JWSR v12n2 - Complete Issue  Semiperipheries in the World-System: Reflecting Eastern European and Latin American Experiences* journal of world-systems research, xii, i, december , – http://www.jwsr.org/ issn 1076–156x © 2006 Manuela Boatcă the socialist experiment(s) – antisystemic or system-preserving? In terms of the potential for transformation with which it has been credited, the socialist solution to global inequality has been considered both among the most promising and among the most overrated political strategies of the past centuries. Especially after the concerted collapse of communist regimes in Eastern Europe and the allegedly defi nitive triumph of liberalism on a world- wide scale (Fukuyama 1992), the exhaustion of such potential became the politi- cal wisdom of the day. Scholarly attention accordingly shifted away from the competition within the formerly “bipolar” political system and toward an assess- ment of the postsocialist societies’ chances of moving from the Second World into the First, i.e., of “catching up” with the advanced capitalist countries. Yet, against the backdrop of Eastern Europe’s ever more clear Th ird-Worldization (Frank 1992:40ff ., Böröcz 1999:200), the negatively descriptive category of “postsocialism,” still not satisfactorily replaced or updated fi fteen years after This paper claims that, since many of the concepts relevant to our analysis of systemic change were coined in and about the core, the potential with which solutions to world- systemic crisis are credited in the long run should be assessed differently depending on the structural location of their origin. In the periphery, such concepts as conservatism, socialism and even liberalism took forms that often retained nothing of the original model but the name, such that strategies of applying them to (semi)peripheral situations ranged from “stretching the ideology” to “discarding the (liberal) myth” altogether. In a first step, “the hypothesis of semiperipheral develop- ment” (Chase-Dunn and Hall), according to which the semiperiphery represents the most likely locus of political, economical, and institutional change, is amended to say that, at least for the late modern world-system, the strength of the semiperiphery resides pri- marily in the cultural and epistemic sphere. In a second step, this contention is illus- trated with the help of major challenges that the Eastern European and Latin American (semi)peripheries have posed to the world- system’s political fields and institutional settings both in the past and to date—with different degrees of success corresponding to their respective structural position. In light of these examples, it is argued that a comparative analysis of continuities among political episte- mologies developed in the semiperiphery can help us understand the ways in which similar attempts can become antisystemic today. abstract: * Th is article goes back to a paper presented at the th Conference of the Political Economy of the World-System (pews), University of Massachusetts at Amherst, April –, . A shorter version endorsing the same argument while emphasizing the political aspect is forthcoming in: Joya Misra and Agustín Lao- Montes (eds.): Th e State Under Neoliberal Globalization, Paradigm Press: Boulder and London, . I thank Tom D. Hall, Agustín Lao-Montes, Joya Misra, and the anonymous reviewer for their comments and critique on earlier drafts of this paper. Manuela Boatcă Katholische Universität Eichstätt-Ingolstadt Lehrstuhl für Soziologie I Ostenstr. 26, 85072 Eichstätt Germany manuela.boatca@ku-eichstaett.de Manuela Boatcă mailto:manuela.boatca@ku-eichstaett.de http://www.jwsr.org Manuela Boatcă322 Semiperipheries in the World-System  the regime change, loses more of its explanatory value every day, as the region’s attractiveness for mainstream social science is dwindling. From a world-systems perspective, on the other hand, socialism was a polit- ical structure used by semiperipheral nations in order to adapt to stage four in the evolution of the modern world-system—the “consolidation” of the industrial capitalist world-economy (Wallerstein 2000:97). As in the case of the Russian Revolution of 1917, which marked the beginning of that stage, the emergence of socialist states was seen as an instance of the classic mercantilist technique of semi-with drawal from the world economy intended to stem a decline towards a peripheral status. Th e availability of core elements at the moment of “socialist revolutions,” Wallerstein pointed out, had made it much more likely for such a path to be chosen by Russia, China, and Cuba than by Th ailand, Liberia, or Paraguay—that is, by peripheral countries lacking both the manufacturing beginnings and the skilled personnel necessary for the successful application of a mercantilist strategy (Wallerstein 2000:100). Th us, world-systems analysts contend that through the allocation of a larger share of the world economic sur- plus, the socialist states had contributed to depolarizing the capitalist system and had therefore consolidated—not undermined it—as the Cold War ideology implied. More important than on the economic level, however, was the equally stabilizing function they performed on the political level (Wallerstein 2000:91). By preventing the unifi ed opposition of all non-core areas against the upper stratum, the emergence of socialist countries as a middle stratum—both agent of and subject to exploitation—had fi lled the required intermediate slot by which semiperipheral states, regardless of their economic roles, had ensured the survival of the modern world-system since its inception. Hence, while their eco- nomic function remains signifi cant for the system’s operativeness, it is primarily the political task that accounts for diff erences among semiperipheral countries.¹ To world-systems analysts, then, the collapse of Eastern European communist regimes 1989 through 1991, rather than heralding the triumph of liberalism as the systems’ leading geoculture, had actually underscored the increasing lack of legitimacy of both liberalism and Marxism as the system’s ideological under- pinnings (Wallerstein 1991b:2). ¹. “Th e essential diff erence between the semiperipheral country that is Brazil or South Africa today and the semiperipheral country that is North Korea or Czechoslovakia is probably less in the economic role each plays in the world- economy than in the political role each plays in confl icts among core countries” (Wallerstein :). the transformative potential of semiperipheries Comparative world-systems studies later built and expanded on this par- ticular case with a view to providing an explanation of fundamental trans- formations in systemic logic in the long run. According to the “hypothesis of semiperipheral development” (Chase-Dunn 1988:31), both system structures and modes of accumulation are often transformed as a result of institutional and organizational changes occurring in semiperipheral areas. On account of being the most likely location in which social, institutional and technological inno- vation, new centers of resource control, and transformational actors will fi rst emerge in the system, the structural position of the semiperiphery as such there- fore comes with “developmental (or evolutionary) signifi cance” (Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997a:79). Th is is not only true of previous world-systems, but also of the modern one, all of whose successive hegemons—the Netherlands in the seventeenth century, Great Britain in the nineteenth, the United States in the twentieth—have previously been semiperipheral states (Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997b:432). More importantly still, “the rise of the West” to the core of the modern world-system can be reasonably interpreted as an instance of semi- peripheral development within the larger Afroeurasian system of the fi fteenth century (Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997b:408). Th e logic behind this argument rests on a twofold premise: on the one hand, as regions located between competing core and peripheral zones, mixing both core and peripheral organizational forms, and displaying institutional features halfway between those in the (proximate) core and those in the (proximate) periphery (Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997a:78, Chase-Dunn 2005), semiperipheral areas enjoy what has been variously theorized² as the “privilege of historic back- wardness” (Trotsky 1932:4). Access to the latest technologies, unencumbered, however, by the costs of empire, as well as a lesser vulnerability to combined attack from core competitors (Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997b:414) foster a condi- ². Systematically dealt with for the fi rst time within evolutionary cultural anthro- pology (Sahlins and Service ), the innovative potential inherent in a region’s lack of specialization and the greater developmental success resulting from it had been pre- viously theorized with respect to the “late industrializers” in terms of the “advantage of backwardness” (Gerschenkron ) or the “merits of borrowing” from an already- industrialized neighbor (Veblen , in: Sahlins and Service :) allowing late- comers to “skip stages” of their predecessors’ industrial evolution (Trotsky :). Th e diff erent wording notwithstanding, Chase-Dunn and Hall (a:) consider these and other related approaches as akin to their own view that a semiperipheral location is a fruitful locus of transformational changes. Manuela Boatcă324 Semiperipheries in the World-System  tion allowing intermediate areas to develop an increasing comparative advan- tage relative to the core and gradually come to dominate the system. On the other hand, the semiperiphery’s intermediate structural position in the world-system provides the best-suited ground for successful antisys- temic movements. While core exploitation of the periphery accounts for the formation of a large middle-class segment and of a labor aristocracy in the core, both of which have habitually acted to the detriment of political polar- ization, class struggle in the periphery has either been suppressed by core intervention or has taken a back seat in favor of nationalist class alliances against the core (Chase-Dunn 2001:606). By contrast, the semiperiphery has enjoyed the particular condition arising from the “double antinomy of class (bourgeois-proletarian) and function in the division of labor (core-periphery)” (Wallerstein 1979:96f.) inherent to this structural position. As a result, both its liberation movements and its socialist revolutions have gained from the confl icting interests of semiperipheral elites and masses, and have accordingly been more class-based and more militant in character than either in the core or the periphery—a luxury they could aff ord not least due to the availability of relative economic and military strength needed in order to counter retaliation on the part of the core. Hence, in this view, the establishment of communist regimes in the semiperiphery and the strong antisystemic challenge they posed to core capitalism in terms of providing an oppositional ideology, transform- ing the dominant mode of accumulation, and limiting the mobility of capital (Chase-Dunn 2001:604) stand proof of the transformative potential of such intermediate positions in the structural hierarchy. Together with the fact that previous semiperipheral locations of other revolutionary movements and politi- cal struggles, such as Mexico, Brazil, or India, resurface today as sites of organi- zational innovation with great transformative capacity,³ this seems to indicate a pattern of structural continuity in semiperiphery-based antisystemic strate- gies (Chase-Dunn 2001:602). In terms of the analysis of current antisystemic movements and the projection of future trends, therefore, the acknowledgment of such continuities entails that substantiated knowledge of the context and dynamics of earlier struggles and the theoretical approaches in which they were anchored acquires momentous relevance for a proper understanding of possible counter-hegemonic scenarios and their political consequences. ³. For an analysis of the radicalization of protest in response to new forms of dependency in today’s Brazil, see Schwartzmann ; for several case studies con- cerning the new coalitions between civil society actors protesting the activities of mul- tinational corporations in India, see Randeria . Drawing on this position, this article will contend that, in the late modern world-system, the semiperiphery⁴ remains a relevant locus of long-term social change, whose strength however now predominantly resides in the cultural and epistemic sphere. Using examples of major challenges that semiperipheral actors in Eastern Europe and Latin America have posed to the world-system’s political fi elds and institutional settings both in the past and to date, it will be argued that a comparative analysis of continuities among political epistemolo- gies developed in the semiperiphery can help us understand the ways in which similar attempts can become antisystemic today. Th at the very structural position meant to ensure both the political and the economic stability of the world-system should at the same time perform the very opposite function—that of generating antisystemic strategies—is para- doxical at fi rst glance. If the very causal explanation accounting for the devel- opment of the system by means of hegemonic cycles is also meant to account for its demise, the logical question to be asked is why haven’t semiperipheral transformations proven antisystemic during previous hegemonic sequences? In order to provide an answer, a further dimension of semiperiphery-based change has to be factored in. semiperiphery revisited: the epistemological dimension of transformative processes In the capitalist world-economy, counter-hegemonic ideologies rooted in a diff erent cultural background than that of the dominant core have consti- tuted a frequent means of challenging core power from semiperipheral loca- tions. To this eff ect, Chase-Dunn and Hall mention both Protestantism—as a religion of the semiperiphery that democratized access to the deity and under- mined Spain’s religious and political authority in the process (Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997a:94)—and the equally semiperipheral communism—as a funda- ⁴. Th e concept of “semiperiphery” as discussed here follows the treatment given it by Wallerstein (), Chase-Dunn (), Arrighi and Drangel (). I agree with Burns et al. () and Terlouw () that the term is undertheorized relative to the notions of “core” and “periphery” and that further subdivisions within the semiperiph- ery would help account for the widely diff erent levels of economic, political, technologi- cal and military strength of countries counting as semiperipheral. For the purposes of the present argument, however, the distinction between the “semicore” and the “semi- periphery” proposed by Kick () and Burns et al. () is however deemed inad- equate for helping to explain the task of all intermediate positions of absorbing and/or resolving tensions between the core and the periphery. Manuela Boatcă326 Semiperipheries in the World-System  mentally oppositional ideology that, at least in principle, called into question the capitalist logic of ceaseless accumulation. Th ey however consider both to be merely types of institutional innovations. Yet for semiperipheral areas to be able to generate new institutional forms capable of transforming both system structures and modes of production, as this perspective suggests, the search for the particular operative rationale on which these forms are based has to be prompted by a diff erent cultural and epistemic logic—one that, as Walter Mignolo has put it, changes the terms, not just the content of the conversa- tion (Mignolo 2000:16). It thus follows that antisystemic initiatives emanat- ing from today’s semiperipheries tend to operate less on the mere institutional and/or state level and rely instead on transforming the world-system’s geopo- litical imaginary by advancing new epistemological perspectives. Hence, while semiperipheral locations have no doubt produced a disproportionate share of signifi cant economic, political and organizational advance, the most promising challenges to the capitalist logic currently consist in the critical utopias being developed within the World Social Forum (a process initiated and consolidated in the Brazilian semiperiphery and gradually expanding into other semiperiph- eral areas) (Quijano 2002, Santos 2004) or inherent in theoretical revolutions such as the one advanced by the Zapatistas (in the Mexican semiperiphery) (Mignolo 2002). It can thus reasonably be argued that the tension between the stabilizing and the counter-hegemonic functions of semiperipheries belongs to the series of internal contradictions that, according to the logic Wallerstein has identifi ed for all historical systems in general and the modern world-system in particular, are exacerbated by the secular trends to the point of bringing about the system’s demise (Wallerstein 1991b:24f.). In the case of the semipe- ripheries, this translates as saying that, in the course of the system’s evolution, their transformative potential has gone from providing a stimulus for upward mobility (challenging the core’s hegemony) to engendering antisystemic strate- gies. As such, the extension of the “hypothesis of semiperipheral development” into the cultural-epistemological realm does not contradict the view according to which the semiperiphery is “the weak link ” in the capitalist world-system (Chase-Dunn 2001:606, Chase-Dunn 2005:174)—it merely amends it by an additional—yet crucial—dimension. Competing for a Voice: Non-Core Attempts at Shaping the System’s Political Imaginary From a postcolonial point of view, the present-day structural positions of core and periphery not only mirror economic and political tasks within the international division of labor, but also the epistemological divides between “developed” and “underdeveloped” societies which the Eurocentric perspective of knowledge accompanying the “rise of the West” helped put in place as of the 16t century. Accordingly, the expansion of the capitalist world-economy went hand in hand with the production of truth claims about the newly colo- nized areas intended to legitimize the system’s basic logic: “Th e construction of ‘pathological’ regions in the periphery as opposed to the so-called ‘normal’ development patterns of the ‘West’ justifi ed an even more intense political and economic intervention from imperial powers. By treating the ‘Other’ as ‘underdeveloped,’ as ‘backward’, metropolitan exploitation and domination were justifi ed in the name of the ‘civilizing mission’ ” (Grosfoguel 2000:370). Th e peripheral areas’ acceptance or even internalization of the system’s succes- sive “global designs” (Mignolo 2000)—whether Christianization, the civilizing mission, Marxism, or neoliberalism—amounted to a “silencing” in terms of the production of knowledge, thereafter defi ned and controlled from the local his- tories of Western Europe (and North America). By contrast, intermediate world-systems positions have in this respect been subjected to the same contradictory yet stimulating tendencies that char- acterize their social and economic development. Historically, this has meant benefi ting from two conditions: fi rst, not being the core entailed experiencing situations of political and economic domination akin to the ones in peripheral areas and facing the need to develop theoretical and practical solutions to them. Second, not being the periphery amounted to a certain degree of visibility in the production of knowledge, which intellectual projects in the “silenced societ- ies” of peripheral areas did not enjoy. Th e discursive practices of the core easily illustrate the diff erent epistemological standing of the semiperiphery to that eff ect: unlike the peripheral Orient, which was constructed as an incomplete Other of Europe and as the locus of barbarism, irrationality, and mysticism (Said 1994:49ff .), the semiperipheral Balkans, to which too many of the attri- butes that had gone into the construction of the (white, Christian, European) Western self were undeniable, have featured in the Western imaginary rather as Europe’s incomplete Self (Todorova 1997:18) since at least the nineteenth century. Geographically European (by 20t century standards, at any rate), yet culturally alien by defi nition, the Balkans, as the Orient, have conveniently absorbed massive political, ideological and cultural tensions inherent to the regions outside the Balkans, thus exempting the West from charges of racism, colonialism, Eurocentrism and Christian intolerance while serving “as a reposi- tory of negative characteristics against which a positive and self-congratulatory image of Europe and the ‘West’ has been constructed” (Todorova 1997:60). Similarly, and at approximately the same time, “Latin” America as an explicit political project of imperial France and, later, of Creole elites in the Manuela Boatcă328 Semiperipheries in the World-System  former Spanish and Portuguese colonies of the Americas started playing the role of a new racial category, primarily defi ned by its marginal status with respect to Europeans and North Americans, rather than by blood descent and skin color (Mignolo 2005:73, Wallerstein 2005a:32). Until World War II, the diff erence attributed to the region with regard to the West was, as in the case of Eastern Europe, more one of degree than one of substance: “although ‘Latin’ American Creoles and elite Mestizos/as considered themselves White, particu- larly in relation to the Indian and the Afro population…, from the perspective of Northern Europe and the US, to be ‘Latin’ American was still not to be White enough” (Mignolo 2005:90). By being gradually associated with those racial, cultural, and temporal attributes that had acquired a negative conno- tation in the context of the self-defi nition of the modern West—non-White, Catholic, and underdeveloped—“Latin America” served in particular as an asymmetric counterconcept for North America in the Occidental construction of Otherness (Feres 2003, 2005). Th e fact that this discursive (mal)treatment should apply to South America and East-Central Europe, whose early incorporation into the modern world- system as areas of coerced labor has made them into “the fi rst large-scale labora- tories of underdevelopment” (Szlajfer 1990:1) is therefore no coincidence. While the structural similarities between the two regions in terms of their imputed “backwardness” are sometimes acknowledged as causes for the emergence of their respective “second serfdoms” (Malowist 1966, Stahl 1993, Wolf 2001), their similar theoretical strategies for the conceptualization of this condi- tion—themselves structural responses to that socioeconomic situation—are rarely perceived as such. Th e reason, as will be suggested in the following, lies not only in the diff erent timing at which the concerns were voiced in the two locations—starting in the late 19t century for Eastern Europe and in mid-20t century for Latin America—but also, and more importantly, in the dissimilar opportunity structure for making these theoretical strategies visible beyond regional (or even state) borders. Given the close link between structural location and valid theoretical pro- duction in the logic of Western modernity, the intellectual division of labor among world-system positions places theory, together with civilization and cul- ture, in the core, while consigning the periphery to an object of study of the former and thus to the status of “silenced societies” in terms of the production of knowledge (Mignolo 2000:73, Mignolo 2005:109). Accordingly, at the same time that awareness of peripheral conditions was enhanced in most semiperiph- eral areas by their own previous experience of peripherality, the knowledge thus produced only obtained a hearing within Western cultures of scholarship once the respective areas ascended into intermediate positions in the world-system. Th us, the radical theoretical challenge which dependency theory and liberation philosophy posed to the hegemonic idea of Latin America in the 1960s (Mignolo 2005:91; 109) owed a signifi cant share of its success to the fact that, at the moment of its emergence, most states in the region had either already attained semiperipheral status or were well on their way to it. From this position of mid- range visibility and power it was possible to advance a dissenting approach to development as a legitimate Th ird World response to the post-war world order (Mignolo 2000:54) for which the modernization school advocated a one-size- fi ts-all solution. By rejecting the dominant view of underdevelopment as a “stage” previous to development, and instead conceptualizing it as a “discrete histori- cal process through which economies that have already achieved a high level of development have not necessarily passed” (Furtado 1964:129), dependency theorists for the fi rst time denounced the core’s explanation for economic back- wardness and the corresponding “catching up” imperative for newly indepen- dent nations as “ideology disguised as science” (Dos Santos 1971:236). Against this background, the phrase “development of underdevelopment” (Frank 1966), meant to highlight what dependency theorists viewed as the essential connec- tion between the industrialization of the core and the economic specialization of the periphery on staple agricultural production, not only came to stand for the dependency perspective as such, but also for one of the most successful epis- temological shifts in the conceptualization of social change. Political Epistemologies in Turn-of-the-Century Romania In contrast, an equally dissident theoretical corpus dealing with the devel- opment of underdevelopment in the periphery and elaborated in Romania⁵ at the end of the 19t and the beginning of the 20t centuries never did obtain international hearing. In this case, the context of the country’s recent politi- cal independence from the Ottoman Empire and renewed peripheralization as Western Europe’s agrarian province made for the accidental geohistorical “edge” (Wallerstein 2000:89) usually considered decisive for a state’s initial eli- gibility for a particular structural position in the world-system. Th e economic ⁵. Th e three Romanian Principalities, Transylvania, Wallachia, and Moldavia, briefl y reunited in , only achieved political unity again in . Because the theo- ries to be discussed in the following were meant to apply to the development of all three provinces, the unifi cation of which had been a long-standing political goal, reference is made to “Romania” in the remainder of this article. For a discussion of the intellectual debates of the th and th centuries in the context of the struggle for political unity, see Boatcă . Manuela Boatcă330 Semiperipheries in the World-System  and political peripheralization was therefore completed on the epistemological level by silencing the critical theories developed in the area⁶ and thus dampen- ing their antisystemic potential. Th is was all the easier in view of Romania’s solitary position with respect to the theoretization of backwardness within Eastern Europe at that time. While economic and political elites in late 18t and early 19t century Poland had diagnosed their country’s underdevelopment as a problem and had employed innovative economic ideas and measures in order to combat it, it wasn’t until after World War II that a critical awareness of under- development crystallized in the region (Szlajfer 1990:3), as it would in Latin America. Th e dependentistas’ socialist solution to the structural underdevelop- ment of Th ird World countries, conceived as a response to the uniformizing tendencies advocated by modernization theory in the 1960s, would amount to an opting out of the international division of labor. In turn, the Romanian theo- rists of the late nineteenth century, faced with a period of interregnum or with what has been called “the shift of peripheral axis” (Bădescu 2004:82ff .) from the periphery of the Ottoman Empire to that of the Western core, were more concerned with controlling the degree of self-determination that incorporation into the world-system entailed. Th eirs was therefore a search for a moderniza- tion process tailored to the country’s specifi c needs and the solutions off ered covered a wide range of options and political stances with potential for systemic change. Th eir starting point was the “theory of forms without substance,” elabo- rated in 1868 by the conservative Titu Maiorescu (1840–1917). As a result of the economic and cultural opening toward the West, Romania’s liberal government of the time had encouraged the adoption of Western laws and institutional structures thought to stimulate a corresponding level of development. Yet, given the country’s position at the crossroads between three empires—the Austro- Hungarian, the Tsarist, and the Ottoman one—the thorough social change the imported cultural forms induced, Maiorescu warned, instead endangered state sovereignty. A peasant country like Romania, he argued, had not been prepared by anything in its history to receive all the “outer forms” of civilization in the absence of “the deeper historical foundations which with necessity produced” ⁶. World-systems theorists were the fi rst to draw attention to the precursory character of the early th century Romanian theories for the analysis of underdevel- opment (Chirot , Stahl ). With few exceptions (see Love ), the theories’ treatment within the larger context of social scientifi c approaches to underdevelop- ment however remained marginal. (Maiorescu 1973a:164) them and it lacked the means to support them—indus- trial production and a middle class. Contrary to the liberals’ claims, imported superstructural forms did not foster progress, but only concealed the power structures inherent in the relationship between Western and Eastern Europe (Maiorescu 1973b:239), the better to exploit the latter. Th e costs of “moderniza- tion,” Maiorescu noted one century in advance of the dependentistas, can only be assessed by considering both terms of the relationship, not by mandating modernity in self-contained societies. Consequently, Romania’s sole possibility of preserving national independence throughout the process of modernization and of realizing her evolutionary potential depended on her providing a spe- cifi c—cultural, economic, and political—foundation to match and sustain the adopted forms. Suspicious of the liberals’ fi rm belief in progress as mankind’s universal law and in civilization as a superior stage of social evolution, the conservative Maiorescu instead emphasized organicity, gradual change, and the need for critical rethinking of wholesale cultural imports. With the help of this “double critique”—that he undertook from within modernity as a conservative, but from its outside as an intellectual of the system’s periphery—Maiorescu laid the groundwork for viewing the borderline between the Western core and the Eastern European periphery as a new locus of enunciation of radically diff erent solutions to social and political change. In the course of the intellectual debates his theory engendered in the decades that followed, the classical political doctrines associated with the con- tenders’ main ideological positions—themselves imported cultural forms— experienced a substantial reinterpretation in accordance with the peripheral status for which they were meant to account. Such attempts to fi t political and socioeconomic writings into Western ideological categories, however, have con- stantly led to misconceptions about most critical knowledge produced in this and other non-core societies. While the “gigantic liberal-Marxist consensus” (Wallerstein 1991b:182) in the core postulated that peripheral development was to be induced by replicating Western development in backward countries on a “stage-by-stage” basis, the conservatives’ departure from this model consisted only in viewing such replication as undesirable, not in questioning its results (Wallerstein 1991b:55). In constrast, the periphery as an epistemological point of departure presupposed the fi ltering of the Western ideological notions through the perspective of the national concerns imposed by a geopolitical and historical context that diff ered from the one on which the political ideologies of the core had been tailored. Given the politically dependent status of most other nations in the region until 1918, these concerns only became apparent as national prob- lems only after independence. Th is explains why, before that date, the state, Manuela Boatcă332 Semiperipheries in the World-System  local economic interests, and the encroachment of foreign capital upon both were contextualized rather within the frame of Russian, Austro-Hungarian and German nationalism in Poland, Hungary, Slovenia, the Czech lands, the Baltic states, and Ukraine (Szlajfer 1990:83). In Romania, eff orts of applying political doctrines of (and about) the core to the development of the periphery ranged from “stretching” the classical liberal doctrine by declaring the anomalies exceptional to “discarding” it altogether as a myth (see Boatcă 2003:120). While both will be addressed in the following, it is especially in this second set of solutions that the main contribution of the Romanian debates to the transformation of the Eurocentric systemic rational- ity resides. Translating the Periphery in Liberal Terms Th e liberal response with which the historian and economist Alexandru Xenopol (1847–1920) counteracted Maiorescu’s theory illustrated the fi rst of the two strategies. Although he, much like Maiorescu, pressed for specifi c instead of universalist solutions to development and viewed the economic specialization of agrarian countries as a danger to their state independence, Xenopol argued that all progress took place from forms to substance and that the import of liberal principles was inherently progressive. At the same time, he diagnosed the dependency of small, underdeveloped countries on industrial nations as a structural problem the cause of which he identifi ed in the unequal exchange between the Western European industrialized core and its agrarian suppliers in the periphery. Free trade, he contended, was a means of exploitation, and the international division of labor the organizational structure within which it was promoted. Moreover, the peripheral countries’ reliance on unskilled and hence cheap agricultural labor prompted the emergence of a non-productive middle class in the service of the State—itself, according to Xenopol, the biggest con- sumer—thus additionally saddling the peasant masses. By yielding a middle class made up of functionaries and “professionals,” the dependent economic context gave rise to an internal division of labor that was in itself no longer self-sustaining, let alone capable of generating profi t. Xenopol viewed unequal exchange, his country’s economic dependency, as well as the changes wrought in its class structure by the export-oriented economy as the aggregated result of the free trade policy maintained by the State and advocated by the industrialized countries. Th e Western countries themselves, however, had not become rich by practicing free trade, he noted. Quite the contrary, it was during mercantilism, a time of government intervention, that their economies had experienced the most signifi cant growth. Th e dominant anti-protectionist stance of his time, then, could not be supported historically, but had an ideological character moti- vated by the core countries’ (by which the economist chiefl y meant England and France) own economic interests. It was, in his words “theory at the service of a practice” (Xenopol 1882:95). Xenopol therefore suggested that Romania should discard the free trade policy advocated by the West, which only served Western economic interests, and instead adopt protectionism, promote large-scale industry, and rely on state investment. Paradoxically, this was in his view the task of the liberal govern- ment, whose policy—adapted to the needs of a peripheral country—Xenopol dubbed “new liberalism”: Until now, we have been ideologues; we used to think that wealth and well- being could result from theoretical creations. We were only concerned with laws which changed the outer form of our institutions, without trying to transform the very substance of our life. (Xenopol :) Consequently, Xenopol saw it as his duty to “dislodge the ideologies” of socio- logical theories. Th e concrete form this took, in his case, involved the search for a strategy of national development, since the situation of cultural and eco- nomic backwardness that he described was important to the extent that it was a national issue. Th e fi rst step in the transition from ideology to science accordingly consisted in abandoning the claim to a universal science and to corresponding universal principles of economic development such as those inherent in classic liberalism’s doctrine of laissez faire. Instead of an individual party policy, “new” liberalism should become a state platform and as such take responsibility for inducing development and promoting industrialization. Th e issue of industrialization itself, more than just a good illustration of the periphery’s general evolutionary potential, was “not only a question of gain, but one of civilization, …not one of gain, but one of nationality” (Xenopol 1882:86), and as such stood in close con- nection with a liberating economic and political course: “…crying out for liberty in a plainly agricultural country is in vain, for liberty is only possible where there are free people, and free people only exist in a country in which industry plays a signifi cant role” (Xenopol 1882:83).⁷ Th e “people,” in this understanding, constituted the unit of progress at the national level, in which national ethnic- ity (as an intermediate human nature in between the individual and mankind) was articulated. Work enhancement at the level of the national economy and in international exchanges, capable of increasing the people’s well-being as well as ⁷. Emphasis in the original Manuela Boatcă334 Semiperipheries in the World-System  of justly distributing it, accordingly represented the right national strategy that the “new liberalism” was supposed to implement. Obviously, theorizing from within the concrete economic and social reali- ties to which Xenopol’s stance represented a response was hardly compatible with political impartiality. Consequently, his eff orts of “dislodging ideologies” had to confi ne themselves to exposing the core’s global designs as an expression of the local histories of Western societies, while at the same time providing as alternative an ideology suited to the local history of his own locus of enuncia- tion. In this particular case, this meant a departure from Western liberalism in favor of a kind of national or state liberalism, more appropriate for the eco- nomic imperatives of peripheral development. In the process, Xenopol antici- pated major concerns of both dependency theory and world-systems analysis, such as the ideological character of Western policies of development, the issue of unequal exchange, or the role of growing state bureaucracies in weakening the political and economic agency of the periphery (see Boatcă 2003:126-135). Peripheral Evolution – The Marxist Bent Th e amount of “stretching” that the socialist doctrine had to undergo before fi tting a peripheral pattern of development was even greater than in the case of liberalism. In the course of recurrent polemics with the Conservatives’ view of organic social evolution, the most prominent Romanian socialist, Constantin Dobrogeanu-Gherea (1855–1920), accounted for the discrepancy between Romania’s economic substance and her political and cultural forms by claim- ing that it constituted a common trait of so-called “semicapitalist countries” on their way to attaining “full capitalism” (Gherea 1908b:459). While attesting to a teleological understanding of social development, his categorization into semi- capitalist (or “backward capitalist”) and capitalist societies clearly also allowed for divergent evolutionary paths, in that it declared the apparent idiosyncra- sies Romania displayed in its transition to capitalism to be a common trait of peripheral regions, and as such consistent with the rule, not exceptions to it. It is on this basis that Gherea would consequently attempt to substantiate his “master idea”—rendering Romanian social history comprehensible by viewing it as an integral part of the expanding capitalist world-system—or, in his terms, of a “superior social organism” operating within “the historical capitalist epoch” (Gherea 1908a:483). According to the “law of the historical epoch” he formu- lated in 1908, it was the “bourgeois capitalism” of advanced industrial countries which imposed specifi c superstructural forms on the backward areas it targeted as new markets for its manufactured products: Backward countries enter the orbit of advanced capitalist ones, they move within the orbit of those countries and their whole life, development and social move- ment are determined by the historical epoch in which we are living, by the bour- geois capitalist epoch. And this determination of the life and social movement of backward countries by the advanced ones is their very condition of life.⁸ (Gherea a:) In terms of modifying the classical socialist doctrine in accordance with the social reality of the Eastern European periphery, Gherea’s formulation implied that the essentially economic causes of transition to a new mode of production predominantly occasioned superstructural (i.e., social and institutional) trans- formations in “less advanced” countries. In turn, his generalization of this rule to all peripheral countries still undergoing capitalist “transition” yielded the exact reverse of what Marxism had propounded, despite Gherea’s claim that it could be subsumed to the general principle: In backward countries, the transformation of social life forms, of juridical, political, social forms, occurs…before the development of that socio-eco- nomic basis which in advanced countries made possible or even created those political and juridical social forms….In capitalist countries, social forms follow after the social substance, in backward countries, it is the social sub- stance which follows after the social form. (Gherea :f.) Th e “new” form of organization of agricultural production that, follow- ing the comprehensive land reform of 1864, had legalized coerced work in the form of labor contracts, Gherea claimed, represented the direct consequence of Romania’s incorporation into the world division of labor, not a return to feudal relations of production. It had, however, proven disastrous to the national econ- omy, as the state started deliberately employing this form of labor control— which Gherea (1910) accordingly labeled “neoserfdom”—in order to fi nance the consumerist habits of its growing bureaucracy. Not only had the so-called “dem- ocratic-bourgeois” state become the biggest consumer, as Xenopol had noted, but it also deliberately employed the neoserf regime as a means to the primary end of a production oriented toward consumerism and squander: “Yet the capital of large property does not face a capitalist form of labor, free wage labor,…but actually serf labor under the guise of contractual, coerced labor. Th us, we pos- sess a double economical agrarian regime, an extraordinary regime: capitalist on the one hand, serf-based on the other…, whose existence for half a century is due only to the extraordinary advantages it holds for our economically domi- nant class” (Gherea 1910:95).⁹ Gherea’s description of Romanian “neoserfdom” as a new form of labor control established as a result of the capitalist penetration ⁸. Emphasis in the original ⁹. Emphases in the original Manuela Boatcă336 Semiperipheries in the World-System  of Romania’s economy, while diff erent from Engels’ “second serfdom,” prefi g- ured Wallerstein’s conceptualization of “coerced cash-crop labor” as an alterna- tive mode of labor control in those regions in which wage labor is less profi table for the world-economy as a whole.¹⁰ While he expected that socialism, too, would be brought to Romania from the outside in the context of the next historical epoch, Gherea also urged for a development policy that acknowledged the specifi city of Romania’s agrarian issue and the social ills derived from it to the country’s structural position in the world-system’s hierarchy. He therefore pleaded for a liberal solution that included industrialization, the adoption of universal suff rage, and the replace- ment of feudal “remnants” by “true” capitalist relations of production, which he viewed as a means to hasten the transition to full capitalism and to prepare the objective and subjective conditions for socialism. No doubt the doctrinary and determinist form which Gherea’s theory took—as in Xenopol’s case, an instance of “stretching the (socialist) ideol- ogy,”—was the expression of the same developmentalist philosophy underlying the civilizing mission that had prompted the Romanian intellectuals’ critical reactions in the fi rst place. Th e most innovative aspects of his theory, however, came precisely from applying that critical spirit by consciously theorizing across ideological commitments from and about the periphery. Poporanism – A Politics for Agrarian Peripheries Th e centrality of the peasant issue eventually made the testing ground on the basis of which the major Western political doctrines were discarded as inadequate for the agricultural periphery. Constantin Stere (1865–1936), founder of a cultural and political program whose label, poporanism, attested to its focus on “the people” (Romanian popor), maintained that internationalist doctrines such as Western liberalism and social democracy could not account for the national problem faced by a small, economically and culturally backward agrarian state situated between three military powers: “In its exceptional situ- ation, the Romanian people cannot pursue any revolutionary policy, nor aspire to the transformation of the very bases of social organization before the happier nations of the West. It still has to fi ght for its very national being, endangered both by its international situation…and by an abnormal social structure…which hinders the healthy development of national middle classes” (Stere 1996:208). ¹⁰. for a discussion of the diff erences and similitudes between Gherea’s, Engels’ and Wallerstein’s approach, see Stahl : , Love : , Boatcă : f., Boatcă :. Since, in purely agrarian countries such as Romania, it was the peasantry, not the proletariat, which overwhelmingly represented the working class, as Stere demonstrated with the help of statistical data, political signifi cance was accordingly devolved to this social category. Th e peasant class of agricultural peripheries could therefore no longer assume the passive political role that its counterpart played in industrial countries. Stere thus openly confronted Gherea by maintaining that, instead of awaiting European social transformation, agrar- ian nations had to devise a path to social progress based on their specifi c socio- economic problem—the peasant question—and on the corresponding political potential available to them (Stere 1996:183). In a deliberate delimitation from both the “new liberal” and the “peripheral socialist” solutions that Xenopol and Gherea had forwarded, Stere denounced protectionism as a “pathetic experiment,” the creation of large-scale industry in Romania as a “dream,” and the reversals of Western evolution in backward agrarian countries as indicative not simply of a diff erent sequence of evolution, but of an entirely diff erent course whose end point most likely was not, and could not be, industrial capitalism (Stere 1996:95; 108). His central argument to this eff ect was that, unlike Western colonial powers, Romania lacked both the amount of capital and the external markets for pursuing large-scale industri- alization, such that its evolution rather resembled that of Europe’s colonies: as in colonial contexts, Western fi nancial capital, “ransacking the world for prof- itable investment” (Stere 1996:116), acted in Romania as a kind of “vagabond capital,” proceeding to proletarianize the local work force in order to subse- quently “siphon off abroad the wealth thereby accumulated” (Stere 1996:117). Whereas, in its country of origin, vagabond capital benefi ted both capitalists and proletarians, its eff ects in the periphery in turn transferred the otherwise internal class struggle to the level of a global antagonism between bourgeois and proletarian nations. Th e notion of “vagabond capital,” as Stere conceived it, on the one hand claimed explanatory power for the “bourgeoisifi cation” of the proletariat in England (and for similar beginnings in Germany and the United States), which thus postponed the transition to socialism in those countries (an explanation remarkably resembling world-systems analysis’ take on the damp- ened class struggle in the core, as mentioned above), and, on the other hand, for the “proletarianization” of the entire work force in the exploited economies. In maintaining that “Vagabond capital, the foreign capital of backward countries, is none other than the commercial and fi nance capital—the antirevolutionary capital—of its country of origin”¹¹ (1996:120), Stere located the causes of macro- ¹¹. Emphasis in the original. Manuela Boatcă338 Semiperipheries in the World-System  structural change on a global level, thus seeing the development of underdevel- opment as an issue of the entire historical system. Socialist transformation, he concluded, could no longer be accomplished within one state, but only at the level of a world revolution—a prospect which he rejected as unrealistic. In the absence of the industrial capital giving rise to both the Western bourgeoisie and proletariat, the social structure of peripheral countries did not mirror that of core countries. Likewise, underdevelopment was not the outcome of social polarization, but of the action of a particular kind of capital, producing a particular kind of capitalism based on fi scal exploitation through local foreign agents. Consequently, the peripheral countries’ contribu- tion to a world socialist revolution could only take the form of a national strug- gle against this type of capital, incapable of organizing capitalist production in the countries which it penetrated and responsible for the antirevolutionary tendencies in its countries of origin. An agrarian and parliamentary reform, universal suff rage, a peasant party willing to defend the interests of the rural majority, and the organization of agricultural production into cooperatives on the basis of small and mid-scale peasant holdings, were Stere’s specifi c solutions for a modernization that, for the fi rst time since the beginning of the debates, did not equal Westernization. Given that this perspective on global class struggle between bourgeois and proletarian nations would only become formalized after World War II within dependency theory (see Emmanuel 1972) and virtually “institutionalized” within world-systems analysis, its emergence in turn-of-the-century Romania in the context of a controversy with orthodox Marxism and of a rejection of the Marxist-liberal philosophy of history based on the theory of forms without substance speaks for the fecundity of a peripheral standpoint in shaping the political imaginary of the system by means of a truly innovative political epis- temology. * * * Th e Romanian theorists’ consistent eff ort of addressing the concrete and the historical in their politically widely divergent views on social development only goes to show that, since many of the concepts relevant to our analysis of systemic change were coined in and about the core, the potential with which solutions to world-systemic crisis are credited in the long run should be assessed diff erently depending on the structural location of their origin. Concepts like Maiorescu’s “forms without substance,” Xenopol’s “unequal exchange,” Gherea’s “semicapitalist” countries and “neoserfdom,” as well as Stere’s “vagabond capi- tal” all represent attempts to outline specifi c realities of the modern world- system’s periphery for which hegemonic social science, centered around an abstract and universal “society,” had no labels. As such, they will be reinvented or independently discovered several times throughout the twentieth century (see Love 1996:175), in precisely those regions—most notably Latin America, but also China and Russia—which faced similar dependency contexts. During the following sequence of imperial control of Eastern Europe, the communist one, these and related theoretical approaches were condemned precisely along the lines of their national dimension, interpreted as a nationalistic and anti-progres- sivist stance. As a result, Titu Maiorescu’s works were banned from publication for their conservatism and alleged anti-progressivism, as were Xenopol’s for their liberalism, Gherea’s for his reformist stance toward the Marxist dogma, and Stere’s—paradoxically—for having opposed Gherea, and, with him, social- democracy. If some of their writings were partially recuperated and gradually republished in the 1960s and 1970s, this never occurred in the context of the authors’ connection with the theory of forms without substance, whose under- lying evolutionism and advocacy of organicity blatantly contradicted the offi cial communist doctrine of revolutionary transformation. Future Prospects As far as the potential political signifi cance of the peasant masses in non- core regions is concerned, current developments prove Stere’s one hundred year-old estimate correct. Th e scope and intensity of protests against neoliberal policies of land alienation, undertaken by ngo networks and social movements in India (Randeria 2003:50) or by the Landless Workers’ Movement¹² in Brazil, and the legal victories thereby achieved attest both to this social category’s anti- systemic capability and to the above-mentioned importance of acknowledging the long-term structural continuities and recurrent challenges of a global system in which, to some extent, plus ça change, plus c’est la même chose. However, if history repeating itself entails a reiteration of chances, it simul- taneously bespeaks a reiteration of risks. Th e collapse of communist regimes in Eastern Europe, taken as proof of the ideological bankruptcy of the socialist model, has prompted the proclamation of the “end of history” (Fukuyama 1992), i.e., the end of the search for political alternatives, as well as a corresponding ultraliberal trend toward privatization and anti-statism (Smith et al. 1999:6). In turn, the developmentalist view underlying both socialist and liberal regimes was ¹². Movimento dos Trabalhadores Rurais Sem Terra – Brazil’s landless workers movement, initiated in . It is now the largest social movement in Latin America, with an estimated . million members (see http://www.mstbrazil.org) http://www.mstbrazil.org Manuela Boatcă340 Semiperipheries in the World-System  replaced by the ideology of globalization (Wallerstein 2005b:323), promoting a withering away of the state to the benefi t of the self-regulating global market. For Eastern European societies, agreeing to the terms of this new “civilizing mission” meant being once again defi ned as “catching up” with the West and embarking on a supposed transition from the Second to the First World, whose conditions—in the form of eu regulations, imf “structural adjustment” policies and World Bank provisions—are being dictated by the latter. Economically, the parallels with the treatment to which Latin American countries were subjected during the 1950s and 60s in the name of modernization are striking. Politically and epistemologically, what is at stake for those ex-communist countries having long made the bone of contention of Europe’s powerful empires is the possibil- ity of a renewed shift of axis¹³—away from the semiperipheral identity of an Eastern bloc country and toward a yet-to-be-defi ned position within the “orbit” of the Euro-American core. Th e fact that this has been characteristic of the entire Eastern European zone since the so-called fall of the Iron Curtain and the beginning of the race for Europeanization becomes evident in the intel- lectual and political discourses of national elites in Croatia, Slovenia, Poland, Hungary, Bulgaria, and Romania, the common denominator of which is the constant downplaying of their countries’ “Eastern ness” and the corresponding emphasis on their will—indeed, their entitlement—to Westerni zation, seen as a “return to Europe” (Bakić-Hayden 1995, Lindstrom 2003, Boatcă 2007). While the political dimension of the core’s latest global design—whether promoted as globalization or Europeanization—aptly conceals the double stan- dard that allows a strengthening of core states’ apparatus even as it mandates the weakening of peripheral states’ sovereignty (Sassen 1996:27), its epistemological component entails the consistent dismissal of state-based policies, government intervention, and national concerns. With the resurgence of Balkanism as part of the Western geopolitical imaginary and the subsequent replacement of the “communist threat” by the “danger of nationalism” in Western media accounts of Eastern Europe, identifying and denouncing nationalism at home therefore became part and parcel of the strategy of political, economic, and intellectual alignment with the European norms embraced by the local political elites. Th is “anti-state ideological backlash” (Böröcz 1999:200), fuelled on the one hand by ¹³. Th e phenomenon that Bădescu has labelled the “shift of peripheral axis” is remarkably similar to the processes that Mitchell Allen () has found to character- ize so-called “contested peripheries” in pre-capitalist world-systems. While it cannot be dealt with at length here, Allen’s concept of the “contested periphery” might prove rewarding when applied to an analysis of Romania’s historical and present case. the delegitimization of (communist) states as agents for prosperity and by neo- liberalism’s promise of economic bounty on the other, acts in the form of a con- certed communist-cum-neoliberal epistemic control that old intellectual circles in dire need of legitimacy, as well as the newly emerged ultra-liberal intellectual and political elites of the region exert on past and present local knowledge pro- duction (Boatcă 2006). Th e Romanian theory of forms without substance and the decade-long debates on the issue of peripheral development it engendered, gradually restored to public memory in a series of sociological and cultural history stud- ies (Bădescu/Ungheanu 2000, Georgiu 2001, Bădescu 2004), have constituted one of the main targets of the “witch hunt” after dissenters from the ideologi- cal hegemony of anti-state discourse in the past 15 years. Th e intellectual dis- credit of approaches developed within this framework, once again defi ned as “nationalist”, “anti-progressive”, ultimately “Anti-European” on account of run- ning counter to the “liberal-Marxist consensus” underlying the modern world- system’s linear philosophy of history, has fi nally led to their political discredit as possible models for social transformation. In the context of a modernization/ globalization theory once again professing the adoption of (political and insti- tutional) forms without (economic and social) substance, Romania is on the one hand equipped with the developmental and antisystemic potential derived from a semiperipheral position, alongside the experience of peripherality and a rich theoretical heritage dealing with it. Th e chance to reassess and promote old solutions to a recurrent problem in the context of a vacuum of political hegemony is however stunted by the continued epistemic discredit of forms of resistance containing a national component, accordingly denounced as dubious scholarship and political dynamite (see Boatcă 2006). On the other hand, Eastern Europe’s “shift of axis” is paralleled by what has routinely been described as Latin America’s “shift to the Left” or “new left axis” in the wake of leftist electoral victories throughout the subcontinent during the past decade. Yet, in spite of echoing the socialist ambitions which the Cuban rev- olution had instilled in the early dependentistas and raising u.s. fears of regional instability on that account, the new leftward swing and the ensuing open policy of rapprochement with Cuba pursued by Brazil, Argentina, Venezuela, Bolivia, and Uruguay is only part of the story. Th e increasing political and institutional affi rmation of Indigenous social movements in Mexico, Bolivia, Ecuador, and Brazil, the emergence of Afro-Carribbean and Afro-Andean movements, and the gaining momentum of the World Social Forum as an epistemological alter- native to neoliberal globalization are part of a process of social and political subject formation that is indicative of a more radical transfor mation (Mignolo 2005; 2006, Quijano 2004). Th us, the unprecedented impact of the Movimento Manuela Boatcă342 Semiperipheries in the World-System  sem Terra in Brazil on the scope of land redistribution and reforms that a peas- ant movement can mobilize, the Afro movements’ claim to epistemic (rather than cultural) rights, and the idea that “there is no global social justice with- out global cognitive justice” that the World Social Forum in Porto Alegre has proposed as an epistemological alternative to the capitalist monoculture of knowledge (Santos 2004:13) reveal the fact that, today, “the key site of struggle” (Mignolo 2005:115) between what Immanuel Wallerstein has called “the spirit of Davos” and “the spirit of Porto Alegre” (Wallerstein 2005a:37) is the epis- temic realm: …the worldwide movement against neoliberalism showed its teeth fi rst at Chiapas, then at Seattle in 1999, and subsequently morphed into the World Social Forum, commonly referred to as Porto Alegre…. What we are seeing here is a geopolitical assertion of Latin America in the world-system. It involves pulling away from Western Hemisphere structures and moving toward Latin American structures, one that are also allied with what we used to call Th ird World structures. Th e game is scarcely over, and there is cer- tainly no guarantee how it will come out. But Latin@ identity, that is Latin American identity, is at the center of that eff ort. (Wallerstein 2005a:36f.) Against this background, rather than a “shift to the Left,” and thus toward a transformative politics that stays within the logic of the capitalist world-econ- omy, the current developments in Latin America have recently been described as a “decolonial shift” (Mignolo 2006) that attempts to transcend the Eurocentric notions of Left and Right by placing the emerging social and political agency of indigenous, subaltern and marginalized groups at the center of decision-making processes. Brazil’s growing importance in organizing resistance and providing alternatives to the neoliberal trade agenda in the period accompanying the con- solidation of the World Social Forum at Porto Alegre, the explicit inclusion of indigenous people’s rights in the agenda of the “Bolivarian revolution” in Venezuela, but especially the redistributive economic policies implemented in Bolivia by Evo Morales, the fi rst Indigenous president in South American his- tory, are seen as indicative of a political epistemology that points to an alterna- tive logic. Neither does the World Social Forum embody the internationalism associated with the anti-capitalist politics of the North in the twentieth cen- tury (Santos 2004:32), nor is the recent nationalization of Bolivia’s oil and gas reserves an instance of a state socialism of a Marxist bent, but these and similar developments in the South represent further stages in a process of decoloni- zation which has been under way for fi ve centuries (Mignolo 2006:94). Th eir current success is in part due to the unprecedented visibility—in this case, of resistance (Quijano 2002:18)—that a semiperipheral position in the world- system hierarchy entails for areas with a long peripheral past. In the end, rather than a “spiral” in which capitalism and socialism are mutually stimulating (Boswell and Chase-Dunn 2000:131ff .), their juxtaposed s(w)ay in Eastern Europe, alongside their lasting explanatory force as leading categories of the world-system’s geoculture as a whole instead gags semiperiph- eral locations for novel solutions to the world-systemic crisis. Th e interregnum at which the communist demise once again placed Romania—and with it, the whole of still-semiperipheral Eastern Europe—at the end of the twentieth cen- tury might therefore turn out to present an epistemological stake as well: suc- ceeding in claiming defi nition power for their own designs for social change and world-systemic transformation, alongside corresponding economic alternatives to the current model, could well become the new geohistorical edge deciding this—and other—semiperipheral regions’ renewed drift into the periphery. references Allen, Mitchell. . “The Mechanisms of Underdevelopment. An Ancient Mesopotamian Example.” Review  ():–. Arrighi, Giovanni, and Jessica Drangel. . “The Stratification of the World- Economy: An Exploration of the Semiperipheral Zone.” Review :–. Bakić-Hayden, Milica. . “Nesting Orientalisms: The Case of Former Yugoslavia.” Slavic Review  ():–. Bădescu, Ilie. . Sincronism european şi cultură critică românească. Cluj Napoca: Ed. Dacia. Bădescu, Ilie, and Mihai Ungheanu, eds. . Enciclopedia valorilor reprimate. Bucharest: Pro-Humanitate. Boatcă, Manuela. . From Neoevolutionism to World-Systems Analysis: The Romanian Theory of ‘Forms without Substance’ in Light of Modern Debates on Social Change. Opladen: Leske + Budrich. _________. . “Peripheral Solutions to Peripheral Development: The Case of Early th Century Romania.” Journal of World-Systems Research xi ():–. http://www.jwsr.org _________. . “Knocking on Europe’s Door: Romanian Academia Between Communist Censorship and Western Neglect.” South Atlantic Quarterly  ():–. _________. . “Define and Rule: The Role of Orientalism in. Re)Colonizing Eastern Europe.” Forthcoming in Islam and the Modern Orientalist World-System, edited by Khaldoun Samman and Mazhar Al-Zo’by. Paradigm: Boulder/ London. Boswell, Terry, and Christopher Chase-Dunn. . The Spiral of Capitalism and Socialism: Toward Global Democracy. Boulder/London: Lynne Riener. http://www.jwsr.org Manuela Boatcă344 Semiperipheries in the World-System  Böröcz, József. . “From Comprador State to Auctioneer State: Property Change, Realignment and Peripheralization in Post-State-Socialist Central and Eastern Europe.” In States and Sovereignty in the Global Economy, edited by David A. Smith, Dorothy J. Solinger, and Steven C. Topik. London & New York: Routledge. Burns, Thomas J., Davis L. Byron, and Edward L. Kick. . “Position in the World- System and National Emissions of Greenhouse Gases.” Journal of World-Systems Research :–. http://www.jwsr.org Chase-Dunn, Christopher. . “Comparing World-Systems: Toward a Theory of Semiperi pheral Development.” Comparative Civilizations Review :–. _________. . “World-Systems Theorizing.” In Handbook of Sociological Theory, edited by Jonathan Turner. New York: Plenum. _________. . “Social Evolution and the Future of World Society” Journal of World-Systems Research xi, , –. http://www.jwsr.org Chase-Dunn, Christopher, and Thomas D. Hall. a. Rise and Demise: Comparing World-Systems. Boulder, CO: Westview Press. _________. b. “Ecological Degradation and the Evolution of World-Systems.” Journal of World-Systems Research :–. http://www.jwsr.org Chirot, Daniel. . “A Romanian Prelude to Contemporary Debates about Development.” Review ii ():–. Dobrogeanu-Gherea, Constantin. a. “Post-scriptum sau Cuvinte uitate.” pp. – in Constantin Dobrogeanu-Gherea, . Opere complete. Vol. . Bucharest: Ed. Politică. _________. b. “Un mic răspuns la o mică recenzie.” In Constantin Dobrogeanu- Gherea. . Opere complete. vol. . Bucharest: Ed. Politică. _________. . Neoiobăgia. Studiu economico-sociologic al problemei noastre agrare. Bucharest: Socec. Emmanuel, Arghiri. . Unequal Exchange: A Study of Imperialism of Trade. New York: Monthly Review Press. Feres Jr., João. . “The History of Counterconcepts: Latin America as an Example.” History of Concepts Newsletter :–. _________. . A história do conceito de “Latin América” nos Estados Unidos. Bauru and São Paulo: edusc/anpocs. Frank, Andre Gunder. . “The Development of Underdevelopment.” Monthly Review  ():–. _________. . “Nothing New in the East: No New World Order.” Social Justice  ():–. Fukuyama, Francis. . The End of History and the Last Man. New York: Avon Books. Georgiu, Grigore. . Identitate şi integrare. De la disjuncţie la conjuncţie. Bucharest: Institutul de Teorie Socială. Grosfoguel, Ramón. . “Developmentalism, Modernity and Dependency Theory in Latin America.” Nepantla: Views from South  ():–. Kick, Edward. . “World System Structure, National Development, and the Prospects for a Socialist World Order.” In America’s Changing Role in the World- System, edited by Terry Boswell and Albert Bergesen. New York: Praeger. Lindstrom, Nicole. . “Between Europe and the Balkans: Mapping Slovenia and Croatia’s ‘Return to Europe’ in the ’s.” Dialectical Anthropology :–. Love, Joseph L. . Crafting the Third World: Theorizing Underdevelopment in Rumania and Brazil. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Maiorescu, Titu. a. “În contra direcţiei de astăzi.” In Critice by Titu Maiorescu. Bucharest: Minerva. _________. b. “Direcţia nouă.” In Critice by Titu Maiorescu. Bucharest: Minerva. Malowist, Marian. . “The Problem of the Inequality of Economic Development in Europe in the Latter Middle Ages.” Economic History Review xix ():–. Mignolo, Walter. . Local Histories/Global Designs: Coloniality, Subaltern Knowledge, and Border Thinking. Princeton: Princeton University Press. _________. . “The Zapatistas’s Theoretical Revolution: Its Historical, Ethical, and Political Consequences.” Review xxv ():–. _________. . The Idea of Latin America. London/New York: Blackwell. _________. . “Evo Morales en Bolivia: ¿giro a la izquierda o giro descolonial?” In Democracias en desconfianza: Ensayos en sociedad civil y politica en América Latina, edited by José da Cruz. Montevideo: Coscoroba. Quijano, Aníbal. . “El nuevo imaginario anticapitalista.” América Latina en movimiento  (xxvi):–. _________. . “El laberinto de América Latina: ¿Hay otras salidas?” Revista Venezolana de Economia y Ciencias Sociales  ():–. Randeria, Shalini. . “Cunning States and Unaccountable International Institutions: Social Movements and the Rights of Local Communities to Common Property Resources.” European Journal of Sociology xvi ():–. Sahlins, Marshall, and Elman R. Service (eds.). . Evolution and Culture. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Said, Edward W. . Orientalism. New York: Vintage Books. Santos, Boaventura de Sousa. . The World Social Forum: A User’s Manual. Madison. Retrieved November ,  http://www.ces.uc.pt/bss/documentos/ fsm_eng.pdf. Sassen, Saskia. . Losing Control? Sovereignty in an Age of Globalization. New York: Columbia University Press. Schwartzmann, Kathleen C. . “Globalization: The New Mechanism of Dependency.” In Globalization, Hegemony & Power: Antisystemic Movements and the Global System, edited by Thomas Ehrlich Reifer. Boulder and London: Paradigm Publishers. Smith, David, Dorothy Soliger, and Steven C. Topik (eds.). . States and Sovereignty in the Global Economy. London and New York: Routledge. Stahl, Henri H. . “Théories de C.D. Gherea sur les lois de la pénétration du capitalisme dans les ‘pays retardataires’.” Review ii():–. http://www.jwsr.org http://www.jwsr.org http://www.jwsr.org http://www.ces.uc.pt/bss/documentos/fsm_eng.pdf Manuela Boatcă346 _________. . “Théories des processus de ‘modernisation’ des Principautés Danubiennes et de l’ancien Royaume de Roumanie. –.” Review xvi ():–. Stere, Constantin. . Social-democratism sau poporanism? Galaţi: Porto Franco. Szlajfer, Henryk. . “Editor’s Introduction.” pp. – in Economic Natio n alism in East-Central Europe and South America –, edited by Henryk Szlajfer. Geneva: Librairie Droz. _________. . “Economic Nationalism of the Peripheries as a Research Problem.” pp. – in Economic Nationalism in East-Central Europe and South America –, edited by Henryk Szlajfer. Geneva: Librairie Droz. Todorova, Maria. . Imagining the Balkans. New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press. Trotsky, Leo. . The History of the Russian Revolution. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. Wallerstein, Immanuel. a. Geopolitics and Geoculture: Essays on the Changing World-System. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. _________. b. Unthinking Social Science: The Limits of Nineteenth-Century Paradigms. Cambridge: Polity Press. _________. . The Capitalist World-Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. _________. . “The Rise and Future Demise of the World Capitalist System.” pp. – in The Essential Wallerstein. New York: The New Press. _________. a. “Latin@s: What’s in a Name?” pp. – in: Latin@s in the World- System. Decolonization Struggles in the st Century U.S. Empire, edited by Ramón Grosfoguel, Nelson Mal donado-Torres, and José David Saldívar. Boulder and London: Paradigm Publishers. _________. b. “After Developmentalism and Globalization, What?” Social Forces  ():–. Wolf, Eric. . “The Second Serfdom in Eastern Europe and Latin America.” pp. – in Pathways of Power. Building an Anthropology of the Modern World. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press. Xenopol, Alexandru D. . “Comerţul exterior al României” pp. – in Studii Economice by Alexandru D. Xenopol, . Bucharest: Ed. Academiei Republicii Socialiste România. Boatcă