SAJEMS NS Vol I (1998) No 3 422 

An Economic Case 'for Regulating Against the 
Use of Non-Deposit Carrying Glass Containers 
of Beverage in South Africa 

SHosking 

Department of Economics, University of Port Elizabeth 

ABSTRACT 

As a result of minimal private cost many people dispose of non-deposit bearing 
glass containers in ways which cause glass pollution: hazardous broken bottles 
and litter. This pollution imposes costs on users of the affected environment 
and on municipalities, which have most of the responsibility to clean up, 
although in South Africa the two main glass packaging producers also play a 
role by operating a recycling system. A case study was carried out in the Port 
Elizabeth area in which exploration is made of the glass that does not get 
recycled and an intuitive analysis is made of the costs of different options for 
managing recyclable glass waste. It is concluded that the case deserves further 
investigation for introducing legislation in South Africa making bottle deposits 
mandatory. 

JELK200 

INTRODUcnON 

From an environmental perspective one of the most promising ways to deal with 
glass packaging pollution is to recycle it. If reprocessed and used again, 
alcoholic and soft drink container bottles do not deface the landscape or add to 
the mound of refuse generated by the modem industrial 'throwaway' society -
ultimately requiring burial in municipal tips. Fortunately, under some 
circumstances it is profitable to recycle glass bottles, and as a result, a recycling 
glass bottle industry has evolved. 

Despite the development of this industry, the problem of glass bottle waste still 
remains an acute environmental problem in South Africa. For this reason the 
question arises of whether the government should not step in and help remedy a 
problem the market is failing to, by introducing more regulation in the beverage 
bottling industry. 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



423 SATEB NR Vol I (1998) Nr 3 

It is not an option to be adopted on weak grounds, because this type of 
regulation can undermine economic freedom (Barry, 1994': 6). Specifically, if 
the government legislated a mandatory deposit-refund system covering all soft 
and alcoholic drinks, the freedom to enter into contracts for beverages contained 
in non-refundable glass bottles would be lost. This paper will explore the 
economic case for this option, using Port Elizabeth as a case study 

THE NATURE OF THE PROBLEM 

This type of regulation is not new in the world. It is usually called container 
deposit legislation elsewhere. In the United States discussion of container 
deposit schemes can be traced back to the 1930s (W.D. Scott and Company Pty. 
Ltd., AUgust, 1983: 10). The legislation encompasses containers of all types of 
beverage. (The type of regulation being considered in this report merely relates 
to glass.) 

The following states of the United States of America had introduced bottle bill 
(container deposit) legislation by 1989: California, Connecticut, Delaware. 
Iowa, Maine, Massachusetts, Michigan, New York, Oregon and Vermont 
(Tietenberg, 1992: 206). There is similar legislation in Canada (Turner, Pearce 
and Bateman, 1993: 259-260). In Australia, South Australia introduced 
container deposit legislation in 1977 (Business Regulation Review Unit, June, 
1989: 11 ). There has also been strong support for various aspects of container 
deposit legislation on the continent of Europe. The following European 
countries have product charge or deposit-refund legislation covering beverage 
containers: Austria, Sweden, Finland, Gennany, Norway, Switzerland and 
Denmark (Turner, Pearce and Bateman, 1993: 259-260). 

In South Africa legal protection of the environment can only be justified if it is 
in human interests; the legal principle being, cum igitur hominum causa ius 
constitulio sit (law is an institution for the sake of men) (Rabie, 1973:1). 
Currently, legal protection against careless disposal of glass bottles is justified 
in terms of this legal principle on the grounds that, like other littering, it is an 
eye-sore and or health risk for other human users of the environment. The 
protection takes the form of litter deterring provisions in the Environmental 
Conservation Act (No. 73) of 1989. In terms of Section 19 of the Act a fme of 
Rl 000 and/or 3 months imprisonment may be imposed on a person for littering 
a public attraction. In sections 20-24, regulations and directions of waste 
management are dealt with. They provide for the imposition of fmes of up to 
Rloo 000 and/or 10 years imprisonment on people who dispose of waste 
illegally. Is this enough, or should the government be doing more? 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



SAJEMS NS Vol I (1998) No 3 424 

Of the representatives spoken to in the beverage industry in S<1uth Africa, few 
were prepared to commit themselves on the desirability of container deposit 
legislation in South Africa. Most representatives spoken to did not foresee it as 
likely in the near future and redirected inquiries on the issue to Owen Bruyns, 
Executive Director, Packaging Council of South Africa (pAC SA), 
Johannesburg. Telephonic and face to face discussions were held with Mr. 
Bruyns on the topic during second half of 1996. He is of the view that the case 
for regulating against non-returnable bottles is weak because: 

• regulation is unnecessary • the bottle manufacturers are already 
addressing the problem, by administering non-profit making glass 
recycling systems (e.g., bottle banks), 

• the impact of the proposed regulation has been researched in other 
countries (USA and Australia) and shown to be an inefficient solution to 
the problem of glass litter, 

• it will not solve the relevant problem but merely change the nature of it -
the relevant consumers will simply switch from disposable glass 
containers to disposable tinplated steel and aluminum cans and to 
disposable plastic PET bottles, 

• it will reduce consumer surplus by reducing choice and pushing up the 
prices of the relevant beverages (because they will be more costly to 
produce), and 

• it will reduce jobs and income (and thereby tax receipts) in the glass 
bottling and beverage industries and/or divert capital to the distribution 
and cleaning sectors. 

The first of these arguments is the one primarily addressed in this paper. The 
second is addressed in sections 2 and 3, but the following issues are not 
addressed: 

• possible consumer substitutions of glass for plastic, aluminum and 
tinplated containers, 

• possible changes to beverage prices, and 
• possible changes to employment and income totals in different industries, 

e.g., due to reductions in some types of bottle production and increases in 
other, and to increases in recycling activities. 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



425 SATEB NR Vol I (1998) Nr 3 

FINDINGS OF SELECTED OTHER STUDIES INTO THE ECONOMICS 
OF LEGISLATING AGAINST NON-RETURNABLE BOTTLES 

The studies to which PACSA refer are those on container deposit legislation by 
W.O. Scott and Company Pty. Ltd. (August, 1983) and the Business Regulation 
Review Unit (June, 1989) - both relate to the case of Australia. They are 
discussed under (a) and (b) below. 

(a) W.O. Scott and Company Pty. Ltd. (August, 1983) analyzed the probable 
economic impact of introducing container deposit legislation throughout 
Australia and concluded that: 
• it would increase the cost of soft drinks and beer in cans and plastic 

containers, and for this reason also their retail prices, as well as the 
retail price of drinks in multi fill containers (to help cover these 
increased costs), 

• skilled or semi-skilled manufacturing jobs would be replaced by 
unskilled bottle sorting and handling jobs, with the result that 
employee earnings would decline, 

• government revenue would decline because sales would decline, 
profits would decline, employee income would decline and 
production plants would be written off, as unprofitable plants were 
closed down, e.g., tinplated steel can producers, 

• overall energy consumption would decrease, but more scarce primary 
energy sources would be used due to increased transport requirements 
(less hydroelectricity, coal and natural gas, but more oil), 

• the raw materials used in the beverage container industry of Australia 
are abundant in the country, 

• the experience of South Australia with mandatory deposit legislation 
was that the reduction in costs of litter management were insignificant 
- only a 3% reduction in total litter, and 

• alternatives to mandatory deposits are more cost effective in reducing 
litter and conserving resources than mandatory deposits, e.g., 
improving return rates on existing multifill packages, improving 
recycling rates and funding comprehensive litter reduction campaigns. 

(b) The Business Regulation Review Unit (June 1989) considered the same 
topic as W.O. Scott and Company Pty. Ltd. (August, 1983), but a few 
years later. It noted that between 1973 and 1978 counts of litter fell by 
80% in the state of South Australia and that container deposit legislation 
was introduced there in 1977. In South Australia mandatory deposits 
apply to all beer, wine cooler, soft drink and milk containers. The 
Business Regulation Review Unit were not of the view that this reduction 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



SAJEMS NS Vol 1 (1998) No 3 426 

was purely and simply due to the introduction of the relevant legislation, 
because some years prior to 1977 there had been vigorous anti-litter 
media campaigns in the state and the introduction of on-the-spot fines for 
littering. Moreover, impressive reductions in litter also occurred in states 
where there was no container deposit legislation, e.g., 63% in New South 
Wales between 1979 and 1985 and 50% in Victoria between 1983 and 
1988. 

Some of the negative features of container deposit legislation were: 
• it imposes a particularly high deposit on cans, which cannot be re-

used, thereby raising the overall price of the product and reducing 
demand, 

• it increases production and retailing costs (bottle washing plants, 
storage of bottles at retailers, slower bottle filling compared to cans 
and increased distribution costs), 

• it increases consumer costs by making them return bottles, and 
• it increases the cost of market entry (e.g., beer from Western 

Australia) thereby facilitating local monopolies. 

The conclusion of the Business Regulation Review Unit was that the cost 
savings, brought about by container deposit legislation as a result of 
reduced garbage disposed, were far outweighed by the increased costs 
this legislation imposed on consumers and producers. The Unit 
suggested that more efficient ways of reducing costs would be privatizing 
waste disposal operations, media campaigns, increased littering fines and 
appealing to beverage and container producers to avoid ring tops (on 
cans) and other devices that can add to the problem of litter. 

One of the well known cost benefit studies carried out on bottle deposit 
legislation in the United States is that of Porter's (1978). 

(c) Porter (1978) conducted a cost benefit study of a proposal to legislate, in 
the state of Michigan in the USA, for the introduction of mandatory 
deposits on beer and soft drinks containers. The proposal was to make 
all beverage containers sold in the state of Michigan subject to a 
returnable deposit of 10 cents. At the time only 27% of the containers 
were returnable. His conclusion was that it depended upon the relative 
valuations of the average citizen's time sacrifice cost and willingness to 
pay for a reduction in container litter. For instance, he calculated that a 
desirability of mandatory deposits equated to an aggregate willingness to 
pay about $200 million per annum (by the 9,1 million citizens), or $27.26 
per annum per citizen (assuming the average citizen's time return cost 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



427 SATEB NR Vol 1 (l998)Nr3 

were equal to the 10 cents deposit proposed). Porter suggests that this 
sum may be higher than what the citizens would be prepared to pay for a 
reduction in container litter. However, it is noted that his justification for 
a return cost estimate equal to 10 cents per returnable bottle is based on a 
rather extreme assumption; that the return cost of the non-returnable 
bottle is trivial and can be ignored. What Porter's analysis strongly 
suggests is that no general answer may be given to the question of 
whether mandatory deposits are desirable. 

(d) Based on the findings of a cross-section of cost benefit studies done on 
deposit-refund systems in Europe and the United States, Turner, Pearce 
and Bateman (1993: 264-265) conclude that they do not generate 
significant net social gains. The problem, as they see it, is that they do 
not reduce the overall volume of municipal waste enough to offset the 
additional administrative costs. 

(e) Although little support has been found amongst industrial groups in the 
United States for government legislated deposit-refund systems, the 
general public have been very supportive of them (Turner, Pearce and 
Bateman ,1993:255). There is evidence that the public respond 
positively to changes in the pricing of waste disposal. The examples of 
Highbridge and Seattle show how changing the incentives to dispose of 
litter have worked in the United States (Tietenberg, 1992). 

• In January, 1988, the town of Highbridge in New Jersey, USA, 
replaced its flat 280 dollar annual fee for the collection of refuse with 
a fee that varied with the amount of trash (New York Imles. 24 
November, 1988, BI,B7). Each household was given 52 stickers for 
140 dollars. Additional stickers could be bought at 1.25 dollars each. 
As a result peoples attitudes towards wastes changed rapidly: the 
amount of refuse required to be collected went down 25% as residents 
began to compost food and yard wastes and recycling programmes 
flourished in glass, newspapers and cans. In 1989 the base sticker 
rate was increased to 200 dollars and additional stickers to 1.65 
dollars each. This increase gave rise to concerns that the new pricing 
strategy for refuse removal was going to place a greater burden on the 
poor. However, that concern was apparently misplaced. Under the 
old system every household paid the same fee for refuse collection, 
regardless of how much refuse was put out, and as poorer households 
were producing less refuse, they were in effect subsidising the 
wealthier ones. 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



SAJEMS NS Vol I (1998) No 3 428 

• Seattle. Washington instituted a similar system. but with higher 
prices. They too experienced a dramatic decline in refuse disposal 
and increase in recycling. 

The lesson learned is that when the incentive not to waste is made direct. 
people change their behavior and waste less. The refund system is similar 
in its effecL A deposit must be paid by the consumer, on the purchase of 
the recyclable item. which reflects the cost of recycling or disposing of iL 
Glass bottles and aluminum cans are good examples of such items. but 
there are also many others to which the system has been successfully 
applied. including cars and car parts (Bohm. 1981. pp.120-124). On 
returning the item to a designated dealer a refund is given. This refund 
creates the incentive for someone. not necessarily the purchaser. to collect 
the item and transport it to the designated dealer. If the purchaser 
considers the incentive insufficient to return it. an opportunity for others. 
probably poorer people. is created to make money out of the system by 
returning it. 

THE MARKET DETERMINED EFFICIENT LEVEL OF GLASS 
RECYCLING 

Investigations of the literature on recycling confinn that in an efficient market. 
devoid of any imperfections, there is no need for intervention because the 
interaction of supply and demand bring about an efficient level of recycling 
(Tietenberg, 1992). In this kind of market the rising costs of virgin materials 
and of waste disposal increase the attractiveness of recycling from both the 
demand and supply sides of the market. Products relying exclusively on virgin 
raw materials would be subject to higher prices than those drawing on recycled 
materials. Consequently, consumers would switch from products relying 
exclusively on virgin raw materials to ones drawing on recycled materials; a 
switch known as the composition of demand effect (Tietenberg, 1992). 

The theory that there is an efficient level of recycling glass waste in South 
Africa does not relate to all glass but only to that which is potentially profitable 
to recycle; mainly to glass used as packaging (bottles and jars). 

There are many private economic incentives to recycle glass. Glass containers 
of beverage are almost 1 WIG recyclable. which means they can be recycled with 
minimal loss of material, or emission of toxic waste. over and over again. 
Moreover, recycled glass melts at lower temperatures than the raw materials 
used for glass production. For each 10% increase in recycled glass containers 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



429 SATEB NR Vol 1 (1998) Nr 3 

added to the mix, the melting en~ required is reduced by about 2,5%. As a 
result both energy usage and wear and tear on capital (the t\imaces) are reduced; 
two of the main costs incurred in producing glass (Glass Recycling Association, 
November, 1996). In the furnaces, molten glass is heated up to a temperature 
of between 1 260 and 1 480 oC. 

Notwithstanding these energy and capital saving incentives, there are limits to 
the amount of glass that it is profitable to recycle. The main limiting factors are 
the collection, processing and transport costs. At some point the energy and 
capital saving of using recyclable glass is outweighed by the greater acquisition 
cost of cullet (crushed used glass packaging) over that of the virgin raw 
materials used in the glass mix (pers. comm., Owen Bruyns, 1996). It is a point 
which is reached fairly quickly in South Africa, because the virgin raw 
materials used to make glass are plentiful: silica sand (58,1% of the mix 
required), soda ash (18,2%), limestone (15,6%), feldspar (4,4%) and dolomite 
(3,7%). There is also a quality deterioration problem (increased bubbles in the 
finished products) if more than 40% of the input material used to make glass is 
made up of cullet (Vogler, 1981:173). This limiting factor is also relevant in 
Australia (Business Regulation Review Unit, June, 1989: 35). 

Of potentially recyclable glass about 65% recycles in South Africa: about 43% 
in the form of returnable bottles and about 22% through bottle bank and buy 
back systems set up by the Glass Recycling Association (Glass Recycling 
Association, November, 1996). Glass recycling with returnable bottles is 
generally found to be more cost effective than with non-returnable ones 
(Vogler, 1981: 178). 

It is deduced that the market choice in South Africa is to recycle 65% of 
packaging glass. If efficient markets are assumed it is deduced that of the 
potentially recyclable glass 35% is inefficient to recycle (the profit incentive is 
insufficient). 

RECYCLING BY SELECTED BOTILING COMPANIES IN SOUTH 
AFRICA 

Softdrinla 

According to PACSA, as a proportion of the total volume packed in returnable 
and non-returnable containers, the volume of soft drinks packed in returnable 
(voluntary deposit) containers in South Africa increased from 65% to 67,4% 
between 1990 and 1993. Of the returnable bottles in 1993: 54% were 1 litre 
glass bottles, 7,3% were 1,5 litre plastic bottles and 6,1% smaller glass bottles. 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



SAJEMS NS Vol 1 (1998) No 3 430 

Of the non-returnable containers: 65% were metal cans (as against 40% in 
1990) and 27% plastic bottles. By comparison with the United States a much 
higher proportion of soft drinks are packaged in returnable containers in South 
Africa. In the United States this proportion is only about 8% (PAC SA, 1996). 
The main bottling company of non-alcoholic beverage (Coca Cola) in South 
Africa, the South African Bottling Company (SABCO), has its head office in 
Port Elizabeth. In November 1996 it reported that 67% of the packaging done 
by it was in glass containers, and 57,11% of the glass packaging was in 
returnable containers (Ernie van Vuuren, Manager SABCO, November, 1996). 
About 6% of the returnable bottles are damaged in the return process. Whereas 
non-returnable bottles are merely rinsed, returnable ones first have to be sorted 
(which is very labour intensive), the caps removed, and then washed. Dave 
Davies, also of SABCO (production manager), is of the view that consumer 
preferences are shifting from soft drinks packed in returnable containers to ones 
packed in non-returnable containers, but no evidence was offered to support this 
view (November 1996). The converse appears to be true in the beer market. 

Beer 

For the period, June 1986 to January 1994, South African Breweries reported to 
PACSA that as a proportion of total sales of all malt beer in South Africa, the 
market share of: 
• returnable re-usable voluntary deposit containers increased from about 

72% to 79010 (and the 750ml specifically, from 64% to 75%), 
• non-returnable metal cans increased from 6% to 10%, and 
• non-returnable dumpies decreased from 9% to 7%. 

It appears that since 1993 the swing away from non-returnable to returnable 
containers has continued in the beer market. In November, 1996, South African 
Breweries Port Elizabeth office (Owen Kingwall, Production Manager, 
November, 1996) reported that of its total sales, market shares by types of 
container were roughly as follows: 

• 80% in 750 ml 'quarts' (returnable), 
• 10% in 375 ml 'pints' (returnable), 
• 5% in 340 ml 'dumpies' (non-returnable), and 
• 5% in cans (non-returnable). 

A returnable beer bottle can be re-used up to 30 times per bottle (Owen 
Kingwall, South African Breweries, Production Manager, November, 1996). 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



431 SATED NR Vol 1 (1998) Nr 3 

RECYCLING IN PRACDCE IN SOUTH AFRICA 

In South Africa the Glass Recycling Association administers glass recovery 
systems. This association was fonned in 1986 by the main two glass packaging 
producers in South Africa, Consol Glass and Metal Box Glass. The rationale 
this association provides for its activities is 'to promote the concepts of a clean 
environment and a healthy community' ('A Message From the Glass Recycling 
Association', November 1996). It employs two methods of glass recovery: a 
bottle bank system and the buy back system. 

The bottle bank system works by consumers putting their unwanted glass jars 
and bottles into one of about 1490 glass bottle banks set up in 11 S cities and 
towns in South Africa, and agents of the company collecting this glass from 
these banks. 

Traffico is the agent appointed to administer the bottle banks in Port Elizabeth. 
There are currently about S4 of them in the city. It collects about % ton of glass 
per week from these S4 bottle banks (Willem Jordaan, Operations Manager, 
Traffico, November 1996). 

The buy back system is a repurchase arrangement with 120 appointed agents in 
designated areas in South Africa. The arrangement is for the purchase by 
Consol Glass of crushed used glass packaging. known as cullet. To qualifY as 
cullet and be repurchased by these companies: 

• only bottle and jar glass should be used 
• glass should be separated by colour (into amber, green, flint or mixed), 

and 
• no contaminants should be mixed in amongst the jar and bottle glass - any 

other type of material, including other types of glass (such as window, 
light bulb, drinking and crystal), and 

• the glass should be crushed (culled) and transported to either of the 
Johannesburg or Cape Town Consol Glass plants. 

In Port Elizabeth, Traffico sees to it that these requirements are met. The bottle 
banks only make up part of its supply. SABCO supplied it with 29 tons of glass 
in 1996; bottles damaged in the process of production (Ernie van Vuuren, 
SABCO, January, 1997). 'Totting rights' to collect glass waste at the 
municipal tip site in Port Elizabeth also yield it a supply (Ken Kendel. PE 
Municipality, November, 1996). as does South African Breweries in the fonn of 
their damaged bottles (Owen Kingwall. Production Manager, South African 
Breweries, November. 1996). 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



SAJEMSNS Vol I (1998) No 3 432 

WHERE THE MARKET (AND CONSUMER MORALITY) FAILS 

The motivation provided by the Glass Recycling Association for its recycling 
activities is moral (rather than profit). It suggests implicit acceptance of a weak 

. version of the producer pays principle by the two main glass packaging 
producers in South Africa, i.e., acceptance that part of the disposal cost relating 
to the non-returnable bottles is their responsibility. We may deduce that they 
feel that the other part lies with the consumer, in the form of a moral obligation 
to take the non-returnable bottle, from which they consume the contents, to one 
of the many bottle banks they provide. 

This position is a reasonable one in an era when the public is continuaHy urged 
to be environmentally conscious, and environmental education and awareness 
campaigns are regularly conducted. 

However, in many circumstances, taking a bottle to the bottle bank is neither the 
most efficient action to take, nor the one people will necessarily be inclined to 
take. For a self-interested person, the most efficient action with respect to 
non-deposit bearing glass containers is to discard them as soon as possible after 
the consumption of their contents, because this imposes the lowest private cost 
on them. Minimizing the return cost is undoubtedly the main reason why 
people would want to purchase this type of bottle instead of the returnable one. 
On privately owned land, this means in a general refuse bin, and on common or 
government land, this means in the park, on the beach, alongside the walkway, 
or on the street. For people who are more sensitive to the social benefits of 
responsible behaviour with respect to litter, one would expect them to make the 
effort to take their non-returnable bottles to the bottle banks. However, even for 
these people, there are circumstances where they may not do this. For instance, 
if they perceive large numbers of others about them not making the effort, they 
may deduce that their actions are of so little consequence that they cease to 
bother themselves (i.e., the public good 'assurance' problem). 

For these reasons (despite public education and awareness campaigns) 35% of 
the glass packaging industry's total output of about 125 000 tons per annum 
ends up either being buried in landfills, together with other refuse or left on the 
ground, frequently in broken pieces (Glass Recycling Association, November. 
1996). In landfills the external cost is passed on to the municipal rate payers 
(estimated at Rl5 million per annum for South Africa) and to refuse workers 
who are injured in the process of transporting it pieces (Glass Recycling 
Association, November. 1996). When left on the ground the external cost of 
packaging glass waste is more difficult to estimate, but it may be even greater 
than for the landfill case. Left broken on the ground it is time consuming to 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



433 SATEB NR Vol I (1998) Nr 3 

pick up, it detracts from the visual appeal of the environment and is physically 
dangerous to those barefoot. The problem is particularly evident at places 
where picking up glass must be done by hand, litter spoils the look and feel of 
the place, and where it is natural for people to want to walk barefoot, for 
instance, the beach. Recreational values are reduced. Significantly, on many 
beaches glass litter is simply left by the administering authorities, presumably 
because the cost of cleaning up is prohibitively high (see Port Elizabeth case 
study below). 

To sum up: an important cost is left out of the calculus that underlies the market 
outcomes on what is recycled in South Africa, namely, the cost that is incurred 
in disposing of the 35% of glass produced per annum, not recycled. Currently 
part of this external cost problem is bome by local governments, in the form of 
refuse collection, cleaning operations and municipal tip management, and part 
by the citizens living and using the environments where the glass packaging is 
disposed. 

The question this paper addresses is whether this external cost can be reduced 
by making a deposit-refund system mandatory for glass beverage packaging, 
without increasing other costs by more than what is saved. 

ASPECfS OF GLASS WASTE DISPOSAL IN PORT ELIZABETH 

Glass waste - a municipal perspective 

The city of Port Elizabeth collects about 1 000 tons of solid waste per day from 
households and firms (Ken Kendell, Chief Cleansing Officer, November 1996). 
The costs of refuse collection amount to about &23,5 million. In addition about 
R15,3 million is spent on cleaning up streams and beaches. The cleansing 
division of the PE municipality employs about 730 people and spends more than 
Rl million per week in total on cleaning. 

A domestic refuse analysis conducted in 5 suburbs in Port Elizabeth 
(Summerstrand, Hollard Park, Newton Park, Sydenham and Framesbury) for the 
city of Port Elizabeth shows that glass accounts for about 7 % of the weight of 
the refuse and 2% of the volume (Table 1). 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



SAJEMS NS Vol I (1998) No 3 434 

Table 1: Cumulative constituents analysis of 5 samples of domestic 
refuse in Port Elizabetb. 

Constituents Sample Weigbt Weigbt%of Volume 0/. of 
(kes) lSJ!- Sample Total Paper 249,85 38,04 

Glass 99,3 7,9 2,36 
Metal 43 3,ll 3,97 
Plastic 50,5 3,66 13,96 
Veg. & Putrescible 497,55 36.04 11,62 
Garden Refuse 373 27,02 25,85 
Rags 13,5 0,98 1,41 
Unclassified 29,6 2,14 0,68 
Wood & Combustible 24,25 1,76 2,11 
Totals 1380,55 100 100 

Source: City of Port Elizabeth, ChiefCleansmg Officer, November 1996. 

As a result of broken glass bottles being placed in black refuse bags, about 2 
injuries per week are sustained by refuse collectors firms (Ken Kendell, Chief 
Cleansing Officer, November, 1996). Mostly these injuries are superficial cuts, 
but there also have been deep leg cuts and kidney damage reported. The 
presence of glass is also dangerous for those who seek to collect specific items 
from the refuse at the municipal tip site; which is the reason why the PE 
municipality is currently considering installing an expensive a conveyer belt 
system at the tip site. 

Glass waste on the beaches 

The highest concentration of Port Elizabeth's glass pollution is found on its 
beaches and recreational areas, especially on its northern beaches, where the 
highest numbers of beach-visitors are found (Ken Kendell, Chief Cleansing 
Officer, November, 1996): On New Year's Day, 1994/5, about 132000 people 
visited PEs northern beaches of Joorst Park, St. Georges, and Wells Estate, and 
about 92 000 PEs southern beaches of Kings, Humewood, Hobie and Pollock 
(95196 Summer Season Lifesaving Report, City of Port Elizabeth). Of the 
incidents reported by the lifeguards at Humewood and Hobie beaches during the 
1995196 Summer Season Lifesaving Report: 
• 8 were for cuts, 
• 39 for 'helpouts', 
• 2 for sprains or fractures, and 
• 3 for stings. 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



435 SAlEB NR Vol 1 (1998) Nr 3 

There were 10 injuries reported as being the result of broken glass by lifeguards 
on the northern beaches of Port Elizabeth (1oorst park, Wells Estate and St. 
Georges Strand); two of which were considered serious. The senior lifeguard 
for the area (Armand) was of the view that excessive use of alcohol was a 
contributing factor to the problem of glass litter on the beach. He deduced that 
inebriated people did not to think or care about the health risk imposed on other 
beach users resulting from the disposal of glass on the beach. 

One of the most common types of glass litter found on the beaches of the Port 
Elizabeth (PE) area is the non-returnable beer dumpie; mainly containers sold 
by South African Breweries. The buyers of these containers constitute a niche 
market for South African Breweries. 10% of the total market (Owen Kingwall, 
South African Breweries, November 1996). These consumers are happy to pay 
a bit more for their beer in order to avoid the time and transport cost of 
returning the bottles after consuming their - presumably the more affluent 
section of the market Beer bought in single-fill bottles is a bit more expensive 
than that bought in returnable ones, after the deposit for the bottle has been 
claimed· usually between 3 and 8%. 

The problem of glass litter is also evident on other beaches near PE, but outside 
PE municipal control. During 1996 Jean Spearpoint and David Brown 
monitored solid waste litter on a 100 square metre section of the beach adjacent 
to the Van Stadens Mouth Resort. The cleaning up of the beach is the 
responsibility of the Department of Culture and Recreation, Eastern Cape, and 
the Eastern Cape Conservation department. Access to the Van Staden Mouth 
Resort and beach is controlled and takes the form of a R15 entry fee per car 
levied by the Department of Culture and Recreation, Eastern Cape, at the 
entrance to the resort. They recorded details of any litter they found in random 
walks during the 6 months from May to October 1996. The results of this study 
are presented in tables 2 to 4 below. 

Table 2: Composition of pollution according to the material of items of 
litter picked up in random walks May to October, 1996, on a 
100 metre stretch of beach at Van Stadens Gorge. 

Material littered Number of items % of total 
Glass 507 86 
Metal cans 76 13 
Plastic 6 1 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



SAJEMS NS Vol 1 (1998) No 3 436 

Table 3: Number of units of glass and weight of broken glass picked up 
in random walks May to October 1996, on a 100 metre stretcb 
of beach at Van Stadens Gorge. 

Month in 1996 Number of Units Weight of broken 
glass in Kgs 

May 53 1,82 
June 67 5,45 
July 94 2,84 
August 131 1.14 
September 114 3,64 
October 48 2,39 
Total 507 17,28 

Table 4: Proportion of items of glass pollution made up of deposit 
bearing containers and non-deposit bearing. 

% 
7 

93 

The particularly interesting aspect of this research is that it indicates what litter 
one could expect to come across on the beach after organized cleaning has taken 
place. Glass is the litter one is most likely to come across and 93% is in the 
form of non-deposit bearing glass containers. 

Mike Bentall, Chief Environmental officer for the East London municipality, 
reported that similar problems are encountered in East London's public places 
(August 1996). 

The public's view on the disposal of glass bottles in Port Elizabeth 

During November 1996, H. Gous carried out a limited public survey of people's 
views in Port Elizabeth on the disposal of glass bottles. The survey method 
employed was personal interviews with people randomly selected from the more 
affluent suburbs of Port Elizabeth. The selection of people from the more 
affluent suburbs was motivated by the smail scale of survey proposed and the 
observation that in the beer market, non-returnable bottles were targeted at the 
wealthier consumers - poorer ones (the majority) preferring the returnable 
containers because the beer is cheaper out of them. Had poorer people been 
included in the survey we would have expected a far smaller proportion of the 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



437 SATEB NR Vol 1 (1998) Nr 3 

sample to indicate that they purchased non-retmnable bottles. A total of 100 
people, aged from 18 to 57 years, were interviewed. 

Of those interviewed (l00): 

• 96 knew which beverage containers were deposit bearing, 
• 45 buy returnable g1ass bottles only, if the option exists, 
• 85 purchase between 1-5 bottles of beverage per week, 10 purchase 6-10 

bottles and 5 were unsure, 
• 60 disposed of their non-returnable bottles in the bottle banks provided 

by the Glass Recycling Association, and 
• 35 regarded the use of bottle banks as too inconvenient. 

M. Akkerman undertook a similar survey in the Northern Suburbs of Cape 
Town during November, 1996, but asked some additional questions - ones 
focusing on why people do not use the recycle systems currently available. He 
interviewed 16 people. Of these people: 

• all thought that the recycling of g1ass was a good idea in principle, 
• 13 knew which beverage containers were deposit bearing and which not 

(although some expressed confusion with respect to bottles containing 
beverages other than soft drinks and beer), 

• 10 regarded returning non-returnable bottles for recycling as 
inconvenient, and 

• 13 thought that they should be compensated monetarily for time and costs 
incurred in returning bottles for recycling. 

G/ass as hazardous waste 

Much of the g1ass collected in Port Elizabeth is not recyclable (see Oliver, 1975, 
on the making and using of glass other than for packaging). This glass is 
disposed of by being treated with chemicals to immobilize heavy metals, 
compacted and covered at a hazardous landfill site. Waste Tech gives 
assistance in the process on request (Susan Alcock, Waste Tech, November, 
1996) and also itself disposes of some hazardous g1ass waste. It removes glass 
waste from Shatterpruff'e, ELMOSA and Associated Glassworks. 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



SAJEMS NS Vol I (1998) No 3 438 

TOW ARBS A CASE FOR REGULATION 

The object of Regulation 

A model is provided in Figure I (below) where the aim of regulation is 
described. 

Figure 1: A Single Market Model of the Case for Regulation 

() 

% OF RECYCLABLE GLASS WASTE DISPOSED 

INTO mE ENVIRONMENT 

100 

In Figure 1 two functions are shown: MCr and MC •. The negatively sloped one 
(MCr) shows the marginal social cost of reducing the amount of glass packaging 
disposed into the environment. The positively sloped one (MCi) shows the 
marginal social cost of increasing glass packaging disposed into the 
environment. 

The object of regulating glass packaging disposal is to bring about an optimal 
level of waste disposal, which, assuming convexity in the damage and 
abatement functions (Perman, Ma and Mcgilvray, 1996: 200-212), is where: 

MC r = MC,. 

In order to achieve this R.,Rz glass packaging waste must be diverted from the 
environment. 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



439 SATED NR Vol I (1998) Nr 3 

The relevance of all this for government is that, if market generated recycling 
only induces a diversion of RoRI waste from the environment, the government 
needs, some way or other. to effect an additional diversion of RIR2 waste, in 
order to facilitate an optimal level of glass waste disposal. 

Instruments of Regulation 

There are various ways governments may set about this objective. The most 
popular four economic instruments are : 

• increasing the imposition of waste disposal charges (a curbside charge on 
consumers - based on volume or weight) and fmes for litterirlg, 

• levying a product charge (packaging tax) on the sales of producers of 
non-refimdable beverage containers, to cover the costs expected to be 
incurred in final disposal, 

• subsidizing recycling production, and/or 
• legislating a deposit-refimd system with respect to all containers (Turner, 

Pearce and Bateman, 1993: 259-260). 

Each option has problems associated with it (Turner. Pearce and Bateman, 
1993: 260-266). For instance, increasing curbside waste disposal charges can 
lead to people either disposing of their waste in other ways which negatively 
impact on the environment, or adding theirs to someone else's bundle, and it 
can be administratively costly. A packaging tax does not directly discourage 
irresponsible waste disposal, only indirectly, by raising prices and so reducing 
demand. Its main attribute is that it raises revenue to cover the environmental 
costs of the waste disposal. Subsidizing recycling systems requires tax payers 
to bear part of the consumers disposal cost and so in effect is an income 
transfer. The main problem with respect to the deposit refimd system is the cost 
benefit studies have not shown it to generate significant net social benefits. 

Thecostbenejitapproach 

The desirability of the above listed littering abatement measures depends upon 
the marginal cost of damage from final disposal being greater than the marginal 
cost associated with implementing that particular measure. The issue reduces to 
one of whether the marginal cost of damage to the final environment is greater 
than the marginal cost of implementing a deposit-refimd system for glass bottle 
containers of beverage. 

One approach to shedding light on the issue is to conduct a cost benefit analysis 
of the proposed legislation at the margin, i.e., using incremental costs. In this 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



SAmMS NS Vol I (1998) No 3 440 

context the cost benefit model advocated by Porter (1978) is popular (Common, 
1996:347). The approach is one of using the net present value (NPV) decision 
rule - the legislation is only deemed to be desirable if the NPV is positive. For 
the case this paper is investigating the NPV would need to be defined as 
follows: 

T 

NPV =L (Bu + BlI + B3l - CII - C21 - C31 )/(1 +rtl 
t-I 

where, 
Bit = the social valuation of the cost saving benefit of the municipality and 

other government institutions in collecting and disposing of glass waste, 
BlI = the cost saving benefit in reduced inputs required to produce the glass 

containers for soft and alcoholic drinks, 
B31 = the social valuation of the benefit of fewer glass litter related accidents 

and less amenity (or eye-sore) damage, 
Cit = the increased cost of inputs used to put soft and alcoholic drinks into 

containers and of collecting and administering the expanded refillable 
container system, 

ClI = the increased cost of greater litter related accidents and amenity (or eye-
sore) damage caused by non-returnable non-glass container substitutes for 
glass ones purchased by consumers, 

C 31 = the social valuation of the increased time cost to households in returning 
empty refillable bottles, 

r = the discount rate, and 
t = number of years after legislation is implemented; t = L .. T. 

There is little doubt that this approach has the potential to yield useful 
information, but the information requirements of it are considerable (see Porter, 
1978); beyond the terms of reference of this exploratory study. The 
estimation of B3l and C31 would require contingent valuations to be carried out 
amongst residents and visitors to the area. Many cost benefit studies conducted 
overseas on the issue have not yielded significant positive net present values 
(Turner, Pearce and Bateman, 1993: 264-265). 

An intuitive approach 

This paper does not use a cost benefit analysis approach in order to weigh up 
the case for bottle deposit legislation, but an intuitive reasoning approach. For 
this purpose an expanded version of the model in Figure 1 is adopted - see 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



441 SATEB NR Vol 1 (1998) Nr 3 

Figure 2 (overleaf). In it four marginal social cost functions are incorporated: 
Me;, Me .. Men! and Mem • 

The Me; curve in Figure 2 is as it was for Figure I, but the Mer curve is defined 
differently. In the model described in Figure 2, the recycling of non-returnable 
bottles is distinguished from that of returnable bottles; the reasons being that the 
costs of recycling and the target consumer markets differ. South African 
Breweries described the market they provide non-returnable containers for as a 
niche one (see section 6 above). Presumably niche markets are catered for by 
beverage suppliers because the economies of scale benefit of producing 
beverage in standard packaging is outweighed by the increased sales revenue 
benefit gained by dividing up the beverage market through different packaging 
and advertising. A more complex Mer curve is defined when this division is 
taken into account: 

Mer = Men!, from Ro to R. (for the returnable share of the glass container 
market), and 

= Memt from R. to It. (for the non-returnable share of the glass container 
market), where, 

Men! = the marginal social cost of recycling deposit bearing refillable bottles, 
and 
Mem = the marginal social cost of recycling non-deposit bearing single fill 

bottles (e.g., through the bottle bank system). 

The return cost of different types of bottle is assumed to be equal from the 
consumer's point of view (implying ell = 0, or that the cost of returning a bottle 
to the bottle bank is equal to returning one to a beverage bottle retailer), but not 
from the beverage supplier's. As most of the profitable glass packaging 
recycling is done in refillable bottles, and the recycling which is being done in 
single fill bottles is mainly sustained on moral rather than commercial grounds, 
it is deduced that: 

The division between the recycling market for returnable and non-returnable 
bottles is shown in Figure 2 by the vertical dotted line above R2• 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



SAJEMS NS Vol I (1998) No 3 

Figure 2: A split market model of the case for regulation. 

~ 
Vl 
0 
U 

MC,.! 

I 
A' 

I 

o 7 
R, R, 

MarkCI: non-~clumablc I Markcl: Aelurnable 
I 

glass conlaiucrs I glass containcrs 

MCm 

1 
35 57 

% OF RECYCLABLE GLASS WASTE DISPOSED 

INTO THE ENVlRONMENT 

442 

100 

Ro 

The case for a mandatory deposit-refund system rests on the benefit of 
removing the market division between non-returnable containers and returnable 
ones. With the removal of this market division, the efficient level of recycling 
increases from R."R2 to R."R). As a result, total costs equal to the shaded area 
ABCD are saved; the vertical difference between the MCrd and the lesser of the 
MC j and MCm curves. It is a cost which is quite likely to increase steadily in the 
future. as citizen opposition mounts to the siting of existing and new tips. so 
pushing up tipping costs (Goldstein, 1995: 358). 

In principle it is conceivable that this gain through regulation could be offset by 
the loss in profits and income gained by the beverage seller and others (like 
advertisers) in servicing niche markets. However. as the beverages can be 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



443 SATEB NR Vol I (1998) Nr 3 

purchased cheaper from refillable bottles, it appears that much of the profit and 
income gained through niche market creation, may be a transfer of consumer 
surplus to advertisers and the beverage producing companies, rather than reflect 
a net social benefit. 

Trends in South African beer and soft drink markets are consistent with this 
interpretation. South African Breweries, being overwhelmingly dominant in 
the beer industry in South Africa during the 1980s and early 1990s, displayed a 
diminishing interest in promoting product differences based on differences in 
glass packaging options - more and more of their beer was sold in refillable 
bottles. (It is conceivable that this trend may be reversed if new competitors 
enter the industry and challenge their market dominance.) In the soft drink 
market, by comparison, where competition is more evident, more attention is 
focused on differences in packaging. 

To sum up: the case for regulating that a deposit-refund system operate in South 
Africa for all glass bottle containers of beverage is based on the external cost 
saving exceeding the profit gain lost in niche markets. It is a plausible case 
because the costs of recycling refillable bottles is less than that of non-refillable 
bottles and the profit and income loss in the non-refillable bottle market is 
mainly a transfer of consumer surplus to the beverage producers and the 
advertisers they commission. 

CONCLUSIONS ON REGULATING AGAINST NON-DEPOSIT 
BEARING GLASS CONTAINERS OF BEVERAGE 

In principle there are many solutions to the problem of glass pollution: 
educating consumers to be more responsible, encouraging producers to bear the 
burden of the external cost, and placing the burden of this cost on consumers, 
by restricting their choice only to glass containers which are deposit bearing. 
The latter approach provides consumers with an income incentive to recycle the 
glass containers, and so harnesses self-interest as its primary driving force. The 
disposal cost of the container is thereby internalized. 

It is concluded that it is an efficient option because: 

• Private costs would be brought into equivalence with social costs and 
most bottle glass waste (over 90%) would never reach final environments. 
In principle a litter tax on glass bottle producers can bring about the same 
end result (after cleaning up operations) but it would not prevent glass 
from reaching final environments. 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



SAJEMS NS Vol 1 (1998) No 3 444 

• The potential external cost saving is uncontroversial. 

Besides being an efficient option, mandatory glass bottle deposit legislation for 
alcoholic and soft drinks also may advantage the following: 
• local businesses over foreign ones, because imported beverages (like 

beer, wine and whisky) would probably need to be packaged locally 
instead of abroad in order to fit in with the requirements of the local 
deposit-refund system, and 

• labour over capital, because a labour intensive production system is 
favoured over a capital intensive one in an economy with a huge surplus 
of labour. 
In reaching this conclusion several potential negative spin-offs of the 
proposed regulation were not investigated. The most important of these 
spin-offs are increased product prices and substitutions in production and 
consumption that aggravate other types of pollution problem, e.g., those 
of plastic, tinplated steel and aluminum waste. The prices of beverage in 
returnable containers could be raised as a result of reduced physical sales 
volumes or the need to recoup forgone profit on the non-returnable 
containers. However, it also bears noting in this connection that: 

• physical sales volumes of refillable containers of beverage could be 
expected to increase, thereby making it possible to derive greater 
economies of scale in production, and 

• plastic. tinplated steel and aluminum waste problems could (and perhaps 
should) be simultaneously addressed, as is commonly done in European 
countries where container deposit legislation has been introduced, e.g., 
through the levYing of charges on products using these types of 
packaging. The latter approach would also have the merit of being less 
distorting with respect to the market for packaging material. 

For the above reasons it is recommended that further investigation be conducted 
into the merits of introducing mandatory bottle deposit legislation into South 
Africa. 

ENDNOTE 

Funding from the Human Sciences Research Council (HSRC) for this 
investigation is gratefully acknowledged, as is the assistance with field work by 
Mr. M. Akkerman, Mr. H. Gous, Mrs. J.G. Hosking, Mrs. J. Spearpoint and Mr. 
D. Brown, and the comments of the anonymous referees of the HSRC. This 
paper is drawn from a research report submitted to the HSRC on 9 February 
1998. 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.



445 SATEB NR Vol I (1998) Nr 3 

REFERENCES 

1. BARRY, N. (1994) 'The Market, Liberty and Regulatory State'. Journal 
of the Institutefor Economic Affairs, 14 (4), 5-12. 

2. BOHM, P. (1981) Deposit-Refund System: Theory and Application to 
Environmental, Conservation and Consumer Policy. Baltimore: John 
Hopkins. 

3. BUSINESS REGULATION REVIEW UNIT (June, 1989) 'Container 
Deposit Legislation and the Control of Litter and Waste', Information 
Paper No. 14. Report for the Ministry of Industry, Technology and 
Commerce, Australia. 

4. COMMON, M. (1996) Environmental and Resource Economics: An 
Introduction. (Second Edition.) London: Longman 

5. GOLDSTEIN, E.S. (1995) Economics and the Environment. New Jersey: 
Prentice Hall 

6. OLIVER, D.S. (1975) The Use of Glass in Engineering. Oxford: Oxford 
University Press. 

7. PORTER, R.C. (1978) 'A social cost benefit analysis of mandatory 
deposits on beverage containers', Journal of Environmental Economics 
and Management, 5, 351-375. 

8. RABIE, A. (1976) South African Environmental Legislation. Pretoria: 
The Institute of Foreign and Comparative Law, UNISA. 

9. SCOTT, W.O. AND COMPANY PTY. LTD. (AUGUST, 1983) 'Study of 
the Economic Impact of Beverage Container Deposit Legislation'. 
Commissioned by Brewers, Soft Drink Fillers and Container 
Manufacturers in Australia. 

10. TIETENBERG, T.H. (1992) Environmental and Natural Resource 
Economics (Third Edition) New York: Harper Collins. 

11. TURNER, R.K., PEARCE, D. AND BATEMAN, I. (1993) 
Environmental Economics: An Elementary Introduction. Baltimore: John 
Hopkins. 

12. VOGLER, J. (1981) Work from Waste. London: Intermediate 
Technology Publications Limited. 

R
ep

ro
du

ce
d 

by
 S

ab
in

et
 G

at
ew

ay
 u

nd
er

 li
ce

nc
e 

gr
an

te
d 

by
 th

e 
P

ub
lis

he
r 

(d
at

ed
 2

00
9)

.