Journal of World-Systems Ressearch - Festschrift for Immanuel Wallerstein Part I 456 World Economic System: On the Genesis of a Concept Theotônio dos Santos Theotônio dos Santos Coordenador da Pós-Graduação de Economia Universidade Federal Fluminense Rua Tiradentes 17–Ingá Niterói Rio de Janeiro (RJ) CEP 24.210-510 Brazil sectheo@vmhpo.uff.br http://www.uff.br/econ/ journal of world-systems research, vi, 2, summer/fall 2000, 456-477 Special Issue: Festchrift for Immanuel Wallerstein – Part I http://csf.colorado.edu/jwsr issn 1076-156x © 2000 Theotônio dos Santos 1. national and international economics Political-economy has been generated during national economies and nation-state constitution; the theoretical effort that served as basis for the rise of economics as a science may be written within the boundaries of the analysis of national economies. This was, for example, Quesnay’s great con- tribution when establishing the economic-cycle concept by departing from the agricultural production and circulation process and going through the manufacturing and other “non-productive” activities. He disputed the mer- cantilist doctrines which saw wealth’s origin in trade, manufacturing, or gold or silver, according to their English, French or Spanish versions, respectively. The reaction Quesnay represented sought to show that wealth formation depended either on agricultural production, or on “productive labour”—what he called primary production—viewing circulation, trade, and the fi nancial sector as “unproductive” activities, dependent on produc- tive labour. This line of thought established by Quesnay was deepened by the clas- sical economists like Smith and Ricardo who posited the basis for national wealth in labour, widening the “productive labour” concept to include manu- http://www.uff.br/econ/ http://csf.colorado.edu/jwsr Theotônio dos Santos457 World Economic System 458 Factors’ diversifi cation that condition the comparable advantages goes through a complex process by including the function of production in the international exchange, which means to introduce the relationship labour/ capital in the analysis. People responsible for this “discovery” (a bit late, because capital’s organic composition had already informed Marxist analysis some decades before) were Heckscher and Ohlin whose theorem not only assumes heroic conditions but also establishes a tendency to international equilibrium, a situation which does not seem to develop in the real world economic system. The diversifi cation of this universe began when Leontieff decided to submit these propositions to an empirical test. This took him away from his “paradox,” when discovering that the tendencies of North American inter- national trade did not follow the deductive directions of the comparative advantages theory, which provoked a search for explanations and new con- cepts. According to Herckscher-Ohlin’s theorem, one should expect North America to specialize in capital intensive products, an abundant factor in the region. Leontieff, however, found an export agenda with a predominance of labour intensive products, particularly agricultural ones. The ensuing debate concentrated on increasing the number of factors to be considered within the production function or, at its best, took into consideration some macro-economic variables that were not considered in the theory before. The theory of world economics continues to be a theory of external trade effects on national economies. This inner limitation of the economic theory only starts to be truly questioned when one starts to accept—a cen- tury after the existence of the phenomenon and its study—the existence of capital movements and, much later, labour movements. It is evident that all such theoretical and analytical efforts are based upon extremely restrictive assumptions. The fi rst one is that economic units are essentially national, an assumption which provides the basis for the whole effort of economic theory. The second is that these national economic units get into relationships with others and basically only exchange goods. Here we have a third assumption, that those national economies are not open either to capital or labour movements, or technology. One assumes comparable advantages in a certain productivity standard that varies in each one of those national economies, in great part due to factor allocation. No thought, let alone research, is allowed on the possible transfer of technology. facturing labour. They put special emphasis on the role of productivity, with the division of labour seen—at that time—as the main tool to reach such higher productivity. It is natural then, that eventually economic science was compelled to face the relations between those national economies with the “outside world” as a problem that demanded—in one way or another—the theoretical open- ing-up of that national economic system. To analyze these relations, Adam Smith elaborated his theory of the absolute advantages which intended to show the need for a specialization in those sectors in which the national economy looked capable of reaching a better standard of productivity. Deep down he was more interested in the effect of external relations on the national economy than in the analysis of the international economy to which he refers sometimes when dealing with the colonial problem. Later on, Ricardo assumed in a much more radical way, the idea of specialization when defending the comparative advantages theory, showing that it is useful—even when a country does not enjoy absolute advantages regarding some products—for it (and for the other country that buys from and sells to it) to specialize in those products that refl ect a relative advan- tage as a result of the higher productivity of some products in relation to others. In a certain way, therefore, it is an internal decision in each country to specialize in those sectors in which it achieves higher productivity, import- ing the products in which it achieves lower productivity even if the prices of these products abroad are not lower than the national ones. The funda- mental issue is that the greater specialization of each one, and the exchange amongst all, produces higher productivity for the set and advantages for all. This view of international economics as an external factor only comple- mentary to the logic of national economics became the drive for the whole theoretical effort of classical economics, from what Marx later called vulgar economics, through to the adoption of the consumer’s viewpoint, generat- ing utility theory and the neoclassical school of thought. The maximum that one will advance will be towards the increase of the factors that explain com- parative advantages, but the analysis’ aim will always be to orient resource allocation in accordance with a specialization each time more sophisticated in face of an increased complexity of the economic activities. The analysis’ aim will be to go on comparing national economies with others because of a possible exchange amongst them. Theotônio dos Santos459 World Economic System 460 When introduced the technological variable was assumed to be a universally available technological asset, as if patent laws and technological monop- oly—which is at the basis of contemporary economics—did not exist. It is true that important economists such as J.S. Mill had already called attention to the fact that the exchange of goods commercial relation assumed the existence of internal markets getting in touch. The analysis of that exchange, therefore, should have also taken up an analysis of inter- nal markets and economies. In spite of widening the basis for analysis, this stand continued at the same level of relations amongst national economies, that is, closed economic units irreducible to each other. It isn’t worth our time to delve into the monetary theories that aggregate this new dimension of a unique theoretical model. Currencies are studied as national currencies that have certain exchange rates established according to their exchange with other national currencies. This view was developed pre- cisely during the historical period in which the dollar converted itself into a world currency, anchored by the Bretton Woods agreements and in which capital movements spread throughout the world, followed by globalization of the international fi nancial system. The analysis of these concrete phenomena either was done at the fringe of theory or was analyzed separately as each country’s internal economic policies. Thus, there was a denial of any phenomenon that might be under- stood as an international economy different from the relations between national economies, a global economy which could be analyzed as a reality in itself. This theoretical and methodological scenario could not survive the evo- lution of the international economy, as all the assumptions on which it was based were broken as the world capitalist economy advanced. Already, at the time in which this theoretical model was constituted, its distance from humanity’s historical experience was assured. The mercantilists, against whom a great part of the constituent effort of classical economy was built up, expressed the European reality of the 15th, 16th and 17th centuries, in which the economic power of the emergent nations in Europe constituted itself as strategies for linking with international trade. Mercantilism emphasized these emergent national economies’ position within that world trade because it was an expression—in the theoretical fi eld—of merchant capital’s then hegemonic interests. This turn to the national dimension created a genuine barrier to rethink these national struc- tures as part of a world economy becoming more complex. Such power constituted itself through the physical and organizational power of monop- oly, fi nancial capital, nation-states and, later on, multinational, transnational and global corporations. History shows us that international trade precedes modern national economies, even being one of its constituent elements. We cannot speak of the creation of Portuguese and Spanish national economies without the processes of maritime discoveries upon which the foundations of these economies were built. It is absurd to talk of their independent constitution apart from international trade since these national economics are the off- spring of the expansion achieved through the wars against the Moors, and the maritime and navigation discoveries. Hence, the assumption of a national economy, internal to itself and independent from international trade is, evidently, a heroic assumption, and an ideological violence, but one accepted in the 18th century as England consolidated itself as a manufactur- ing and industrial economy. It was such consolidation of a national economy that allowed England to take the hegemonic position at the international level. Actually English wealth and national state power could not have been possible without the international effects of gold discovery in Minas Gerais (which Pierre Vilar (1974) analyses in a magnifi cent way in his historical studies on gold and currency); without its still feeble Asian expansion; with- out the hegemonic relations established between it and the Portuguese state through the Methuen Treaty (which made viable the transference of enor- mous surplus from the Portuguese colonies to the purchase of English com- modities); and fi nally, without the profi table slave trade which was one of the main sources of primitive accumulation that made the English national economy viable. Smith’s and Ricardo’s theoretical efforts turned in great part toward the opening of England to cereal imports, allowing for a reduction in labour costs inside the country at the expense of the destruction of traditional Eng- lish agriculture and liberating the agricultural labour force for its absorption by the rising industries. Finally, the colonial phenomenon was also an essential part of the national uniformities of those countries: Portugal, Spain, Holland, Belgium, Theotônio dos Santos461 World Economic System 462 England and France—European centers for capital accumulation—were essentially colonizing economies, and the colonial trade was one of the fun- damental sources of capitalist accumulation in those economies. I also sug- gest a detailed reading of the third volume of the book Civilização Material: Economia e Capitalismo do Século XVI ao Século XVIII, by Fernand Braudel (1979c), as well as Ouro e Moeda na História entre 1450 e 1920, by Pierre Vilar (1974). In Os Descobrimentos da Economia Mundial, by Vitorino Magalhães Godinho (1981), the history of discoveries is coupled with Portuguese economic history (in which, by the way, he was preceded by other great Portuguese historians, such as Antônio Sérgio). I also propose one take into consideration Immanuel Wallerstein’s book (1974), The Modern World System I: Capitalist Agriculture and the Origins of European World Economy in the XVI Century. All these studies insist on the thesis that national econo- mies stem from a world economy, or—in Wallerstein’s case—a world Euro- pean economy which was converted into the basis for the world economic system. Here, we are not so concerned with refi ning the historical analysis, but rather with the methodological issues. The thesis that national economies were the basis for international economic relations was, evidently, a his- torical and methodological violence which began disappearing once—in the 18th century—national economies began to acquire a certain degree of independence from that world economy. By independence I do not mean secession or withdrawal but, actually, a more and more determinant role within that world economy. The industrial revolution produced a techno- logical leap substantial enough to allow national economies to become hege- monic within the world economy due to their internal productive capacity. Adam Smith’s theoretical inquiry makes sense. The origins of the nations’ wealth lay in their systems’ productivity. Those national systems that reach a high degree of productivity through the division of labour and adoption of modern manufacturing manage to establish, at a national level, the hegemony of a strong nation-state with a hegemonic industrial bour- geoisie. We will see, however, different theoretical traditions that posit other foundations for economic development. We could point out in the work of the authors quoted here—Smith, Ricardo, J.S. Mill, etc.—very impor- tant considerations about the colonial phenomenon at their time and on the world economy itself that have not been suffi ciently stressed by followers of these theorists. We emphasize here those who have been doing a differ- ent reading of these theorists’ works, an alternative body of theoretical work where the elements of the world economy and the idea of a world economic system have not been erased and denied. Karl Marx apparently did not dedicate himself specifi cally to the study of world trade and world economy as essential elements in the constitution of his theoretical scenario. A fi rst reading of Marx could even indicate that he would have followed a path similar to Smith and Ricardo by starting from the national economy in order to later open up an analysis of the international economy, a task he did not even manage to carry out due to his premature death. However, a more detailed analysis results in a differ- ent reading. Capital begins with the commodity, an analysis which does not assume, necessarily, the idea of a world economy. Nevertheless, by creating the category of commodity, Marx shows that it is produced in the context of trade, and is essentially a phenomenon of intertribal, inter-communities, international. So, when Marx sets the category of commodity as constituent of a given economic system—in this case the capitalist system—he is situat- ing this system within a wider context than local units, either imperial or national. Marx did not build the category of world economics elaborated much later, and in a brilliant fashion by Fernand Braudel (1979a, b, and c; 1987 a and b). Braudel showed that the basic economic units of capitalism were neither local nor national, but were rather regional economic units which included several local realities, linked amongst them by a system of rela- tions (mainly commercial) that constituted a world economy. That concept shows us how the concept of commodity assumed the existence of a phe- nomenon of the sort of a world economy, fi nally, of a region relatively impor- tant where there is an exchange of commodities with a certain division of labour amongst their various parts that establish relations relatively system- atic between them. By rethinking the category of commodity in the present context of eco- nomic history, we want to reaffi rm Marx’s methodological effort’s power, of great methodological and theoretical implications, because, by taking the category of commodity as central element from which one could deduct Theotônio dos Santos463 World Economic System 464 the basic economic relations for the constitution of a capitalist production mode, Marx situated capitalism as a result of a given historical process that, in no way, can be thought only as a national process, and that, above all, he did not think as an exclusively national process. Such evidence is in the Capital’s chapters he devoted to the issue of prim- itive accumulation, that is, the accumulation that serves as basis for the con- stitution of the capitalist mode of production and subject it to its logic. For him, such primitive accumulation is made of resources acquired through the expropriation of communal lands, until then administered by peasants, which was done by merchant capital and allowed it to concentrate a big wealth. Primitive accumulation was also based upon profi ts of world trade, whose enormous increase and high productivity allowed capital to lay up a big treasure. Sheer and simple pillage besides colonial tax charges also allowed—through the expropriation of the wealth obtained by other eco- nomic systems—one to reach an enormous capital concentration. Besides colonial trade—which was based upon value and exchange according to the value law—there was a wild commerce based upon exploi- tation of cultural and civilization differences which allowed Europe to obtain enormous profi ts generated by prices without any evident regulation. Moreover, there was the slave trade, one of the biggest sources of wealth in this historical period, on which Marx puts great emphasis. Hence, in Capi- tal, modern capitalist economic constitution clearly goes through the gen- eration of capital surplus gotten in the context of a world economy. The possibility that merchant relations being converted to its hegemonic way of social and economic relations—not only creating local spaces but also originating national markets—could only happen in the context of modern world trade. This historical and logical standpoint adopted by Marx—who substan- tiates his methodological dialectical view—does not allow us to situate Marx within classical political economy’s thought. Such theoretical reduc- tion is only possible through an aslant reading with disregard to Marx’s methodological wealth, to his Hegelian and dialectical view, in order to be led simply by concepts on which Marx worked, a great part of them com- ing—actually—from classical political economy. The historical and logical treatment entirely exits the fi eld of classical political economy, up to an extent that Marx’s understanding by economists educated in such a limited methodological fi eld becomes impossible. The evidence that a reading of Marx only within classical political economy would not be correct, is the fact that Marx’s followers and pupils go naturally towards reinforcing the analy- sis of capitalism as a world economic system. One of the peaks of intellectual effort pointing at this theoretical direc- tion is the book, originally published in 1904 by Hilferding (1981), Financial Capital. When analyzing the phenomenon of economic concentration and modern monopolies’ constitution, he showed the bank system’s hegemony over the industrial one, which would have originated fi nancial capital. Hil- ferding also shows that capitalism was getting into a new stage in which merchant relations changed content once the price system and the com- mercial exchange were more and more under the hegemony of such fi nan- cial capital. Based upon monopoly, it imposed on the economy as a whole a logic characterized by price administration and by global investment deci- sions, where average profi t imposed itself over the interests of each branch or sector. Protectionism and colonial policy are two consequences of these changes occupying a relevant role in his analysis. So we see that his Marxist education conducts him to a global view and does not restrict him to the nations’ universe as a basis for theoretical refl ection. Rosa Luxemburg’s (1976) famous book of 1913, Capital Accumulation, also gives some thought to the issue of capitalist reproduction in the impe- rialist context. Marx, in the second volume of Capital could give the impres- sion of having restricted himself to a closed system at a national level when, thinking of the reproduction process, he departs from a scheme similar to Quesnay’s and establishes a national cycle where capital would reproduce itself within that national context. Rosa Luxemburg tries to show how this limitation to the national context is a diffi culty for the Marxist scheme. (We should not forget that Capital’s second volume is an unfi nished work and that Marx intended—in posterior volumes—to devote himself to fi ve big topics: income, wages, state, international trade and world economy, which were in his original program of political economy’s critiques, basis for Capi- tal. In Capital’s methodology, each new theoretical stage enrolls the previous analysis to a new level of abstraction which—in its turn—redefi nes all the concepts previously studied. We can assume, therefore, that the analytical level of international trade would redefi ne many concepts and laws found in the previous volumes.) Theotônio dos Santos465 World Economic System 466 Luxemburg examines the reproduction process in the face of techno- logical change which Marx himself analyzed, in the sense of an increasing organic composition of capital. She examines the reproduction process in face of pre-capitalist economies, thought of as colonial economies or econo- mies towards which the capitalist system expanded at a world level. She analyzes still the fundamental role of economies external to capital’s pure movement, such as military and State intervention expenditures, which also become explanatory elements of the real movement of capitalist reproduc- tion and accumulation. Rosa Luxemburg compels us to think capitalism as a world system in order to reach a right conception of its evolution and its theoretical movement. Lenin’s studies go in the same direction (1979). In his 1916 book Imperi- alism, Final Stage of Capitalism, he collects a contribution from Hilferding and Hobson (1983), in order to create his imperialism theory as capitalism’s new phase, beginning at late XIX century (he sometimes refers to the date of 1895). For him—as his book title suggests—the monopolist system, based upon fi nancial capital and capital exportation—Hobson’s typical problem- atic—would represent a superior stage of capitalism. Later, he re-dimen- sions the key elements of such new stage by introducing the issue of state intervention and the constitution of State monopolist capital. Such new phase would be characterized by monopoly, monopolist enterprise, capital movements and state action’s importance which would generate the new sort of contradictions between groups of States or state alliances at a world level and would give birth to capitalist system’s new phase, seen, thus, as a world system. This same view is shared by Bukharin (1979), Lenin’s pupil, and also by Trotsky (1971), who also views the Russian Revolution process of 1905 within a world system which—in constant transformation—results in a permanent revolution, that becomes one of the central issues of his political thought in the book with the same title published in 1930. (See Trotsky 1979). Bukharin represents an important moment in the elaboration of a world system’s theory by stressing the role of international division of labour within the State Nations for the constitution of a modern capitalist world economy. Such economy is actually based upon the contradiction between its international character and its national basis, mutually being the depen- dent. The more national economies are strengthened, the more their inter- national interests get stronger and the deeper their interdependence with these international economies become. It was the internationalist standpoint adopted by Marx, Hilferding, Hobson, Rosa Luxemburg, Kautsky, Lenin, Bukharin and Trotsky among others, that theoretically was the basis for the creation of the fi rst and the second Workers International, and that was on the basis of the creation of Lenin’s Third International, out of which 21 statements demanded affi lia- tion to a world party that had national sessions. Paradoxically, such supra- national conception of the Third International seemed to be inspired by the conception of ultra-imperialism Kautsky had developed in 1913. Accord- ing to this thesis—that Lenin and Bukharin fought with special empha- sis—capitalism would evolve to a unique world economy in which a unique monopoly would prevail bound to an unique State. Lenin and Bukharin’s efforts were in a sense to show that before such a unique economy could have been produced, the internal contradictions of capitalist accumulation would produce revolutions and confrontations on international and national scales. In a certain way Lenin and Bukharin analyzed the world not only of the inter-imperialists wars—as the First World War which they had seen— but also anticipated the Second World War and the great anti-colonial and national liberation struggles. By the way, in evolving the Third Internation- al’s infl uence became more effective exactly within the societies in which this national issue was imposed as essential. We can also quote the evolution of different Marxist schools of thought which—after the Russian revolution—spread out at an international level and insisted on treating imperialist phenomena as a contemporaneous world designing factor. Within the Leninist tradition the Communist Internation- al’s congresses preceded any analysis of national reality by a world juncture which would start to determine the global strategy and tactics at the inter- national level besides the national ones.1 Thus interpretative line gained 1. Maybe the fi rst attempt to produce a world juncture analysis took place at the League of the Nations soon after World War I. The Third International or Communist International’s congresses produced several studies on the world juncture. In the I Congress see Tesis sobre la Situación Internacional y la Política de la Entente, in the II Congress one ends up with a Manifesto on El Mundo Capitalista y la Internacional Comunista (Pasado y Presente 43-1a parte); the III Congress opens up with a Tesis sobre la Situación Mundial y la Tarea de la Internacional Comunista; the IV Congress shows—besides a resolution on the Theotônio dos Santos467 World Economic System 468 more substance with the creation of the World Economics Institute in the Soviet Union which had Eugênio Varga as its great leader. Two fundamen- tal theories for the understanding of the present ideological struggle had their birth in this institute: the theory of capitalism’s general crisis which would have begun in 1917—with the Russian Revolution—and the theory of monopolist state capitalism which anticipated the growth of the State as a necessary trend of the hegemony established by monopolist capital. The Trotskyist tradition—within the Fourth International—followed the same method of the great analysis of international juncture that pre- ceded the national scenarios analysis, thus creating a fractional contentious model of political programs and juncture reports that became famous among the world’s left-wing. The debate between the communist parties of the USSR and Yugoslavia were marked by this style in which the discussion on the trends of world economics had a fundamental place. Such confronta- tion assumed, since the start, on the side of the Yugoslavian party, an opposi- tion to Cold War, which led it to formulate a Third Way that ended up with Tito’s participation in the Bandung Conference and in the non-alignment doctrine’s formulation. The same happened to the confl ict between the Soviet Union and China that marked the 60’s and a big part of the 70’s. The Chinese critiques had already started in the late 50’s when the Chinese Communist Party attacked Yugoslavian revisionism manifested in the peaceful coexistence thesis that ended up by being adopted by the USSR’s Communist Party. Thereupon, critiques started to widen up to the extent of the theory on countryside seizing the cities, which at an international level had the design of agrarian countries seizing industrial ones. From this doctrine comes the thesis of alliance between North-American imperialism and Soviet search for hege- mony (the latter had even reached the extent of being considered the main enemy). Such pretentious theoretical formulations many times hid the more immediate interests and policies’ confl icts, provoking an analytical and polit- ical infl exibility extremely negative for the mental health of the militants who handled them. But the formulations of the international ideological struggle apparatus associated with intelligence, diplomatic or even academic schemes—not always more open or more successful—were not less sec- tarian and ambitious. Actually, international studies’ tradition started to become a requirement for the international organizations’ analysis since the creation of the League of the Nations. Once more, Marxist thought did not nothing else than anticipate themes and viewpoints which would later gen- eralize to the remaining theoretical or doctrinal studies. Within the Marxist tradition, there is, however, a theoretical scenario more differentiated. Rosa Luxemburg’s followers insisted on the world prob- lematic. Amongst them we should stress the work of Fritz Sternberg (1926), whose analysis of imperialism followed rigorously the thesis of under-con- sumption, whose origin would be found in the work of Rosa Luxemburg. He put—in his written books after the Second World War—a special emphasis on military expenditure, a thesis that maintains his link to his Luxemburgist past, already quite forgotten at that time. Grossmann (1927-1979) puts more emphasis on the accumulation and reproduction processes, as well as Moskowska (1943-1981), Paul Sweezy (1938) and Paul Baran (1957) who followed—in great part—this under-consumption tradition, without dis- missing, however, the role of international trade. But many times they tried Versailles Treaty and the thesis on the East—a resolution on a International Communist tactics that makes up a chapter about capitalism decaying period, the international political situation, capital’s advance, international fascism and the possibility of new pacifi st illusions (Pasado y Presente, n. 47, 2nd part). The V Congress considered a report Sobre la Situación Económica Mundial besides the traditional chapter on the international situation which opens up the resolutions about communist tactics (Pasado y Presente, n.55 and 56). The VI Congress already acquires a shape that becomes classic in Tese Sobre a Situação e as Tarefas da Internacional Comunista starting with a chapter on world economics and its technique, following it with the thesis on the struggle against the imperialist war and then, the thesis on the revolutionary movement and the colonies and semi-colonies that consolidate III International’s relationship with the colonial countries, were presented (Pasado y Presente, n.66). The reports of the congress show Bukarin’s work on The International Situation and the Communist International Tasks (Pasado y Presente, n.67). René Dreiffus (1987) describes with much detail research institution formation and public policies formulation in the international entrepreneurial fi eld which, by chance, start at the same time as the Communist International, May 1919, with the Round Table Groups which give birth to the Council of Foreign Relations, under the incontestable leadership of Morgan Group which moves itself “in the past thirty years to the Rockfeller group.” See also the organized data in the book by Hugo Assman and others (1998). Theotônio dos Santos469 World Economic System 470 to analyze them departing from a micro-economic context, in which the monopolist enterprise functioning gains a central position. This theoretical tradition did not stop being a necessary precedent for the contemporane- ous analysis of transnational enterprises, which followed, in great part, the advances produced by these authors, by linking the micro-economic to big capital movements in the international arena. In post-war France, very peculiar Marxist tendencies turned up. They were developed within an intellectual environment marked by rationalism’s traditional presence, but carrying a very strong new existentialist element. We can distinguish a group that—in spite of cultivating a viewpoint pre- dominantly geared to the sociology of technology and labour—extrapo- lates their analysis to the world economic level, under the infl uence of their Marxist theoretical origins. Georges Friedmann and Pierre Naville were to fi nd themselves amongst their best representatives. On the other hand, mag- azines such as Argument or Socialisme ou Barbarie give birth to a whole plan- etary philosophical viewpoint very infl uenced by changes in the media and by the analysis of a new popular culture. These sectors were identifi ed many times as a sort of special detachment from Trotskyism but are actually clas- sifi ed under Luxemburg’s infl uences. There are also some authors who have been under the infl uence of the Yugoslavian experience—in a band close to a sociological thought which tried to combine Marx, Weber and Durkheim—and that followed its own line of historical interpretation. It is in this universe where we can situate Georges Gurvitch and the big sociologists, anthropologists and economists group that were around him, in the “Revue Française de Sociologie,” seeking a global viewpoint, capable of establishing at the same time a typology of the possible societies in the industrial phase. In the more specifi c fi eld of economics, François Perroux deserves an outstanding position. He is the one to recover a view of a world economy that served as basis for a modern economic thought. He did not restrict him- self only to the macro-economic plan but also sought to fi nd the peculiari- ties of the modern macro-economic level when in those post-war decades the differentiation idea between the micro and the macro started to become widespread. Economic theory starts to penetrate sociological theory under the infl uence of Physics evolution to the atomic and nuclear level, creating a micro level that Henri Mendras seeks to reproduce by trying to create a micro-economic and micro-sociological analysis space. Such evolution is very rich in what it is going to leave as theoretical advance. Undoubtedly, it is in this fi eld that Fernand Braudel develops his work. He reached notoriety in the 60’s and 70’s as one of the main theoreti- cians of the world economic system with his book Material Civilization: Eco- nomics and Capitalism. That tradition, however, can be seen as independent from Marxism, sometimes even critical of Marxism, but very much built in the debate with it, in relation with it and with its distinct ways: a critique of Stalinism, Trotskyism, Luxemburgism, etc. and a critique of Marxism as a whole. This scenario reaffi rms the idea that it’s necessary to build a model for theoretical analysis of economic, sociological and political realities, in which world economics phenomena are present and is truly a dialectical precedent of the idea of national economies. bibliography Abel, Christopher, Colin M. (1985). Latin America, Economic Imperialism and the State: The Political Economy of External Connection From Independence to Present. Anderson, J. L. (1991). Explaining Long-Term Economic Change. Houndmills: Macmillan Education Ltd. Andreff, W. (1987). Les Multinationales. Paris: La Découverte. Amim, Samir (1974). Accumulation on a World Scale: A Critique of the Theory of Underdevelopment. New York: Monthly Review Press. Amim, Samir (1991). L’Empire du Chaos—La Nouvelle Mondialisation du Capitalisme, L’Harmattan, Paris. Apter, David E. (1990). Rethinking Development Modernization, Dependency and Post- Modern Politics. London: Sage Publications. Assman, Hugo and others (1978)., A Trilateral: Nova Fase do Capitalismo Mundial, Petrópolis. Vozes. Auvers, Denis (1987). L’Economie Mondiale. Paris: Éditions La Découverte. Bambirra, Vania (1978). Teoria de la Dependencia: una Anticrítica. Mexico: Serie Popular Era. Banco Mundial (1993). Relatório sobre o Desenvolvimento Mundial—Indicadores do Desenvolvimento Mundial. Rio de Janeiro. Fundação Getúlio Vargas. Barraclough, Geoffrey (1973). An Introduction to Contemporary History. Harmondsworth: 5th Ed. Penguin Books. Beaud, Michel (1981). Histoire du Capitalisme de 1500 à nos Jours. Paris: Éditions du Seuil. Beaud, Michel (1987). Le Système National/ Mondial Hierarquisé—Une Nouvelle Lecture du Capitalisme Mondial. Paris: Éditions La Découverte. Beaud, Michel (1990). Sur la Connaissance de l’Économie Mondiale. Paris: Mimeo. Blomstrom, Magnus an Hettne, Bjorn (1984). Development Theory in Transition, The Dependency Debate and Beyond: Third World Responses. London: Zed Books. Theotônio dos Santos471 World Economic System 472 Bodenheimer, Suzanne (1970). “Dependency and Imperialism,” Politics and Society, n. 5. Brand, Willy and Manley, Michael (1985). Global Challenge, from Crisis to Cooperation: Breaking the North-South Stalemate. Report of the Socialist International Committee on Economic Policy, London and Sidney: Pan Books. Braudel, Fernand (1979a). Les Structures du Quotidien; Civilization Matérielle, Economie et Capitalisme XV-XVIII Siècle. Tome 1, Paris: Armand Colin. Braudel, Fernand (1979b). Les Jeux de L’Echange ; Civilization Matérielle, Economie et Capitalisme XV-XVIII. Tome 2, Paris: Armand Colin. Braudel, Fernand (1979c). Les Temps du Monde; Civilization Matérielle, Économie et Capitalisme XV-XVIII. Tome 3, Paris: Armand Colin. Braudel, Fernand (1983). O Mediterrâneo e o Mundo Mediterrânico. 2 vols., Portugal: Martins Fontes. Braudel, Fernand (1984). O Mediterrâneo e o Mundo Mediterrânico. Vol. 1, Portugal; Martins Fontes. Braudel, Fernand (1985). La Mediterranée—L’Espace et Histoire. France: Flammarion. Braudel, Fernand (1987a). A Dinâmica do Capitalismo. Rio de Janeiro, Rocco. Braudel, Fernand (1987b). Grammaire des Civilizations. Paris: Editions Arthaud- Flammarion. Brunet, Roger and Dollfus, Olivier (1990). “Mondes Nouveaux,” in Géographie Universelle. Paris: Hachette/Reclus. Bukharin,Nicolai (1969). O Imperialismo e a Economia Mundial. Rio, Laemmert. Camacho,Daniel (Ed.) (1979). Debates Sobre la Teoría de la Dependencia y la Sociologia Latinoamericana. San José:Educa. Cardoso, Fernando Henrique (1973). “Imperialism and Dependency in Latin America” in F. Bonilla and R. Gilling (Eds.) Structures of Dependency. Stanford: Institute of Political Studies. Castro, Fidel (1983). The World Economic and Social Crisis. Delhi: People Publishing House. Club of Rome (1972). The Limits to Growth. New York: Universe Books. Chaliand, Gérard and Rageau, Jean Pierre (1988). Atlas Stratégique: Géopolitique des Rapports de Force dans le Monde. France: Editions Complexe. Chilcote, Ronald H. (1974). “A Critical Synthesis of the Dependency Literature,” Latin American Perspectives. I, Spring. Chilcote, Ronald (1984). Theories of Development and Underdevelopment. Boulder: Westiew Press. Cox, Robert W. (1987). Production, Power and World Order: Social Forces in the Making of History. New York: Columbia University Press. Cueva, Augustín, Problemas y Perspectivas de la Teoría de la Dependencia. Mexico: CELA/ UNAM: Siglo XXI, dateless. Cueva, Augustín (1978). El Desarrollo del Capitalismo en America Latina. Mexico: Siglo XXI. Dadayan, Vladislav (1988). The Orbits of the Global Economy. Moscow: Progress Publishers. Davydov, Vladimir (1984). Nueva Ronda de Debates Acerca de la Dependencia. Moscow: América Latina, n.11. Davydov, Vladimir (1985). Que es la Teoria de la Dependencia?. part 1, Moscow: America Latina, n.12. Davydov, Vladimir (1986). Que es la Teoria de la Dependencia?. part 2, Moscow: America Latina, n.3 Dollfus, Olivier (dateless). “Le Système Monde,” L’Information Géographique, n.54, p.p. 45-52. Dos Santos, Theotônio (1970). La Crisis Norte-Americana y America Latina. Santiago: Ed. Pla. Dos Santos, Theotônio (1973). Imperialismo y Corporaciones Multinacionales. Santiago: Ed.Pla. Dos Santos, Theotônio (1978-A). Imperialismo y Dependencia. Mexico: Ed. Era. Dos Santos, Theotônio (1978-B). The Multinational Corporations: Cells of Contemporary Capitalism. Toronto: Laru Studies, n.6. Dos Santos, Theotônio (1993). Quelques Idées sur le Système Monde. Paris: Cahier du Gemdev, n.20 (Points de Vue sur le Système Monde). Dreifuss, René (1987). A Internacional Capitalista: Estratégias e Táticas do Empresariado Transnacional: 1918 a 1986. Rio de Janeiro: Espaço e Tempo. Chase-Dunn, Chis (1975). “The Effects of International Economic Dependence,” Comparative Politics, n. 7, April. Ellul, Jacques (1956). Histoire des Institutions. Tome Second, Paris: Presses Universitaires de France. Fieldhouse, David K. (1978). Economia e Império—La Expansión de Europa 1830-1914. Mexico: Siglo Veintiuno Editores. FMI (1980- ). World Economic Outlook. Fortune (1993). The Fortune Global:The Largest Industrial Corporations in The World. New York: July, 26. Fossaert, Robert (1991). Le Monde au XXI Siècle. France: Fayard. Frank, Andre Gunder Frank (1978-A). World Accumulation 1492-1789. Monthly Review. Frank, Andre Gunder (1978-B). Dependent Accumulation and Underdevelopment. New York: Monthly Review. Frank, Andre Gunder (1980). Crisis in the World Economy. New York: Holmes and Meier. Frank, Andre Gunder (1986). Ironias en una Introducción a la Economia Política Mundial Contradicciones en el Desarrollo Histórico Y Cíclico de un Sistema Mundial Único. Barranquilla: Desarrollo Indoamericano. Frank, Andre Gunder (1987). Prefacio a El Desafi o de la Crisis—Ensayos sobre la Crisis Economica Mundial. Ironias Políticas Internacionales y Desafi o Europeo. Amsterdam. Frank, Andre Gunder (1990). “A Theoretical Introduction to 5000 Years of World System History,” Review. Vol. XIII, n.2, Spring. Frank, Andre Gunder (1991a). Algunos Altibajos en la Ruta de la Seda. Mexico: El Gallo Ilustrado, 1489, Domingo 6 de Enero. Frank, Andre Gunder (1991b). Economic Ironies in World Politics—A Sequel to Political Ironies in the World Economy . Amsterdam. Theotônio dos Santos473 World Economic System 474 Frank, Andre Gunder (1991c). Review of Bernard Nossiter’s—Fat Years and Lean: The American Economy since Roosevelt. Amsterdam. Frank, Andre Gunder (1991d). Third World War: A Political Economy of the Gulf War and New World Order. Amsterdam: University of Amsterdam. Frank, Andre Gunder and Gills, Barry K. (1990). “The Cumulation of Accumulation: Theses and Research Agenda for 5000 years of World System History,” Dialectical Anthropology, n. 15: 19-42. Frank, Andre Gunder and Gills, Barry K. (1991). “World System Cycles, Crisis and Hegemonic Transitions,” Vancouver. Paper prepared for the annual meeting of the International Studies Association, 19-23 March. Frobel, F., Heirichs, J., Kreye, O. (1981). La Nueva División Internacional del Trabajo: Paro Estructural en los Países Industrializados y Industrialización de los Países en Desarrollo. Mexico: Siglo XXI Editores. Fukuyama, Francis (1992). The End of History and the Last Man. Girvan, Norman (1973). “The Development of Dependency Economics in the Caribbean and Latin America: Review and Comparison,” Social and Economic Studies, n.22, March. Godinho, Vitorio Magalhães (1981). Os Descobrimentos e a Economia Mundial, Volume I. Lisbon: 2nd Edition, Editorial Presença. Grou, Pierre (1990). “Atlas Mondial des Multinationales et L’Éspace des Multinationales,” Paris: Réclus- La Documentation Française. Hobson, J.A. (1983). A Evolução do Capitalismo Moderno. São Paulo: Abril Cultural Hettne, Bjorn (1990). Development Theory and the Three Worlds. London: Longman. Heilbroner, Robert L. (1975). An Inquiry Into the Human Prospect. New York: W.W. Norton and Company. Herrera, Amilcar and Alli (1976). Catastrophe or New Society? A Latin American World Model. Ottawa: IDRC. Herrera, Amilcar and Alli (1991). Las Nuevas Tecnologias y el Futuro de America Latina. Campinas; Unicamp. Hilferding, Rudolf (1981). El capital Financiero. Madrid, Tecnos. IMEMO (1978). Developing Countries: Regularities, Tendencies and Perspectives. Moscow. Jaffe, Hosea (1980). The Pyramid of Nations. Milan: Victor. Johnson, Douglas (Ed.) (1971). The Making of the Modern World, Vol.1. London: Ernest Been Limited. Johnson, Douglas (Ed.) (1973). The World of Empires. London: Ernest Been Limited. Kahl, Joseph A. (1976). Modernization, Exploitation and Dependency in Latin America. New Jersey: New Brunswick. Kauffman, Robert and Alli (1975). “A Preliminary Test of the Theory of Dependency,” Comparative Politics, n.7, April. Kawaguchi, Kiyofumi (1991). “Growth of the Service Sector in Japan,” Kyoto:Ritsumeikan Social Sciences Review, Vol. XXVII, n.2, September. Klamer, Arjo (1988). Conversas com Economistas: Os Novos Economistas Clássicos e seus Opositores Falam sobre a Atual Controvérsia em Macroeconomia. São Paulo; Pioneira. Lall, Sanjaya (1975). “Is Dependence a Useful Concept in Analyzing Underdevelopment?” World Development, n.3, November. Lenin, V., (1979). O Imperialismo, Fase Superior do Capitalismo (popular essay). Obras Escolhidas, vol. 1, São Paulo, Alfa-Ômega. Leontieff, W. (1977). The Future of World Economy. New York: United Nations. Luxemburgo, Rosa (1976). A Acumulação de Capital. Rio, Zahar. Maidánik, Kiva (1982). El Proceso Revolucionário de América Latina Visto desde la URSS. Santo Domingo; Editora Taller. Marini, Ruy Mauro (1973). Dialética de la Dependencia, Mexico: Ediciones Era. Martz, John (1971). Political Science and Latin American Studies: A Discipline in Search of a Region, Latin American Research Review, VI Spring. Meier, Gerald M. International Trade and Development, Harper International Student Reprints, dateless. Michalet, C. A. (1976). Le Capitalisme Mondial, Paris: P.U.F. Michalet, C. A. (1985). Le Capitalisme Mondial. Paris: P.U.F., 2nd Edition. Moreira, Marcílio Marques (1980). Poder, Liberdade, Desnvolvimento: Indicações para o Debate Brasileiro. Rio de Janeiro: Tempo Brasileiro. Muñoz, Heraldo (1979). “El Analisis de la Teoria de la Dependencia en los Centros: Ejemplos de E.E.U.U.” Estudios Internacionales, Vol.12,n.45, January-March, p.p. 68-76. Muñoz, Heraldo (1982). From Dependency to Development Strategies to Overcome Underdevelopment and Inequality. Westview Press; Boulder. Nishikawa, Jun (1988). “Les Investissements Exterieur Directs: Approches Théoriques et Multinalisation des Firmes Japonaises,” Waseda Economic Papers, n.27, Tokyo: p.p.41-63. O’Brien, Philip (1975). “A Critique of Latin American Theories of Dependence,” in Oxgal and Alli, Beyond the Sociology of Development, London. OECD (1961). Economic Outlook OECD (1979). Interfutures, Paris Okita, Saburo (1988). De Aquí para Allá–Autobiografi a. Buenos Aires; Edeuba. Oman, Charlesand Ganeshan, Wignajara (1991). The Postwar Evolution of Development Thinking. Paris; OECD. Peet, Richard (1991). Global Capitalism: Theories of Societal Development. New York: Routledge. Perroux, François (1960). La Coexistencia Pacífi ca. Mexico: Fondo de Cultura Economica. Petitot, Jean and Alli (1985). “Local/Global,” in Eciclopédia Einaudi, Volume 4, Porto: Imprensa Nacional/Casa da Moeda. Portantiero, Juan Carlos “Latin American Marxism,” in History of Marxism, Hobsbawn, Eric J. (Coord.), dateless. Prebisch, Raul (1981). Capitalismo Periférico, Crisis y Transformación, Mexico: Fondode Cultura Economica. Relatório da Comissão Sul (1990). Desafi o ao Sul, Ed. Afrontamento. Theotônio dos Santos475 World Economic System 476 Rodriguez, Gustavo O. (1979). De la Cepal a la Teoria de la Dependencia: Un Esquema Descriptivo. Cochabamba, IESE. Rodriguez, Octavio (1974). Informe sobre las Críticas a la Concepción de la Cepal. Mexico, Secretaria de la Presidencia. Rossi, Paolo (1992). Os Sinais do Tempo: História da Terra e História das Nações de Hooke à Vico. São Paulo; Companhia das Letras. Schumpeter, J. A. (1908). The Nature and Essence of Theoretical Economics. Schumpeter, J. A. (1911). The Theory of Economic Development. Schumpeter, J. A. (1939). Business Cycles. Schumpeter, J. A. (1942). Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. Schumpeter, J. A. (1954). History of Economic Analysis. Schumpeter, J. A. (1991). The Economics and Sociology of Capitalism, Edited by Richard Swedberg, Princeton University Press, Princeton. Semo, Enrique (1975). La Crisis Actual del Capitalismo. Mexico, Ed. de Cultura Popular. Smith, Alan K. (1991). Creating a World Economy, Merchant Capital, Colonialism and World Trade: 1400-1825. Boulder: Westwiew Press. Sonntag, Heintz R. (1989). Duda/Certeza/Crisis. La Evolución de las Ciencias Sociales de América Latina. Caracas: Editorial Nueva Sociedad. So, Alvin (1990). Social Change and Development Modernization: Dependency and World System Theories. London: Sage. Sunkel, O. (1973). “Transnational Capitalism and National Disintegration in Latin America,” Social and Economics Studies. University of West Indies, 22-1. Szentes, Tamás (1988). The Transformation of the World Economy: New Directions and New Interests. London: Zed Books. The Dag Hammarskjold Report to the United Nations (1979). “What Now?” Development Dialogue, 1-2. The Economist (1993). “A Survey of Multinationals,” The Economist. London:March 27th. Timberger, Jean (Coord.). (1976). “Reshaping the International Order,” Report to the Club of Rome. New York. Toynbee, Arnold (1987). Um Estudo da História. Brasília: Editora Universidade de Brasília e Livraria Martins Fontes Ltda. Transnational Corporations and Management Division (1982). Transnational Corporations as Engine of Growth. New York: United Nations. Trotsky, Lev Davidoditch, (1971). 1905. London: Penguin Books. Trotsky, Lev Davidovitch, (1977). A Revolução Permanente. São Paulo, LECH. Umesao, Tadao (1983). Le Japon à l’Ère Planétaire. France: Publications Orientalistes de France. Umesao, Tadao (1984). Keynote Address: Japanese Civilization in the Modern World. Osaka: Senri Ethnological Studies, n.16, National Museum of Ethnology. Umesao, Tadao (1986). Keynote Address: The Methodology of the Comparative Study of Civilization. Osaka Senri Ethnological, n. 19, National Museum of Ethnology. Umesao, Tadao (1989-A). Keynote Address: The Methodology of the Comparative Study of Civilization, Osaka: Senri Ethnological, n. 19, National Museum of Ethnology. Umesao, Tadao (1989-A). Keynote Address: The Methodology of the Comparative Study of Civilization, Osaka: Senri Ethnological Studies, n. 26, National Museum of Ethnology. Umesao, Tadao (1989-B). The Study of Civilization and the Study of Japan, Osaka: Senri Ethnological Studies, n. 25, National Museum of Ethnology. Umesao, Tadao (1990-A). Keynote Address: Tradition of Culturedness in Modern Japan, Osaka: Senri Ethnological Studies, n. 28, National Museum of Ethnology. Umesao, Tadao (1990-B). Keynote modernization and religion, Osaka Senri Ethmological Studies, n.29, National Museum of Ethnology. UNDP (1991- ). Human Development Report. New York: United Nations Publications. United Nations Center on Transnational Corporations (1983). Transnational Corporations in World Development: Third Survey, New York: United Nations. United Nations Center on Transnational Corporations (1988). Transnational Corporations in World Development Trends and Prospects, New York: United Nations. Ure, John (1977). Dom Henrique: O Navegador. Brasília: Editora Universidade de Brasília. U.S.A. (1980). The Global 2000 to the President of the U.S.A., Washington, D. C. Government Printing Offi ce. Vergopoulos, Kostas (1990). Mondialisation et Dispersion. Paris: Université de Paris VIII, Mimeo. Vilar, Pierre (1974). Or et Monnaie dans l’Histoire. Paris: Flammarion. Wallerstein, Immanuel (1974). The Modern World System, Vol. I. New York: Academic Press. Wallerstein, Immanuel (1979). The Capitalist World Economy. Paris: Maison des Sciences de L’Homme. Wallerstein, Immanuel (1980). “Marx and History: Fruitful and Unfruitful Emphases,” Thesis Eleven, n. 8, January. Wallerstein, Immanuel (1984). The Modern World-System as a Civilization. Fernand Braudel Center, State University of New York at Binghamton. Wallerstein, Immanuel (1984). The Politics of the World Economy. Paris. Wallerstein, Immanuel (1985). “Le Capitalisme, Ennemi du Marché? Réfl exions sur la Thèse de Braudel,” Fernand Braudel Center, State University of New York at Binghamton. Wallerstein, Immanuel (1987). Le Capitalisme Historique. Paris: Editions La Découverte. Wallerstein, Immanuel (1989). The Modern World System III. New York: Academic. Wallerstein, Immanuel (1990). “The Cold War and the Third World: The Good Old Days?” Paper Presented at Workshop on The Cold War and the Third World: Past and Present Sponsored by SSRC- CASPIC and the Center for Latin American Studies, University of Chicago. Wallerstein, Immanuel (1991). “Who Excludes Whom? Or The Collapse of Liberalism and Dilemas of the Antisistemic Strategy,” Paper prepared for the Rencontre International de Delphes. Wallerstein, Immanuel (1993). “Foes and Friends?” Washington Foreign Policy, n.90, Spring. Wallerstein, Immanuel (dateless).“Periphery,” Fernand Braudel Center, State University of New York at Binghamton. Theotônio dos Santos477 Weber, Max (1955). La Etica Protestante y el Espírito del Capitalismo. Madrid: Editorial Revista de Derecho Privado. Weber, Max (1959). Le Savant et le Politique. Paris: Librairie Plon. Weber, Max (1977). Economia y Sociedad. Mexico: 3rd Reprinting of the Second Spanish Edition, Fondo de Cultura Economica. Willy Brand Commission Report (1980). North-South. A Programme for Survival. London and Sidney: Pan Books. Willy Brand Commission Report (1983). Common Crisis North-South: Cooperation for World Recovery. London and Sidney. Wolfgang, J. Mommsen (1975). La Época del Imperialismo: Europa 1885-1918. Madrid: Siglo XXI. World Bank (1978-1994). World Development Report. World Bank. World Development Indicators. dateless.