Bergesen 's Way Forward For World-System Theory After Gunder Frank Sing C. Chew Helmholtz Centre for Environmental Research-UFZ Leipzig, Germany sing .ch ew@ufz .de Gunder Frank's ReOrienting the J 9h Century, published posthumously, was based on a long-term project of an evolving five-thousand year old world system undertaken in partnership with Barry Gills in the early 1990s (Frank 1990, 1991, 1994; Frank and Gills 1992, 1993). This endeavor of Frank and Gills also produced a theoretically infused world system history of the making of the "modern" world. Frank ' s ReOrient: Global Economy in the Asian Age (RGEA) 1 was the first monograph of this theoretically informed world system history, and ReOrienting the J 9'h Century (Rl 9C) was the continuation volume. The latter, the topic of this symposium, despite being unfinished , resumes the argument of ReOrient: Global Economy in the Asian Age. ReOrient: Global Economy in the Asian Age questioned (theoretically and historically) the manner we have interpreted long-term social change , and especially, our common understanding of the timing of the rise of the European domination of the world economy /system (the 1500 divide), and therefore , the specific region that was the dominant power of the world system at the particular historical conjuncture. ReOrienting the J 9h Century further buttressed this line of argument that the periodization of European dominance, as has been commonly accepted, needed even further revisions. With these two volumes, Frank not only challenged the contemporary understanding (theoretically and historically) of the making of the "modem" world, but as well, the writings of his colleagues (such as Wallerstein, Arrighi, Amin, etc.) in world- systems analysis, and even his own contributions to world-systems analysis prior to the early 1990s. Following Frank's typical critical iconoclastic stance, even Femand Braudel was not spared (Frank 1994; Chew and Lauderdale 2010). Despite Gunder's numerous pleas, not too many in world-systems analysis pursued his demand for reorientation theoretically and historically in the rethinking of world history. In spite of this silence, in 1995, a core group of scholars from various disciplines, including Frank, convened in Lund (Sweden) to discuss the evolution of the world system /world-systems (Denemark et al. 2000). The product of the discussions was to engage and write world system history along a trans-disciplinary approach. It is best summed up by the title of the first volume of the group's collective research: World System History: The Social Science of Long- Term Change. Following this, numerous other world system history accounts of the making of the "modem" world were published (see, for example, Chase-Dunn and Hall 1997; Modelski and Thompson 1996; Chew 2001, 2007, 2008; Chase-Dunn and Anderson 2005; Gills and Thompson 2006 ; Modelski 2003; Modelski, Devezas, and 1 For a critical review of RGEA, see the contributions of Arrighi , Amin, and Wallerstein in Review vol. 22, no.3 , 1999. This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 United States License. Journal of World-Systems Research, Volume 21, Number 1, Pages 162-173, ISSN 1076-156X Bergesen' s Way Forward for W arid-System Theory 163 Thompson 2007). In this regard, Gunder Frank's monographs (RGEA and Rl9C) can be viewed as products of the World System History Group, and these two volumes should be considered as his last and lasting contributions to world system history. Bergesen's Way Forward: Forget History, Long Live Empiricism! Bergesen's article for consideration in this symposium, World-System Theory After Andre Gunder Frank, proposes to use some of the deliberations of Frank and Gills' conceptualization of the five thousand year-old world system as the way forward for world-system theory. His starting point, ontologically and epistemologically, is that we accept an "objective, non-theoretically constructed, facts-defined world, or global economy, to which can then be applied and evaluated the PEWS or any other model. .. rather than trying to explain the object (world-economy)" that "is fused with its theoretical explanation" (Bergesen 2015). Some might find this dictum welcoming, while others might not. I suspect even Gunder Frank might have difficulty making this shift, for in Rl9C he wrote: "Not surprisingly, the further back we go through history, the scarcer and less reliable become the hard and especially quantitative data. Beyond these "natural" or "scientific" limitations, we run into essentially ideological ones. The selection of data to research and publish, and especially of those not to examine, is largely a function of the interests of the chronicler or researcher" (2014: 75). For those of us who are trying to re-think world history, it has always been an exercise of utilizing a history infused theory and a theory infused history to explain world development, hence the phrase, world system history. Notwithstanding this minor objection, let's proceed to consider the other elements ofBergesen's proposals. Bergesen's First Proposal Bergesen's going forward plan recommends dropping the concept of capitalism as a mode of production underlining the world-economy when dealing with the post-1500s global changes, and to realize the theoretical utility of his "world-system based globology approach." He joins Gunder Frank (1991) in dismissing the utility of the capitalist mode of production framework in understanding and explaining long-term change. Bergesen's argument, based on an ontological understanding of what is capitalism by definition, is rather straightforward. Because world-systems theory's level of analysis is the world- economy or world economy, and the capitalist mode of production theoretically belongs to the national level defined by worker-owner social relations guaranteed by a national state, "capitalism, as a mode of production, remains a societal/national entity"; he suggests that there is an issue in terms of translation-utilizing a concept that is based at the national level and employing it at the global level, though as he has correctly suggests, it has not prevented Lenin and Hobson from doing so. This "theoretical error" of Lenin and Hobson that starts from national accumulation, and then leads to the export of capital for further accumulation ( exemplified by imperialism as the final stage of capitalism) on the world scale has to be dropped, according to Bergesen, if we intend to undertake a world-system level analysis. What Bergesen has done is accept the position taken by Lenin as the only theory on the circuit of capital accumulation. The work of the 164Journal of World-System Research late Rosa Luxemburg (1968), a contemporary of Lenin and Trotsky, offers us a much different formulation of the nature of the capitalist mode of production. Her theoretical edifice starts from the position that the circuit of capital accumulation involves different geographic zones/groups (that are capitalist, non-capitalist, protocapitalist, etc.), which capital absorbs/includes in its accumulation process. Hence, for Luxemburg capital accumulation has been a world-scale process since its inception, and not necessarily one starting from national accumulation and then the export of capital (globally) in the form of imperialism for global accumulation. 2 Whereas Bergesen utilizes ontological and epistemological assertions to dismiss the world-system as having a capitalist mode of production in the post-1500 era, Frank's ( 1991) dismissal of using capitalism as a mode of production to understand the evolution of the world system is based mostly on his fervent insistence that the only "correct" route to understand long-term change or system transition is a world systemic analysis based on history and theory. In Frank's case, his declaration that feudalism, capitalism, and socialism are transitional ideological modes that has put blinders on our eyes, and thus has prevented us from really understanding and explaining the course of world history, is based on an examination of the historical processes of global history, and whether the characteristics of capitalism existed prior to 1500-hence, his 'continuity thesis.' Frank's rejection was historically based, and not derived from ontological and epistemological shifts of the sort Bergesen has proposed for world-system theory after Frank. Is Frank successful in convincing us to discount the need to use, in his terms, these ideological modes and myths that have imprisoned our world-system/world system analyses? RGEA and RI 9C are supposed to provide the historical information-theoretical reformulations to substantiate his claims. Bergesen's Second Proposal Frank's RGEA and RI 9C propose that we consider seriously analyzing the trading patterns and networks in terms of volumes of trade flows at the world system level in order to understand the course of world development, and to distinguish the economic and financial trends according to the different regions of the world economy. Because of his demand that everything has to be considered at the world level, bilateral trading flows do not capture the socioeconomic historical reality of what really happened in world history. A historical multilateral trading pattern analysis would be more precise in determining the relative dominance of the world system, and therefore, in socioeconomic and political terms, the real hegemonic region of the world system that is not ideologically derived and mythically reinforced. Frank's new 'mode of analysis' continues to mirror his previous mode of analysis, pre- and post- early 1990s, by focusing still on the "exchange" moment of the circulation of capital instead of directing his gaze more on the "production" and the "consumption" moments of the capital accumulation 2 See Wallerstein (1980) for a theoretical-historical twist of Lenin's accumulation thesis within the perspective of world-systems analysis. Bergesen' s Way Forward for W arid-System Theory 165 circuit that world-systems analysis a la Wallerstein has done much to explain. 3 This is very clear in RGEA and RI 9C, and especially in RGEA. Bergesen, following Frank, suggests that world-system theory drop the core- periphery relational economic form of analysis and shift to a multilateral structural model of trade triangles based on positional placements (location) in the matrix. Added to this change should be a political economic dimension so that control and power can then be brought into the picture. This will better serve us to understand the relationship between the dominant region/power and the dominated in terms of economic resources that are derived by the dominant. According to Bergesen, this is how Frank in RI 9C has been able to explain Britain's position in Frank's revised dating of British hegemony in the late 19th century. In both RGEA and RI9C, Frank's argument was to deny it was Britain's indigenous assets and forces that led to Europe's domination of the world economy-a widely-accepted position that Frank sought to dismiss. 4 To do this, it is understandable that Frank has to rely on external factors and the world system level model to dismiss what he has deemed a Eurocentric explanation for European domination of the world economy. A theory-sensitized search for the historical information was mounted, collected, and marshaled quite convincingly for this dismissal in RI 9C. I am sure there are, and will be, critiques on the periodization, the data, and other historical information that have been presented by Frank, besides his lack of sensitivity to the role of indigenous ideas and knowledge that precipitated Britain's and Europe's rise to global dominance. Notwithstanding these critiques, which one can either treat as minor or even dismiss, the important contribution of Frank is that he is trying to offer an alternate explanation of past historical moments in world development and the historical processes that have produced such a course of world history. Bergesen (2015), however, proposes the opposite: that we should just research multilateral trade structures, and that we should take a "radical departure from present efforts to map properties of the historical moment, or moments past, or speculate upon moments to come"-all of which he considers no longer very helpful for our world-systems enterprise. He characterizes current world- systems practioners' efforts to explain the dynamics of the world economy as similar to a dog chasing its tail; "each tum of a dog chasing its tail is somewhat different from the previous one, and research effort can either be spent noting the unique properties of each tum, or identifying the finite properties of the dog and the tail that generate these endless turns." He proposes doing the latter. His proposal, therefore, underscores the "continuity thesis" (see Chapter 3 of RI 9C for a historical application of this) that Frank and Gills have been arguing for since the early 1990s (see, for example, Gills 1996; Frank 1998): there is more continuity in terms of socioeconomic patterns and structures, especially the latter, than disruptions or dissipations of structures. In this sense, for example, there has been no break starting from 1500 onwards. Bergesen's proposal, notwithstanding his disavowal of the need to consider historical moments and historically informed theory, presents us with the same concerns I have raised in the past with Frank's continuity argument (Chew 2002). Historical 3 See the critique of Brenner (1977) of early world-systems analysis of Frank and W allerstein. Whereas W allerstein's later works looking at production commodity chains, households, and antisystemic movements have addressed Brenner's various criticisms, Frank has never fully responded to them, other than in his joint work with his late wife, Marta Fuentes on anti-systemic movements. 4 See for ex., the works of Goldstone (2002), Mann (1986), Jones (1981), etc. 166 Journal of World-System Research moments of ruptures and dissipations no longer are considered important to explain the course of world history, or for that matter, world system history. By declaring the theoretical irrelevance of the mode of production to explain the development pattern and the nature of change, Gunder Frank had diminished any specific contingent factors or processes that underline system transformation (and the change that follows) which the mode of production form of analysis had been able to furnish and distinguish. In other words, for Gunder Frank world development is distinguished by the economic cycles of expansion and contraction, center-periphery relations, hegemonic rivalry, etc. There is no specificity of a transformation for a particular historical epoch: "the rules of the game are not much altered so much as the position of the players" (1996: 44). Frank again repeated this in a draft version 5 of ReOrienting the 1