Journal of World-Systems Research, IX:1, Winter 2003 37 Spatial Synchrony Among and Within World- Systems: Insights From Theoretical Ecology* Peter Turchin Th omas D. Hall Peter Turchin Department of Ecology and Evolutionary Biology 75 N. Eagleville Rd University of Connecticut Storrs, CT 06269-3043 turchin@uconnvm.uconn.edu http://www.eeb.uconn.edu/faculty/turchin/turchin.htm Th omas D. Hall Department of Sociology & Anthropology DePauw University Greencastle, IN 46135 thall@depauw.edu http://acad.depauw.edu/~thall/hp1.htm journal of world-systems research, ix, 1, winter 2003, 37–64 http://jwsr.ucr.edu issn 1076–156x © 2003 Peter Turchin & Th omas D. Hall I N T RODUC TION Political processes within world-systems are often characterized by cycles or waves. Chiefdoms cycle (Anderson 1994, 1996), empires rise and fall, and the modern state system undergoes “power cycle” or “hegemonic sequence.” Furthermore, all world-systems “pulsate”—expand rapidly, then more slowly, or even contract (Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997, 2000). Because spatial waves of expansion/contraction occur across all types of world-systems, such pulsations cannot be rooted in a specifi c mode of production or mode of accumulation. Rather, these cycles are themselves evidence that polities and world systems are dynamical systems with various feedback loops. Afroeurasia (in conventional terms Asia, Europe, northern Africa) has been linked, at least at the information and luxury goods exchange levels (Chase- Dunn and Hall 1997), for two and a half millennia or more. Th us, events and processes in Europe cannot be explained solely by examining European pro- cesses, a conclusion strongly supported by Pomeranz (2000). On the other hand, the degree of Afroeurasia-wide linkage fl uctuated, so that world-systems at opposite ends of Afroeurasia were nearly isolated for long periods of time. One interesting puzzle is why there is a substantial linking of rise/fall processes at the western and eastern ends of Afroeurasia during the last two millennia (Teggart * We would like to thank the two anonymous reviewers for cogent suggestions. Th eir com- ments improved the clarity of our argument. We also thank Eric Titolo for his help in formatting Figure 1. We retain responsibility for remaining errors.Th is paper reports on research in population ecology and suggests ways it might be useful in explaining spatial dynamics of states, groups, and world-systems. In particular it focuses on how and why populations at opposite of ends of Afroeurasia come to rise and fall simultaneously over long periods of time. We call for exploration of research in population ecology for understanding world- system evolution and suggest directions for possible future research. abstract mailto:turchin@uconnvm.uconn.edu http://www.eeb.uconn.edu/faculty/turchin/turchin.htm mailto:thall@depauw.edu http://acad.depauw.edu/~thall/hp1.htm http://jwsr.ucr.edu/ Peter Turchin & Th omas D. Hall38 Spatial Synchrony Among and Within World-Systems 39 1939; Frank and Gills 1993; Frank 1992, 1993; Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997, 2000; Denemark et al. 2000). For example, increases and decreases in the territorial sizes of empires and the population size of cities correlate between East Asia and West Asia/Mediterranean (e.g., Chase-Dunn, Manning, and Hall 2000). Yet, there appears to be little linkage to cyclical processes in South Asia (Chase- Dunn, Manning, and Hall 2000). Interestingly, archaeologists have noted seem- ing parallels in rise and fall of ancient cultures in what is now southeastern and southwestern United States (Neitzel 1999). Th ere has been much speculation about what processes drive various cycles within world-systems, what mechanisms may lead to (partial) synchrony between some world-systems separated by great distances, and why there is little or no synchrony between others (Denemark et al. 2000; Frank 1993; Grimes 2000). Th e current state of the fi eld bears a striking similarity to the debates that occurred among population ecologists a few decades ago. Ecologists also found that many population systems go through regular oscillations, and that these population cycles are synchronized across distances of hundreds, and sometimes thousands of kilometers. We argue in this paper that there is much to be learned from what ecologists have found from their studies, analyses, and models of oscillatory population systems. While ecological models and analytical approaches cannot be imported wholesale, or without adjustment, into world- system problems, they do off er a number of useful insights, and suggestions for future research. Many ecological studies are highly analytical, and current standards of scien- tifi c rigor in the discipline (especially in the study of population oscillations and spatial synchrony) require translation of verbal hypotheses into mathematical equations. Th e benefi ts of this approach are the ability to subject predictions from rival hypotheses to rigorous quantitative tests. However, model construc- tion requires making simplifying assumptions. Surprisingly, however, the resul- tant models are often quite robust with respect to these initial assumptions. Th at is, “fi rst-cut” models can be investigated mathematically as to the consequences of relaxing the initial assumptions for theoretical predictions. Repeated applica- tions of this process can extend theory and simultaneously increase confi dence in the answers that it provides. Th e conditions under which population cycles become synchronized have been a focus of an intense theoretical (and empiri- cal) investigation over the last several decades, leading to a fairly mature state of understanding of synchrony. A key insight from ecological theory is that the processes driving oscillations (the rise/fall dynamics) and the processes causing large-scale synchrony need not be the same. In fact, current empirical research shows that in ecological systems they are typically distinct. Ecological models show that if two (or more) sys- tems separated in space are driven by largely endogenous dynamics, and if their endogenous dynamics are broadly similar (e.g., have approximately the same period), then their cycles may be synchronized by a variety of shared exogenous perturbations, and these perturbations need not be very strong. Th e process of bringing spatially distant oscillations into phase by weak exogenous infl uences is sometimes called “entraining” or “phase-locking.” Th is insight, in particular, is suggestive for possible explanations for the synchrony of population and city- size changes in east and west Asia. Our goal in this paper is to review recent developments in ecological theory of spatial synchrony, and discuss its possible applications in world-system research. Because the nature of endogenous processes underlying systemic oscil- lations is a key ingredient in the explanation of large-scale synchrony, we begin by reviewing cyclical processes aff ecting the dynamics of polities and world-sys- tems. Second, we review the theoretical results from ecological models. Th ird, we discuss some broad patterns in the Afroeurasian history from the point of view of the theory we present here. Fourth, we conclude that this preliminary examination is suffi ciently promising to warrant further theoretical and empiri- cal investigation of this extension of ecological theory to world-systems prob- lems. Finally, we discuss directions for future research suggested by the theory, and, in particular, how some of these hypotheses might be tested with data. C YC LIC PRO C E S SE S I N WOR LD SYST E MS For the most part world-system analysts have focused on two cyclical processes: the Kondratieff wave (K-wave) and the hegemonic cycle. K-waves are shown by approximately 50–year cycles in prices. Th e upswing is called the A-phase, the downswing the B-phase. K-waves are notoriously diffi cult to date precisely because they must be measured indirectly via trade volume and prices (Barr 1979; Boswell and Misra 1995; Goldstein 1988; Grimes 2000). Th e basic dynamic is that a new technology allows economic expansion. Eventually the market saturates, and competition increases, and the expansion slows until another cycle, based on yet another new or renewed technology develops. Kondratieff waves have been discussed primarily in the context of the modern capitalist world economy. However, several authors (Modelski and Th ompson 1996, 2000) have traced K-waves back into the 12th century. Hegemony, in a non-Gramscian sense, is a condition in which one state in a core region dominates a world-system through economic and political power, typically without overt coercion. Once its power peaks, hegemony is lost, or at least declines, and the core is marked by much more intense inter-state rivalry and competition. Hegemonic cycles are about a century long, and may be related to K-waves in complex ways that are currently debated (Th ompson 2000). Peter Turchin & Th omas D. Hall40 Spatial Synchrony Among and Within World-Systems 41 sociopolitical instability suggests that agrarian societies should go through cycles of alternating phases of political centralization/population growth and political decentralization/population decline. A typical period of such “secular cycles” is two to three centuries (although the theory predicts that in societies character- ized by widespread elite polygyny, the cycle period should be shorter, around one century—these are “Ibn Khaldun” cycles, which we will discuss in later section). A recent survey by Turchin and Nefedov (2004) suggests that secular cycles are a ubiquitous feature of Afroeurasian history during the last 3–4 millennia. Eff ects of hegemonic cycles and secular waves ripple through world-systems and, perhaps, beyond. Sociopolitical cycles give rise to cycles of colonization and decolonization, war and peace, state-formation and state collapse, and a variety of social and cultural movements. Th ese cycles do not necessarily determine or cause these processes. Rather, they may create structural conditions that facili- tate, or retard, their course (see Grimes 2000; Boswell 1989; Boswell and Sweat 1991; Boswell and Chase-Dunn 2000:Ch. 2). Arrighi and Silver (1999; Arrighi 1999) argue that globalization also has spread in waves, corresponding to cycles of hegemony. A key part of their argu- ment is that state capacity to govern is never entirely stable but waxes and wanes with world-systemic cycles. Waves of globalization are yet another example of how these cycles shape social processes. Chase-Dunn et al. (2000) document waves of globalization in the late 19th and late 20th centuries. We also note that a world-system typically has multiple kinds of boundar- ies, and except for small systems, islands, and the 20th century world-system, these boundaries do not coincide—they are nested within each other. Th ere are at least four diff erent types of boundaries (Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997). At the smallest scale are the bounds of bulk goods trade, the bulk goods network (BGN). Next in size are the bounds of regular political-military interaction, the political-military network (PMN). Th en there are two much larger, but typi- cally diff erent boundaries. Often the slightly smaller of the two is the luxury or prestige good net (PGN), and the typically somewhat larger, information or cul- tural net (IN). All four boundaries can be fuzzy. If one thinks of a topographic map of each of these features, the “boundary” would be zone of a sharp drop off , what would look like a cliff or very steep slope. Synchronization can occur at any of these four levels. However, each level would have its own mechanisms and dynamics. Th ese diff erences between networks and corresponding boundaries, of course, are more salient in ancient world-systems than they are in the contem- porary world-system. Clearly, there are many potential levels of synchrony among the various world-system cycles. As noted in the introduction, several have been docu- mented empirically (e.g., Chase-Dunn, Manning, Hall 2000). Other than the “Secular cycles,” periodic waves of state breakdown accompanied by oscilla- tions in population numbers, are a third type of cycle (Goldstone 1991; Fischer 1996; Nefedov 2001; Turchin 2003). Secular waves arise as a prediction from demographic-structural theory, which focuses on the dynamic interaction between population numbers and sociopolitical stability. Jack Goldstone (1991) analyzed the eff ect of population growth on state breakdown. Briefl y, population growth in excess of the productivity gains from the land leads to persistent infl a- tion and rising real costs, which outstrips the ability of the state to increase tax revenues. Rapid expansion of population also results in an increased number of aspirants for elite positions, putting further fi scal strains on the state, and inten- sifying intra-elite competition and factionalism. Increased rural misery, urban migration, and falling real wages lead to frequent food riots and wage protests; expansion of youth cohorts contributes to the population mobilization potential; and elite competition and popular discontent fuel ideological confl icts. As all these trends intensify, the end result is state bankruptcy and consequent loss of military control, elite movements of regional and national rebellion, and a com- bination of elite-mobilized and popular uprisings that manifest the breakdown of central authority (Goldstone 1991:25). State breakdown and resulting sociopolitical instability cause a population decline, both through their eff ects on demographic rates, and by damaging a society’s productive capacity (Turchin 2003). First, political instability causes lower reproduction rates, because during uncertain times people choose to marry later and to have fewer children. Also, family limitation practices may be disguised as increased child mortality. Second, mortality rates rise as a result of increased crime, banditry, and internal and external warfare. Migration from war– or famine–aff ected areas leads to increased emigration, declining birth rates (because people on the move cannot aff ord to have children), and epidem- ics. Increased vagrancy, movements of armies, and movements of rebels spread disease by connecting areas that would stay isolated during better times. Political stability or instability can also aff ect the “carrying capacity.” Strong states sup- port the agricultural productivity by constructing irrigation canals and roads, by implementing fl ood control measures, by clearing land from forests, etc., thus increasing the numbers of people that can be gainfully employed growing food. Additionally, a strong state off ers protection. In an anarchic society people can live only in natural strongholds, or places that can be made defensible. Fear of attack can lead farmers to cultivate only that proportion of productive area that is near fortifi ed settlements. A strong state protects the productive population from external and internal (banditry, civil war) threats, and thus allows nearly all cultivable area to be put into production. Mathematical modeling of the interaction between population dynamics and Peter Turchin & Th omas D. Hall42 Spatial Synchrony Among and Within World-Systems 43 speculations by Chase-Dunn, Manning and Hall (2000), very little has been off ered by way of explanation. Furthermore, synchrony, or entraining, between east and west Asia does not extend to south Asia, which itself is another puzzle. We argue that an examination of what ecologists have found about synchrony may provide leads for exploring the mechanisms and hence explaining the causes of synchrony across world-systems. We begin that task with a brief overview of synchrony from an ecological perspective. W H AT T H E E COLO GICA L T H EORY SAYS A BOU T SY NC H RON Y Ecologists have long puzzled over why many oscillatory population systems exhibit large-scale spatial synchrony. In fact, in the very paper that inaugurated the scientifi c study of population cycles Charles Elton also speculated why lem- ming peak years should be synchronized across much of Norway (Elton 1924). An even more striking pattern of spatial synchrony was later observed in the Hudson Bay Company data on lynx pelts (Elton 1924). It turned out that the ten-year lynx cycle is synchronized over the whole taiga region of Canada. In 1953 P.A.P. Moran developed statistical approaches for analyzing spatial aspects of lynx population cycles, and proposed a formal mechanism that could explain large-scale synchrony (Moran 1953). Th is mechanism is currently known in the ecological literature as “the Moran eff ect” (Bjornstad, 1999; more on the Moran eff ect below). Moran’s pioneering work inspired an enormous number of model- ing, statistical, and empirical studies, leading to a rapid maturation of the theory of spatial population dynamics during the 1990s (for a review see Bjornstad, 1999). A key issue was determining which mechanisms may cause synchrony. Synchronizing Mechanisms Ecologists have classifi ed mechanisms that induce spatial synchrony along two continua: exogenous versus endogenous and local versus “global.” A factor X is called an exogenous mechanism if it is not part of the feedback loop: X aff ects the variable of interest, while the variable of interest does not aff ect X. By contrast, an endogenous factor is one that is part of a feedback loop: the variable of interest aff ects X and then the change in X aff ects the variable of interest. Of course, we do not always (or even often) know all the feedback loops that aff ect the dynamics of the variable of interest. Th us, in practice, we call endog- enous only those mechanisms, whose feedback infl uences are explicitly taken into account (e.g., modeled). For example, in human-dominated ecosystems the usual assumption that climate aff ects population, but population does not aff ect climate, does not necessarily hold. Chew (2001) shows that early human civilizations so denuded forests and salinized agricultural land that they may, indeed have changed local, if not regional, climates. Some of these changes may be system-wide. Planetary changes are probably only a 20th or 21st century phe- nomenon (see also Crowley 2000; Hornborg 2001; Mann 2000; Th omas 1956; Turner 1990). Still, in world-system applications some climatic changes may need to be modeled as endogenous, rather than exogenous processes. Ecological theorizing uses the terms “local” and “global” in ways that diff er signifi cantly from usage in world-systems analysis, a diff erence that can gener- ate confusion. We review these diff erences since virtually all ecological research uses these terms in a consistent way. A “local” mechanism is one whose eff ects fall off with distance. By contrast, a “global” mechanism aff ects all points in the relevant space similarly, without any regard to how far these points are from each other. Th us, the term “global,” as used in ecological literature, might be glossed as “system-wide” in world-system terms. For clarity, we use “planetary” when we mean the entire world, and “global” only as in ecological theory. Th e spatial scale of a local mechanism can be measured in a variety of ways. One of the most useful approaches is to calculate the spatial autocorrelation function (ACF). A typical ACF is close to 1 for small spatial lags (because points located near each other tend to be highly correlated). As spatial lag is increased, ACF declines to zero (refl ecting lack of correlation between points separated by large distances). Th us, a rough measure of the spatial scale of spatial autocorrelation is the spatial lag at which ACF becomes statistically indistinguishable from zero. As the spa- tial scale on which a process operates increases local mechanisms grade smoothly into global. In practice, whenever the spatial scale of a mechanism is greater than the extent of the spatial domain, within which the dynamics of interest occur, it should be treated as global. ACFs of global processes remain positive (do not decline to zero) for the whole range of spatial lags possible within the spatial domain. In other words, even points situated at the opposite sides of the domain exhibit some degree of synchrony. Given the two classifi catory dimensions (endogeneity and locality), we can defi ne four regions of a universe of potentially synchronizing processes (Figure 1). Ecologists have tended to concentrate on two: the global exogenous and local endogenous mechanisms. Th e most discussed global exogenous factor in ecology is climatic variation. It is a quintessentially exogenous process because variation in temperature and rainfall can have a very strong eff ect on survival and repro- duction of organisms, while fl uctuations in organism population numbers almost never have an eff ect on weather (although in humans this is not necessarily true, as noted above), especially on the short time scales of interest to population dynamicists. On the spatial scale at which ecologists study most populations, weather patterns are best thought of as global. For example, variations in temper- ature are highly cross-correlated across hundreds of kilometers. On short tem- poral scales, precipitation may have a distinct local character (when a summer Peter Turchin & Th omas D. Hall44 Spatial Synchrony Among and Within World-Systems 45 thunderstorm dumps a couple of cm of water in one locality, while leaving another, only a km away, dry). On a longer time scale, however, such local eff ects tend to even out (wet versus dry summer conditions aff ect large areas, hundreds of km in extent). In any case, close examination of specifi c mechanisms shows that the global-local distinction defi nes a continuum, and not a dichotomy. For world-systems analysis, given the potential eff ects of human activity on climate (see Chew 2001), clearly “global” or system-wide mechanisms would be a massive volcanic eruption or collision with a sizable comet. Alternatively, if there is a truly exogenous climatic shift (due, say, to sun spot cycles or some such mechanism that humans could not aff ect) and if it were planetary, then we should see global synchrony, across Afroeurasia, Meso– and South America, Southeast Asia, and sub–Saharan Africa. Th is would still require some subsidiary explanation for the already documented lack of synchrony in South Asia. Th e quintessential local endogenous mechanism is movement. It is endog- enous because the number of organisms spreading from a source depends very much on the population density at the source. It is local, because organisms do not “teleport”—in order to get to there from here, an organism must travel through the intervening space. Th e result is a characteristic pattern of movement, in which the density of dispersers declines with the distance from source. We note that movement is not limited to the population under study; it may also refer to movement of other components in the dynamical system, such as preda- tors or pathogens. Socially, disputes in family succession among elites, as among Mongols who had competing lines of succession (Barfi eld 1989; Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997: Ch. 8) would be examples (laterally and lineally). Rules of suc- cession or descent vary by cultural group, and thus are typically highly localized. Such rules do change, but typically only very slowly, often pushed by changes in the ecology of production and adaptation. Once again, although movement tends to the local endogenous corner of the classifi catory universe, under certain circumstances it may become either exogenous or global (or both). An example of movement acting in an exog- enous manner is when the area under study is subjected to recurrent invasions of predators or pathogens from outside. Movement may act globally (or in a system-wide manner), rather than locally, when the scale of dispersal is much larger than the extent of the spatial domain. In ecological applications, move- ments by predators often occur on a much larger scale than movements of their prey. For example, lynx—the main predator of snowshoe hares—have been known to travel over a thousand kilometers. To give another ecological example, many fungal pathogens disperse by spores that may be carried by wind over very large distances. An analogous feature among humans would be the propensity to bring small, exotic souvenirs from distant places, and/or to trade them over great distances (Helms 1988). Another example might be the appearance of new, airborne pathogen that (nearly) simultaneously aff ected all human populations. Th e diff usion of the Black Death in the 14th century, might be such an instance, since it appears to have spread from Central Asia to both East Asia and West Asia (and Europe) (McNeill 1976). Finally an ecumene-spanning empire, or a world-economy might be considered an endogenous global factor. Consider the widespread eff ects of the Roman Empire or the current eff ects of U.S. foreign policy, which may be the analog of “highly mobile predator.” Th us, both Iraq and North Korea, separated by thousands of kilometers, are under similar kinds of pressure to change. Finally, there is the local, exogenous corner of the classifi catory universe. Th is is essentially the “random” corner, where noise, or contingency seems most likely. In social terms, this would be “historical accident.” We note, however, that while the event(s) may be accidental or random, their consequences are not (in the sense that their eff ect may depend on the state of the system). We reiterate that local-global and exogenous-endogenous are not discrete dichotomies, but rather continua between extremes. As one moves toward the center of the classifi catory universe, these distinctions begin to blur and fi nally merge together. Types of Oscillatory Dynamics Th e effi cacy of diff erent mechanisms described above to synchronize oscil- lations depends on the nature of the dynamics characterizing the synchronized systems. Th e key distinction is between stable and chaotic oscillations. Chaos Figure 1– Dimensional Continua of Mechanisms of Spatial Synchronicity Local Exogenous Global Exogenous Endogenous Local Endogenous Global “noise,” contingency historical accident climate, invasions by predators or pathogens comet or volcano pandemic, or world-empire, or world-economy movement family succession dispute movement by highly mobile predators or pathogens Peter Turchin & Th omas D. Hall46 Spatial Synchrony Among and Within World-Systems 47 is defi ned as bounded oscillations with sensitive dependence on initial conditions (Eckman and Ruelle 1985). Sensitive dependence can be illustrated with the fol- lowing mental experiment (or even better, a computer experiment). Suppose we have a dynamic system, which started from a certain initial condition and then generated a certain trajectory. Now imagine that we restart the system from an initial condition that is slightly diff erent (on the computer, we simply rerun the program, but give it a diff erent initial data). If the system is chaotic, then we will observe that the two trajectories starting from very similar but diff erent initial points will diverge with time, and eventually oscillate in a completely uncorre- lated fashion. If the system is stable, then the two trajectories will converge and soon become completely indistinguishable from each other; they will oscillate in perfect synchrony. Returning to the chaotic system, the faster trajectories diverge the more sensitive to initial conditions (and therefore the more chaotic) the system is. Th e same argument applies to the behavior of two identical or very similar systems. If their dynamics are stable, then the two systems starting from similar initial conidtions will tend to oscillate in synchrony. Small random perturbations will keep them out of perfect synchrony but the stable nature of the two systems will act to bring the two trajectories back in synchrony. By contrast, two identi- cal chaotic systems starting even from very similar initial conditions will rapidly diverge and oscillate asynchronously (this is sometimes known as the “butterfl y eff ect”). Small random perturbations will make this process of divergence even faster. Th is is why the dynamical stability is such an important factor in allowing synchronous oscillations. It is very hard to synchronize two chaotic systems. The Effect of Different Synchronizing Mechanisms on Spatial Dynamics Th e ability of any particular mechanism to synchronize dynamics depends on its nature, as well as on the nature of local population dynamics. In general, exogenous drivers are not particularly powerful synchronizing mechanisms. A substantial degree of spatial synchrony requires, fi rst, that local dynamics are stable (nonchaotic) oscillations and that, second, the exogenous factor acts in a global (or system-wide) manner. Th e mechanism of entrainment is the Moran eff ect, which acts as follows. Consider two stable dynamical systems driven by identical (or, at least, similar) mechanisms. For example, two spatially separate locations are inhabited by the same prey and predator species that undergo cyclic population interactions. Subjecting the two stable systems to similar per- turbations from an exogenous driver is akin to starting them with similar initial conditions: eventually both systems will oscillate in synchrony. By contrast, sub- jecting two chaotic systems to identical perturbations will not synchronize them, because they will diverge from each other due to their sensitive dependence properties. If an exogenous factor acts in a local manner, then its synchronizing strength will depend on how eff ectively the exogenous perturbations acting on each local system are cross-correlated. Furthermore, the eff ects of synchronizing external drivers may be degraded by other exogenous drivers, which may act indepen- dently on each system. Note that the usual way of modeling exogenous infl uences in dynamical sys- tems is by assuming that exogenous drivers aff ect the rate of change of a dynamic variable such as the population density of the studied organism. For example, an unseasonable freeze may impose 50 mortality on a population, which means that the population size will be halved. Such relative changes cannot synchronize chaotic systems for reasons given above. Another kind of an exogenous infl u- ence is one that “resets” each system to approximately the same value, instead of aff ecting its rate of change. Th at is, it makes the initial conditions in both systems virtually identical, hence they will be synchronized for some time, until the cha- otic process begins to produce divergence. Multiple “resetting” perturbations can impose a fairly high degree of synchrony even on chaotic systems. Th e average degree of synchrony will depend on how frequently “resetting” events occur, and how fast trajectories of local systems diverge after each resetting event. Endogenous factors such as movement have a greater potential for induc- ing spatial synchronization, especially if the local dynamics are characterized by stable limit cycles. Ranta et al. (1998) showed that even relatively low rates of movement can induce a near-perfect synchrony of local cycling populations. Th is property of nonlinear systems is called phase-locking (Bjornstad 1999). However, populations coupled by movement will remain uncorrelated if they are characterized by locally chaotic dynamics. Oscillatory dynamics in ecology arise most often as a result of population interactions between predators and prey (or, more generally, between ecological consumers and their resources, see Turchin 2003). It is important to remember that both predators and prey can move around. Depending on the dynamical nature of interaction (e.g., stable equilibrium, stable limit cycles, or chaos), and on the details of movement behavior (e.g., the movement rate of predators rela- tive to that of prey, ability of predators to track prey aggregations) predator-prey systems in space can give rise to second-order spatial covariance, which can take the form of traveling waves and static patchy patterns (Bjornstad 1999). We do not have space here to give justice to this rich and subtle theory, but wish to men- tion one kind of behavior, which may be of relevance to world-system dynamics —out-of-phase oscillations. To illustrate this kind of behavior, consider a two-patch system incorporat- ing both dispersal and local dynamics, coupling two discrete-time logistic equa- tions (Hastings 1993). Th is deceptively simple system is capable of a surprising Peter Turchin & Th omas D. Hall48 Spatial Synchrony Among and Within World-Systems 49 diversity of dynamical behaviors, depending on parameter values and initial conditions, but we are interested only in the out-of-phase cycles. What happens is that when patch 1 is low, patch 2 is high. On the next step, population in patch 1 grows, plus the patch gets a lot of migrants from patch 2. Th is causes patch 1 to overshoot its equilibrium, so on the subsequent step the population in it col- lapses. Meanwhile, patch 2 is aff ected by the same events, except they are shifted in phase with respect to patch 1. In other words, the interplay of movement and local dynamics leads to the behavior in which population size in each patch goes through recurrent cycles, while the total population (the sum of both patches) is constant. Statistical Issues Above we have devoted a lot of attention to the issue of what mechanisms may bring about large-scale synchrony. Th e implicit assumption here is that we are dealing with an empirical case of synchronous dynamics and the question is how to explain it. Given limited and noisy data, however, how do we know that there is a pattern to be explained, in the fi rst place? Th us, we need to say something about the null hypothesis of no synchrony, and how to distinguish it statistically from cases where synchrony is present. Th e problem is that two unconnected systems, but with similar dynamics (for example, the same period of oscillations) may look like they are synchronized, especially in limited runs of data. If, purely by chance, the two systems are in phase at the beginning of the observed period, they will continue cycling in phase for several oscillations, simply because the endogenous dynamics of each system generate cycles of the same period. Such a spurious synchrony may continue for some time before the systems diverge, either because their periods are not exactly the same, or because each system is aff ected by a diff erent set of exogenous infl uences (or because of sensitive dependence). If data are limited, however, it may appear as though the two processes have been synchronized by some external force. An example of spurious synchrony is Charles Elton’s proposal that the lynx cycle in boreal Canada is driven by the sunspot cycle. Indeed, during the 19th century, the two series were largely in phase. However, eventually the two series diverged, so that by mid–20th century they were in a perfect antiphase! Th ese two dynamical systems appear to be entirely unconnected, and the spurious synchrony observed during the 19th century arose as a result of very similar periods of oscillations (both slightly above 10 years). Th us, it is important to keep in mind that simple-minded approaches, such as measuring cross-correlations and testing their statistical signifi cance with some standard formula such as Bartlett’s rule (Chatfi eld 1989) can be very mis- leading. Standard measures of signifi cance assume that data are independent of each other, while in an oscillatory system subsequent data points are positively autocorrelated, infl ating the statistical signifi cance of the test. Methods for cor- recting signifi cance level in such situations exist (e.g., Sciremammano 1979), but perhaps the best approach is to use some version of bootstrap (Efron and Tibshirani 1993).1 Th e problem is that rigorous approaches require rather long data sets. In other words, tests for signifi cant cross-correlation between two oscillatory time series are characterized by low power. Th e problem is not lack of cleverness in designing powerful tests, but in the nature of the problem. In order to be sure that two series are not spuriously correlated may require a very long wait to see if they diverge. Fortunately, mechanism-free statistical tests are not the only way to investigate spatial synchrony. An alternative (or, rather, complementary) approach is to characterize the potential mechanisms that may (or may not) bring about spatial autocorrelation. Th us, in practice the question of whether there is synchrony and what factors explain it are not completely separable, and need to be addressed jointly. Summary Spatial dynamical systems are capable of a very diverse spectrum of behav- iors. Nevertheless, certain common themes emerge from this review. First, spatial synchrony is promoted when two local systems are driven by similar dynamical mechanisms. In fact, such systems can exhibit spurious synchrony: even though there is no synchronizing mechanism, the two systems oscillate in step because they happened to start from similar initial conditions. Second, processes that act globally (that is, on a system-wide basis) promote large-scale spatial synchrony. Th ird, the type of local dynamics aff ects very much whether any particular mechanism will induce synchrony. Systems with stable oscillations can be syn- chronized over vast geographic distances by global exogenous infl uences. Th e degree of synchrony will usually not be very high, because each local system will also be aff ected by other exogenous factors that are not highly autocorrelated 1. A bootstrap is a computer-intensive method for testing hypotheses. Th e basic idea is to construct a model for the null hypothesis—in this case, two oscillating system without any synchronizing connections. One then generates many data sets similar to this situation (e.g., same length of time-series and same degree of noise), and calculates the test statistic—here the cross-correlation coeffi cient. Th en the data-base correlation coef- fi cient is compared to the bootstrapped correlations. For example, for a p-level of 0.05, the data-based statistic should be greater than 95 of bootstrap statistics (see Efron and Tibshirani [1993] for more elaborate discussion). Peter Turchin & Th omas D. Hall50 Spatial Synchrony Among and Within World-Systems 51 the late 2nd and most of the 1st century bce, then the Principate, followed by the troubled 3rd century, and fi nally, the Dominate, followed by a fi nal collapse in the West during the late 5th century. By contrast, the fi rst peak of the Chinese empire (Western Han Dynasty) occurred during the 1st century bce, just when the Roman polity was convulsed by a series of civil wars. Th e interregnum between the Western and Eastern Han dynasties was during the 1st half of the 1st century ce, the Eastern Han peak was during the 2nd century, and the collapse of the Han dynasty occurred during the 3rd century, which coincided with the similar period of the Roman Empire. Th ere was no third secular wave in China, however, but a long period of disunity until the Sui-Tang unifi cation. Population fl uctuations, as far as they are known, followed closely the sociopolitical dynam- ics. Th us, while the broad period of 200 bce–200 ce was characterized by large empires and high population densities at both ends of Eurasia, fi ner dynamics within the period came into and out of phase. A similar pattern appears to hold during the next warming period (roughly from 700 to 1200 ce). Th e peak of the Early Tang dynasty occurred around 700 ce. It experienced a collapse during the middle of the 8th century, a restoration (the Late Tang dynasty) during the 9th century, and a fi nal collapse in 907. By contrast, Carolingian empire reached its peak around 800 ce, and disintegrated during the 9th century. During the same period another large Eurasian empire, the Caliphate, went through two shorter cycles: Omayyads (661–750) and the Abbasids (750 to around 860 when the dynasty became a pawn of the Turkic ghulams [slave-warriors]). In the next wave, North Sung declined during the 12th century, followed by the Mongol conquest of the 13th century (South Sung fell to the Mongols only in 1279). Chinese population declined catastrophically during the 13th century dynastic collapse and nomadic conquest. By contrast, in Western Europe the population peaked around 1300 ce, and the actual collapse occurred only in post-Black Death period. Political disintegration in Western Europe, however, occurred in patchy manner. Th e German–Roman (later known as Holy Roman) Empire disintegrated fairly synchronously with the Sung (although the process was by far less violent). On the other hand, France experienced the worst periods of civil war around 1370s and 1420s (two peaks of the Hundred Years War), while England’s turn came only in 1450–1485 (the Wars of the Roses). By that time the Chinese had already expelled the Mongols (in 1368) and unifi ed all China under the Ming dynasty. Again, when viewed broadly, the Medieval Warm Period is the time of strong empires and dense populations, but when we consider dynamics within the period, synchronicity largely falls apart. Th is observation supports the idea that climate did not directly drive the secular wave, but rather modifi ed it across space (noise, contingency). Endogenous factors such as movement may result in a very high degree of synchrony—phase-locking, but the spatial extent of such synchronous oscillations may not be great, because the eff ect of move- ment tends to attenuate rapidly with space. Additionally, endogenous processes may cause out-of-phase cycles (anti-synchrony, so to speak). Finally, chaotic systems are very diffi cult to synchronize either by exogenous or endogenous mechanisms. Only global catastrophes that reset all locations to approximately the same initial conditions can impose some (fl eeting) degree of synchrony on chaotic systems. Examples include events such as collision with a large comet, like the one that is hypothesized to have led to the extinction of dinosaurs, or a massive volcanic eruption, such as Th era (see also Weiss, et al. 1993). I M PLICATIONS FOR WOR LD SYST E M R E SE A RC H East-West Synchronicity and Global Climate As we mentioned in the Introduction, one empirical pattern that requires explanation is synchronous changes of empire sizes in West and East Afroeurasia. Ecological theory suggests several hypotheses, the simplest one being the eff ect of an exogenous global factor—climate. World-system theorists (Chase-Dunn et al 2000) have already suggested this explanation, but historical demography (Galloway 1986) presents it in its most developed form. Galloway (1986: Figure 6) plotted the solar activity index (considered to be one of the most important drivers of global climate change) and populations of Western Europe and China from 400 bce to 1800 ce. Dynamics of the solar activity index (see Eddy 1977: Table 1) suggests that there was a long-term period of warm climate with the peak around 20 bce–80 ad (the Roman Maximum). Th e second such warm period was from 1120 to 1280 ce (the Medieval Maximum). Between these two maxima, there was a period of cooler temperatures (the Medieval Minimum, 640 –710 ce). After the Medieval Maximum, solar activity declined (the Spoerer Minimum, 1400–1510 ce), then increased somewhat, declined again (the Maunder Minimum, 1640–1710), and increased again in the late 19th and 20th centuries. As noted by Galloway, populations of Western Europe and China increased and decreased roughly in parallel with solar activity. Th e Roman Maximum in solar activity coincides with two great empires dominating the eastern and western ends of Eurasia: Han China and the Roman Empire. However, while this is a remarkable correlation when examined at a coarse time scale, fi ner scale resolution does not reveal a close parallelism in the sociopolitical dynamics of the two empires. Th e Roman polity went through three secular cycles: the Republic, followed by the decentralization phase during Peter Turchin & Th omas D. Hall52 Spatial Synchrony Among and Within World-Systems 53 in a way that imposed a certain degree of synchrony between the East and the West.2 The 17th Century Crisis What is highly interesting is that the next wave of state collapse—the so- called crisis of the 17th century—aff ected practically all Eurasian empires (apart from the South Asian region) essentially simultaneously (Goldstone 1991). Th e “long 17th century” began ca. 1570 with religious warfare in France, the Dutch Revolt, the troubled second half of Ivan the Terrible’s reign in Russia, and the daimyo-led civil war in Japan. During the fi rst half of the 17th century, Russia went through the Time of Troubles, Central Europe was devastated by the Th irty Year War (during which Germany lost a third to half of its population), the Ming dynasty fell in China and was replaced by the Manchus, Spain experi- enced the Portugese and Catalonian revolts, the Ottoman Empire almost disin- tegrated, and the English decapitated their king. Th e 17th century was also the period of widespread famine and epidemics. All regions of Eurasia (apart from India and Iran) experienced population declines, in some cases quite extreme (as in Central Europe). Th e crisis in the 17th century was unique in the history of Eurasia. Th e next wave of state collapse was not as tightly bunched. Th us, the Age of Revolutions in continental Europe started with the French revolution of late 18th century, and ended with the revolutions of 1848–1849. By contrast, Russia, China, Turkey, and Iran went through their revolutions during the early 20th century. England entirely avoided state collapse during the 19th century, but had to let its empire go in the 20th century (Ireland in 1920, India in 1947, Africa in early 1960s). In fact, it appears that the revolutions in the 19th – early 20th centuries are “echos” of the 17th century; oscillations that began to diverge as a result of, perhaps, slightly diff erent periods, and an accumulation of historical accidents peculiar to each specifi c polity. Why was the 17th century crisis Eurasia-wide? One possible explanation is again the global climate. Th e 17th century saw a trend to lower tempera- tures, which in most Eurasia (apart from the Indian subcontinent) should have resulted in decreased harvests. According to the demographic-structural theory, the root cause of crisis is in the imbalance between population numbers and the productive capacity of the land. Th is imbalance can be achieved either by exces- sive population growth, or by a rapid decline in the productive capacity of the environment, for example, as a result of a string of colder, wetter years. Note that in this scenario climate change does not directly cause state collapse: its eff ect is, rather, mediated by social structure (population numbers in relation to the productive capacity of land). The Mongol conquest as a “resetting catastrophe” Another explanation of the 17th century crisis would look back to the events during the previous secular wave. Most world-system theorists agree that the Mongol conquest in the 13th century was a key event in the Afroeurasian his- tory. Not only did the Mongol Empire briefl y connect East with the West, it also started a series of remarkably coherent oscillations in Central Asia and adjoining regions. Th e huge territory conquered by the Mongols during the fi rst half of the 13th century contained four large “cultural areas” inhabited by settled people: China, Transoxania, Persia (including Mesopotamia), and eastern Europe. From the middle in the 13th century, these four areas were ruled by four separate Chingissid dynasties: (1) Kublai and his successors (the Yuan dynasty) in China; (2) Jagataids in Turkestan (which included Transoxania); (3) Hulagu and his successors (Il-Khans) in Persia; and (4) Juchids (Batu and his successors) in the Kipchak Steppe (the Golden Horde). According to the theory advanced in Turchin (2003: Chapter 7), these four polities should be subject to the Ibn Khaldun cycles of around a century in period. Th e Ibn Khaldun cycle, named after the 14th century Arab sociologist who fi rst described it, is a variety of a secular wave that tends to aff ect societies with elites drawn from adjacent nomadic groups. Th e dynamics of the Ibn Khaldunian world-system are determined by the interaction between a sedentary, agrarian state and surrounding steppe or desert pastoral “tribes.” Th e sedentary state region is the site of recurrent state building/collapse episodes. It is inhabited by indigenous commoner population, that provides the productive basis of the soci- ety. Th e steppe or desert is inhabited by stateless tribes that periodically conquer the civilized region and establish a ruling dynasty there. Steppe or desert tribes, thus, supply the elites (nobility) for the sedentary state. Ibn Khaldun cycles tend to operate on a faster time scale, so that their period is about 4 generations, or a century. Th e events in Eurasia after the Mongol conquest appear to provide a reason- able fi t to this theory: 2. One anonymous reviewer noted that Galloway’s data focuses on long-term fl uctu- ations, of much longer period than city-size or empires. We actually concur with obser- vation. Th us, this type of climate change may not be the mechanism for East—West Asia synchrony. Still, it illustrates how other climatic changes, occurring on a shorter scale, might produce such synchrony. Peter Turchin & Th omas D. Hall54 Spatial Synchrony Among and Within World-Systems 55 1. In China, the civil war between the successors of Kublai broke out in 1328. The 1350s saw numerous revolts led by native leaders, and in 1368 one of these leaders expelled the Mongols and established the Ming dynasty. 2. Turkestan was unified until 1333–1334, when a nomad-led insurrection broke out against the Jagataid regime in Eastern Turkestan. By 1350 the power in Transoxania passed into the hands of local Turkic nobles. After a period of turmoil, Timur established a new dynasty. Timur unified Transoxania in 1379, and conquered Iran during the 1390s. The Timurids dynasty also lasted about a century. In 1469 Persia was lost to the White Sheep Horde, while Transoxania splintered between warring branches of Timur’s descendants. 3. The Persia of Il-Khans underwent dissolution in 1335. After a period of civil war it was conquered by Timur (see above). When the Timurids lost Persia in 1469, another turbulent period followed, and eventually, by 1500, Persia was unified by a native dynasty (Safavids). 4. A similar course of events occurred in the Kipchak Steppe. The Juchids’ rule ended in 1359, when the Kipchak steppe fell into anarchy. After a period of civil war, the Golden Horde underwent a revival under Timur Qutlugh, who re-consolidated his dominion over Russia, although a series of punitive expeditions were required during the early 15th century to keep the tribute flowing. In the middle of the 15th century, however, the revived Golden Horde began disintegrating again. The first part to secede was the Crimean Khanate in 1430. The Khanates of Kazan and Astrakhan followed (in 1445 and 1466, respectively). The Moscovite polity went through its own period of civil war during the second quarter of the 15th century, which, curiously, coincided with the civil war on the steppe that lead to the final splintering of the Golden Horde. As soon as the civil war ended, Muscovy became de facto an independent state (de jure independence had to wait until 1480). Th is is an alternative way of viewing the analyses of Barfi eld (1989) and Chase-Dunn and Hall (1997: Ch. 8). As Barfi eld notes, however, the Mongol conquest was somewhat exceptional with respect to the usual strategy employed by the central–Asian nomads. First, the Mongols succeeded in capturing much vaster regions, due in the main part to innovations in organization by Chinggis. Second, instead of merely exploiting sedentary states via the outer frontier strat- egy, the Mongols actually conquered large empires and had to run them. Finally, the break-up grew out of Mongol rules of dynastic succession that emphasized both lateral and linear descent. Th ese extensive Mongol conquests also disrupted the Ibn Khaldun cylces, in eff ect resetting them in several diff erent areas simul- taneously. Among nomads this contradiction produced confl icts that both allowed one strong leader to emerge and tended to eliminate rivals. While useful for pastoralists, this multifaceted civil war strategy for succession is disastrous for states. Chase-Dunn and Hall (1997: Ch. 8) argue that the issue was not that the Mongols could not change their system of succession—they clearly knew how states worked. Rather, it was that they could not change their system and remain Mongols. To have a more orderly system of succession like those found in states, would have destroyed the very mechanisms that allowed leaders like Chinggis to emerge. Th e Ottomans, however, seem to have solved this problem. Th ey insti- tutionalized succession so that change happened very quickly—one heir wins, all others are strangled with a silken chord. As a result, the secular cycles of the Ottoman Empire were 200–300 years long. To summarize, all Chinggisid dynasties went through typical Ibn Khaldun cycles of about a century in period, and all experienced collapse at approximately the same time. In China, a native dynasty expelled the Mongols after one cycle, while in Russia and Iran the steppe dynasties went through two cycles before giving way to native rulers. Incidentally, the central Eurasian steppes continued to undergo Ibn Khaldun cycles, until their conquest and division between the Russian and the Chinese empires (Barfi eld 1989). What is remarkable is the degree of synchrony in the socio-political dynamics of the settled regions ini- tially conquered by the Mongols in the 13th century. One possible explanation of this pattern is that an initial catastrophic event—the Mongol conquest—reset all regions to approximately the same initial conditions. Th ereafter, each region oscillated as a result of its endogenous dynamics, but because oscillations were driven by similar mechanisms, political collapses occurred at about the same time. The Black Death as a Resetting Catastrophe Returning to the fates of Eurasia as a whole, the continent-wide spread of Black Death from its endemic region (Central Asia) may have been another resetting catastrophe. Th e Black Death pandemic is widely credited to the Mongol conquest, and the resulting density and speed of traffi c, trade, raids, and communications across Central Asia—for which the Mongols are widely famous. Th e increase in traffi c made it possible for various vectors to survive to spread various pathogens, notably the plague bacteria, over large distances Peter Turchin & Th omas D. Hall56 Spatial Synchrony Among and Within World-Systems 57 shocks, global in their eff ect on most of Eurasian polities, that caused secular oscillations across the continent to get in phase. Th e repeated nature of these shocks, and especially that they happened to be three centuries apart (leading to a potential resonance eff ect) may go a long way to explaining the remarkable degree of Eurasia-wide synchrony during the last millenium.4 Spread of Pathogens, Ideas, and People Th e above discussion has already brought in the disease as one potentially synchronizing factor. Th e Black Death, however, was a rather unsual episode in the history of epidemics, because of its global (within Eurasia) eff ect. It was not a unique occurrence (for example, the fl u pandemic of 1911 was even more global in its eff ect), but most diseases tend to spread in a more local fashion. Recent research on measles epidemics during the 20th century (when we have excel- lent data sets, e.g. for England, see Grenfell et al. 2001) has traced how disease spreads from town to town. In general, we would expect that epidemics would be an important synchronizing factor within world-systems, but except for unusual circumstances they will not spread between world-systems. One such exception, as noted above, would be the rapid spread of the Black Death within Eurasia during the 1330s and 40s (McNeill 1976). Cultural infl uences, innovations, and fads could also spread in a manner similar to epidemics. A dramatic example is the wave of revolutions that spread through western and central Europe in 1848–1849. Other potential examples include the spread of agricultural innovations (which elevate the carrying capac- ity) and birth-control practices (which reduce population growth rate). Finally, actual population movements between agrarian polities are prob- ably too slow to synchronize them, although within a polity they should play an important role (e.g. migration to urban centers at the end of population increase phase). We can evaluate the rate of migration by considering histori- cal instances of colonization movement, such as the Iberian Reconquista or the colonization of European steppe by the Russians. Incidentally, both of these examples involved interpolity migration. Th e Reconquista resulted in a major transplantation of Spaniards from the north into the reconquered south, but also in massive movements of the French settlers into the north (Bartlett 1993: (McNeill 1976).³ Th e Mongol conquest, however, was largely complete by mid- 13th century, while the Black Death struck a hundred years later. Why was there such a delay? We do not know, but one hypothesis may explain it: that disease tends to spread particularly rapidly during the decentralization phase of the secular cycle (this was mentioned above). If this hypothesis is correct, then it was not the fact of Mongol unifi cation per se, but that simultaneous disntegration of various Mongol polities that threw the Great Steppe in turmoil, causing large numbers of people to move back and forth, and thus spread the Black Death to both ends of the continent. Th at is, as suggested earlier, these social processes transformed what might have been an exogenous-global mechanism in to an endogenous-global mechanism. Th e Black Death caused Eurasia-wide turmoil simply by its terrifying impact on populations. But it also probably had an additional eff ect that tended to bring distant polities in phase with each other. Epidemics generally infl ict a higher mortality on lower strata of society, while the elites tend to escape relatively lightly. A side eff ect of an epidemic, therefore, is to increase imbalance between the productive strata and elites. According to demographic-structural theory, excessive elite numbers are a highly destabilizing factor for any society. Th us, polities experiencing a severe epidemic should be more likely to go into a collapse than polities avoiding such a fate. Note that the logic of this argument is similar to the hypothesized connection between climate change and sociopoliti- cal stability made above: both disease and climate are assumed to act indirectly, by aff ecting social structure. Th e 14th century, therefore, was similar to the 17th century in that much of Eurasia was in crisis, and in that it was the century of widespread population decline. (Additionally, it was the time of decreasing temperatures, leading to the Spoerer minimum). Th is raises the possibility that the crisis in the 17th century was simply an echo of the 14th century. A more wholistic view, however, would be to consider the Black Death and the two minima of solar activity as repeated 3. Chase-Dunn and Hall (1997, Chs. 6 and 8) present this argument. Th ey further note (p. 116) contra to Goldstone’s claim that there is little or no world-system eff ect here, that the Black Death spread precisely along the pathways of trade that formed the Afroeurasian-wide world-system. In situations like this where world-systems that were either isolated, or only connected at the two widest levels (information and prestige goods), begin to merge, the endogenous—exogenous distinction becomes particularly muddy. Th is is where a more quantitative (and dynamical) approach is called for. For example, we need to obtain numerical estimates of how the spatial scale of information and prestige goods exchange fl uctuated during this period. 4. But we should not overstate the observed degree of synchrony. Secular waves do not have very regular period of oscillations, so we should expect divergence after just one or two cycles after a resetting perturbation. Perhaps that is why the Age of Revolutions occurred in Western Europe earlier than in other parts of Eurasia. Peter Turchin & Th omas D. Hall58 Spatial Synchrony Among and Within World-Systems 59 179). Populations moving into the European steppe came from Russia, Poland- Lithuania (Ukrainians and Jews) and even Germany. Both processes were very slow, occurring on the time scale of centuries. Iberian Reconquista occurred in two main pushes, 1080–1150 and 1212–1265 (Bartlett 1993). Russian colonization started with the conquest of Kazan in 1552 and continued after the incorporation of Crimea in 1783. Nomadic populations, however, may be an altogether diff erent story (see Barfi eld 1989 and Frank 1992). McNeill (1963, 1987) suggests that diff ering ecological conditions created a “steppe gradient” that tended to encourage move- ment of Central Asian Steppe nomads to the west whenever events in the east disrupted their lifeways.⁵ Such disruptions could be socio-political, for instance temporary success of Chinese military campaigns against them, or climatic, in quality of grazing, or a sudden growth in population (of animals or people or both) that strained the carrying capacity of the local environment (again, these in turn might have social and/or climatic sources). Th e net eff ect is one of many relatively short-distance movements that create a net westward migration across Central Asia toward the west. Because nomads are much more mobile than agri- culturalists, disturbances at the east end of the Great Steppe can rapidly propa- gate to the western end, probably on the time scale of years and decades. Asynchronous South Asia If we consider the Steppe Gradient, along with Jared Diamond’s (1999) observation that absent formidable barriers, east—west movement along similar latitudes (and therefore similar climates) is easier than north—south movement that must traverse signifi cantly diff erent ecological zones, we can construct one explanation for the puzzling fi ndings of Chase-Dunn et al. (2000) that east and west Asia synchronize, but not south Asia. Th is is all the more so, since the Himalayas are a formidable barrier to contact and exchange. To be sure, there has been extensive traffi c across the Himalayas, but it may not have been suffi cient to synchronize the various systems. Steppe nomads seldom made incursions into south Asia. Central-Asian infl uence on India was transmitted indirectly via the Iranian plateau (for example, the Moguls, whose name is a corruption of the “Mongol,” conquered India from Afghanistan). Two additional factors give tangential support to this supposition. First, while bulk goods, large populations, and armies rarely moved between South and Central Asia, travelers and ideas did so extensively. Th e spread of Buddhism and of silk and other luxury goods are familiar examples. Both illustrate the criti- cal diff erence between the various boundaries of world-system, bulk goods and the military-political exchanges on the one hand versus information and luxury goods on the other. Second, south Asia had tremendous eff ects on southeast Asia. Again there is the spread of Buddhism, but also other cultural features, and trade in luxury goods. Yet, if the east—west vs. north—south diff erential is at work, there should be some synchrony between south Asia and Southeast Asia, and less synchrony between Southeast Asia and east Asia. Unless, of course, the somewhat lower barriers between east and southeast Asia did allow suffi cient contact and exchange to promote synchrony. Th e second explanation for asynchronous dynamics in South Asia is the eff ect of climate. Cold, wet, climate leading to problems in most of Eurasia might have been a boon for South Asian agriculturalists. Th e two hypotheses, movement (of people, goods, and ideas) and global climate are not mutually exclusive. A possible third explanation for asynchronous dynamics in South Asia is that local, i.e., endogenous, processes may have diff ered signifi cantly between south Asia and the rest of Asia. Th is would seem less likely, but it is a possibility that warrants consideration. Currently we do not have suffi cient data to discriminate among these expla- nations. Still, the arguments and analyses presented here suggest ways these issues might be addressed empirically. CON LUSIONS A N D DI R E C TIONS FOR F U T U R E R E SE A RC H Much (if not all) of our discussion of potentially synchronizing factors and their interplay with sociopolitical cycles in Eurasia is highly speculative. However, these speculations constitute a powerful argument for the relevance and utility of further systematic, theoretical and empirical extensions of ecological theories to world-systems analysis. Our key conclusion is that this synthesis of these two widely separated theoretical traditions can lead to much more rigorous explora- tion and testing of theories of the processes of world-systemic change. Our goal in this paper was not to provide answers, but to generate hypoth- eses that can be subsequently tested with data. Th us, the last topic that we need to discuss here is how such empirical testing might be accomplished. We argue that explicit mathematical models are necessary ingredients in this empirical program. Th e reason is that nonlinear dynamics such as cycles are suffi ciently complex in themselves, but when we add a spatial component, the resulting problems become much too diffi cult to be grasped by the “naked” 5. However, in the fi rst millennium bce the predominant direction of movement was to the east, leading to the spread of Indo-European nomads (see McNeill 1987, pp. 265- 67, especially the map on p. 266). Peter Turchin & Th omas D. Hall60 Spatial Synchrony Among and Within World-Systems 61 human mind. What is needed is mathematical formalism to be able to state the problem precisely—as models—and computers to solve the models. As we men- tioned in the Introduction, some social scientists might object to mathematical models on the grounds that they oversimplify the reality. We seek to understand such complex systems by building models systematically, starting with simple assumptions and then adding more complex processes, as they are warranted by data. Th e power of mathematical models is that they make quantitative predictions that can be compared to data using standard statistical methods. One statistical methodology for investigating spatial synchrony is the autocorrelation analysis. Th e correlation coeffi cients calculated by Chase-Dunn et al (2000) between empire sizes in the Central, East Asian, and Indic PMNs was a very useful step that has already yielded highly suggestive results, but it can be improved upon. First, we can estimate spatial autocorrelation functions (ACF), that is, how the correlation coeffi cient changes with distance between the polities. Diff erent synchronizing mechanisms leave diff erent “signatures” in the ACF. Th us, a local process should result in an ACF that declines with distance: high correlation between territorial dynamics if polities are located near each other, and low or no correlation for polities separated by great distances. In other words, the scale at which ACF becomes indistinguishable from 0 is related to the spatial scale at which a process operates. By contrast, a global mechanism should result in no relationship between the correlation coeffi cient and distance. Th e approach sketched above tests a qualitative prediction—the question of whether the ACF declines with distance has a binary answer (yes or no). A more informative approach would address the quantitative aspects of ACF, such as the spatial scale at which it becomes indistinguishable from zero. Th us, an even stronger test would be to construct a mathematical model of synchronous oscillations, estimate the spatial scale at which the postulated factor operates (for example, how fast and how far epidemics spread), and then make quantitative predictions about the shape of the ACF. Furthermore, spatial autocorrelation analysis is not the only statistical approach that could be used. Very useful insights can be obtained by examining cross-correlations between two or more factors. For example, we can investigate how political dynamics are correlated (in space and time) with disease dynamics. Again, qualitative predictions can be made readily (for example, no crosscorrela- tions between polity size dynamics and disease probably means that these two factors are unrelated to each other). However, more progress will be made if we can make quantitative predictions using explicit models. Th e approach that we are advocating needs several ingredients for success. On the empirical side we need a more detailed database of territorial dynamics of all polities within the Afroeurasia (omitting, perhaps, ones that are smaller than a certain threshold).⁶ We also need data on spatio-temporal dynamics of any other variables that may aff ect synchrony, such as epidemics and climate. Some databases already exist, e.g. Biraben’s (1975) compilation of places aff ected by the Black Death in Europe and the Mediterranean. Certain kinds of data, such as climate change, are in the process of being developed in other disciplines and all we need to do is wait (e.g., see Mann 2000). Other data will probably need to be developed from scratch (here recent developments in historical GIS may be of great help). On the modeling side we need a better understanding of processes that may cause oscillations and synchrony. What would be particularly useful in the study of synchrony is estimates of the rates of movement for diff erent “things”—goods, pathogens, ideas, and people. Th e research program combining mathematical theory with sophisticated statistical approaches is costly—it requires a large quantity of data and some changes in research practice. However, we think that such an investment is warranted. Recent results that suggest sociopolitical cycles and wide-scale syn- chronicity within the Afroeurasia are “intoxicating,” to use the word of Robert Denemark (2000). If there are regular empirical patterns, then history is not just a collection of accidents. But unraveling the complex interactions causing the empirical regularities will require sophisticated quantitative tools. R E F E R E NC E S Anderson, David. G. (1994). Th e Savannah River Chiefdoms: Political Change in the Late Prehistoric Southeast. Tuscaloosa: University of Alabama Press. Anderson, David G. (1996). “Fluctuations Between Simple And Complex Chiefdoms: Cycling In Th e Late Prehistoric Southwest,” Pp. 231–252 in Political Structures And Change In Th e Prehistoric Southeastern United States, edited by J. F. Scarry. Gainesville, FL: University Press of Florida. Arrighi, Giovanni. (1999). “Th e Global Market.” Journal of World-Systems Research 5: 217–25. http://jwsr.ucr.edu/ Arrighi, Giovanni and Beverly J. Silver (1999). Chaos and Governance in the Modern World System. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. Barfi eld, Th omas J. (1989). Th e Perilous Frontier: Nomadic Empires And China. Oxford, UK: Blackwell, 6. Peter Turchin is in the process of developing such a database for Europe 1000- 2000 ce, using the historical computer atlas CENTENNIA. http://jwsr.ucr.edu/ Peter Turchin & Th omas D. Hall62 Spatial Synchrony Among and Within World-Systems 63 Barr, Kenneth (1979). “Long Waves: A Selected Annotated Bibliography,” Review 2: 671–718. Bartlett, Robert (1993). Th e Making of Europe: Conquest, Colonization and Cultural Change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Biraben, Jean-Noël (1975). Les hommes et la peste en France et dans les pays européens et méditerranéens. Paris: Mouton. Bjornstad, O. N., R. A. Ims, and X. Lambin (1999). “Spatial Population Dynamics: Analyzing Patterns And Processes Of Population Synchrony,” Trends in Ecology and Evolution. 14:427–432. Boswell, Terry (1989). “Colonial Empires and the Capitalist World-System: A Time Series Analysis of Colonization, 1640–1960,” American Sociological Review. 54: 180–196. Boswell, Terry and Christopher Chase-Dunn (2000). Th e Spiral of Capitalism and Socialism: Th e Decline of State Socialism and the Future of the World-System. Boulder, CO: Lynne-Rienner. Boswell, Terry and Joya Misra (1995). “Cycles and Trends in the Early Capitalist World- Economy: An Analysis of Leading Sector Commodity Trades, 1500–1600/50– 1750,” Review 18:450–485. Boswell, Terry, and Mike Sweat (1991). “Hegemony, Long Waves, and Major Wars: A Time Series Analysis of Systemic Dynamics, 1496–1967,” International Studies Quarterly 35:123–149. Chase-Dunn, Christopher and Th omas D. Hall (1997). Rise and Demise: Comparing World-Systems. Boulder: Westview Press. Chase-Dunn, Christopher and Th omas D. Hall (2000). “Comparing World-systems to Explain Social Evolution,” Pp. 86–111 in World System History: Th e Social Science of Long-Term Change, edited by Robert Denemark, Jonathan Friedman, Barry K. Gills, and George Modelski. London: Routledge. Chase-Dunn, Christopher, Susan Manning, and Th omas D. Hall (2000). “Rise and Fall: East-West Synchronicity and Indic Exceptionalism Reexamined,” Social Science History. 24:727–754. Chase-Dunn, Christopher, Yukio Kawano, and Benjamin D. Brewer. (2000). “ Trade Globalization Since 1795: Waves of Integration in the World-System,” American Sociological Review 65:77–95. Chatfi eld, Chris. (1989). Th e Analysis of Time Series: An Introduction, 4th edition. London: Chapman and Hall. Chew, Sing C. (2001). World Ecological Degradation: Accumulation, Urbanization, and Deforestation 3000 B.C. – A. D. 2000. Walnut Creek, CA: Altamira Press. Crowley, Th omas J. (2000). “Causes of Climate Change Over the Past 1000 Years,” Science. 289:270–277. Denemark, Robert A. (2000). “Cumulation and Direction in World System History,” Pp. 299–312 in World System History: Th e Social Science of Long-Term Change, edited by Robert A. Denemark, Jonathan Friedman, Barry K. Gills, and George Modelski. London: Routledge. Denemark, Robert, Jonathan Friedman, Barry K. Gills, and George Modelski, eds. (2000). World System History: Th e Social Science of Long-Term Change. London: Routledge. Diamond, Jared (1997). Guns, Germs, and Steel: Th e Fates of Human Societies. New York: W.W. Norton. Eckmann, J.-P., and D. Ruelle (1985). “Ergodic Th eory of Chaos and Strange Attractors,” Review of Modern Physics. 57: 617–656. Eddy, J. A. (1977). “Climate and the Changing Sun,” Climatic Change 1:173–190. Efron, Bradley, and Robert J. Tibshirani (1993). An Introduction to the Bootstrap. New York: Chapman and Hall. Elton, Charles, and M. Nicholson (1942). “Th e ten-year cycle in numbers of the lynx in Canada,” Journal of Animal Ecology 11:215–244. Elton, C. S. (1924). “Periodic Fluctuations in the Number of Animals: Th eir Causes and Eff ects,” British Journal of Experimental Biology 2:119–163. Fischer, David H. (1996). Th e Great Wave: Price Revolutions and the Rhythm of History. New York: Oxford University Press. Frank, Andre Gunder (1992). Th e Centrality of Central Asia. Amsterdam: VU University Press for Center for Asian Studies Amsterdam (CASA), Comparative Asian Studies No.8. Frank, Andre Gunder (1993). “Th e Bronze Age World System and its Cycles,” Current Anthropology 34:383–413. Frank, Andre Gunder and Barry K. Gills, eds. (1993). Th e World System: Five Hundred Years of Five Th ousand? London: Routledge. Galloway, Patrick R. (1986). “Long-Term Fluctuations in Climate and Population in the Preindustrial Era,” Population and Development Review. 12:1–24. Goldstein, Joshua (1988). Long Cycles: Prosperity and War in the Modern Age. New Haven: Yale University Press. Goldstone, Jack (1991). Revolution and Rebellion in the Early Modern World. Berkeley: University of California Press. Grenfell, B. T., O. N. Bjørnstad, and J. Kappey (2001). “ Travelling Waves and Spatial Hierarchies in Measles Epidemics,” Nature. 414:716–723. Grimes, Peter (2000). “Recent Research on World-Systems,” Pp. 29–55 in A World- Systems Reader: New Perspectives on Gender, Urbanism, Cultures, Indigenous Peoples, and Ecology, edited by Th omas D. Hall. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefi eld. Hastings, A. (1993). “Complex Interactions Between Dispersal and Dynamics: Lessons from Coupled Logistic Equations,” Ecology, 74:1362–1372. Helms, Mary W. (1988). Ulysses’ Sail: An Ethnographic Odyssey of Power, Knowledge, and Geographical Distance. Princeton University Press. Hornborg, Alf (2001). Th e Power of the Machine: Global Inequalities of Economy, Technology, and Environment. Walnut Creek, CA: Altamira Press. Mann, Michael E. (2000). “Lessons for a New Millenium,” Science. 289:253–254. McNeill, William (1963). Th e Rise of the West: A History of the Human Commnity. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. McNeill, William (1976). Plagues and Peoples. Garden City, New York: Doubleday. Peter Turchin & Th omas D. Hall64 McNeill, William (1987). A History of the Human Community, Vol. I: Prehistory to 1500, 2nd ed. Englewood Cliff s, NJ: Prentice Hall. Modelski, George and William R. Th ompson (1996). Leading Sectors and World Powers: Th e Coevolution of Global Politics and Economics. Columbia: University of South Carolina Press. Modelski, George and William R. Th ompson. (2000). “World System Evolution,” Pp. 24–53 in World System History: Th e Social Science of Long-Term Change, edited by Robert A. Denemark, Jonathan Friedman, Barry K. Gills, and George Modelski. London: Routledge. Moran, P. A. P. (1953). “Th e Statistical Analysis of the Canada Lynx Cycle,” Synchronization and Meteorology. Australian Journal of Zoology 1:291–298. Nefedov, Sergey (2001). “On the Th eory of Demographic Cycles,” http:// hist1.narod.ru/Science/Engl/Mainat.htm (last verifi ed 4/16/03) Neitzel, Jill E., ed. (1999). Great Towns and Regional Polities in the Prehistorical Southwest and Southeast. Albuquerque, NM: University of New Mexico Press (An Amerind Foundation Publication, Dragoon, AZ). Pomeranz, Kenneth (2000). Th e Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Ranta, E., V. Kaitala, and P. Lundberg (1998). “Population Variability in Space and Time: the Dynamics of Synchronous Populations,” Oikos. 83:376–382. Sciremammano, F. (1979). “A Suggestion for the Presentation of Correlations and their Signifi cance Levels,” Journal of Physical Oceanography. 9:1273–1276. Teggart, Frederick (1939). Rome and China: A Study of Correlations in Historical Events. Berkeley: University of California Press. Th omas, William L., ed. (1956). Man’s Role in Change the Face of the Earth, Vol. 1. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Turner, B. L. II, William C. Clark, Robert W. Kates, John F. Richards, J. T. Matthews, and William R. Meyer, eds. (1990). Th e Earth as Transformed by Human Action: Global and Regional Changes in the Biosphere over the Past 300 Years. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Turchin, Peter (2002). Complex Population Dynamics: A Th eoretical/Empirical Synthesis. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Turchin, Peter (2003). Historical Dynamics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press (in press). http://www.eeb.uconn.edu/faculty/turchin/hd.html Turchin, Peter and Sergey Nefedov (2004). Secular Cycles. Book MS in progress. Weiss, Harvey; M.-A Courty, W. Wetterstron, F. Guichard, L. Senior and A. Curnow (1993). “Th e Genesis and Collapse of Th ird Millenium North Mesopotamian Civilization,” Science. 261:995–1004. http://hist1.narod.ru/Science/Engl/Mainat.htm http://hist1.narod.ru/Science/Engl/Mainat.htm http://www.eeb.uconn.edu/faculty/turchin/hd.html Turchin & Hall