SAJEMS NS Vol 5 (2002) No 3 683 Transfer Pricing as Strategic Planning Tool for Multinational Enterprises in a Post-Isolation South Africa Petri Schutte Po/chefstroom Business School, Po/chefs/room University for Christian Higher Education Jozua Loots Tax Services, KPMG ABSTRACT Political and trade liberalisation leads to irrevocable change, exposing South Africa to the demands of the dynamic global market, driven by a deluge of competitive forces, demanding world-class, global competitiveness. The challenge facing South African organisations is to successfully transform in an economy undergoing structural change, moving away from import substitution to global competitiveness. Historically, stringent exchange controls prevented profits to emigrate from South Africa. Trade iberalization necessitates the introduction of transfer pricing legislation to protect the national tax base. Application of transfer pricing in practice is complex, information constraints compel the use of foreign comparables in determining a reward consistent with the arm's length standard, challenging objectiveness and risk adjustment. Strategic opportunities exist if transfer pricing is not entrenched in national regulation compliance. JELF23,M40 INTRODUCTION Sanctions and trade embargos effectively isolated the South Atrican economy from international markets. South Africa's economy prior to democratisation and trade Iiberalisation was predominantly geared towards import substitution. South Africa's re-entry into the international market must be seen within the context of expansion in international trade and commerce manifesting in wide- ranging changes in trade volume and complexity. The latest UNCT AD! World Investment Report (2000: I) reports that transnational corporations (TNCs) totals 63 000 parent firms with 690 000 R ep ro du ce d by S ab in et G at ew ay u nd er li ce nc e gr an te d by th e P ub lis he r (d at ed 2 00 9) . 684 SAmMS NS Vol 5 (2002) No 3 foreign affiliates. These TNCs are involved in transactions that extend across virtually all countries impacting on all the economies they come into conflict with. The volume and mobility of international financial capital force governments of developing countries to adopt a conservative stance; economic policies are more restrictive with monetary and fiscal policy decision making at the core of achieving diminishing budget deficits along with single figure inflation targets. Utmost care must be taken not to embark on a fiscal route that might ,ead to a decrease in investment in health. education. housing and infrastructure if measured in real terms. Funding such investment, governments must prevent erosion of their tax. base. South Africa had stringent exchange controls that effectively prevented profits to emigrate. Trade liberalisation and relaxation of exchange controls forced the South African . government to protect the South African tax. base with transfer pricing and thin capitalisation provisions with the introduction in 1995 of Section 31 of the Income Tax Act. Application of transfer pricing in practice is complex; infonnation constraints necessitate the use of foreign com parables in determining a reward consistent with the arm's length principle. Use of foreign comparables challenge objectiveness and practical application relating to risk adjustment. Strategic opportunities exist if multinationals look beyond transfer pricing compliance and national regulations. INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND SOUTH AFRICA IN ISOLATION Since SOuth Africa's return to active participation in global trade, structural policy adjustment, economic growth and development strategies were embarked on in an attempt to increase global competitiveness of South African organisations. World organisations established since the Second World War and the influence they have had on international trade as well as the trade policies they enforced, played a major role in South Africa's exclusion from international trade. International economies' increased integration in terms of banking and international finance drew national economies closer, resulting in the evolution of trade blocs during the late eighties and early nineties. Economic sanctions, as South Africa experienced prior to 1994, have a major effect on the domestic economy. South Africa emerged from sanctions with R ep ro du ce d by S ab in et G at ew ay u nd er li ce nc e gr an te d by th e P ub lis he r (d at ed 2 00 9) . SAJEMS NS Vol 5 (2002) No 3 685 artificially high domestic prices; an international trade vacuum existed and domestic manufacturing was geared towards import substitution. The South African reaction to sanctions was domestic protection. Balassa (1972: 66) indicates that based on research done in developing countries2, protection tends to increase from lower to higher stages uf fabrication. It seems that protection regimes follow the value chain of production. South Africa used tariffs and subsidies to substitute domestic production for imports and to balance domestic production and demand as far as possible. Since 1994 and under international agreements, tariff reduction in line with WTO bindings continues on route to lowering tariffs, following a tendency3 similar to the one reported by Balassa (1972: 71). POST-ISOLATION CHALLENGES AND COMPETITIVENESS The Reconstruction and Development Programme (RDP) the South African government embarked on since 1994 aims to create a better life for all and forms the central objective of economic policies. The Minister of Finance first presented the government's macro-economic strategy Growth Employment and Redistribution programme (GEAR) during the course of the Finance Budget vote on 14th June 1996. Macroeconomic Strategy The objectives of the GEAR strategy were to move towards a competitive, outward-orientated economy. The following core element s were to facilitate this: Export led growth Expansion of private sector capital formation Accelerated private sector investment Increased infrastructure development and Improved labour intensive production. Although the scenario projections gave a clear indication of expectations, it would have been prudent if cognisance was taken of the tollowmg realitIes: Growth of at best 3 per cent per annum is expected. With an optimistic economic growth rate, substantially higher spending on social services than was possible in the past is unlikely, given the reduction in the deficit of the budget. Exchange rate volatility as experienced since February 1996 and the inherent danger of capital in- and outflows, add to the risk of a potential balancc of payments crisis. Short-term adjustment in an event of rapid capital outflows must rest on monetary policy so that economic R ep ro du ce d by S ab in et G at ew ay u nd er li ce nc e gr an te d by th e P ub lis he r (d at ed 2 00 9) . 686 SAJEMS NS Vol 5 (2002) No 3 contraction and the resulting decline in import demand can be effectively managed. The GEAR strategy does have flaws and with hindsight GEAR proved to be of value, providing a clear message of strategic intent. Industrial Strategy Historically South Africa was characterised by an industrial policy best described as import~substituting industrialisation. Import protection combined with import~substituting industrialisation led to a skewed concentration of economic ownership. Protectionist policies were increasingly associated with inefficiencies (Balassa, 1972: 22), which led to stagnant economies, whose employment was threatened by lower cost producers in the global economy. Continuation of protectionist policies would have led to further stagnation and the persistence of inefficient production with diminishing formal employment. The South African government made a deliberate attempt to move away from import-substituting industrialisation and sought to liberalise imports through encouraging exports and a shift from demand-side measures4 to supply~side measures5 to stimulate the South African economy, in line with the GEAR strategy. A formal programme of phased tariff reductions and tariff harmonisation commenced in 1995 in terms of the offer presented at the World Trade Organisation (WTO) in 1993. Although the tariff offer was based on consultation between business, labour and government, the reality was that average tariffs, maximum tariffs and the number of tariff lines decreased significantly. The Free Trade Agreement (FTA) between South Africa (SA) and the European Union (EU) became effective in 1999. Unfortunately, a multiplicity of supply-side programmes were introduced over a very short period of time, resulting in ineffective implementation due to a lack of coherence and vision. The full potential economic benefits of these policies therefore never materialised in South African. Globalisation and Competitiveness From an economic policy perspective, arguably the most significant development in recent times is the global extension of markets. Technology changes and global economic policies reduced barriers to the flows of goods and capital into Africa, which flows reached the $10 billion6 mark in 1999, on the R ep ro du ce d by S ab in et G at ew ay u nd er li ce nc e gr an te d by th e P ub lis he r (d at ed 2 00 9) . SAJEMS NS Vol 5 (2002) No 3 687 back of African governments actively seeking FDI through business friendly economic policies. In 1999, the Clinton Administration re-launched the Africa Growth and Opportunity Act, now titled the Africa Trade and Development Act. At the Africa-European Union (EU) Summit held in Cairo during April 2000, emphasis was placed on integrating Africa into the world economy with Africa and the EU expressing a need to develop a strategic partnership: ... any serious reflection on the future of the world economy and therefore the living standards of the billions who inhabit our world, will show that a strategic shift towards a significantly larger world economy can only be achieved as a result of raising living standards in the countries of the South, and therefore the radical expansion of the world markets for capital, goods and services (Mbeki, 2000). Joshi (1996: 1) describes competitiveness as "the ability ofa country to achieve sustained high rates of growth in the GDP per capita". Joshi also identifies identifies investment and saving as vital prerequisites, based on the premise that economic growth is driven by investment. Investment should be expanded to incorporate investment in the skills of people, acknowledging that people are the most important resource in the creation of wealth. Lambert (1997: 25) takes this argument further stating that training works, provided objectives are clearly set, learners know exactly what is expected from them and management understands how what is learned, will help achieving goals. Not enough can be done to increase South Africa's skills base, although the skills development levy may go some way to address the current skill shortage. Sunter (1997: II) states that to be a world-class company "you need to pass a written as well as an oral examination", with the written examination based on "financial statistics, growing real earnings per share (EPS) by five per cent per annum for ten years as well as offering the shareholders a total real return of at least ten percent for ten years, the so-called 5xlOxlO rule". Schutte (1999: 1) defines competitiveness within the South African paradigm as the "ten golden rules of a competitive society": Create a stable and predictable legislative environment. Work on a flexible and resilient economic structure. Invest in trade and technological infrastructure. Promote private savings and domestic investment. Develop aggressiveness on international markets as well as attractiveness for foreign value added industries. Focus on quality and speed in the conduct of administration and reforms. Maintain a relationship between wage levels, productivity and taxation R ep ro du ce d by S ab in et G at ew ay u nd er li ce nc e gr an te d by th e P ub lis he r (d at ed 2 00 9) . 688 SAJEMS NS Vol 5 (2002) No 3 Preserve the social fabric by reducing wage disparity and strengthening the middle class. Invest in education, especially at secondary level and in the life long training and improvement of the workforce. Balance the economy of globality and proximity to ensure wealth generation, maintain social cohesion and the value system." MULTINATIONAL ENTERPRISES Literature (Douglas & Craig, 1989: 373, Hout et al., 1982:106, Levitt, 1983: 57 & Salvatore, 1987: 307) suggests that the existence of multinational enterprises is initially driven by the competitive advantage provided by a global network of production and distribution. This is called a "multi domestic competitor" (Hout et ai., 1982: 98) which later becomes a global organisation (Douglas & Craig, 1989: 371, Hout et aI., 1982: 106 and Levitt, 1983: 65). Levitt (1983: 65) identifies two vectors that shape the world within this context, namely technology, a determinant of human preference and globalisation, an economic reality. Given the fact that commerce and business at large is about profit and wealth maximisation, the global company according to Levitt will "shape the vectors of technology and globalisation, pushing it towards convergence," which then become tangible as high quality, standardised products at an optimum price. Douglas and Craig (l989: 384) state that initially, domestic competition and core competencies are extended internationally. However, they conclude that the ultimate goal is "maximal efficiencies in allocating of resources", confirming Levitt's view. The multinational enterprise generates approximately $9.5 trillion of global sales through foreign affiliates (UNCTAD, 1998: I) with global exports by foreign affiliates at $2 trillion. Gross product (UNCTAD, 2000: I) associated with international production and foreign affiliate sales worldwide, increased faster than the total international production with sales reaching $14 trillion towards the turn of the century, compared to $3 trillion in 1980. Levitt (1983: 53) predicted that that the globalisation of markets is at hand with the end of the multinational as he sees it In an article titled "How global companies win out" (Hout et al., 1982: 98) it is submitted that competition is changing in many industries, forcin¥ international companies to change from being a "multi domestic competitor" to a global company. In this context, the global company attempts to exert leverage it might have, which ranges from R ep ro du ce d by S ab in et G at ew ay u nd er li ce nc e gr an te d by th e P ub lis he r (d at ed 2 00 9) . SAJEMS NS Vol 5 (2002) No 3 689 cross national production scale economies to foreign competitors' cash flow resources through price competition. National transfer pricing legislation might restrict price cuts insofar as it does not conform to the arm's length standard. In terms of South Africa's current regulations (South Africa, 1999: 12), these price cuts might be attributed to business strategies8 and as such the multinational might not be regarded as being involved in tax avoidance through transfer price manipulation. National regulation should prevent intemationalisation of cross border transactions to the extent that these transactions bypass national controls and scrutiny with proactive transfer pricing practices. Multinationals can use transfer pricing mechanisms based on connected party transactions to minimise tax exposure, depriving home or host economies from tax revenues. Nations worldwide have instituted regulatory changes to attract investment as measured by FDI, in an attempt to reap the benefits from FDI investment Cross border merger and acquisition activity is driven by companies' survival strategies in response to globalisation. The annual growth rate of mergers and acquisitions (M & A) of 35.4 per cent in 1999, indicates corporate strategy (UNCTAD, 2000: 14) recognising the effect of technological change, and changes in capital markets and regulatory environment (of which transfer pricing is one aspect). With mergers and acquisitions, corporations respond with strategies designed to expand current markets and explore new markets, increase market presence and consolidate market dominance, access to assets and proprietary assets and core competencies, financial opportunities and integration and diversification of risk. Over the short term, mergers and acquisitions might have small benefits for a developing country. The effect of mergers and acquisitions on the national economy is best described by the following: Insofar investment capital inflow is not adding value to the current capital stock, it replaces only some existing capital and as such no additional capital is ploughed into the economy. It is unlikely that new technologies will be transferred to developing economies on the back of a merger or acquisition. Vernon (1979: 199) and Lindert (1992: 107) indicate that when new technology is not crucial to comparative advantage of the corporation, it would migrate to countries that might have comparative advantage in other inputs such as labour. It is unlikely that mergers and acquisitions will lead to job creation. The functions of the newly acquired member of the multinational might be extended, although certain functions might be performed centrally to eliminate duplication. R ep ro du ce d by S ab in et G at ew ay u nd er li ce nc e gr an te d by th e P ub lis he r (d at ed 2 00 9) . 690 SAJEMS NS Vol 5 (2002) No 3 Multinational Enterprises and Transfer Pricing Salvatore (1987: 306) and Practice Note 7 (South Africa, 1999: 39) identify managerial expertise, technology, goods, parts and marketing intangibles as some of the goods and services that are transferred between the holding company and its foreign affiliate and on which the holding company expects a return. Within the transfer pricing paradigm, the return should be commensurate with the functions performed, assets used and the risk assumed by the various members of the multinational (South Africa, 1999: 34). Exchange controls have historically provided some protection against the more significant manipulation of transfer prices to transfer profits to lower tax jurisdictions. In anticipation of the relaxation of exchange controls and the envisaged adverse effect on the South African tax base, section 31 was introduced into the Act in 1995. Section 3 I enables the Commissioner to adjust the consideration in respect of a supply or acquisition of goods or services in terms of an international agreement between connected persons. Transfer Pricing The term transfer pricing describes the process by which entities set the prices at which they transfer goods or services between each other. The transfer prices adopted by a multinational have a direct bearing on the proportional profit it makes in each country it operates. If a non-market value9 is paid for the transfer of goods or services, the income attributed to each of the members of a multinational will be inconsistent with their relative economic contributions. This distortion will impact on the tax revenues and or tax liabilities in the relevant tax jurisdictions in which they operate. The concept of transfer pricing does not imply anything complex; it is in essence a simple concept. However, the determination of transfer prices in practice can be very complex and measurement problems may arise, mainly due to information constraints relating to a South African comparable. Practice Note 7 and the OECD guidelines on the other hand, provide practical guidelines to taxpayers for determining arm's length transfer prices. Although no statutory requirement has been placed on the South African taxpayer to document their respective transfer pricing practices, the need for documentation is evident from the approach the Commissioner will follow if such documentation does not exist. In view of the above, the taxpayer should make conscientious efforts to establish transfer prices that comply with the arm's length principle and prepare documentation \() to evidence such compliance. R ep ro du ce d by S ab in et G at ew ay u nd er li ce nc e gr an te d by th e P ub lis he r (d at ed 2 00 9) . SAJEMS NS Vol 5 (2002) No 3 691 Transfer Pricing Methodologies When selecting an ann's length transfer pricing methodology, taxpayers choose from those endorsed by SARS in Practice Note 7. Accordingly, the most appropriate method will be the one that produces the highest level of comparability based on facts and circumstances at hand, availability of data on which to base a comparability analysis and the nature and extent of any assumptions made in the study. The most appropriate method is selected by testing comparability. The challenge is to obtain the most reliable measure of ann's length results. Practice Note 7(South Africa, 1999: 10)" states that the assessment of comparability can be affected by the characteristics of goods or services, relative importance of functions perfonned, tenns and conditions of relevant agreements, relative risks assumed by the taxpayer, economic and market conditions and business strategies. The standard transfer pricing methods recognised by Practice Note 7 (South Africa, 1999: 17) are the comparable uncontrolled price method (CUP method), the resale price method (RP method), the cost plus method (CP method), the transactional net margin method (TNMM) and the profit split method. Section 31 of the Act does not impose a hierarchy of transfer pricing methods. However, in effect a hierarchy exists in that certain methods might provide a more reliable result. Although the Commissioner acknowledges (South Africa 1999: 14) that the use of a particular method will depend on the facts on hand and that the most reliable method will be the method that requires the least adjustments to enhance comparability. Testing the application of the various methodologies empirically, made apparent that methodology application is driven by the lack of comparable infonnation publicly available in South Africa. The CUP method is hardly used at all, the resale price and cost plus methods are used if the transfer pricing practitioners have access to international databases such as Compustat. The transactional net margin method and the profit split methods are used, although the latter is used with a degree of subjectivity. In tenns of reliability, comparability and ease of application, to test if connected parties' dealings are at ann's length, it should be attempted to test as high as possible in the income statement. The potential negative effect operating expenses might have on comparability is limited to a large extent. R ep ro du ce d by S ab in et G at ew ay u nd er li ce nc e gr an te d by th e P ub lis he r (d at ed 2 00 9) . 692 SAJEMS NS VolS (2002) No 3 Figure 1 Transfer pricing methodologies comparison mcup II Resale Price [lCOlt Plus mTNMM ClProfit SpUt S Point Scale Reliability ComparabUity Application The CUP method is the most reliable and the method that requires the highest level of comparability, whereas the TNMM method's application is relatively easy compared to the CUP method. Transfer Pricing Practice In practice, the traditional methods such as the CUP, resale price and cost plus might prove almost impossible to apply, due to information constraints. The lack of comparable uncontrolled transactions and published gross margins data, make it necessary to resort to the transactional profits methods such as the transactional net margin and profit split methods. The availability of data will probably determine methodology selection as South Africa is a relatively small economy and under certain circumstances reliable comparables may prove difficult, if not impossible to find. Applying a transfer pricing method to multiple comparable data after thorough consideration to the functions performed, assets used and risk assumed by the tested party should arrive at a result consistent with an arm's length outcome. Criteria for the selection of comparable finns from independent databases are based on functional similarity; that is, the extent to which the functions undertaken are similar to the functions being investigated. Databases used to perform comparability research classify companies by Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) codes and allow a keyword search to be perfonned. In the study, the March 2001 version of Standard & Poor's Research Insight (Compustat) (North American and Canadian) database was used. R ep ro du ce d by S ab in et G at ew ay u nd er li ce nc e gr an te d by th e P ub lis he r (d at ed 2 00 9) . SAJEMS NS Vol 5 (2002) No 3 693 Comparability searches provide profit level information of comparable companies operating in different economies, in this instance, the US and Canada. Comparability would be negatively affected if knowledge of prevalent risk in the market was disregarded. Conceptual ising national or sovereign risk within the transfer pricing context is not difficult. However, quantifying the difference in risk and making risk adjustments to the comparable dataset to enhance direct comparability, is complicated and requires a degree of subjective judgement. Risk Adjustment Various companies might be accepted on the basis of comparability. Profitability of comparable US companies should be adjusted by a country risk premium to enhance comparability. Using profitability level indicators of unadjusted US companies would be naIve and determining the arm's length range without due consideution of the perceived risks associated with investing capital in South Africa would certainly not enhance comparability. The difference in risk between the US market and the South African market is considered the country risk premium. The profitability of the comparable US companies in addition to the country risk premium will provide a reliable measure of arm's-length result for companies conducting their operations in these countries. Determining a risk adjustment premium is one aspect that complicates transfer pricing. Differences between inflation, short term interest rates and bond yields must be considered to provide for the market risk element within national economies. Multinationals' operations are diverse, functional activities stretch across industries, sectors and product ranges, and an approach must be found that accurately measures the risk-return trade-off and the effect diversification has on the actual rate of return. The risk-return relation is often seen within the context of high returns associated with high risk. Alternative theories have been documented with the Bowman paradox (Kim et al., 1993: 275) postulating that companies with high returns can have low risk. Global market diversification provided companies with strategic options and opportunities (Kim et al., 1993: 276) beyond domestic companies and might explain the high return low risk profile. The approach followed in the study was based on testing the risk-return trade off on a stand-alone basis, extending the research to incorporate diversification across industry sectors and applying the stand-alone test of risk and diversification to a hypothetical South African company. The aim is to R ep ro du ce d by S ab in et G at ew ay u nd er li ce nc e gr an te d by th e P ub lis he r (d at ed 2 00 9) . 694 SAJEMS NS Vol 5 (2002) No 3 investigate the link between diversification strategies of the comparable datasets as identified during a multinational functional comparability analysis, as part of a transfer pricing study and their risk-return performance. Following accepted practice in diversification research, company risk was measured by the standard deviation ofROA over the study period, 1995 to 2000. The methodology used in determining the hypothetical risk adjustment is as follows: i. Determine SIC codes applicable to identified functions to set parameters for comparable industry research. ii. Query data sources (Compustat database used in this study) based on identified SIC codes to determine potential comparable companies to be used in the study. iii. Select comparables based on independence, market level comparability and product similarities. iv. Calculate ROA as comparable profit level (return) indicator. v. Calculate industry risk as the standard deviation of ROA over the period under investigation. If this approach does not suffice, alternatives will be explored. vi. Calculate weighted industry return of comparable companies based on the ratio of actual sales to total sales as determined by data analysis. vii. Calculate the weighted industry risk by making use of the standard deviation based on ROA of the comparables for the period under investigation. According to Kim et al. (1993: 275) the weighted industry risk is an appropriate measure of risk. Brigham et al. (1999: 172) state that in the determination ofthe risk in a portfolio context, the standard deviation of the portfolio, as a measure of portfolio risk, is generally not the weighted average of the standard deviation of the individual assets in the portfolio. The portfolio's standard deviation is generally smaller than the weighted average of the asset's standard deviation. Research Results The SIC codes used in the analysis were major groups 50 and 65 to test the diversity risk trade-off assumption. Both functions being tested are not asset- intensive with plant, property and equipment ratio to sales less than 20 per cent. Undertaking the comparability search, 25 and 54 potentially comparable companies were identified. Screening measures to ensure comparability were based on independence, functional and product similarity. From the ROA summary, there is a distinct difference in realised return between the two industry sectors. This difference (amount of spread) in realised returns R ep ro du ce d by S ab in et G at ew ay u nd er li ce nc e gr an te d by th e P ub lis he r (d at ed 2 00 9) . SAJEMS NS Vol 5 (2002) No 3 695 within, as well as between the sectors, would be a good measure of the inherent risk within these industry sectors. Industry risk can be measured on a stand- alone basis by using the standard deviation ofROA within the industry sectors. Table 1 Standard deviation ROA 1998 1999 '""'-'--'---t--'-'-'--'--+- 2000 10.62% 11.84% 10.87% % 16.06% 6.11% 13.00% Although the one industry sector is not discernably riskier than the other according to the standard deviation, on average major group 65 has the lower standard deviation and could be regarded not as risky as major group 50. The rate of return within portfolio context, is merely the weighted average rate of return for the specific year on the individual functions performed and assets used in terms of the portfolio. However, the risk of this hypothetical portfolio is not the weighted average of the standard deviation of the individual functions being performed in the portfolio. The portfolio's standard deviation will probably be smaller than the weighted average standard deviation of the assets in the portfolio. Functions' rate of return might move counter cyclically to each other. Measuring this tendency of functions' return could be achieved by making use of the correlation coefficient r. In reality, whilst performing various functions, it would be unlikely that the different functions would be perfectly positively correlated. However, positive correlation exists and on average, combining positively correlated functions in a portfolio sense, would reduce risk but would certainly not eliminate it. It can be deduced that some risk remains even with diversification, but the risk might be smaller than it would be if the functions were seen in isolation. An amount of risk can be eliminated; the diversifiable risk can be managed. However, the remaining portion of risk, market risk, stems from factors that influence all participants in the economy including war, recessions, inflation and interest rates. It is apparent that investors demand a premium for assuming risk. Within the context of transfer pricing, risk should not be regarded functionally on a stand- alone basis, but rather within the wider context of operations where the company performs various functions, each exposed to a different level of risk. R ep ro du ce d by S ab in et G at ew ay u nd er li ce nc e gr an te d by th e P ub lis he r (d at ed 2 00 9) . 696 SAJEMS NS Vol 5 (2002) No 3 Two industry sectors were identified; returns and industry risk were tested for each. Major group 65 realised lower returns and was exposed to lower industry risk measured by the standard deviation on a stand-alone basis. This illustrates the risk-return assumption on a stand-alone basis. Making use of a weighting scale based on functional sales' contribution to total sales of the two functions performed by the business units in different industry sectors would allow for an analysis of the risk-return and industry diversification. A similar approach to the one followed testing the risk-return relationship in a stand-alone basis will be followed to determine a hypothetical risk adjustment factor. First, the weighted industry return of a company that diversified into industry sectors 50 and 65 was tested and second, the weighted industry risk is measured to get a better understanding of the diversification effect across industry on risk. Table 2 Weighted industry ROA and standard deviation 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Diversified - ROAunAdu 0.171747 0.146965 0.175535 0.144309 0.107208 0.109946 Diversified - st