacity in one firm decreases the full price
(price plus waiting cost) and leads to a flow of customers from the other firm.
Two implications of this approach are a negative correlation between service



136 Journal ofBusiness Strategies Vol. 22, No.2

capacity and price, and an underinvestment in service capacity compared to
the non-strategic case.

The present note extends this second line of research in two ways. First, we
develop a model of optimal level of service in which service is not viewed as
capacity. Second, we study the provision of services in a non-strategic setting
characterized by a monopoly and in a strategic setting, a differentiated price
duopoly. We find that in both settings increased services lead to increased prices.
However, unlike the Ilmakunnas model, the strategic setting results in greater
services than the non-strategic case. Additionally, the effects on consumer wel-
fare are discussed. We conclude with a summary and implications for managers
competing in the strategic setting.

The Provision of Services under Two Settings
Consider the following demand facing producers

Q(P,Sj = S(A-Pj, (1)

where P is price, S is the per unit level of service provided in the market, and
A is a shift parameter corresponding to the intercept on a linear demand curve. l

According to (1 ), quantity demanded is inversely related to price and increases
with the per unit level of service provided. Note, however, that since service is
multiplied by the difference (A-P), demand does not shift parallel with an increase
in service, but rather, rotates around the price axis. This is reasonable, since it
suggests that the customer must purchase the good for service to have an effect
on demand. Alternatively, if P = A so that producers price themselves out of the
market, the effect of service on demand will be zero.

This multiplicative form is not overly restrictive, with the interaction of price
and service extending capacity models of service. Such models use an additive
demand curve with separate service price and final product price, and assume
that the only service provided by firms is the capacity to reduce buyer waiting
times in equilibrium. This type of service is similar to added check-out lines
in grocery stores. The multiplicative form of demand assumed in (l) involves
service that is more closely bundled to the product and covers such things as
information on product assembly or product repair. It can also cover new and
attractive store displays and other types of service where costs are incorporated
into product price.

The good, for sake of simplicity, is assumed to be supplied at constant marginal
cost C. Service (S) is assumed to be supplied at constant cost per unit of service <po
These assumptions result in a total cost of output plus service TC = q( C + qJS).

We begin with the provision of service by a monopoly seller of the product.
This situation is a simplification of a non-strategically operating price-setting
firm. For the monopoly, begin with the profit function

n(P,S) = PQ(P,S) - C(Q,S) = PS(A - Pj - (qJ + C)S(A - Pj, (2)



Fall 2005 Hegji and Moore: Strategic Use a/Service 137

The monopolist maximizes (2) with respect to price and level of service.
Differentiating (2) with respect to P results in the monopoly price of

p*
2A + C,

3
(3)

Differentiating (2) with respect to S and using (3) obtains the equilibrium level
of service provided by the monopolist of

A - C,
s* =

3rp
(4)

Equation (3) reveals that, as expected, the monopolist prices above cost. In
addition price increases with the marginal cost of production and the unit cost
of providing services. Equation (4) shows that the level of services provided by
the monopolist decreases both with the marginal cost of providing services q>
and the unit cost C of providing the good. Note that an increase in demand and
price, resulting from an increase in the parameter A, leads to an increase in the
optimal level of service. Service and price are therefore positively correlated in
this non-strategic setting.

Next consider the following differentiated price Bertrand setting. Assume that
for i,} = 1, 2 demand is given by

qi = S/A - Pi + PP)I2, where 0 < f3 < 1. (5)

The above specification is derived by assuming that without strategic interaction
between firms H3 = 0 and SJ at the normalized value I), each firm begins play
with one half of the monopoly's market share. Output produced by firms i and}
are substitutes with an increase in competitor price (P) resulting in an increase
in own quantity demanded (q). The usual assumption is that demand is more
sensitive to own price effects, such that P< I. Note that by the above specifica-
tion demand in market i is a function of services provided in that market only.
An interpretation is that the level of service S, appearing in (5) represents the net
services provided by firm i relative to firm}.

The present situation can be thought of as a two-stage game. In the first stage,
firms independently and simultaneously choose price. Given the equi librium price,
each firm determines its optimal level of service. Begin with profits of firm i:

2rr,(P"S) =: S/A - Pi + PP)Pi - S/A - Pi + PP)(C + cpS) (6)



138 Journal ofBusiness Strategies Vol. 22, No.2

Differentiating (6) with respect to price results in firm i's reaction function

p=
I

A + C + qJS + /3P"
I i

2
(7)

Differentiating (6) with respect to the level of services S, yields the relationship
S (P - C)l2qJ. Use of this relationship and (7) results in the equilibrium price

I ,

and level of service in the differentiated price Bertrand model:

p = p = p* =
1 2

2A + C,

3 - 2/3
(8)

A - C + f)C,
S = S = s* =

1 2 cp(3 _ 2/3)
(9)

Equation (7) shows that, as in the monopoly model, firms engaged in differenti-
ated Bertrand price competition set price above marginal production cost and the
total cost of providing service. This reaction function shows that, as in the non-
strategic case, price and service are positively correlated. This positive correlation
is also evident in the equilibrium price and level of service in equations (8) and
(9). Both service and price increase with an increase in the demand parameter A.

The level of service provided by a Bertrand firm decreases as the marginal
cost of providing service cp increases. Note that since 13 < 1, the level of service
provided also decreases with the marginal production cost c. 2

Both price and the amount of service provided by the Bertrand firm relative
to the monopoly are immediately apparent. A comparison of equations (3) and
(8) reveals that the equilibrium price for the Bertrand firms is higher than in
the non-strategic case. This characteristic of the differentiated price Bertrand
model is well known, its source being evident in the Bertrand reaction function.
Equation (7) shows that the firm's price responds positively to an increase in the
competitor's price. This complementarity of strategic responses results in higher
equilibrium prices than in the non-strategic case.

Comparing equations (5) and (8) reveals that the equilibrium level of service
in the Bertrand model is greater than in the non-strategic case. This differs from
Ilmakunnas' (2002) model and is a direct result of service being bundled to the
product rather than sold as capacity units. Suppose that the competitor increases
service provided to its customers. This allows the competitor to increase price.
Since the firm's own price is complementary to the competitor's price, the firm
will increase its price allowing the firm to increase service to compensate for the
corresponding decrease in quantity demanded. The end result will be a level of
service greater than the non-strategic monopoly case.



Fall 2005 Hegji and Moore: Strategic Use of Service 139

A related question is whether the consumer benefits from this strategic competi-
tion. Consumers gain from the competition in the differentiated price Bertrand
model due to greater service, but lose due to higher prices compared to the non-
strategic case. Without an explicit consumer utility function in goods and service,
a reasonable approximation of consumer welfare is consumer surplus. For the
monopoly this is given by CS = (l/2)(A - P*)q*, where p* and q* are the profit-
maximizing price and quantity, where quantity is a function of service provided
by the monopoly. The consumer surplus for the differentiated Bertrand model is
similarly computed, with q* being the sum of the quantities produced by both
firms, quantity again being a function of the level of service provided by the firm.

The total consumer surplus for the Bertrand firms (CS
B

) and of the monopoly
market (CSl.) are

(A - C + /3CP(A(1 - 2/3) - C),

2q:J(3 - 2/3Y
(10)

(11 )

By design CSs = CSM when 13 = 0.
3 However, as ~) increases from 0 to I the

consumer surplus in the Bertrand market decreases. This is evident as the deriva-
tive of (1 0) with respect to /3 is

/3(2A + C)2(A + (/3 - I )C)

q:J(3 - 2~)4
(12)

which is negative. In other words, the consumer surplus in the Bertrand market
is less than that of the non-strategic monopoly setting for all feasible values of
/3.4 An inspection of equation (12) also reveals that the decrease in CS

B
increases

as 13, a measure of product differentiation, increases. Gains to consumers from
increased service provision are more than offset by price increases in the Ber-
trand market.

Summary and Managerial Implications
In this note we have developed a model of optimal service level provision in

which service is not viewed as capacity. The demand function used in the analysis
involves a multiplicative relationship between service and pricing. Such a function
allows service to be viewed as more closely bundled to the product as opposed
to an offering that can be purchased in addition to the product.

We find that the service provision and prices in the strategic Bertrand market
are greater than that of a non-strategic monopoly market. We show that any gains



140 Journal ofBusiness Strategies Vol. 22, No.2

in consumer surplus from increased service provision in the Bertrand market
are more than offset by the associated higher equilibrium prices. This analysis
reveals that consumer surplus is greater in the non-strategic case. Additionally,
consumer surplus is further decreased in the Bertrand market as product dif-
ferentiation increases.

Managers of firms competing in the Bertrand markets realize higher profits
due to the strategic complementarities of pricing and service. However, although
higher service levels lead to higher equilibrium prices in this strategic setting,
consumer surplus decreases. As consumers become aware of their decrease in
welfare due to the higher product price, product switching may begin to occur.
Additionally, higher prices due to higher service levels may encourage entry
into the market by new firms. 5 This would likely hurt the long run profitability
of existing firms. The bottom line for managers is that although competition in
the provision of service may at times seem attractive, in that increased services
allow for higher prices, price competition should be considered the preferred
long-run strategy.

References

De Vany, A. (1976) Uncertainty, waiting time, and capacity utilization: A stochastic theory
of product quality. Journal of Political Economy. 84,523-542.

De Vany, A., and Saving, T. ( 1983) The economics ofquality. Journal ofPolitical Economy,
9/,979-1000.

Ilmakunnas, P. (2002) Strategic behavior in a service industry. Managerial and Decision
Economics, 23, 69-82.

Kalai, E., Kamien, M., and Rabinovich, M. (1992) Optimal service speed in a competitive
environment. Management Science. 38, 1154-1163.

Koenigsburg, E. (1980) Uncertainty, capacity, and market share in oligopoly: A stochastic
theory of product quality. Journal of Business. 53, 151-164.

Li, L., and Lee, YS. (1994) Pricing and delivery time performance in a competitive en-
vironment. Management Science. 40, 633-646.

Marvel, H., and McCafferty, S. (1996) Comparing vertical restraints. Journal ofEconom-
ics and Business, 48,473-486.

Pep an, L., Richards, D., & Norman, G. (2002) Industrial organization: Contemporary
theory and practice. (2 nd ed.). Mason: South-Western.

Stidham, Jr., S. (1992) Pricing and capacity decisions for a service facility: Stability and
multiple local optima. Management Science, 38, 1121-1139.



Fall 2005 Hegji and Moore: Strategic Use ofService 141

Telser, L. (1960) Why should manufacturers want fair trade? The Journal of Law and
Economics, 3, 86-105.

Telser, L. (1990) Why should manufacturers want fair trade II? The Journal of Law and
Economics, 33,409-417.

Footnotes

I A close variant of this demand has been suggested as a vehicle for studying
customer service by Pepall, Richards, and Norman (2002, p. 487). The multipli-
cative demand function has been used in models for quality as well. This type
of demand indicates that increases in services raise consumer reservation prices
and the maximum market size.

2 This restriction (~ < 1) is standard with differentiated Bertrand models indi-
cating that responsiveness to changes in the product's own price is greater than
responsiveness to changes in the rival's price.

3 See the discussion surrounding equation (5).

4 We point out that while 0 < 13 < 1 is a standard assumption, 0 < 1.5 is necessary
to ensure positive equilibrium prices.

5 Although the model presented is static, this is the likely result in a dynamic
model with entry.

Dr. Charles Hegji, Ph.D. (Washington University S1. Louis) is a Distinguished
Research Professor in the Department of Economics at Auburn University Mont-
gomery. He has been with the department since 1985 and is currently a full profes-
sor. His primary teaching interests are in Managerial Economics, Principles of
Microeconomics, and Statistics. His primary area of research is in firm strategy
and market structure. He also enj oys publishing electronic music; you may listen
to his music at www.acidplanet.com under the artist name DrH.

Dr. Evan Moore, Ph.D. (Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University)
joined the Department of Economics at Auburn University Montgomery in
2002 and is currently an assistant professor. His primary teaching interests are
Industrial Organization, Principles of Microeconomics, and the Economics of
Decision Making. His primary areas of research include industrial organization
and experimental economics. He has a coauthored work forthcoming in the
American Economic Review.


	A Note on the Strategic Use of Service